+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality...

Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality...

Date post: 01-Apr-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
23
Clark University Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia Author(s): Henry Wai-chung Yeung and George C. S. Lin Source: Economic Geography, Vol. 79, No. 2 (Apr., 2003), pp. 107-128 Published by: Clark University Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/30032920 Accessed: 15/04/2010 02:56 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=clark. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Clark University is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Economic Geography. http://www.jstor.org
Transcript
Page 1: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

Clark University

Theorizing Economic Geographies of AsiaAuthor(s): Henry Wai-chung Yeung and George C. S. LinSource: Economic Geography, Vol. 79, No. 2 (Apr., 2003), pp. 107-128Published by: Clark UniversityStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/30032920Accessed: 15/04/2010 02:56

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available athttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unlessyou have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and youmay use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained athttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=clark.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printedpage of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range ofcontent in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new formsof scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

Clark University is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Economic Geography.

http://www.jstor.org

Page 2: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

Economic Geography 79(2): 107-128, 2003. O 2003 Clark University. http://www.clarku.edu/econgeography

Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia

Henry Wai-chung Yeung Department of Geography, National University of Singapore,

1 Arts Link, Singapore 117570 [email protected]

George C. S. Lin

Department of Geography, University of Hong Kong, Pokfulam Road, Hong Kong SAR

[email protected]

Abstract: Economic geographies of Asia are highly fascinating, not the least because Asia has increasingly emerged as a significant economic player in all spheres of global competition: production, consumption, and circulation. This dynamic mosaic of economic landscapes in Asia was further complicated during the 1997-1998 economic crisis and thereafter. While some aspects of these economic geographies of Asia have

already received research attention, many complex economic geographic processes in Asia have been undertheorized in the literature. This agenda-setting article makes two critical observations. First, the theorization of dynamic economic changes in Asia needs to be more critical of economic geography theories developed elsewhere in the Anglo-American context. The Asian case may significantly challenge existing theories in economic geography. Second, certain geographic processes in Asia require fundamentally new approaches to theorization that may contribute to the develop- ment of broader theories in economic geography. The economic dynamism of Asia has provided a useful site for the development of theory and empirical understanding in contemporary economic geography. To support our arguments and observa- tions, we discuss the situatedness and specificity of influential theories of economic geography and offer some constructive suggestions for an intellectual

agenda for developing new theories in economic geography.

Key words: economic geography, Asia, theory, epistemology, intellectual agenda.

The articles in this special issue originated in a special session held at the 98th annual meeting of the Association of American Geographers, Los Angeles, 19-23 March 2002. We thank Fulong Wu for co-

organizing the session and all presenters for their participation. The submitted papers went through a

rigorous review process and different rounds of revisions. We are grateful to the authors, numerous reviewers, and editorial board members for their cooperation and hard work in putting this issue together. An earlier version of this introductory article was presented as a keynote address at the annual

meeting of the Canadian Association of Geographers, Toronto, Canada, 29 May-i June 2002. Henry Yeung thanks Philip Kelly and Glen Norcliffe for their kind invitation to attend this conference and the CAG Study Group on Social and Economic Change for funding his travel. David Edgington, the

paper's discussant, provided useful comments. We also received helpful comments from David Angel, Tim Bunnell, and Adrian Smith. This article was subsequently presented to various audiences in the United Kingdom and we owe a great deal to insightful comments from the participants: Raymond Bryant, David Demeritt, Chris Hamnett, Keith Hoggart, and Geoff Wilson, of King's College London; Ash Amin, Emma Mawdsley, Joe Painter, and Janet Townsend, of the University of Durham; and Clive Barnett, Keith Bassett, Tony Hoare, Simon Naylor, Nigel Thrift, and Adam Tickell, of the University of Bristol. While we have incorporated their comments as much as possible into this version, none of these institutions and individuals should be responsible for any shortcomings of this article.

107

Page 3: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

108 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003

For a long time economic geographers have almost taken for granted that theories

emerging from geographic studies of Silicon Valley or the City of London have been natu- ralized unequivocally as what may be termed "mainstream economic geography"-the influential core of Anglo-American economic

geography.' One needs only to glance through recent major collections of economic geography published in English (e.g., Bryson, Henry, Keeble, and Martin 1999; Clark, Feldman, and Gertler 2000; Sheppard and Barnes 2000) to reinforce the point that an overwhelming majority of the chapters tend to address theoretical and empirical issues specific to only a handful of advanced industrialized economies (see Yeung 2002a). This heavy concentration of economic geography theories in relation to their sites of production and dissemination has certainly shaped the directions of research in economic geography in many other countries and/or regions, albeit each at a different pace of diffusion and adoption. Studies of economic geography of other localities have not only tended to follow the "templates" that have been institution- alized and legitimized by this mainstream economic geography, but also have earned the strange title as some kind of "regional geography." In this vein, geographic research on industrial locations in China and export-

SWe use the term economic geography to refer to a discipline that deals with "the nature of world areas in their direct influence upon the produc- tion of commodities and the movement of goods" (Gotz, quoted in Barnes 2001c, 531) or what Scott (2000, 484) described as "the spatial and loca- tional foundations of economic life." Economic geography supposedly has a wide spectrum of subjects, ranging from agrarian and pastoral economies to resource utilization and changes in land use. However, we have observed that major theoretical advancements in economic geography in recent decades have been overwhelmingly focused on the transformation of industrial economies in North America and Western Europe. We propose that economic geographers need to move forward along the lines of recon- structing a kind of global economic geographies that are broader in perspective and more inclu- sive in both sectoral and geographic terms.

processing zones in Malaysia is often labeled as "Asian geography"; studies of the informal sector in Africa, as "African geography"; and

investigations of gender relations in Latin American labor markets, as "Latin American

geography." Potter (2001, 423; original italics) vividly described this bias in economic

geography as follows:

Those who work outside the Euro-North American orbit are excluded, or at best margin- alized, from the specialisms which see them- selves making up the core of the discipline of Geography. Quite simply, they are regarded as "ists" of the Latin American, Caribbean, African or Asian variety. If they endeavour to be comprehensive in their consideration of other regions of the globe, then they may qualify as the ultimate "ists": as full-blown "developmentalists"!

Such geographic specificity in

constructing both leading theories in economic geography and the "other geogra- phies" or "distant geographies" perhaps should not be surprising in light of the insti- tutionalization of geography as an academic discipline (see Johnston 1997; Barnes 2000; Scott 2000). Few economic geographers have attempted to contextualize this speci- ficity in the epistemology of economic geog- raphy and to offer suggestions for what may be done to redress it (see Yeung 2001a; Olds and Poon 2002; Smith 2002). In this article, we focus on a particular historical- geographic moment-the rise of Asia-and outline our vision for the development of theory in economic geography emanating from a rapidly growing number of geogra- phers working on the dynamic economic transformations of Asia. We term this effort

"theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences and trajectories of economic trans- formations in Asia. There is thus no singular economic geography of Asia but, rather, multiple pathways and diversities. By the same token, there should be many models and theories of these transformations in economic geography.

Page 4: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

VOL. 79 No. 2 THEORIZING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHIES OF ASIA 109

This article has two interrelated aims. First, we offer a brief critique of leading theoretical perspectives in Anglo-American economic geography. We identify their inherent limits in relation to their analyt- ical focus on historically and geographi- cally specific industrial transformations. Second, we outline our advocacy for more theorization in future research on economic

geographies of Asia. In steering the direc- tion and content of this special issue, we were particularly driven by two concurrent trends--one intellectual and another empir- ical-that we believe will powerfully shape the future of economic geography. On the intellectual front, our efforts and that of the contributors to this special issue echo the recent institutional turn in economic geog- raphy from nationalistic economic geography to global economic geographies. Traditional economic geography has been concerned mainly with explaining patterns and

processes within national space-economies. When such work is done within the Anglo- American countries, the subsequent models and theories are deemed universally true and applicable. More recently, however, an increasing number of economic geogra- phers have begun to question seriously the situatedness of theories and knowledge of the global economy. This new kind of economic geography has become much more inclusive and open to ideas and opin- ions conceived outside a few dominant cores. This turn clearly supports Taylor's (1996) broader call for abandoning the "embedded statism" in the social sciences to open up to the new intellectual spaces of global economic geographies. It is interesting to note that this opening up in geography has been well recognized by scholars from other social scientific disciplines. For example, political theorist Martin Shaw (2000, 73-74; original italics) argued, in the context of

geography's role in globalization debates, that

[t]he disciplines of anthropology, geography and international relations have shown greater openness to global understanding than economics, politics and sociology, the histor-

ically defining fields of social science. Interestingly, the former are all fields in which historically the national-international nexus was formerly not just a methodological bias, but more or less explicitly constitutive. The openness of both social anthropology and geog- raphy to globalization debates follows their abandonment of nineteenth- and early twen- tieth-century nationalist and imperialist constructions of their subjects. These subjects underwent theoretical and ideological trans- formations earlier in the post-war period, which have prepared the way for the recog- nition of globalization.

In redressing the thematic (industrial) and

geographic (Anglo-American) specificity in mainstream theories of economic geography, we aim to develop what Slater (1999, 67) called "reverse discourses" in order for non- Western work to "theorize back" at the West. These discourses should constitute "coun- terposed imaginations and visions emanating from different sites of experience and subjec- tivity." Similarly, Appadurai (1999, 237) argued for a conversation about and an imag- ination of research "to which scholars from other societies and traditions of inquiry could

bring their own ideas about what counts as new knowledge and about what communi- ties of judgment and accountability they might judge to be central in the pursuit of such knowledge."

This last point relates to the second concurrent trend in the empirical realm that has made the economic geographies of Asia highly fascinating. Asia has increasingly emerged as a significant economic player in different spheres of global competition: production, consumption, and circulation. This dynamic mosaic of economic landscapes in Asia was further complicated during the 1997-1998 economic crisis and afterward. Although some aspects of these economic

geographies of Asia have already received research attention, many complex economic geographic processes in Asia have been undertheorized in the geographic literature, which leads to two important possibilities for future research. First, the theorization of dynamic economic changes in Asia needs to be more critical in adopting economic

Page 5: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

110 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003

geography theories developed elsewhere in the Anglo-American context. As shown in the four articles in this special issue, the "Asian" case can significantly challenge existing theories in mainstream economic geography. Second, the economic dynamism and geographic processes in Asia require a fundamentally new approach to theorization that may contribute to the development of broader theories in economic geography. Through this process, we may witness the

emergence of new kinds of theories that can account for differences and differentiation in global economic geographies-the distin-

guishing theme of economic geography reemphasized by Clark, Feldman, and Gertler (2000).

In the remainder of this article, we discuss the situatedness of mainstream theories of economic geography and show how Asia has been theorized in mainstream economic

geography. We then examine how economic geographers may move from straightforward applications of' "Western" theories in main- stream economic geography to the critical

interrogation of these theories and the devel- opment of new theories through carefully grounded empirical research. We also offer some constructive suggestions for an intellectual agenda for developing new theo- ries in economic geography.

Geographies of Economic Geography: The Situatedness of Theories

We have now been well told by historians of economic geography that dominant theo- ries have always emerged from particular historical and geographic contexts (see Barnes 1996; Scott 2000). From locational models to spatial divisions of labor and from flexible specialization to local embedded- ness, leading theories of economic geography have their peculiar histories and geographies. Their histories are very much outcomes of the conscious efforts of individual economic geographers in the context of creative tensions among different "paradigms" (see Barnes and Curry 1983; Sidaway 1997; Thrift

and Walling 2000; Barnes 2001b). In this and the next sections, we attempt to answer two related questions to explore further the situatedness of dominant theories in economic geography. First, why are economic geography theories, from the quantitative revolution and Marxism to flex- ible specialization and the recent "cultural turn," so dominant as if they were universal theories capable of explaining diverse economic geographic processes? Yet, why are they so little used in the economic

geographic studies of other regions? Second, why have theoretical insights that have emerged from area studies and regional geography failed so far to capture the imaginations of mainstream economic geog- raphers?

There is a noticeable gap between the obsession of some mainstream economic geographers with the universalization of their Western-based theories and the preoc- cupation of regional geographers with the task of meticulously sorting out the geographic specificities of particular coun- tries or regions. We argue that this gap has been the consequence of historically specific circumstances, including the legacy of earlier colonialism, or what Hudson (1977, 12) referred to as the interests of European and American imperialism in world commerce and territorial acquisition (see also Barnes 2001c, 530); provincialism during and after the Vietnam War; linguistic and cultural barriers; and an intellectual environment that was dominated, until recently, by the Enlightenment and modernization school of thought. The persistence of this bifurca- tion in epistemology and methodology has led to the phenomenon of "the tragedy of the commons" in economic geography- theories that are derived from specific histor- ical geographies become universalized among the former group of economic geog- raphers, and descriptive specificities of regional geographies have little generality to offer to geographic studies in other coun- tries and/or regions. We believe that such a tragedy of the commons has severely hindered the growth of a new kind of economic geography, known as global

Page 6: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

VOL. 79 No. 2 THEORIZING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHIES OF ASIA

111

economic geographies, that must be built on

comparative understandings of economic

geographic processes emerging from and

interconnecting different regions of the

global economy. In Table 1, we summarize several leading

theoretical perspectives in mainstream economic geography that rose to promi- nence during the past two decades or so.

111

In constructing this table, we did not intend to "fit" different economic geography theo- ries (and their proponents) into specific boxes. Rather, the table should be read as a heuristic device for the purpose of this article. Furthermore, we did not intend the table or the finality and "paradigmatic" nature of these theoretical themes to be complete and all-inclusive. We regret that

Table 1

Leading Theoretical Perspectives in Economic Geography and Their Historical Geographies

Geographic Specificities Theoretical Perspectives Period of Prominence Key Authors of Research

1. Location theory and the behavioral location model

2. Spatial divisions of labor

3. Flexible specialization and new industrial spaces

4. Networks and embedded- ness

5. Regional agglomerations and clusters

6. Regulation theory and

governance

7. Cultural economies

1960s-1970s

1980s

1980s-1990s

1990s

mid-1990s

mid-1990s

mid-1990s

Brian Berry Peter Haggett Peter Dicken F. E. I. Hamilton Doreen Massey Gordon Clark Allen Scott Michael Storper David Harvey Richard Florida Meric Gertler Andrew Sayer Nigel Thrift Peter Dicken Gernot Grabher

Philip Cooke Ash Amin Michael Storper Allen Scott

Philip Cooke Kevin Morgan Anders Malmberg Peter Maskell

Ray Hudson

John Lovering Jamie Peck Adam Tickell Erik Swyngedouw Nigel Thrift Ash Amin Erica Schoenberger Linda McDowell Trevor Barnes

J.-K. Gibson-Graham

Roger Lee

Jane Wills

United States United Kingdom

United Kingdom United States United States

Italy Germany

United Kingdom Europe

United States United Kingdom Europe

France United Kingdom Europe United Kingdom United States and Canada (to a lesser extent)

Page 7: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

112 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003

certain key histories of (mainstream) economic geography have not been included in this table and the text. For example, one may notice that most theoretical perspec- tives in Table 1 deal with industries, rather than rural economies, natural resources and land use, financial markets, development processes, and so on. Yet largely for reasons

suggested later, these theoretical perspec- tives are the most influential in contempo- rary economic geography as if they consti- tute the core of economic geography. Although a full critique of this industrial bias in contemporary economic geography is

beyond the scope of this article, it is clear that even within Anglo-American economic geography, there is a significant marginal- ization of research into spheres of economic activities other than industries. This obser- vation, we believe, has a lot to do with the historical and geographic specificity of these theoretical perspectives.

Bearing in mind these caveats, we point out that none of the major proponents of these theories of economic geography orig- inated from outside the Anglo-American countries. Neither do most of them conduct their empirical research outside these advanced industrialized economies. This

sweeping generalization points to the geographic specificities of these leading or dominant theories-they have been really leading and dominant among English- speaking economic geographers (see also Olds and Poon 2002). Location theory, for

example, originates from what Barnes (2001a, 546) termed "epistemological theorizing," which assumes "that spatial economic phenomena could be expressed in an explicitly abstract, formal, and ratio- nalist vocabulary and directly connected to the empirical world." This assumption allows for location theory to be universally gener- alizable from one geographic site to another. We should therefore expect it to be well

applied in research on the economic geog- raphy of Asia. The reality, however, seems to work on the contrary. With the exception of G. William Skinner's (1964) influential work on marketing and social structure in rural China (see Cartier 2001 for a critique),

much of the research in economic geography in Asia during the 1960s and the 1970s remained descriptive and aligned with area studies and regional geography (Spencer 1954; Spate and Learmonth 1967; Ginsburg and Brush 1958; McGee 1967; Wheatley 1971; Murphey 1953; McGee and Yeung 1977).

Subsequent critiques of location theory and its variant in the behavioral locational model by such radical economic geographers as Massey (1973, 1984) and Walker and

Storper (1981) led to the development of alternative theories on how to explain spatial economic phenomena. On the basis of their empirical studies of (de)industrialization in the United Kingdom and the United States, Clark (1981), Massey (1984), and Storper and Walker (1989) arrived at their respec- tive theories of spatial divisions of labor and spatial switching by capital (see Table 1). These theories attempted to explain why (de)industrialization occurred in some but not all regions in the United Kingdom and the United States. The objective of the project was to specify the interdependent links between social processes of capitalist production and the spatial structures and distribution of industry, work, and classes. Although these theoretical perspectives on spatial divisions of labor generated much heated and exciting debates in subsequent studies of industrial restructuring and specific localities, most of these studies remained grounded in the industrial land- scapes of the Anglo-American countries. Given their prominence in the mainstream economic geography of the 1980s, we would expect these perspectives to be universally applied to other research and empirical contexts. To the best of our knowledge, however, there has not been a significant diffusion of these theories of economic geog- raphy to geographic studies of other regions and countries that are concurrently experi- encing dramatic processes of industrializa- tion, economic restructuring, and rural development. This observation is certainly applicable to studies of the economic geography of Asia, although it is equally interesting to note that some Asian

Page 8: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

VOL. 79 No. 2 THEORIZING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHIES OF ASIA 113

economies experienced unprecedented processes of industrialization during exactly the same periods-the 1970s and the 1980s. Mainstream economic geography thus fails to extend its analytical lens to examine geographic industrialization-let alone other aspects of economic transformations (e.g., rural changes and deprivation)-in other

developing regions of the world economy. In the next section we outline what theo- retical insights emerged from other social scientific studies of industrialization in Asia during these two decades.

Into the 1990s, mainstream economic geography certainly experienced a kind of intellectual renaissance through which a plethora of complementary theoretical

perspectives were proposed-flexible specialization, networks and embeddedness, agglomerations and clusters, and regulation and governance. As is summarized in Table 1, these perspectives were concerned with why certain territorial ensembles-- whether regions or new industrial spaces-- emerged as the motors of growth in a partic- ular country. It is no historical coincidence that during the late 1980s and the 1990s, several regions in the United States and some European economies became the leading engines of growth in the global economy. These theories vividly mirrored the historical and geographic specificities of the global space-economy. On the basis of his empirical analysis of the growth of high-tech industries in California, Italy, and France, Scott (1988) argued that a major shift was under way in contemporary capi- talist industries-from mass production of the Fordist kind toward a post-Fordist form of flexible specialization and customization of production. These highly geographically specific observations led Scott (1988, 4; origi- nal italics) to conclude that "a series of new industrial spaces had come into existence and were beginning to form important alter- native centers of capitalist accumulation based on a strong social division of labor, proliferations of small to medium-sized industrial establishments, and the marked reagglomeration of production." Although Scott's conclusions were not entirely new

vis-d-vis Piore and Sabel's (1984) earlier

study of the Second Industrial Divide, his

arguments for the rise of new industrial

spaces did make a major impact on research in economic geography up to the mid-1990s (see a review in Yeung 1994).

New theoretical insights were also required to explain the geographic organi- zation of production through firms and networks in these so-called new industrial spaces. Geographic agglomeration, prox- imity, processes of tacit knowledge and learning, and cooperative networks were

conceptual categories proposed within this genre of theoretical and empirical research that has come to dominate much of Anglo- American economic geography since the late 1980s. More recent theoretical work on "relational assets," agglomeration economies, and institutional governance in the United Kingdom and the United States has rein- forced the resurgence of the "regional world" of production as the dominant research theme in mainstream economic geography (see Yeung 2000). This resurgence, however, must again be situated in its peculiar histor- ical and geographic contexts. Flexible production methods and agglomeration economies have been in existence for centuries, as found in craft industries and so on. The rise of these production methods and geographic economies to intellectual prominence within Anglo-American economic geography must have something to do with the "crisis of Fordism" during which an earlier wave of methods of mass production and economies of scale could no longer maintain a competitive edge with incumbent firms and corporations in advanced industrialized economies. This crisis, nevertheless, can also be understood from the historical perspective of the immense Japanese challenge to Anglo- American industrial might during the late 1970s and the 1980s (see the next section). These new theories of economic geog- raphy thus emerged as an unintended response to historical urgency-to explain the downfall of Fordist firms and indus- tries and the rise of new propulsive indus- tries (e.g., in Silicon Valley and elsewhere).

Page 9: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

114 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003 An important question remains: why did not these important and innovative theories in economic geography emerge from research on Fordism's competitors-Japan and the newly industrialized economies (NIEs) in Asia? Why did we not have economic

geography theories that examined the crisis of Fordism and the rise of new industrial spaces in relation to the growing economic might of Japan and the NIEs? We return to this question in the next section.

The geographic context of these theories in economic geography is equally intriguing. Two observations are critical here. First, most theoretical work was based on empir- ical studies of a few selected regions in advanced industrialized economies in the United States (e.g., Silicon Valley and Route 128) and Europe (e.g., the M4 corridor and Cambridge, in the United Kingdom, the Third Italy, Baden-Wiirttemberg in

Germany, and the Scientific City in France). This spatial selectivity of empirical cases places an upper limit on the applicability of these theories even to different regions of the same country, let alone countries with contrasting forms of capitalism (Clegg and Redding 1990; Whitley 1999; Stark and Bruszt 2001). The geographic specificity of these theories explains why certain (propul- sive) industries are privileged in their explanatory matrixes and why other impor- tant issues in economic geography are sidestepped. While flexible specialization may be crucial to understanding the economic transformation of the United States during the 1980s, one may surely argue that the transformation of agrarian economies under the auspices of neolib- eral economic policies may be equally signif- icant to the economic geographic under-

standing of many developing economies. We do not deny that a less-visible community of economic geographers, or those who have been branded as "development geographers" by the mainstream, have been studying the latter phenomenon. But their influence in economic geography remains limited precisely because mainstream economic geographers during the past two decades were narrowly focusing on a few industries

and regions in a handful of advanced economies. Second and relatedly, most leading proponents of these theories come from a few prestigious research departments in the United States and the United Kingdom. This geographic situatedness of authorship does not automatically invalidate the general applicability of their theories. But it does explain why certain theories emerge and become influential through more intensive interactions among like- minded scholars and research activities in these institutions. Their applicability to other geographic contexts needs to be interrogated and validated through carefully designed empirical research (see the articles in this special issue).

The situatedness of theories of economic geography is perhaps best illustrated by the recent "cultural turn" in economic geog- raphy toward a kind of "new economic geographies" that is much more reflexive and open in its nature and subject matter (Thrift and Olds 1996; Lee and Wills 1997; Yeung forthcoming). Indeed, Thrift and Olds (1996, 313) argued that we need to "make a space for new kinds of economic geography that can supplement or even replace the older forms of economic geography." In this process, Wills and Lee (1997, xvii) stated, we must appreciate how to "contextualize rather than to undermine the economic, by locating it within the cultural, social and political relations through which it takes on meaning and direction." According to Barnes (2001a, 551), this mode of "hermeneutic theorizing" differs significantly from the "epistemological theorizing" manifested in the quantitative revolution because it "[1] rejects fixed and final foundations ... [2] promotes experimentation and engagement with radically different vocabularies, pressing them as far as they will go ... [3] cultivates critical self-awareness of social and histor- ical location and recognizes its influence on knowledge ... [and] [4] is interested in

keeping the conversation going." Precisely because of the inherent reflexivity and open- ness in the new economic geographies, it is very difficult to summarize diverse strands of theories and empirical findings. At the

Page 10: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

VOL. 79 No. 2 THEORIZING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHIES OF ASIA 115

least, new economic geographers have refig- ured the economic through an excursion into the cultural and the political. As Barnes (1999, 17) noted, the basic explanatory cate-

gories become "social power, cultural

identity and institutional situatedness rather than economic ownership, universal defin- itions and individual agency." Several features of the new economic geographies include understanding the social embed- dedness of economic action, mapping shifting identities of economic actors, and

exploring the role of context in explaining economic behavior (see a review in Barnes 2001a; Yeung 2001b; forthcoming).

To sum up our sympathetic critique, mainstream economic geography, which was

developed in the Anglo-American countries, has experienced tremendous internal trans- formations and metamorphism during the

past four decades. Its theoretical core has moved from universalizing location theory during the quantitative revolution to

geographically specific theories of territorial development during the 1980s and the 1990s and, recently, to the more reflexive cultural turn that champions heightened sensitivity to the positionality of knowledge and theo- ries and the context in which these theo- ries emerge. This unprecedented intellec- tual movement in the epistemology of economic geography provides an exciting and important opportunity for us to recon- sider what theories of economic geography may be if we situate these theories in specific regions beyond the Anglo-American coun- tries (see the articles in this issue). More significant, we may have arrived at a time when new kinds of theories of economic geography are needed to account for the diversity of experience and transformations in the global economy. In this way, we may be able to construct genuine global economic

geographies that are attuned to the histor- ical and geographic specificities of our theo- ries and yet are capable of producing a much broader and comparative understanding of dramatic economic transformations in the new millennium. Before we theorize the economic geographies of Asia, it is impor-

tant for us to situate the region in the

emerging global economic geographies.

Situating Asia in Global Economic Geographies

As a prelude to our advocacy, we argue that if we look seriously beyond North America and Western Europe, we can undoubtedly find innovative theoretical insights from social science studies of other regions. Although these theoretical insights are no less historically and geograph- ically specific than those championed in mainstream economic geography, few have really originated from the work of economic

geographers or human geographers in

general. Instead, these theoretical insights have emerged mostly from developmental studies, anthropology and sociology, and

political economy. The situated nature of theoretical insights gathered from intensive studies of specific countries and/or regions should not be surprising if we take theories as hermeneutics or discursive formations that must be firmly grounded in material realities. These realities, however, differ from one historical moment to another and from one geographic setting to another. For example, whereas studies of Latin America have given rise to dependency theory, social science studies of Asia have similarly gener- ated many important theoretical insights, some of which have been followed up in the recent literature on economic geography: (1) the flying geese hypothesis (Hart- Landsberg and Burkett 1998; Edgington and Hayter 2000); (2) the new international divi- sion of labor (Frobel, Heinrichs, and Kreye 1980; Henderson 1989); (3) the devel- opmental state (Douglass 1994; Clark and Kim 1995; Brohman 1996; B.-G. Park 1998; Yeung 1999; Hsu and Cheng 2002); (4) social

capital (Leung 1993; Hsing 1998; Yeung 1998c; Olds 2001a); and, more recently, (5) transnationalism (Mitchell 1995; Olds and Yeung 1999; Ley 1999; Hsu and Saxenian 2000; Yeoh and Chang 2001; Zhou and Tseng 2001; G. C. S. Lin 2002a; Ma and Cartier 2003).

Page 11: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

116 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003

It is important to note, however, that in stark contrast to such theories as spatial divi- sions of labor and flexible specialization, these theoretical interrogations that are

grounded in Asia have not yet made a signif- icant impact on the development of main- stream economic geography described in the previous section. Instead, mainstream economic geography produces the "right" kind of theories, emanating from specific cases in the Anglo-American countries that remain to be tested as universal principles that are equally applicable to other, more

marginal, regions of the global economy. Economic geographers fail to heed

Appadurai's (1999, 230) telling warning, in the context of area studies, that "the more

marginal regions of the world are not simply producers of data for the theory mills of the North." How, then, has this highly unequal division of labor in research on economic geography emerged? We analyze this phenomenon in relation to three groups of geographers: (1) those who have engaged in mainstream enquiry, (2) those who have

engaged in area studies, and (3) those who have interrogated mainstream theories on the basis of the Asian experience.

Historically, Asia-just like Africa, Russia, and Eastern Europe-has never really attracted serious attention in mainstream economic geography, despite the discipline's celebrated interest in spatial differentia- tion and uneven development. Even if it did, Asia was treated as "the others" in "the Far East," previously a market to be opened up by colonialism and now posing a challenge to the industrial might in Europe and North America (see Amsden 2001). This tendency toward what Said (1978) termed "Orientalism" is no less significant in economic geography than in the humanities and the other social sciences. The real differ- ence, however, rests with the fact that Asia, along with Africa and Latin America, has been well studied by development specialists outside mainstream economic geography. Development is clearly central to the studies of economic geography and has always been one of the most exciting topics to university students of economic

geography in North America and Western

Europe. Ironically, development geography has been largely constituted outside main- stream economic geography, in which over-

whelming attention was devoted to indus- trial transformation in a few advanced economies and/or regions. This tension between development geography and economic geography has effectively margin- alized, if not excluded, Asia on the research agenda of economic geography.

Meanwhile, the empirical landscape of Asia has undergone dramatic transforma- tions since the 1970s, when Japan began to

emerge as the leading competitor and alter- native to the Anglo-American model of industrial capitalism. Ezra Vogel's (1979) influential book Japan as Number One was widely circulated in major intellectual and policy circles (that are often based in Washington, D.C., or the two Cambridges- one in England and the other in New England). Coupled with the emergence of Asian NIEs and the 1973 oil crisis, the rise of Japan triggered what was later concep- tualized as flexibility, post-Fordism, and globalization. It is interesting that the social scientists who first realized the indis-

pensable role of Japan and Asia in their theo- rization of global economic change came largely from area studies (Vogel 1989; Frank 1998), political science (Johnson 1982; Amsden 1989; Wade 1990), and economic sociology (Hamilton and Biggart 1988; Redding 1990).

More specifically, Japan was signifi- cantly featured in Piore and Sabel's (1984) The Second Industrial Divide and Womack, Jones, and Roos's (1990) The Machines That

Changed the World. Both MIT (Cambridge, Mass.) products have fundamentally shaped the subsequent debates about America's and, by extension, the world's industrial future.

During the same period (the 1980s and early 1990s), flexible specialization attracted substantial attention from economic geog- raphers (see Table 1). As we noted earlier, much of this work was inspired by empirical studies in California, the Third Italy, and other European regions, with limited applic- ability to the Asian context (see Patchell

Page 12: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

VOL. 79 No. 2 THEORIZING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHIES OF ASIA 117

1993a, 1993b; Eng 1997). In comparison with other major social sciences and with a few exceptions (e.g., Dicken 2003; Florida and Kenney 1990; Angel 1994), mainstream economic geography has certainly missed the boat in exerting its intellectual influence on major policy debates in the United States and Europe about the imminent economic challenge from Asia and elsewhere (cf. Reich 1991; Tyson 1993; World Bank 1993).

Vogel's influential warning in Japan as Number One, nevertheless, was short lived. With the downturn of the Japanese economy since the early 1990s and the Asian financial crisis during 1997-1998, few people now take seriously "the Asian miracles" and the dawn of "the Asian century." In

deconstructing "the myth of the Asian mira- cles" and the recent Asian economic crisis, mainstream economic geographers once again have failed to assume intellectual lead- ership in the broader social sciences. Curiously, it is the economists and their political science counterparts who have spearheaded the debates about the down- fall of Japan, the Asian economic crisis (Krugman 1994, 1998; Radelet and Sachs 1998; Wade and Veneroso 1998), and the

alleged rise of China as a threat (Vogel 1989; Goodhart and Xu 1996; Gertz 2000). Asking "Where have all the geographers gone?," Kelly, Olds, and Yeung (2001, x-xi) noted the absence of economic geographers in debates on the origins and impact of the Asian economic crisis. This lacuna is unfor- tunate because the crisis has much to offer to our understanding of the destabilization of a global financial architecture that is essentially built on the Bretton Woods insti- tutions. The sheer scale and scope of the crisis also provided a unique case for reworking the fundamental nature and future of global capitalism and its powerful institutions (see Stiglitz and Yusuf 2001; Wade 2002).

If mainstream economic geography cannot contribute much to our under- standing of the complex economic land- scapes of Asia (other than making available situated theories for superficial testing and straightforward applications elsewhere), can

we turn to area studies specialists (often known as development geographers), who

may offer such an understanding from a more grounded perspective? Asia has long been studied by human and economic geog- raphers who are interested in what cultural anthropologist Geertz (1973) termed a "thick description" of the land and the people outside Europe and North America. These geographers include indigenous scholars living in the regions and Western scholars who are interested in Asia. The former group has as sizable a population as their coun- terpart in Western Europe and North America. For instance, in the 1970s, over 6,000 professional geographers were working and teaching in socialist China, a size similar to if not greater than that in the United States (Pannell 1980, 176). Today, these Chinese professional geographers are all full- time researchers or university professors on the payroll of the state. Unfortunately, indigenous geographers in Asian countries have never been able to make any signifi- cant impact on mainstream enquiry in economic geography, largely because of the linguistic and cultural barriers as well as their different methodological traditions that have severely hindered meaningful scholarly exchanges with mainstream economic geog- raphers. On the other hand, Western scholars who are interested in Asia have been in the minority, preoccupied with sorting out the facts about a mysterious region in the "Far East" for the occasional curiosity of Western academics and continuous strategic and economic interests.

With the exception of perhaps the flying geese model, studies of the economic geography of Japan have never occupied any prime position equivalent to the global signif- icance of its national economy--not even in the flexible-specialization debate of the late 1980s and early 1990s.2 Geographic studies of China and India, whose combined

2 We regret that no article on Japan is included in this special issue, primarily because of insuf- ficient submissions. See recent work by Peck and Miyamachi (1994), Aoyama (2000), and Patchell (2002).

Page 13: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

118 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003

population constitutes nearly half the people of the world, have not generated research

published in English-language media that is

anywhere near the global significance of their population (see also Potter 2001). A

systematic search of articles published in the top 10 international journals in human geog- raphy from 1971 to 2000 found that only 66 articles, less than 1 percent of the total, dealt with the geography of China (G. C. S. Lin 2002b, 1813). Most of these studies were

empirical and "had shallow roots, received little nourishment and predictably bore few and unappetizing fruits" (Leeming 1980, 218). It has only been recently that geogra- phers who are interested in China have ventured to formulate some contextually sensitive theories (Fan, Ma, Pannell, and Tan forthcoming). The article by Yu Zhou and Tong Xin in this special issue thus signif- icantly contributes to the critique of the liter- ature on innovative regions that has primarily focused on localized endogenous factors in

sustaining innovation and regional develop- ment. Through their intensive research in a high-tech cluster in Beijing, Zhou and Xin found important interactive and interde-

pendent relations between local Chinese firms and global corporations in the joint development and commercialization of new information technologies. Their work complements the growing literature in economic geography on the critical impor- tance of nonlocal and decentralized learning and innovations for understanding regional development (e.g., Bunnell and Coe 2001; MacKinnon, Cumbers, and Chapman 2002).

A relatively small group of geographers have managed to develop original theoret- ical insights from their grounded studies of the Asian experience. Through their work, some grounded theories have emerged that have proved to be influential in certain subfields of human geography and, to a lesser extent, economic geography. A promi- nent example of such grounded theories is

Terry McGee's (1967, 1971) model of the Southeast Asian city (see also Armstrong and McGee 1985). In this morphological model of the internal structure of the city, McGee argued that different urban-economic activ-

ities have different spatial requirements and locational characteristics. For example, the informal sector tends to be located in the inner ring of the city. McGee's model has

subsequently been well applied to the geographic study of other Third World cities. More crucially, it originated from empir- ical studies of such cities; it was not devel- oped from studying the internal structures of advanced industrialized countries and then applied universally to Third World cities (akin to "epistemological theorizing" described earlier). Despite its generality in studies of urbanization and urban economic activities, McGee's model regrettably had

only a limited impact on mainstream economic geography of the 1970s and 1980s, which was preoccupied with radical Marxism and post-Fordism.

More recently, geographic studies of transnational business activities and transna- tionalism represent a significant attempt to

bring grounded theories of economic geogra- phies of Asia back into mainstream economic

geography (Leung 1993; Mitchell 1995; Yeung 1997; Zhou 1998; Hsu and Saxenian 2000; Olds 2001a). In particular, this body of literature on economic geography has

managed to blend into its theoretical frame- work two important ingredients-a special blend that is well grounded in the Asian context. First, it has brought to its analytical forefront the conceptual lenses of networks and embeddedness. Although these concep- tual categories did not originate from economic geographic studies of Asia, it is equally important to note that mainstream economic geographers did not develop them either. Indeed, these conceptual categories were first proposed by economic sociologists (Polanyi 1944; Granovetter 1985) and subse- quently introduced into and appropriated by mainstream economic geography during the debate on flexible specialization (see Dicken and Thrift 1992). It is true that main- stream economic geography has further enhanced the theoretical sophistication of both conceptual categories through major debates on industrial districts (Asheim 2000), the spatial transfer of technologies (Gertler 2001), organizational change (Yeung 1994,

Page 14: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

VOL. 79 No. 2 THEORIZING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHIES OF ASIA 119

1998a; Schoenberger 1997), and institu- tionalism in urban and regional development (Amin 1999). But then it must be equally valid to argue that economic geographic studies of Asia during the 1990s significantly advanced the spatialization of these concep- tual categories by theorizing the complex interactions among business networks, ethnicity/culture, embeddedness, and histor- ical specificity. This effort to theorize the

spatial rudiments of networks and embed- dedness is no less significant than that of debates on industrial districts and so on (see Table 1).

Second, economic geographic studies of Asian diasporas and their worldwide webs in Europe and North America have made significant inroads into the debate on glob- alization. In many ways, this body of litera- ture has contributed to enhancing economic

geography's growing visibility in social scien- tific debates on globalization. Once again, geographers have not been well represented among leading scholars of globalization: one can literally think of only two works by geog- raphers-Peter Dicken's (2003) Global Shift and David Harvey's (1989) The Condition of Postmodernity-that have represented different kinds of geographic takes on

globalization and thereby have attracted different sorts of audiences. Economic geog- raphers, however, have something signifi- cant to say about the geographic specifici- ties of globalization in relation to the origins, processes, and outcomes of globalization (see Amin 1997; Yeung 1998b, 2002b; Kelly 1999; Peck and Yeung 2003).3 Put in this perspec- tive, economic geography research on Asian diasporas and their global networks

3 The recent special issue of Economic Geography (2002) on geographies of global economic change represents an important mile- stone in this endeavor to put geographers back on the intellectual table of globalization studies. The special issue originated from the 2001 Leir conference (http://www.clarku.edu/leir/index. shtml) funded by the U.S. National Science Foundation, to rethink how to build theories of geographies of global economic change and to unveil the theoretical and methodological obstacles to the process of theory building.

augments well the key mission of main- stream economic geography to ground glob- alization processes in specific territorial ensembles and formations. It helps not only to demystify the "faceless" representations of globalization by its ultra-supporters (e.g., Ohmae 1990), but also to make economic geographers aware of the highly uneven

geographic outcomes of processes associ- ated with globalization. To us, this

geographic research on the globalization of Asia is worth as much intellectual capital as is other equally worthy research on global- ization in economic geography on changing urban and regional governance (Brenner 1999) and the organizations of economic activities (Dicken, Kelly, Olds, and Yeung 2001).

Theories Wanted! An Intellectual Agenda for Economic Geographies of Asia

We are at a critical juncture in economic

geography. There are unprecedented oppor- tunities for mainstream economic geogra- phers to give up our long-standing Euro- American-centric bias and develop theories that account for differences and differenti- ation in an era of accelerated globalization (cf. McGee 1991; Olds 2001b; Yeung 2001a). Although concerns about national security remain large, especially after the September 11, 2001, tragedy, earlier warped provin- cialism can no longer inhibit economic geog- raphers who actively study the rapid trans- formation of regional economies in Asia. Major funding agencies, such as the National Science Foundation in the United States, the Economic and Social Research Council in the United Kingdom, and the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council in Canada, have recently supported a growing number of research projects on Asia. Many leading universities in Anglo- America have actively recruited geographers to work on Asia. On the other side of the Pacific, most of the Asian economies have rearticulated themselves actively and openly to take part in the theater of global capital

Page 15: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

120 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003

accumulation. Indigenous geographers in Asia have made special attempts to over- come linguistic and cultural barriers as they forge bilateral scholarly linkages and research collaborations with geographers in the English-speaking world. Intellectually, universalism as one of the defining features of the Enlightenment and modernization school of thought has given way to a more

open-ended, plural, and contextually sensi- tive perspective on changing geographies in different world regions. Overall, the insti- tutional setting that previously separated the regional geography of Asia from mainstream economic geography in the Anglo-American countries has undergone a profound trans- formation in a direction favorable to the development of global economic geogra- phies.

Indeed, we are beginning to witness such a change in the direction of mainstream economic geography-more inclusive quality control in the academic production of knowl-

edge and more intellectual activities orga- nized outside the Anglo-American centers (see Barkema, 2001 for management studies). It is now incumbent on economic geographers who are interested in Asia to move from area studies to engage more actively with mainstream theoretical (re)constructions and interrogations. In this sense, there is a need for two intellectual movements. First, we must avoid uncritical applications of "Western" theories in main- stream economic geography as if these theo- ries were universally true. We need to inter- rogate these theories critically through our detailed research on economic geogra- phies of Asia. Through this process of crit- ical engagement with mainstream theories, we will be able not only to contribute to economic geography through our refinement and reconstruction of these theories, but also to understand the economic landscapes of Asia from a grounded perspective. Second, we must turn away from doing what may be termed "Asian economic geography" because such a parochial approach to economic geographies of Asia will provide few significant theoretical insights that may be useful in other geographic contexts.

Rather, we must endeavor to develop new theories, grounded in Asia, that might better inform our understanding of the "economic" in economic geography at large. Commenting on management studies, Barkema (2001, 616) noted that "[i]f different management concepts, theories, and practices apply in different cultural and institutional settings, international research might lead to novel theory and evidence showing how." In this sense, there should not be a "mainstream" economic geography on the basis of geographic divides (the Anglo-American centers versus the rest of the world) or thematic divides (industrial geography versus rural or development geog- raphy).

Why is such an intellectual turn toward more-inclusive global economic geographies necessary? As outlined briefly in the intro- duction, we believe that two important concurrent trends warrant this turn. The first trend is inevitably related to the globaliza- tion of knowledge and theories. Economic geographers from major Anglo-American centers are increasingly reaching out to Asia so that Asia can be integrated into their theo- ries and comparative analyses. As we argue later in the empirical realm, Asia is becoming too important to be ignored by economic geographers; it is, of course, also too impor- tant to be left to economic geographers only. This interest in Asia is exemplified by the recent work on flexibility, globalization, social capital, the cultural turn, the institutional turn, and the relational turn in economic geography. There is a growing interest among economic geographers in investi- gating territorial formations outside the Anglo-American contexts not as an anomaly or "other economic geography" from the perspective of Anglo-American economic geography, but instead as an original subject of inquiry in its own right. In this special issue, Smart and Lee critically engage one major theoretical strand in recent work in economic geography-regulation theory (see Table 1). Analyzing the vital role of real estate and property assets in Hong Kong's regime of accumulation and economic devel- opment during the past two decades, Smart

Page 16: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

VOL. 79 No. 2 THEORIZING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHIES OF ASIA 121

and Lee argue that the Hong Kong case should not be interpreted as an anomaly that deviates from the developmental trajectory of Anglo-American capitalism (see also Kerr 2002 for an analysis of Japan). The distinc- tive features of Hong Kong's regime of accu- mulation mean that it is indeed possible to "examine them as forerunners of a possible future property-based mode of regulation that might emerge in the West, and thus to diagnose the potential problems and oppor- tunities of such a path" (Smart and Lee 2003, 153; our emphasis). This "theorizing back" does not entail an unproblematical applica- tion of Western-centric theories per se. Instead, it uses conceptual apparatuses in these theories and empirical evidence in Asia to open up new directions for understanding the future of a variety of capitalisms that, no doubt, include the dominant Anglo- American genre.

This trend toward reaching out to Asia clearly does not represent a one-way flow in the globalization of knowledge and theories.

Today, more economic geographers who are interested in Asia are themselves Asians who have received their academic training in the Anglo-American centers (e.g., both authors of this article and most contributors to this special issue). This two-way intellectual fertilization allows them to benefit from the best of both worlds, so to speak. On the one hand, their particular backgrounds and origins in Asia enable their work to be firmly grounded in the material realities of Asia. Their emic understanding of Asia is difficult to emulate by geographers from other regional origins. On the other hand, these geographers are well equipped with sophisticated theoretical ideas and rigorous methodological procedures to enhance their research on economic geographies of Asia. They are certainly capable of growing out of Asia in their theoretical work to make major contributions to global economic geogra- phies. The articles in this special issue clearly exemplify this theoretical sophistication and methodological rigor among economic geog- raphers with Asian origins. For example, in explaining the recent liberalization and glob- alization of the South Korean automobile

industry, Park not only draws on theoretical ideas from the debate on the multiscalar

processes of globalization, but makes an orig- inal contribution to the literature by high- lighting the interscalar contestation between the national state and the local community in shaping the globalization processes of the industry. Although this national-local tension has been analyzed in the regional governance literature in economic geography (see Table 1), it has been mostly ignored in the

geographic studies of the impact of global- ization that have focused primarily on global- local tensions. Similarly, Poon and Thompson examine rigorously the concept of embeddedness in explaining the parent- subsidiary relationship in global corpora- tions. By unpacking the nature of the embeddedness of subsidiaries in the global networks of their parent companies, they draw our attention away from localized embeddedness that has been well docu- mented in the "new regionalism" literature (see Table 1) and contribute to our under- standing of the spatial organization of economic activities among global corpora- tions.

What in Asia attracts these economic geographers such that Asia becomes their key subject of inquiry? Our answer lies with the empirical trend toward the rapid and dramatic transformations in the economic landscapes of Asia in more recent decades. Asia has become a new site for theory devel- opment and empirical analysis in economic geography, as amply shown by the four excel- lent articles in this special issue. The impor- tance of this new site does not merely rest with its internal transformations. More crucially, Asia's importance for economic geography is predicated on its potential to facilitate the production of new theoretical insights and, in Slater's (1999) words, "counter discourses" that allow economic geographers to "theorize back" at our situ- ated knowledge emanating from Europe and North America (e.g., Park, Smart and Lee, and Zhou and Tong in this issue). As we noted earlier, Japan came to the forefront of social scientific inquiry during the 1980s because of its technological and economic

Page 17: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

122 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003

prowess. Together with insights from other newly industrialized economies (except Hong Kong), research on Japan's rapid post-World War II economic development points to the role of the developmental state. From an economic geography perspective, this theorization allows economic geography to reconsider location theory and the devel-

opment of industrial districts in novel ways that otherwise are unlikely to be achieved single-handedly through research on the

Anglo-American countries (see Markusen and Park 1993; Park and Markusen 1995). It allows for the attainment of the "translocal" understanding and development advocated by Smith (2002). This movement in theorization entails more than just using different empirical contexts for theorization. Rather, it produces a new kind of theory that

challenges, for example, the market-state dualism that is so ingrained in Anglo- American economic thinking, particularly among the neoliberals and "deregulation- ists" as labeled by Storper and Salais (1997, 246).

The rise of China since the late 1970s

represents another critical juncture in the

historiography of economic geography. For decades, the transformation of the Chinese space-economy under socialist authoritarianism has often been consid- ered to be too unique or peculiar and thus incompatible with the international norms and theoretical templates. The peculiarity of the Chinese experience, plus the lack of necessary information for meaningful studies, had made it extremely difficult for economic geography theorists and China geographers to have fruitful communication (see also Liu and Lu 2002). In recent

years, however, the Chinese space-economy has undergone profound structural and

spatial transformations as the post-Mao regime changed its approach from rigid utopian socialism to market-oriented prag- matism and from self-isolation to active

participation in globalization. A fascinating mosaic of plan and market, state and private sectors, central authoritarianism, and local corporatism has emerged to recontour the economic landscape (G. C. S. Lin 1997;

Marton 2000; Wei 2000). Given the funda- mental importance of both the Chinese culture and its restructured socialist insti- tutional setting to the transformation of the Chinese space-economy, incorporating the Chinese case into the development of

theory in mainstream economic geography seems to be timely and appropriate (e.g., Zhou and Tong in this issue).

Recent institutional and economic processes in China have not only invalidated our received wisdom of the geography of industrialization and economic transition, but also present themselves as fertile grounds for the development of new theo- ries. First, economic geographers have been accustomed to industrialization occurring virtually hand in hand with rapid urbaniza- tion and industrial activities located within urban areas. The core geographic argument for this trend toward urban-biased industri- alization is related to the Marshallian notion of agglomeration economies and, more recently, to increasing returns to scale, as demonstrated in the endogenous growth models (Martin and Sunley 1998). This abstract theorization of industrialization and regional growth, however, ignores historical

specificity and institutional rigidities that continue to exert strong effects in the case of China. A process of rural industrializa- tion has come to characterize the postreform pattern of industrialization in China through which the labor force is expected to stay in rural areas and industrial activities are brought to their doorsteps (Marton 2000). The enormous contributions of township and village enterprises (TVEs) to China's gross domestic products (GDP) and employment are one such indicator of the pervasive extent of rural industrialization. Widely scattered all over the vast countryside, the TVEs

generated over 30 percent of China's GDP and provided employment opportunities to 27 percent of the total rural labor force by the year 2000 (Editorial Board 2001, 4-5). This finding, of course, does not mean that urban-centered industrialization does not take place in China. But it does call for a reconceptualization of industrialization and urban-regional development in China

Page 18: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

VoL. 79 No. 2 THEORIZING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHIES OF ASIA 123

not as a special case of geographic industri- alization, but as an original subject of inquiry that may yield new theoretical insights into urbanization, industrialization, rural devel- opment, and agrarian change.

Second, China's transitional economy allows for new theories of economic transi- tion and organizational change that are just making significant inroads into the major social sciences, such as sociology and economics. Sociologists like Victor Nee (1989), Andrew Walder (1995), Nan Lin (1995; N. Lin and Bian 1991), and Doug Guthrie (1997) have worked on China's postreform development and collectively developed what may be termed the market- transition theory (see Stark 1996 and Pickles and Smith 1998 for the case of Eastern

Europe). This theory has certainly reinvig- orated sociological studies of changing social structures and economic organization in transitional economies. In economics, Barry Naughton (1991), Thomas Rawski (1994), Alwyn Young (2000), and others have shown how conventional neoclassical economics has failed to provide a valid theoretical model for explaining China's economic develop- ment (see also Amsden 1991; Young 1995). Alternative economic models are therefore called for that account for China's unprece- dented economic transformations. Although we have not yet observed a similar theoret- ical development and disciplinary impact of research on Asia in economic geography, we have certainly noticed some novel concep- tualizations arising from recent work on China (Hsing 1998; Olds 2001a; Fan 2002; Zhou and Tong in this issue) and other economies in East and Southeast Asia (Kelly 2001a, 2001b; Hsu and Saxenian 2000; Coe and Kelly 2002; Park in this issue).

To conclude this extended introduction to the special issue, we believe that theo-

rizing economic geographies of Asia is clearly an unfinished intellectual project. In fact, we go so far as to suggest that it simply marks the beginning of a new intellectual era for economic geography toward the develop- ment of global economic geographies. Economic geographies of Asia must not be a subject of theorization from the perspec-

tives of mainstream Anglo-American economic geography. But equally, they are too important to be left to Asian economic

geographers alone. Building on a growing body of economic geography research on Asia, what we aim to achieve through this

special issue is a further and, we hope, signif- icant step toward more genuine theoretical dialogues among economic geographers with different regional interests. This bold aim cannot be achieved without more theoret- ical work that is grounded in the material realities of Asia but that speaks to an audi- ence that is well tuned into the transmission frequency of global economic geographies. The future of economic geography must be bright and exciting. In this sense, we fully concur with Barnes and Sheppard's (2000, 6; our emphasis) assessment: "There is a Chinese saying: 'May you live in inter- esting times.' Our argument is that they are here now in economic geography." Obviously, we-both ethnic Chinese

writers--cannot agree more.

References

Amin, A. 1997. Placing globalization. Theory, Culture and Society 14:123-37.

-. 1999. An institutionalist perspective on regional economic development. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 23:365-78.

Amsden, A. 1989. Asia's next giant: South Korea and late industrialization. New York: Oxford University Press.

-. 1991. Diffusion of development: The late industrializing model and greater Asia. American Economic Review 81:282-6.

-. 2001. The rise of "the rest": Challenges to the West from late-industrializing economies. New York: Oxford University Press.

Angel, D. P. 1994. Restructuring for innova- tion: The remaking of the U.S. semiconductor industry. New York: Guilford Press.

Aoyama, Y. 2000. Networks, keiretsu and loca- tions of the Japanese electronics industry in Asia. Environment and Planning A 32:223-44.

Appadurai, A. 1999. Globalization and the research imagination. International Social Science Journal 51:229-38.

Armstrong, W., and McGee, T. G. 1985. Theatres of accumulation: Studies in Asian and Latin American urbanization. London: Methuen.

Page 19: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

124 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003

Asheim, B. T. 2000. Industrial districts: The contributions of Marshall and beyond. In The Oxford handbook of economic geography, ed. G. L. Clark, M. A. Feldman, and M. S. Gertler, 413-31. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford

University Press. Barkema, H. 2001. From the editors. Academy

of Management Journal 44:615-17. Barnes, T. J. 1996. Logics of dislocation: Models,

metaphors, and meanings of economic space. New York: Guilford Press.

-. 1999. Industrial geography, institutional economics and Innis. In The new industrial

geography: Regions, regulation and institu- tions, ed. T. J. Barnes and M. S. Gertler, 1-22. London: Routledge.

-. 2000. Inventing Anglo-American economic geography, 1889-1960. In A

companion to economic geography, ed. E.

Sheppard and T. J. Barnes, 11-26. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell.

-. 2001a. Retheorizing economic geog- raphy: From the quantitative revolution to the "cultural turn." Annals of the Association of American Geographers 91:546-65.

-. 2001b. Lives lived and lives told:

Biographies of the quantitative revolution. Environment and Planning D: Society and

Space 19:409-29. -. 2001c. In the beginning was economic

geography-a science studies approach to disci-

plinary history. Progress in Human Geography 25:521-44.

Barnes, T. J., and Curry, M. 1983. Towards a contextualist approach to geographical knowl-

edge. Transactions of the Institute of British

Geographers 8:467-82. Barnes, T. J., and Sheppard, E. 2000.

Introduction: The art of economic geography. In A companion to economic geography, ed. E. Sheppard and T. J. Barnes, 1-8. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell.

Brenner, N. 1999. Globalization as reterritorial- isation: The European re-scaling of urban

governance in the European Union. Urban Studies 36:431-51.

Brohman, J. 1996. Postwar development in the Asian NICs: Does the neoliberal model fit

reality? Economic Geography 72:107-30.

Bryson, J.; Henry, N.; Keeble, D.; and Martin, R., eds. 1999. The economic geography reader: Producing and consuming global capitalism. Chichester, U.K.: John Wiley & Sons.

Bunnell, T. G., and Coe, N. M. 2001. Spaces and scales of innovation. Progress in Human Geography 25:569-90.

Cartier, C. 2001. Globalizing South China. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell.

Clark, G. L. 1981. The employment relation and spatial division of labor: A hypothesis. Annals of the Association of American

Geographers 71:412-24. Clark, G. L.; Feldman, M. A.; and Gertler, M. S.,

eds. 2000. The Oxford handbook of economic geography. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

Clark, G. L., and Kim, W. B., eds. 1995. Asian NIEs in the global economy. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Clegg, S. R., and Redding, S. G., eds. 1990. Capitalism in contrasting cultures. Berlin: de Gruyter.

Coe, N. M., and Kelly, P. F. 2002. Languages of labour: Representational strategies in

Singapore's labour control regime. Political

Geography 21:341-71. Dicken, P. 2003. Global shift: Transforming the

world economy. 4th ed. London: Sage. Dicken, P.; Kelly, P.; Olds, K.; and Yeung,

H. W.-c. 2001. Chains and networks, territo- ries and scales: Towards an analytical frame- work for the global economy. Global Networks 1:89-112.

Dicken, P., and Thrift, N. 1992. The organiza- tion of production and the production of orga- nization: Why business enterprises matter in the study of geographical industrialization. Transactions, Institute of British Geographers 17:279-91.

Douglass, M. 1994. The "developmental state" and the NIEs of Asia. Environment and Planning A 26:543-66.

Economic Geography 2002. Special issue on global economic change. 78(3).

Edgington, D. W., and Hayter, R. 2000. Foreign direct investment and the flying geese model: Japanese electronics firms in the Asia Pacific. Environment and Planning A 32:281-304.

Editorial Board. 2001. Almanac of China's town-

ship and village enterprises (2001). Beijing: China Agricultural Press.

Eng, I. 1997. Flexible production in late indus- trialization: The case of Hong Kong. Economic Geography 73:26-43.

Fan, C. C. 2002. The elite, the natives, and the outsiders: Migration and labor market segmen- tation in urban China. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 91:103-24.

Fan, C. C.; Ma, L. J. C.; Pannell, C. C.; and Tan, K. C. Forthcoming. China geography in North America. In Geography in America at

Page 20: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

VOL. 79 No. 2 THEORIZING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHIES OF ASIA 125

the dawn of the 21st century, ed. G. L. Gaile and C. J. Willmott. New York: Oxford

University Press. Florida, R., and Kenney, M. 1990. The break-

through illusion. New York: Basic Books. Frank, A. G. 1998. ReORIENT: Global economy

in the Asian age. Berkeley: University of California Press.

Frobel, F.; Heinrichs, J.; and Kreye, 0. 1980. The new international division of labour.

Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Geertz, C. 1973. The interpretation of cultures.

New York: Basic Books. Gertler, M. S. 2001. Best practice? Geography,

learning and the institutional limits to strong convergence. Journal of Economic Geography 1:5-26.

Gertz, B. 2000. The China threat: How the

People's Republic targets America.

Washington, D.C.: Regnery. Ginsburg, N. S., and Brush, J. E. 1958. The

pattern of Asia. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall.

Goodhart, C., and Xu, C., 1996. The rise of China as an economic power. Cambridge, Mass.: Institute for International Development, Harvard University.

Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action, and social structure: The problem of embedded- ness. American Journal of Sociology 91:481-510.

Guthrie, D. 1997. Between markets and politics: Organizational responses to reform in China. American Journal of Sociology 102:1258-304.

Hamilton, G. G., and Biggart, N. W. 1988. Market, culture, and authority: A comparative analysis of management and organization in the Far East. American Journal of Sociology 94:S52-S94.

Hart-Landsberg, M., and Burkett, P. 1998. Contradictions of capitalist industrialization in East Asia: A critique of "flying geese" theories of development. Economic Geography 74:87-110.

Harvey, D. 1989. The condition of postmoder- nity: An enquiry into the origins of cultural change. Oxford, U.K.: Basil Blackwell.

Henderson, J. 1989. The globalisation of high technology production. London: Routledge.

Hsing, Y.-t. 1998. Making capitalism in China: The Taiwan connection. New York: Oxford

University Press. Hsu, J.-Y., and Cheng, L.-L. 2002. Revisiting

economic development in post-war Taiwan: The dynamic process of geographical indus- trialization. Regional Studies 36:897-908.

Hsu, J.-Y., and Saxenian, A. 2000. The limits of Guanxi capitalism: Transnational collaboration between Taiwan and the USA. Environment and Planning A 32:1991-2005.

Hudson, B. 1977. The new geography and the new imperialism: 1870-1918. Antipode 9:12-19.

Johnson, C. 1982. MITI and the Japanese economic miracle, Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.

Johnston, R. J. 1997. Geography and geographers: Anglo-American human geography since 1945, 5th ed. London: Arnold.

Kelly, P. F. 1999. The geographies and politics of globalization. Progress in Human Geography 23:379-400.

-. 2001a. The political economy of local labor control in the Philippines. Economic Geography 77:1-22.

-. 2001b. Metaphors of meltdown: Political representations of economic space in the Asian financial crisis. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space 19:719-42.

Kelly, P. F.; Olds, K.; and Yeung, H. W.-c. 2001. Introduction: Geographical perspectives on the Asian economic crisis. Geoforum 32:vii-xiii.

Kerr, D. 2002. The "place" of land in Japan's postwar development, and the dynamic of the 1980s real-estate "bubble" and 1990s banking crisis. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space 20:345-74.

Krugman, P. 1994. The myth of Asia miracle. Foreign Affairs 73:62-78.

-. 1998. Asia: What went wrong? Fortune 137(4):32.

Lee, R., and Wills, J., eds. 1997. Geographies of economies. London: Arnold.

Leeming, F. 1980. On Chinese geography. Progress in Human Geography 4:218-37.

Leung, C.-k. 1993. Personal contacts, subcon- tracting linkages, and development in the Hong Kong-Zhujiang Delta region. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 83:272-302.

Ley, D. 1999. Myths and meaning of immigra- tion and the metropolis. Canadian Geographer 43:2-19.

Lin, G. C. S. 1997. Red capitalism in South China: Growth and development of the Pearl River Delta. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.

-. 2002a. Transnationalism and the geog- raphy of sub-ethnicity in Hong Kong. Urban Geography 23:57-84.

... 2002b. Changing discourses in China geography: A narrative evaluation. Environment and Planning A 34:1809-31.

Page 21: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

126 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003

Lin, N. 1995. Local market socialism: Local

corporatism in action in rural China. Theory and Society 24:301-54.

Lin, N., and Bian, Y. 1991. Getting ahead in urban China. American Journal of Sociology 97:657-88.

Liu, W., and Lu, D. 2002. Rethinking the

development of economic geography in main- land China. Environment and Planning A 34:2107-126.

Ma, L. J. C., and Cartier, C., eds. 2003. The Chinese diaspora: Space, place, mobility and

identity, Boulder, Colo.: Rowman & Littlefield. MacKinnon, D.; Cumbers, A.; and Chapman, K.

2002. Learning, innovation and regional devel-

opment: A critical appraisal of recent debates.

Progress in Human Geography 26:293-311. Markusen, A., and Park, S. 0. 1993. The state

as industrial locator and district builder: The case of Changwon, South Korea. Economic

Geography 69:157-81. Martin, R., and Sunley, P. 1998. Slow conver-

gence? The new endogenous growth theory and regional development. Economic

Geography 74:201-27. Marton, A. M. 2000. China's spatial economic

development: Regional transformation in the lower Yangzi Delta. London: Routledge.

Massey, D. 1973. Towards a critique of industrial location theory. Antipode 5:33-9.

-. 1984. Spatial division of labour: Social structures and the geography of production. London: Macmillan.

McGee, T. G. 1967. The southeast Asian city. London: Bell.

-. 1971. The urbanization process in the Third World: Explorations in search of a theory. London: Bell.

-. 1991. Eurocentrism in geography-- The case of Asian urbanization. Canadian

Geographer 35:332-44. McGee, T. G., and Yeung, Y.-m. 1977. Hawkers

in southeast Asian cities: Planning for the bazaar economy. Ottawa: International

Development Research Centre. Mitchell, K. 1995. Flexible circulation in the

Pacific Rim: Capitalism in cultural context. Economic Geography 71:364-82.

Murphey, R. 1953. Shanghai: Key to modern China. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

Naughton, B. 1991. Why has economic reform led to inflation. American Economic Review 81:207-11.

Nee, V. 1989. A theory of market transition: From redistribution to markets in state socialism. American Sociological Review 54:663-81.

Ohmae, K. 1990. The borderless world: Power and strategy in the interlinked economy. London: Collins.

Olds, K. 2001a. Globalization and urban change: Capital, culture and Pacific Rim mega projects. New York: Oxford University Press.

-. 2001b. Practices for "process geogra- phies": A view from within and outside the

periphery. Environment and Planning D:

Society and Space 19:127-36. Olds, K., and Poon, J. 2002. Theories and

discourses of economic geography. Environment and Planning A 34:379-83.

Olds, K., and Yeung, H. W.-c. 1999. (Re)shaping "Chinese" business networks in a globalising era. Environment and Planning D: Society and

Space 17:535-55. Pannell, C. W. 1980. Geography. In Science in

contemporary China, ed. L. A. Orleans, 167-87. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.

Park, B.-G. 1998. Where do tigers sleep at night? The state's role in housing policy in South Korea and Singapore. Economic Geography 74:272-88.

Park, S. O., and Markusen, A. 1995. Generalizing new industrial districts: A theoretical agenda and an application from a non-Western

economy. Environment and Planning A 27:81-104.

Patchell, J. 1993a. From production systems to

learning systems-lessons from Japan. Environment and Planning A 25:797-815.

-. 1993b. Composing robot production systems-Japan as a flexible manufacturing system. Environment and Planning A 25:923-44.

- . 2002. Linking production and consumption. The coevolution of interaction systems in the Japanese house industry. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 92:284-301.

Peck, J. A., and Miyamachi, Y. 1994. Regulating Japan? Regulation theory versus the Japanese experience. Environment and Planning D:

Society and Space 12:639-74. Peck, J. A., and Yeung, H. W.-c., eds. 2003.

Remaking the global economy: Economic-

geographical perspectives. London: Sage. Pickles, J., and Smith, A., eds. 1998. Theorising

transition: The political economy of post- Communist transformations. London: Routledge.

Piore, M. J., and Sabel, C. F. 1984. The second industrial divide: Possibilities for prosperity. New York: Basic Books.

Page 22: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

VOL. 79 No. 2 THEORIZING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHIES OF ASIA 127

Polanyi, K. 1944. The great transformation. New York: Holt, Rinehart.

Potter, R. 2001. Geography and development: "Core and periphery"? Area 33:422-7.

Radelet, S., and Sachs, J. D. 1998. The East Asian financial crisis: Diagnosis, remedies, prospects. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:1-90.

Rawski, T. G. 1994. Chinese industrial reform:

Accomplishments, prospects, and implications. American Economic Review 84:271-5.

Redding, S. G. 1990. The spirit of Chinese capi- talism. Berlin: de Gruyter.

Reich, R. B. 1991. The work of nations: Preparing ourselves for 21st century capitalism. New York: Vintage Books.

Said, E. W. 1978. Orientalism. London:

Routledge. Schoenberger, E. 1997. The cultural crisis of

the firm. Oxford, U.K.: Basil Blackwell. Scott, A. J. 1988. New industrial spaces: Flexible

production, organisation and regional devel-

opment in North America and Western

Europe. London: Pion. -. 2000. Economic geography: The great

half-century. Cambridge Journal ofEconomics 24:483-504.

Shaw, M. 2000. Theory of the global state:

Globality as unfinished revolution. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Sheppard, E., and Barnes, T. J., eds. 2000. A

companion to economic geography. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell.

Sidaway, J. D. 1997. The production of British

geography. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 22:488-504.

Skinner, G. W. 1964. Marketing and social struc- ture in rural China (Part I). Journal of Asian Studies 24:3-44.

Slater, D. 1999. Situating geopolitical represen- tations: Inside/outside and the power of impe- rial interventions. In Human Geography Today, ed. D. Massey, J. Allen, and P. Sarre, 62-84. Cambridge, U.K.: Polity Press.

Smith, A. 2002. Trans-locals, critical area studies and geography's others, or why "development" should not be geography's organising frame- work: A response to Potter. Area 34:210-3.

Spate, O. H. K. and Learmonth, A. T. A. 1967. India and Pakistan: A general and regional geography. London: Methuen.

Spencer, J. E. 1954. Asia, East by South: A cultural geography. New York: John Wiley & Sons.

Stark, D. 1996. Recombinant property in East European capitalism. American Journal of Sociology 101:993-1027.

Stark, D., and Bruszt, L. 2001. One way or

multiple paths: For a comparative sociology of East European capitalism. American Journal of Sociology 106:1129-37.

Stiglitz, J. E., and Yusuf, S., eds. 2001. Rethinking the East Asian miracle. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

Storper, M., and Salais, R. 1997. Worlds of production: The action frameworks of the

economy. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard

University Press.

Storper, M., and Walker, M. 1989. The capitalist imperative: Territory, technology and indus- trial growth. Oxford, U.K.: Basil Blackwell.

Taylor, P. J. 1996. Embedded statism and the social sciences: Opening up to new spaces. Environment and Planning A 28:1917-28.

Thrift, N., and Olds, K. 1996. Refiguring the economic in economic geography. Progress in Human Geography 20:311-37.

Thrift, N., and Walling, D. 2000. Geography in the United Kingdom 1996-2000. Geographical Journal 166:96-124.

Tyson, L. D'A. 1993. Who's bashing whom? Trade conflicts in high-technology industries.

Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.

Vogel, E. F. 1979. Japan as number one: Lessons for America. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard

University Press. -. 1989. One step ahead in China:

Guangdong under reform. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

Wade, R. 1990. Governing the market: Economic theory and the role of government in East Asian industrialization. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

-. 2002. U.S. hegemony and the World Bank: The fight over people and ideas. Review of International Political Economy 9:215-43.

Wade, R., and Veneroso, F. 1998. The Asian crisis: The high debt model versus the Wall Street-Treasury-IMF complex. New Left Review 228:3-23.

Walder, A. G. 1995. Local governments as indus- trial firms: An organizational analysis of China's transitional economy. American Journal of Sociology 101:263-301.

Walker, R., and Storper, M. 1981. Capital and industrial location. Progress in Human

Geography 5:473-509. Wei, Y. D. 2000. Regional development in China:

States, globalization, and inequality. London: Routledge.

Wheatley, P. 1971. The pivot of the four quar- ters: A preliminary enquiry into the origins

Page 23: Theorizing Economic Geographies of Asia · "theorizing economic geographies of Asia." The plurality of the term represents a delib- erate attempt to theorize the diverse expe- riences

128 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY APRIL 2003

and character of the ancient Chinese city. Chicago: Aldine.

Whitley, R. 1999. Divergent capitalisms: The social structuring and change of business systems. New York: Oxford University Press.

Wills, J., and Lee, R. 1997. Introduction. In

Geographies of economies, ed. R. Lee and J. Wills, xv-xviii. London: Arnold.

Womack, J. P.; Jones, D. T.; and Roos, D. 1990. The machines that changed the world. New York: Rawson Associates.

World Bank 1993. The East Asian miracle. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

Yeoh, B. S. A., and Chang, T. C. 2001. Globalising Singapore: Debating transnational flows in the

city. Urban Studies 38:1025-44. Yeung, H. W.-c. 1994. Critical reviews of

geographical perspectives on business organ- isations and the organisation of production: Towards a network approach. Progress in Human Geography 18:460-90.

-. 1997. Business networks and transna- tional corporations: A study of Hong Kong firms in the ASEAN region. Economic

Geography 73:1-25. -. 1998a. The social-spatial constitution

of business organisations: A geographical perspective. Organization 5:101-28.

.. 1998b. Capital, state and space: Contesting the borderless world. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 23:291-309.

-. 1998c. Transnational corporations and business networks: Hong Kong firms in the ASEAN region. London: Routledge.

-. 1999. Regulating investment abroad? The political economy of the regionalisation of Singaporean firms. Antipode 31:245-73.

-. 2000. Organising "the firm" in indus- trial geography, I: Networks, institutions and

regional development. Progress in Human

Geography 24:301-15. -. 2001a. Redressing the geographical bias

in social science knowledge. Environment and

Planning A 33:2-9. -. 2001b. Regulating "the firm" and socio-

cultural practices in industrial geography, II.

Progress in Human Geography 25:293-302. -. 2002a. Doing what kind of economic

geography? Journal of Economic Geography 2:250-2.

-. 2002b. The limits to globalization theory: A geographical perspective on global economic change. Economic Geography 78:285-305.

-. Forthcoming. Practicing new economic

geographies: A methodological examination. Annals of the Association of American

Geographers 93(2). Young, A. 1995. The tyranny of numbers-

Confronting the statistical realities of the East Asian growth experience. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110:641-80.

-. 2000. The razor's edge: Distortions and incremental reform in the People's Republic of China. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115:1091-1135.

Zhou, Y. 1998. Beyond ethnic enclaves: Location

strategies of Chinese producer service firms in Los Angeles. Economic Geography 74:228-51.

Zhou, Y., and Tseng, Y.-F. 2001. Regrounding the "Ungrounded Empires": Localization as the geographical catalyst for transnationalism. Global Networks 1:131-54.


Recommended