+ All Categories
Home > Documents > TRADEMARKING VERSUS PATENTING: THE EFFECTS … · Sutton’s (2007) work on endogenous sunk costs...

TRADEMARKING VERSUS PATENTING: THE EFFECTS … · Sutton’s (2007) work on endogenous sunk costs...

Date post: 01-May-2018
Category:
Upload: truongque
View: 219 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
39
Paper to be presented at the 35th DRUID Celebration Conference 2013, Barcelona, Spain, June 17-19 TRADEMARKING VERSUS PATENTING: THE EFFECTS OF MARKET STRUCTURE, CUSTOMER TYPE AND VENTURE CAPITAL FINANCING Enrico Pennings Erasmus University Rotterdam Applied Economics [email protected] Joern Block University of Trier [email protected] Geertjan De Vries Erasmus University Rotterdam [email protected] Abstract We analyze the initial IP rights of 4,703 start-up entrants in the US, distinguishing between trademark- and patent applications. Results show that start-ups are more likely to file a trademark instead of a patent when entering more competitive market structures. Further, we find that start-ups with a focus on distribution, serving end-consumers, are more prone to file a trademark, and that start-ups operating upstream, selling to other businesses are more likely to file for patents. Lastly, external influences on the start-up?s management, such as the involvement of a venture capitalist (VC), affect IP applications. The increased incentive of VC-backed start-ups to become operational on the market makes them more likely to file initial IP in the form of a trademark rather than a patent. Among other things, we control for the R&D- and advertising intensity in the industry, and distinguish between more technical- versus more service driven industries. Jelcodes:O34,L10
Transcript

Paper to be presented at the

35th DRUID Celebration Conference 2013, Barcelona, Spain, June 17-19

TRADEMARKING VERSUS PATENTING: THE EFFECTS OF MARKET

STRUCTURE, CUSTOMER TYPE AND VENTURE CAPITAL FINANCINGEnrico Pennings

Erasmus University RotterdamApplied Economics

[email protected]

Joern BlockUniversity of Trier

[email protected]

Geertjan De VriesErasmus University Rotterdam

[email protected]

AbstractWe analyze the initial IP rights of 4,703 start-up entrants in the US, distinguishing between trademark- and patentapplications. Results show that start-ups are more likely to file a trademark instead of a patent when entering morecompetitive market structures. Further, we find that start-ups with a focus on distribution, serving end-consumers, aremore prone to file a trademark, and that start-ups operating upstream, selling to other businesses are more likely to filefor patents. Lastly, external influences on the start-up?s management, such as the involvement of a venture capitalist(VC), affect IP applications. The increased incentive of VC-backed start-ups to become operational on the market makesthem more likely to file initial IP in the form of a trademark rather than a patent. Among other things, we control for theR&D- and advertising intensity in the industry, and distinguish between more technical- versus more service drivenindustries.

Jelcodes:O34,L10

1

TRADEMARKING VERSUS PATENTING: THE EFFECTS OF

MARKET STRUCTURE, CUSTOMER TYPE AND VENTURE

CAPITAL FINANCING

ABSTRACT

We analyze the initial IP rights of 4,703 start-up entrants in the US, distinguishing

between trademark- and patent applications. Results show that start-ups are more likely

to file a trademark instead of a patent when entering more competitive market

structures. Further, we find that start-ups with a focus on distribution, serving end-

consumers, are more prone to file a trademark, and that start-ups operating upstream,

selling to other businesses are more likely to file for patents. Lastly, external influences

on the start-up’s management, such as the involvement of a venture capitalist (VC),

affect IP applications. The increased incentive of VC-backed start-ups to become

operational on the market makes them more likely to file initial IP in the form of a

trademark rather than a patent. Among other things, we control for the R&D- and

advertising intensity in the industry, and distinguish between more technical- versus

more service driven industries.

Keywords: Intellectual property, competition; venture capital; trademarks; patents.

JEL classifications: O34, L10, G24

First version: January 2013 This version: February 2013

2

INTRODUCTION

Throughout the previous decade, research on intellectual property rights has expanded from

being mainly patent orientated, to also finding a significant role for trademarks: Similar to

patents, trademarks were found positively related to firm valuations (Greenhalgh & Rogers

2006b; 2007; Sandner & Block, 2011) and firm survival (Helmers and Rogers, 2010; Wagner

and Cockburn, 2010). For example, Apple’s brand value, protected by trademarks, is

estimated at a value of $182bn. in 20121, while the value of its patents has been estimated by

John Hauser of MIT in the court case between Apple and Samsung at $90-$100 per device.

This type of complementarities between patents and trademarks have been examined and

confirmed in Amara, Landry, & Traoré (2008), Graham & Somaya (2004) and Kong &

Seldon (2004). Further, next to patents, trademarks have been suggested as an indicator for

innovative activities (Flikkema, De Man & Wolters, 2010; Malmberg, 2005; Mendonça,

Pereira, & Godinho, 2004). Finally, not only patents, but also trademarks were found to

function as an entry barrier for new start-up firms (Davies, 2009; Kong & Seldon, 2004;

Ramello, 2006; Ramello & Silva, 2006).

Patent and trademarks are interesting to analyze because they each reflect specific

strategic intentions: where patents relate to the protection of technological assets (Greenhalgh

& Rogers, 2010), trademarks relate to the commercialization of an invention, and the

protection of a firm’s brand and marketing assets (Sandner & Block, 2011). Thus far, the

common explanation of an intellectual property (IP) strategy is that firms active in R&D-

intensive and more technical industries will file for patent protection (Griliches, 1984; 1998;

Kortum, 1993), while firms active in advertising intensive, consumer- and service related

industries are more likely to file for trademark protection (Malmberg, 2005; Mendonça et al.,

2004). This explanation however only considers the type of activity a firm is engaged in, and

1 according to Millward Brown Optimor's 2012 BrandZ study.

3

no other determinants, neither theoretically nor empirically, have been explored. We address

this research gap by examining the initial IP direction (trademark or patent) of 4,743 start-up

entrants in the US, filing for an initial IP right between 1998 and 2007.

Following the start-up strategy literature, partly derived from Porter’s (1980)

differentiation typology, trademark applications are mostly used by start-ups operating

according to the marketing differentiation strategy, where patents are the primary protection

mechanism for start-ups operating under the technical- or product differentiation strategy (see

also Carter et al., 1994; McGee et al., 1995). Though both patents and trademarks are

important in the protection of a firm’s intangible assets, we have still little knowledge about

the determinants of a firm’s IP strategy. Sutton’s (2007) work on endogenous sunk costs

provides a theoretical base for advertising and R&D as strategies to increase consumers’

willingness to pay for a product. Appropriating the benefits from these strategies requires

filing for trademark and patent protection, respectively. In addition to these endogenous sunk

costs, Sutton (2007) states that the existence of economies of scale imposes an exogenous

sunk cost on firms that intend to enter an industry. The way in which exogenous and

endogenous sunk costs interact with each other determines firm concentration in an industry.

As economies of scale in the production of a good or service can arise from various reasons,

it is generally hard to measure. Given that endogenous sunk costs (in the form of R&D and

advertising costs) and exogenous sunk costs (in terms of entry barriers) jointly determine

industry concentration, we include industry concentration in our analysis controlling for

endogenous sunk costs at the industry level (and beyond the control of an individual firm).

This way, we indirectly examine how exogenous sunk costs affect a start-up’s choice of IP

strategy.

Because trademarks are an important tool in establishing the communicative link to

consumers (Economides, 1988; Sandner & Block, 2011), trademarks should be more relevant

4

in markets with differentiated goods where exogenous sunk costs are low, supporting a start-

up’s visibility among the variety of available products. In contrast, patents may be a more

critical tool especially in winner-takes-it-all, i.e. less competitive markets, where dominant

technologies are industry standards. In these markets, start-ups that enter a market with novel,

patented technological knowledge pose a greater threat to the established incumbent(s)

(Abernathy & Clark, 1984; Christensen & Bower, 1996; Henderson, 1993; Hill &

Rothaermel, 2003).

The firm perspective that we take in this paper also allows us to consider firm level

explanations in addition to industry level explanations. We argue that IP strategy is partly

related to a start-up’s customer type. Start-ups that operate upstream in the supply chain and

sell to other businesses are more likely to operate under a technical- or product differentiation

strategy, because they provide relevant inputs for the product development process (McGee

et al., 1995). Such company assets are protected by patents. In comparison, down-stream

start-ups which serve end-consumers are probably more focused on marketing and

distribution, and thus more likely to operate under a marketing differentiation strategy (Carter

et al., 1994; Tan, 2001). Brand- and marketing assets are typically protected by trademarks.

Thirdly, we argue that influences on the start-up’s management, such as the involvement

of a venture capital (VC) investor, may influence IP orientation. VCs hold significant

decision power, and spend most of their time advising and monitoring the start-ups they

invest in (Gompers & Lerner, 2004; Sahlman, 1990). When engaging with a start-up, VCs are

likely to prioritize towards the commercialization of a start-up’s invention by setting mile

stones that are primarily related to market orientation and the generation of initial revenues

(Berkery, 2008; Hellman & Puri, 2000; 2002; Hills, 1984; Hisrisch, 1989). Such a focus on

commercialization may push a start-up towards a more trademark orientated IP strategy.

5

Analyzing a sample of 4,703 start-ups in the US, we show that as market competition

intensifies, start-ups will be more likely to file initial IP in the form of a trademark and less

likely in the form of a patent. Secondly, start-ups serving end-consumers are more likely to

file for trademark protection, as compared to start-ups serving other businesses, which are

more likely to file for patent protection. Thirdly, we find that the involvement of a VC

investor leads to a higher likelihood of filing initial IP in the form of a trademark as

compared to a patent. In our analysis we control for the R&D- and advertising intensity

within the start-up’s market niche and sector fixed effects.

We provide significant contributions to several literature streams. Firstly, our findings

contribute to the start-up strategy literature (Carter et al., 1994; McGee et al., 1995) as we

are, to the best of our knowledge, the first study to examine the determinants behind start-up

IP direction, reflecting strategic intentions. These findings connect to previous works as

patents can be associated with a more technical- or product differentiation strategy, and

trademarks, protecting brand- and marketing assets, with a marketing differentiation strategy

(see also Carter et al., 1994; Chaganti et al., 1989; Li, 2007; McGee et al., 1995; Miles and

Snow, 1978; Miller, 1986; 1991; Porter, 1980; Schrader and Siegel, 2007). Secondly, as

mentioned earlier, by providing empirical evidence on the influences of firm- and industry

level characteristics on trademark- versus patent filings, we contribute to the growing body of

literature that addresses the relevance of trademarks next to the role of patents in the

protection of innovative assets (e.g. Amara et al., 2008; Davies, 2009; Ramello, 2006;

Sandner and Block, 2011). Thirdly, we contribute to the IP-market structure literature. A

main discussion point in this literature lies around the relationship between market structure

and the incentive to innovate and file for IP protection. Hypotheses of Schumpeter (1950) and

Arrow (1962) in this respect have been tested and discussed in many follow-up works (e.g.,

Arora, 1997; Acs & Audretsch, 1987; Greenhalgh & Rogers, 2006a; Levin, Cohen, &

6

Mowery, 1985; Loury, 1979; Malerba & Orsenigo, 2002; Scherer, 1984). However, thus far

little is known how market structure may affect the type of IP protection filed. Depending on

the intensity of competition, start-ups may behave differently, filing the type of IP that is

most suitable given exogenous sunk cost, and build towards a competitive advantage.

Overall, this literature stream has solely addressed the role of patents. Fourth, we contribute

to the VC-IP literature. In the VC-IP literature, it is shown that start-up’s filing for IP rights

have a higher likelihood of receiving VC funds in the first place (Cao & Hsu, 2011; Engel &

Keilbach, 2007; Haeussler, Harhoff, & Muller, 2009), and that IP rights have a positive

relation with subsequent start-up valuations by VCs (Baum and Silverman, 2004; Block, De

Vries, Sandner, & Schumann, 2012; Hsu & Ziedonis, 2007; Lerner, 1994). Yet, the influence

of a VC investor on a start-up’s type of IP applications has thus far not been explored. VCs

have powerful decision rights and spend most of their time as advisors to the start-up

companies (Gompers & Lerner, 2004). VCs are therefore likely to influence the strategy of

the start-up, partly reflected in IP decisions.

The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 discusses relevant

background information on trademarks and patents. Section 3 develops our hypotheses with

regard to the effects of market competition, customer type, and the involvement of VC

investors on a start-up’s IP preferences. Section 4 describes our data. Section 5 presents

descriptive and multivariate results, which are discussed in Section 6. Section 7 discusses

limitations and avenues for future research. Section 8 presents the conclusions of our study.

BACKGROUND INFORMATION ON TRADEMARKS AND PATENTS

Because many previous works have addressed the role of patents for start-ups, we will

elaborate somewhat more around trademarks in this section. Relevant comparisons to patents

are made.

7

A trademark is “a distinctive sign, which identifies certain goods or services as those

produced or provided by a specific person or enterprise” (World Intellectual Property

Organization (WIPO), 2011). Trademarks are most commonly filed in the form of a logo,

symbol, name or phrase, but can also be filed as a specific color, sound, smell or combination

of these factors. Most importantly, a trademark should be distinctive, i.e. it should not

confuse consumers by being too identical or similar to an already granted trademark

(Economides, 1988; Mendonça et al., 2004). The primary motivation behind filing a

trademark is the ability to distinguish a firm’s products or services from competition. Via a

trademarked brand name, consumers are able to identify the products offered by a specific

firm. This allows a firm to build consumer loyalty, with the potential to charge a higher price

(Flikkema et al, 2012). Trademarks function as the legal basis on which brand value can be

built, securing benefits from future marketing investments (Sandner & Block, 2011).

Comparing patents and trademarks, both protect elements that are relevant for an

innovative start-up. Where a trademark is important for the commercialization and the

diffusion of a start-up’s innovation, a patent protects a start-up’s technological knowledge,

reflecting the start-up’s willingness to protect its invention. Patents and trademarks can

therefore be suggested as complementary assets in the allocation of returns from an

innovation (Teece, 1986). In line with this, both patents and trademarks can be a signal of

new product development (Mendonça et al., 2004). Further, with regard to their exclusion

right, patents have been widely discussed as a relevant protector of competitive advantage,

giving immediate power to exclude competitors from the use of critical technological

knowledge (e.g., Greenhalgh & Rogers, 2010). Similarly, also trademarks can serve as an

exclusion mechanism, providing market power (Davies, 2009; Kong, & Seldon, 2004;

Ramello, 2006; Ramello & Silva, 2006). A relevant difference however is that market power

embedded in trademarks has to be built through frequent consumer interaction over time,

8

whereas the filing of a patent immediately excludes competitors from producing and offering

a product in the first place. Another relevant difference between patents and trademarks

regards their duration: patents offer temporary protection, for a period of usually 20 years.

Trademarks can be renewed indefinitely, as long as a renewal fee is paid every 10 years, and

under the condition that its holder has been actively using the trademark. Furthermore,

patents and trademarks differ with regard to the related investments that they protect.

Investments leading to an invention are conducted before a patent’s filing date. In contrast,

branding and marketing investments that are protected by a trademark are generally

conducted after a trademark’s filing date (Sandner & Block, 2011).

When explaining IP strategy, the start-up’s type of activity should be an important

explanatory factor. Where a start-up’s activities are more R&D intensive, it will have a

greater likelihood of filing for a patent (Griliches, 1984; 1998; Kortum, 1993). And naturally,

start-ups that are more consumer-orientated and advertising intensive are more likely to file

for a trademark (Malmberg, 2005; Mendonça et al., 2004). The following section develops

hypotheses considering additional explanatory factors that may drive the type of IP

applications filed.

HYPOTHESES DEVELOPMENT

Market competition and IP strategy

We argue that the intensity of competition within a market may affect an entering start-up’s

IP strategy. We distinguish between a trademark- and a patent-orientated IP strategy.

We suggest that a start-up is more likely to adopt a trademark orientated strategy when

entering a more competitive market. Supporting the connection between firms and

consumers, the filing of a trademark should become more relevant when consumers have

more, rather similar firms to choose from in their purchasing decisions. When there are more

9

competing firms, a start-up’s visibility in the market becomes more relevant in order to

persuade consumers to purchase its product. Trademarks are primarily a tool in establishing

the communication link to consumers (Economices, 1988; Flikkema et al., 2010). A second

argument relates to the finding that more competitive markets are likely to have lower entry

barriers in place (Caves & Porter, 1977; McAfee, Mialon, & Williams, 2004). Within a

market that lacks powerful exclusion mechanisms, it is easy for new start-ups to become

operational. It has been shown that, especially in markets that lack a strong entry barrier, such

as for example a patented technology, competition may occur at the level of branding, and

competitive advantage can become embedded into trademark(s) (Davies, 2009; Onkvisit &

Shaw, 1989; Ramello & Silva, 2006; Schmalensee, 1978). Trademarks introduce

differentiation into a market, as consumers can perceive one brand as being superior to the

other (DeYong & Örs, 2004; Ramello, 2006). In competitive markets, start-ups tend to rely

more heavily on trademarks as a basic branding instrument in order to create competitive

advantage (Abimbola, 2001). Because a start-up’s resources are limited, it focuses firstly on

the designing of logo’s, symbols, and a suitable brand name, which are protected by

trademarks. At this stage, few funds are available for more advanced tools such as

advertising. Overall, the above discussion suggests that start-ups entering more competitive

markets are likely to have a trademark orientated IP strategy.

In contrast, we suggest that a patent strategy becomes more crucial for start-ups as the

level of market competition is lower. Under weak competition, entry barriers are likely to be

in place, allocating market power to the incumbent firm(s). Explanations of more

concentrated markets can be the presence of economies of scale, limited market size, or

superior access to inputs (Besanko, Dranove, Shanley, & Schaefer, 2010). When entering a

more concentrated market, a patent will exclude the incumbent firm(s) from the use of a start-

up’s technological knowledge. A patent also suggests that the start-up’s invention is novel,

10

non-obvious, and useful (WIPO, 2004). This suggests that patents can play a critical role for

start-ups that attempt to capture some initial market share. Prior work indicates that start-up’s

entering with protected novel technical knowledge are likely to pose a greater threat to

established, powerful incumbent(s) (Abernathy & Clark, 1984; Christensen & Bower, 1996;

Henderson, 1993; Hill & Rothaermel, 2003). On the contrary, a trademark does not directly

exclude competitors from a new technology. The only requirement here is that competitors

should do business under a different unique brand name than the start-up, and thus do not

mislead consumers (Mendonça et al., 2004). Overall, without strong protection of the core

qualities of the start-up, it becomes more difficult to pose a threat to incumbent firm(s) who

are in control of the resources within an industry. The above discussion suggests that start-

ups entering less competitive industries are more likely to have a patent orientated IP

strategy. We pose the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1. As market competition increases, start-ups are more likely to file initial IP

in the form of a trademark rather than a patent.

Customer type and IP strategy

IP strategy may also be explained by the start-up’s type of customer, and the start-up’s related

position within the supply chain. We distinguish between start-ups operating downstream in

the supply chain, serving end-consumers, and start-ups operating more upstream in the supply

chain, serving other businesses (Harland, 1996; Beamon, 1998). Where product development

is generally conducted upstream, it seems likely that start-ups selling to other businesses are

providing relevant inputs to the product development process. In contrast, start-ups selling to

end-consumers should already own a marketable product, and thus have a greater need to

focus on distribution and marketing (Tan, 2001).

11

The concepts of product development versus marketing as a core type of activity are

recognized as strategic typologies in the start-up strategy literature. Based on Porter’s (1980)

differentiation typology, it is distinguished between technical- or product differentiation

strategy on the one hand, and marketing differentiation strategy on the other hand (Carter et

al., 1994; Chaganti et al., 1989; Li, 2001; McGee et al., 1995; Miller, 1991; Schrader and

Siegel, 2007). Under the product differentiation strategy, the start-up aims to achieve

differentiation via R&D activities, creating a competitive advantage through product

innovation (McGee et al, 1995), which is an upstream activity. In the case of a marketing

differentiation strategy, the start-up is specialized in marketing activities such as branding,

promotion, design, service, image, and distribution, which are more downstream activities.

Furthermore, these start-ups are highly unlikely to come up with a new product (Carter et al.,

1994; Miller, 1986). Accordingly, we expect that start-ups with downstream activities,

serving end-consumers, are more likely to work under a marketing orientated strategy, and

will therefore be in need of trademark protection. Start-ups supplying to other businesses are

more likely to be involved in product development, and should therefore benefit more from

patent protection. We formulate the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 2. Compared to start-ups selling to other businesses, start-ups selling to end-

consumers are more likely to file initial IP in the form of a trademark rather than a

patent.

The impact of VC funding on IP strategy

External influences on the start-up’s management may also affect IP orientation. VCs are

active investors that do not only provide funding, but also spend most of their time advising

and monitoring the management of the start-ups they invest in. VCs often sit on the board of

12

directors, and they have powerful rights, such as for example firing the management of the

start-up (Gompers & Lerner, 2004; Sahlman, 1990). We argue that the involvement of a VC

is likely to shift a start-up’s focus towards the commercialization of its inventions. Prior work

shows that VCs find early stage start-ups to be overly-focused on the development of their

invention. VCs are of the opinion that start-ups should be more consumer-orientated and

conduct market analysis (Hills, 1984; Hills, Hultman, & Miles, 2008; Hisrisch, 1989;

Wortman, Spann, & Adams, 1989). When deciding to invest, a VC sets milestones that the

start-up needs to achieve in order to receive subsequent funding rounds. In early stages, such

milestones are likely to be directed towards market orientation, making the product more

consumer-friendly, and to localizing initial consumers that are willing to buy the product

(Berkery, 2008). Accordingly, the involvement of a VC investor is likely to shorten a start-

up’s time-to-market, and speeds up the professionalization of marketing activities compared

to non-VC funded start-ups (Hellman & Puri, 2000; 2002). VCs only have a limited time

period to turn a start-up in a functioning company that can either conduct an IPO, or that can

be sold to an industrial firm. The VC seeks to bring a product to the market as early as

possible. The filing of a trademark is likely to be one of the initial steps taken in the

commercialization process, securing the brand name of the start-up, and protecting a start-

up’s future marketing efforts (Sandner & Block, 2011). Hence, we derive the following

hypothesis:

Hypothesis 3. VC-backed start-ups are more likely to file initial IP in the form of a

trademark rather than in the form of a patent.

DATA AND VARIABLES

Data sources

13

We analyze the influence of market competition, the start-up’s customer type, and the

engagement of VC investors on a start-up’s type of initial IP application, distinguishing

between trademarks and patents. We used several data sources but restricted our data

searches to the Unites States. VC funded start-ups were taken from the VentureXpert

database of Thomson Reuters. Using the six-digit NAICS industry classification codes

available in VentureXpert, we merged R&D- and advertising intensity measures calculated

from COMPUSTAT, and competition intensity data accessed through the US Census Bureau.

In a next step, patent and trademark filing records were matched manually to the start-up’s

name and former aliases reported in VentureXpert.

Sample and NAICS data

From VentureXpert, we selected US-based start-ups that received VC funds in the period of

1998 to 2007, resulting in a sample of 11,808 start-ups. We focussed on start-ups with a valid

reported NAICS classification, foundation date, and amounts of VC funds received. We were

unable to take into account data beyond 2007 because of the lengthy process surrounding

patent applications and the successive granting of international patent protection. Patent

filings are kept secret for 18 months, after which it may take several more years to secure

international protection (Greenhalgh & Rogers, 2010).

We define the market niche in which a start-up is operating by the six-digit NAICS code

available in VentureXpert. For each NAICS classification we used the COMPUSTAT

database in order to calculate three year averages of R&D- and advertising intensity over our

sample period (1998-2007). COMPUSTAT data is commonly used in previous works to

calculate such measures (e.g., Chauvin & Hirschey, 1993; Waring, 1996). We were able to

determine R&D- and advertising intensity measures for the market niches of 11,582 start-ups.

Next, we obtained competition intensity data published by the US Census Bureau, which is

14

published every 5 years. Competition data provided by the US Census bureau is reliable, as

each firm in the US is required by law to respond to the US Census survey (see Ali, Klasa, &

Yeung, 2009 for a review).2 Competition intensity data was available for the market niches of

9,678 start-ups. Finally, we gathered US trademark- and patent data for this sample.

Trademark and patent data

IP searches were done via a manual process. Trademark applications were obtained from the

United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) (see also Graham, Hancock, Marco,

Myers; 2013). US Patent applications were accessed through the PATSTAT database. The

extent of IP activities could be determined for 8,247 of the remaining start-ups (85.2%). A

start-up was excluded when its name or one of its former aliases did not give a unique search

result. Imperfect matches were verified via industry and location records available from

VentureXpert. We selected the start-ups that filed a first IP application in the period of 1998

to 2007, leading to a final sample of 4,703 start-ups, which are active in 333 separate NAICS

classes.

Variables

Our dependent variable is the binary variable trademark or patent, indicating whether a start-

up filed its first IP application in the form of a trademark (=1) or a patent (=0). We used the

application dates because they relate to the point in time at which the start-up made the

strategic decision to obtain a specific type of IP. The publication date is less suitable to

determine this point in time because the length of the application procedure may vary from

case to case, and is generally more complicated and lengthy for patents (WIPO, 2011).

2 US Census concentration measures are also used by the Federal Trade Commission when taking decisions on anti-trust cases.

15

Because our dependent variable is binary, we use logistic regression models. As our main

independent variables, we measure competition intensity by the C4 ratio, which is the sum of

the market share of the four largest firms that are active within a particular NAICS class.3

The C4 ratio is widely accepted as a measure of competition intensity (e.g., Domowitz,

Hubbard, & Peterson, 1986; Harris, 1998). As noted above, competition data is published

every 5 years by the US Census Bureau. Accordingly, we use the C4 ratio published in 1997

for the start-ups in our sample that applied for initial IP up until 2002. We use the C4 ratio

published in 2002 for start-ups that filed initial IP up until 2007. Further, we measure the

effect of a VC investor on start-up IP strategy with the VC dummy variable, indicating

whether the start-up has received any VC funds up until the point in time of its first IP

application. The start-up’s customer type is captured by the Business to consumer dummy,

indicating whether the start-up is serving consumers (=1) or other businesses (=0).

Information on the start-up’s customer type was reported in VentureXpert at the time of

receiving VC funding. Of the 1,895 VC-backed start-ups in our sample, 1,438 start-ups were

defined as serving either consumers or other businesses. Our hypothesis addressing the

relation between the start-up’s customer type and its initial IP application will therefore be

analyzed via this subsample. In order to capture other factors that may influence the initial IP

application of a start-up we use the following control variables.

We control for the average R&D intensity and the average advertising intensity,

calculated for each individual market niche in COMPUSTAT. We calculated the average

R&D- and advertising intensity within the market niche over the 3 years prior to the start-ups

initial IP application. Start-ups operating in research intensive market niches are more likely

3 The Herfindahl index was also available from the US Census Bureau, but is only published for manufacturing sectors. We used the four-firm-ratio because it was available for a broader range of industries. The correlation between the Herfindahl index and the four-firm-ratio was 0.93. Also, previous works suggest that there are no substantial differences between the two measures (e.g. Scott, 1993).

16

to file patent applications (Griliches, 1984; 1998). Similarly, a higher advertising intensity

within a market niche may be related to a more trademark orientated IP strategy (Malmberg,

2005; Mendonça et al., 2004).

Further, we calculated start-up age in years at the point in time of a start-up’s first IP

application. To control for time trends in trademark or patent applications, we use 10

application year dummies indicating the year in which the start-up applied for first IP. Time

related shifts in environmental, management, or legal conditions may affect IP applications

(Kortum & Lerner, 1999). We distinguish between six industry dummies, categorized by

VentureXpert, which are “biotechnology”, “communications and media”, “computer related”,

“medical/health/life science”, “non-high-technology”, and “semiconductors/other

electronics”. IP protection regimes may vary across different industry types (Dushnitsky &

Shaver, 2009). Lastly, possible regional influences are controlled for by 17 US region

dummies. The type and degree of regional technology orientation (e.g., Silicon Valley, New

England) may affect IP behavior (Audretsch & Feldman, 1996).

RESULTS

Descriptive results

Table 1 shows descriptive statistics across industries. As can be expected, patents are more

likely to be filed as a first IP right within technology based industries such as the biotech-,

semiconductors-, and medical/life science industries. Having a trademark as a first IP right is

more likely in non-high-tech-, communications-, and computer related industries.4

Concerning the start-ups customer type, we see that start-ups are most likely to sell to

consumers in the Medical/ life science industry (37.8%) and in the non-high tech industry

(35.1%). Start-ups supply to other businesses most frequently in the Semiconductors industry

4 Computer related start-ups were mainly engaged in computer software, services, and internet related activities.

17

(98.4%). This seems in line with the suggestion that start-ups serving other businesses are

more likely to operate under the technical- or product differentiation strategy. Further,

average R&D intensity (NAICS based) is highest for markets related to biotech (on average

44.2% of sales), where advertising intensity is highest in computer related- and

semiconductor industries (on average 1.6% of sales). Lastly, the C4 ratio reveals that

competition is least intensive in more technical, patent driven markets such as

semiconductors (C4 of 50.2%) and biotech (C4 of 41.3%). This is in line with previous works

that underscore the role of patents as powerful exclusion rights (Besanko et al., 2010;

Greenhalgh & Rogers, 2010).

Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics for our full sample. Of the start-ups in our

sample, 61% filed for a trademark first instead of a patent. This can be explained by the

slightly broader applicability of a trademark, being potentially relevant in both technology-

and service related markets, whereas patents are especially relevant in technology based

markets (Greenhalgh & Rogers, 2006a). Further, we see that different types of competition

intensity are represented in our sample. The average C4 ratio of the market niches entered is

36.4% (median 34.9%). Interestingly, the most competitive market niche is dental services

with a C4 ratio of 0.7% (NAICS classification = 621210). In contrast, the least competitive

market niche is the manufacturing of space vehicles with a C4 ratio of 91.6% (NAICS

classification = 336414). With regard to VC financing, we observe that 40% of the start-ups

in our sample had received VC funding before applying for their first IP right. Further, the

market niches show on average a higher R&D (14.2% of sales) than advertising intensity

(1.4% of sales). Both measures are right-skewed (e.g., maximum of R&D intensity =

2,456.7%, mean = 14.2%). In the additional analysis section, we correct for this by taking

only NAICS sectors into account for which we have R&D and advertising intensity

information of at least 5 firms (this resulted in a mean R&D intensity of 11.5%, and a

18

maximum value of 38.9%). Lastly, the average start-up’s age when applying for a first IP

right was 2.3 years. We use the logarithm of start-up age in our regression analysis.

Table 3 shows the correlations and variance inflation factors (VIFs). The reported

correlations are in line with our hypothesized effects. The VIFs in our regressions models are

well below the critical level of 10, indicating that multicollinearity is not a problem in our

models (see also Neter, Wasserman & Kutner, 1985; Hair, Black, Babin, Anderson, &

Tatham, 2006).

--------------------------------------------- Insert Tables 1, 2 and 3 about here

---------------------------------------------

Multivariate results

Table 4 shows logistic regression results for our dependent variable trademark or patent.

Model 1 only includes our control variables, but still excludes the industry dummy variables.

Interestingly, log(start-up age) shows that relatively younger start-ups are more likely to file

for patents first. This seems intuitive as R&D and product development activities tend to take

place in an earlier stage as compared to marketing, which regards the commercialization of

an already sellable product. This effect is also in line with existing work showing that start-

ups tend to be overly focused on their invention rather than on market orientation within early

stages (Hisrisch, 1989; Wortman et al., 1989). In the subsequent models we test our

hypothesized effects. Model 2 includes the C4 ratio, which is close to being significant at the

5% level with a p-value of 0.053 (two-sided test). Its coefficient indicates that an increase in

competition is likely to lead to a higher likelihood of filing the first IP right in the form of a

trademark rather than a patent. More specifically, a decrease in the C4 ratio of 1% is likely to

lead to a 1.2% increase in the likelihood of filing a trademark first. Further, Model 2 shows a

19

negative and significant coefficient for R&D intensity, indicating a positive effect of this

variable on filing for a patent. The effect of advertising intensity is positively significant at

the 10% significance level, indicating a positive effect of this variable on filing for a

trademark. In Model 3, we introduce the VC dummy variable, of which the coefficient shows

that VC-backed start-ups are more likely to file their first IP right in the form of a trademark

rather than a patent (p<0.01). This provides support for our third Hypothesis. Next, Model 4

includes both the VC dummy and the C4 ratio, revealing that the C4 ratio is significant at the

5% significance level when also controlling for the influence of VC investors on start-up

management. This provides support for our first Hypothesis. Finally, Model 5 checks the

robustness of our results when introducing the industry dummy variables. Because the

industry dummies capture variance in competition, the coefficient of the C4 ratio decreases,

and becomes significant at the 10% level. The VC dummy variable remains highly significant.

Table 5 presents results with regard to a start-up’s customer type (Hypothesis 2). We

analyze the subsample of 1,438 VC-backed start-ups for which we have customer type

information. Model 1 is a baseline model, also including the C4 ratio (p<0.01), which is

again negative and significant. Model 2 includes the Business to consumer dummy. Its

positive coefficient indicates that start-ups selling to consumers are more likely to file initial

IP in the form of a trademark, where start-ups selling to other businesses are more likely to

file initial IP in the form of a patent. When including the industry dummy variables in Model

3, the business to consumer dummy remains significant (p<0.05). The C4 ratio, constructed

on a sector level, is no longer significant when including industry dummies. This is likely to

be related to the lowered statistical power by focusing on the VC-backed subsample.

------------------------------------------ Insert Tables 4 and 5 about here

------------------------------------------

20

Additional analyses and robustness checks

We conducted several additional analyses. A first robustness check is related to the R&D-

and advertising intensity measures, which are rightly-skewed. As noted, these measures are

calculated for each NAICS class based on COMPUSTAT data. For some sectors, however,

the COMPUSTAT data holds information for only a few individual firms. We corrected for

this by using only the average R&D- and advertising intensity measures which are based on

sectors holding at least 5 firms, reducing the volatility of these measures. This reduced our

sample to 3,966 start-ups active in 216 different NAICS classifications. The regression results

are presented in Table 6, showing a more intuitive coefficient for the R&D intensity (e.g. -

0.001 in Model 1, Table 4 versus -0.029, in Model 1, Table 6). Table 6 shows similar results

for our hypothesized effects.

As a second robustness check, we excluded the start-ups in our sample for which the

dates of the first patent- and trademark application were recorded within 6 months of each

other. Given that these start-ups applied for both types of IP within a short period of time,

there may be no clear preference for either a trademark or a patent. Further, by excluding

these start-ups we reduce the possibility that our dependent variable is incorrect due to errors

or delays in the recording of the application dates, or due to differences between the filing

systems of patents and trademarks. This step reduced our sample to 3,819 start-ups active in

319 NIACS sectors. The results of our hypothesized effects remain similar as compared to

the results from our main analysis. The only difference is that within this subsample, the C4

ratio is significant also on a 5% level when including the industry dummy variables.5

Thirdly, it could be that our results are driven by large numbers of start-ups being active

in the same NAICS class. Overall, our sample holds 4,703 start-ups that are active in 333

5 The result of this robustness check and subsequent regressions are available upon request.

21

separate NAICS classes. As the C4 ratio, and also R&D- and advertising intensity are

measured per NAICS category, the variance in our sample becomes limited when many start-

ups are active within the same NAICS classes. The distribution of start-ups over NAICS

classes is highly skewed (1,267 start-ups were active in the most prominent NAICS class,

followed by 441 start-ups in the second most prominent NAICS class). We checked for the

impact of the sector distribution by excluding the NAICS classes that held more than 50 start-

ups. We found similar results with regard to our hypothesized effects. Shifting the cut-off

point regarding the number of start-ups per NIACS class further down, for example excluding

NAICS classes with more than 25 start-ups, also led to similar results.

Finally, the VentureXpert database, reporting VC investments, contains additional

information on the start-ups in our sample which may be relevant to control for. We

conducted a subsample analysis, considering only the start-ups that have received VC funds

when applying for their first IP right.6 For these start-ups, we are able to control for more

information that we gathered from the reported funding round in VentureXpert. VCs

categorize a start-up as being in a specific stage, differentiating whether a start-up is still

working on its first proto-type, or if it is already in a later stage, working on initial sales,

expanding its market share, or ultimately, looking for an exit. Furthermore, we are able to

control for the funding stage (round number), the amount of VC funds received, the number

of investors involved, the VCs’ experience and maturity levels, and the different types of VC

investors (VC firms, business angel, corporate investor, financial institution, governmental

investors). Each specific VC actor type operates under a different set of incentives, and may

therefore influence the start-up’s management in a different manner (Dushnitsky & Shapira,

2010; Sorenson & Stuart, 2008). Controlling for these additional factors, we find similar

6 40 percent of the start-ups received VC funds before their first IP application.

22

effects for the C4 ratio (ß = –0.016, p<0.01) and the Business to consumer dummy (ß = 0.650,

p<0.01).

----------------------------------------- Insert Table 6 about here

-----------------------------------------

DISCUSSION

Our work is the first to analyze determinants of IP orientation distinguishing between patent

and trademarks applications. We examine the initial IP direction (a trademark, or a patent) of

4,743 start-up entrants in the US between 1998 and 2007. Our findings contribute to several

literature streams.

Firstly, we extend the literature on market structure and IP rights. Previous studies have

focused mainly on the relations between market structure and patenting (e.g. Arora, 1997;

Acs & Audretsch, 1987; Greenhalgh & Rogers, 2006a; Levin et al., 1985; Loury, 1979;

Malerba & Orsenigo, 2002; Scherer, 1984), and, more recently, also considered the role of

trademarks (Davies, 2009; Kong, & Seldon, 2004; Ramello, 2006; Ramello & Silva, 2006).

We contribute to this literature by addressing trademarks and patents jointly, considering the

effect of market structure on the IP strategy of entering start-ups. We show that entering start-

ups are more trademark-orientated in competitive markets, and become more patent-

orientated as market competition decreases.

Previous studies addressing the relationship between patents and market structure

suggest that market power gives an increased incentive to invest in R&D, and therefore leads

to increased patenting (Schumpeterian view). Moreover, in a similar vein, patents are

suggested as one of the main determinants of market structure (Arora, 1997; see also Cohen

& Levin (1989) who discuss empirical work on both relations). With regard to these prior

findings, we argue that reverse causality should not be an issue in our analysis. We consider

23

initial patent- and trademark applications of new entering start-ups. These IP applications are

unlikely to have affected the given C4 ratio, measured prior to these application dates.

Further, the included controls regarding industry types and the average R&D intensity within

the specific market niche should reduce the likelihood that the effect found for the C4 ratio is

determined by patenting.

Secondly, we contribute by providing empirical evidence for the intuition that the

protection of brand- and advertising assets by trademarks is more relevant for start-ups

operating downstream, distributing a product to end-consumers (Carter et al., 1994; Miller,

1986; Tan, 2001). Correspondingly, we show that patents, protecting inputs in the production

process, are more likely used upstream when selling to other businesses (Lambert, 2008;

McGee et al, 1995).

Thirdly, our findings contribute to the literature on the role of IP rights in venture capital

financing, by showing that VC-backed start-ups are more likely to file initial IP in the form of

a trademark rather than a patent, as compared to start-ups that are not yet under the care of a

VC. Previous works in this area show that VC investors value patents positively, and also

suggest that patented start-ups should be able to attract VC funds more easily compared to

other start-ups (Audretsch, Bönte, & Mahagaonkar, 2012; Cao & Hsu, 2011; Engel &

Keilbach, 2007; Haeussler et al., 2009; Baum & Silverman, 2004; Hsu & Ziedonis, 2007;

Lerner, 1994; Mann & Sager, 2007). The work of Block et al. (2012) is the first to address

trademark valuations by VCs, showing that trademarks are valued positively in early start-up

stages. Our study extends this literature by showing that VCs also affect the type of IP filed

by the start-ups they invest in. The preference of VCs towards the filing of a trademark is

understandable when considering the timeline a VC has to relate to (5 to 10 years generally to

exit a start-up) and therefore the need to become operational on the market (see also Hellman

& Puri, 2000). The results also contribute to literature addressing the impact of VC financing

24

on the development of start-up firms. Thus far it is shown that VCs are likely to affect the

financial performance of the start-up invested in (Schefczyk & Gerpott, 2001; Fitza, Matusik,

& Mosakowski, 2009), the professionalization of the start-up (Hellman & Puri, 2002), the

start-up’s time-to-market (Hellman & Puri, 2000), the start-up’s growth rate (Davila, Foster,

& Gupta, 2003), and its probability of surviving (Manigart, Baeyens, & Van Hyfte, 2002).

Our findings add to this that VCs are likely to influence the IP management of start-ups,

increasing the likelihood of filing initial IP in the form of a trademark rather than a patent.

LIMITATIONS AND FURTHER RESEARCH

Although we provide novel contributions, our paper contains a number of limitations leading

to several suggestions for future research. First, our analysis only considers the very first IP

application filed by start-up firms. Though early stage entrants have the advantage of not

being likely to influence market structure (as measured by the C4 concentration index), we

have to be careful in drawing conclusions regarding the IP strategies of later stage, more

mature companies. Future research could analyze interactions of IP strategies and market

structure over time, taking into account the causality issues discussed in the patent-market

structure literature (Cohen & Levin, 1989). Second, our dataset containing information on

market dynamics and start-up firm level characteristics had to be constructed from several

data sources. With regard to the IP data, the matching process relied on the manual creation

of company name patterns used to extract information on trademark and patent filings. This

method proved to be highly reliable and was individually checked with the records in the

USPTO trademark register. Still, we cannot completely rule out possible mismatches or the

failure to include relevant IP applications in our dataset (IP data could be identified for 85.3%

of the start-ups taken from VentureXpert). Third, we have only limited information with

regard to the background of the entrepreneurs involved in the start-up. For example, venture

25

founding teams with a more technical background might be more focused on patenting in

early stages, where founders with more previous experience in the marketing field may be

more likely to recognize the relevance of trademarks (see also Munari & Toschi, 2010;

Wright, Lockett, Clarysse, & Binks, 2006). As our work employs solely publicly available

data sources, survey-based data could help us understand IP decisions more thoroughly at the

firm-level.

As we expect that trademarks play a relevant, potentially powerful role especially in

combination with patents in the protection of innovative assets, we encourage future work to

help us understand IP strategies at a portfolio level, and into later company stages.

CONCLUSIONS

Analyzing the initial trademark- and patent applications of 4,703 start-up entrants, we find

that market structure, the start-up’s customer type, and the involvement of a VC investor have

a significant influence on the start-ups initial IP direction. Our findings show that as market

competition intensifies, entering start-ups will be more likely to file initial IP in the form of a

trademark and less likely in the form of a patent. Our results further show that trademarks are

of a greater priority for start-ups that serve end-consumers, as compared to patents, which are

more likely to be filed by start-ups operating more upstream. Lastly, we find that the

ambition of VC investors to bring a start-up’s product to the market leads to a greater

likelihood of filing initial IP in the form of a trademark.

26

REFERENCES

Abernathy WJ, Clark KB. 1984. Innovation: mapping the winds of creative destruction. Research Policy 14 (1): 3-22.

Abimbola T. 2001. Branding as a competitive strategy for demand management in SMEs. Journal of Research in Marketing & Entrepreneurship 3 (2): 97-106.

Acs ZJ, Audretsch DB. 1987. Innovation, market structure, and firm size. The review of Economics and Statistics 69 (4): 567-574.

Ali A, Klasa S, Yeung E. 2009. The limitations of industry concentration measures constructed with compustat data: implications for finance research. Review of Financial Studies 22 (10): 3839-3871.

Amara N, Landry R, Traoré N. 2008. Managing the protection of innovations in knowledge-intensive business services. Research Policy 37 (9): 1530-1547.

Arora A. 1997. Patents, licensing, and market structure in the chemical industry. Research Policy 26 (4-5): 391-403.

Arrow K. 1962. Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: Nelson, R. (Eds.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity. Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Audretsch DB, Feldmann MP. 1996. R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. The American Economic Review 86 (3): 630-640.

Audretsch DB, Bönte W, Mahagaonkar P. 2012. Financial signaling by innovative nascent ventures: the relevance of patents and prototypes. Research Policy 41 (8): 1407-1421.

Baum JAC, Silverman BS. 2004. Picking winners or building them? Alliance, intellectual, and human capital as selection criteria in venture financing and performance of biotech start-ups. Journal of Business Venturing 19 (3): 411-436.

Beamon BM. 1998. Supply chain design and analysis: models and methods. International Journal of Production Economics 55 (3): 281-294.

Berkery D. 2008. Raising venture capital for the serious entrepreneur. McGraw-Hill, New York.

Besanko D, Dranove D, Shanley M, Schaefer S. 2010. Economics of Strategy. Wiley: New York.

Block JH, De Vries AGB, Schumann J, Sandner PG. 2012. Trademarks and early-stage venture capital valuation. Working paper. Available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2064508

Carter NM, Stearns TM, Reynolds PD, Miller BA. 1994. New venture strategies: theory development with an empirical base. Strategic Management Journal 15 (1): 21-41.

27

Caves RE, Porter ME. 1977. From entry barriers to mobility barriers: conjectural decisions and contrived deterrence to new competition. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 91 (2): 241-262.

Cao J, Hsu PH. 2011. The informational role of patents in venture capital financing. Working paper. Available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1678809.

Chaganti R, Chaganti R, Mahajan V. 1989. Profitable small business strategies under different types of competition. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 13 (3), 21-35.

Chauvin KW, Hirschey M. 1993. Advertising, R&D expenditures and the market value of the firm. Financial Management 22 (4): 128-140.

Christensen CM, Bower JL. 1996. Customer power, strategic investment, and the failure of leading firms. Strategic Management Journal 17 (3): 197-218.

Cohen WM, Levin RC. 1989. Empirical studies of innovation and market structure. In: Schmalensee R., Willig RD. (eds), Handbook of Industrial Organization. Elsevier.

Davies LN. 2009. Leveraging trademarks to capture innovation returns. Working paper. Available at: http://www2.druid.dk/conferences/viewpaper.php?id=5655&cf=32

Davila A, Foster G, Gupta M. 2003. Venture capital financing and the growth of startup firms. Journal of Business Venturing 18 (6): 689-708.

DeYong R, Örs E. 2004. Advertising and pricing at multiple-output firms: evidence from US thrift institutions. Working paper. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

Domowitz I, Hubbard RG, Peterson BC. 1986. Business cycles and the relationship between concentration and price-cost margins. The RAND Journal of Economics 17 (1): 1-17.

Dushnitsky G, Shapira Z. 2010. Entrepreneurial finance meets organizational reality: comparing investment practices and performance of corporate and independent venture capitalists. Strategic Management Journal 31 (9): 990-1017.

Dushnitsky G, Shaver JM. 2009. Limitations to interorganizational knowledge acquisition: the paradox of corporate venture capital. Strategic Management Journal 30 (10): 1045-1064.

Economides N. 1988. The economics of trademarks. Trademark Reporter 78: 523-539.

Engel D, Keilbach M. 2007. Firm-level implications of early stage venture capital investment – An empirical investigation. Journal of Empirical Finance 14 (2): 150-167.

Fitza M, Matusik SF, Mosakowski E. 2009. Do VCs matter? The importance of owners on performance variance in start-up firms. Strategic Management Journal 30 (4): 387-404.

Flikkema MJ, De Man AP, Wolters M. 2010. New trademark registration as an indicator of innovation: results of an explorative study of Benelux trademark data. Working paper, available at: ftp://zappa.ubvu.vu.nl/20100009.pdf

Gompers PA, Lerner J. 2004. The venture capital cycle. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

28

Graham SJH, Hancock G, Marco AC, Myers AF. 2013. The USPTO trademark case files dataset: descriptions, lessons, and insights. Working paper, available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2188621

Graham S, Somaya D. 2004. Complementary uses of patents, copyrights and trademarks by software firms: evidence from litigation. Working paper, available at: http://zinc.zew.de/pub/zew-docs/div/IKT04/Paper_Graham.pdf

Greenhalgh C, Rogers M. 2006a. The value of innovation: the interaction of competition, R&D and IP. Research Policy 35 (4): 562-580.

Greenhalgh C, Rogers M. 2006b. Trade marks and market value in UK firms. Melbourne Institute Working Paper Series. Available at: http://economics.ouls.ox.ac.uk/13545/1/Item.pdf.

Greenhalgh C, Rogers M. 2007. Trade marks and performance in UK firms: evidence of Schumpeterian competition through innovation. Discussion Paper. Department of Economics, University of Oxford. Available at: http://economics.ouls.ox.ac.uk/13545/1/Item.pdf.

Greenhalgh C, Rogers M. 2010. Innovation, intellectual property, and economic growth. Princeton University Press.

Griliches Z. 1984. R&D, patents and productivity. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Griliches Z. 1998. R&D and productivity: the econometric evidence. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Haeussler C, Harhoff D, Muller E. 2009. To be financed or not: the role of patents for venture capital financing. Working paper. Available at: http://epub.ub.uni-muenchen.de/8970/1/Haeussler_et_al_VCPat_Jan2009LMU_WP_Reihe.pdf

Hair J, Black WC, Babin B, Anderson RE, Tatham RL. 2006. Multivariate data analysis (6th ed.). Prentice Hall. Englewood Cliffs.

Harris MS. 1998. The association between competition and managers’ business segment reporting decisions. Journal of Accounting Research 36 (1): 111-128.

Harland, C.M. 1996. Supply chain management: relationships, chains and networks. British Journal of Management 7, Special Issue, S63-S83.

Hellman T, Puri M. 2000. The interaction between product market and financing strategy: the role of venture capital. Review of Financial Studies 13 (4): 959-984.

Hellman T, Puri M. 2002. Venture capital and the professionalization of start-up firms: empirical evidence. The Journal of Finance 57 (1): 169-197.

Helmers C, Rogers M. 2010. Innovation and the survival of new firms in the UK. Review of Industrial Organization 36 (3), 227-248.

29

Henderson R. 1993. Underinvestment and incompetence as response to radical innovation: evidence from the photolithographic alignment equipment industry. The RAND Journal of Economics 24 (2): 248-270.

Hill CWL, Rothaermel FT. 2003. The performance of incumbent firms in the face of radical technological innovation. Academy of Management Review 28 (2): 257-274.

Hills GE. 1984. Market analysis and marketing in new ventures: venture capitalists’ perceptions. Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research: 167-182.

Hills GE, Hultman CM, Miles MP. 2008. The evolution and development of entrepreneurial marketing. Journal of Small Business Management 46 (1): 99-112.

Hisrich RD. 1989. Marketing and entrepreneurship research interface, in: Hills G, LaForge RW, Parker BJ. (eds), Research at the marketing/ entrepreneurship interface: 3-17. Chicago, University of Illinois.

Hsu DH, Ziedonis RH. 2007. Patents as quality signals for entrepreneurial ventures. Working paper. Available at: http://www2.druid.dk/conferences/viewpaper.php?id=1717&cf=9.

Kong Y, Seldon JR. 2004. Pseudo-generic products and barriers to entry in pharmaceutical markets. Review of Industrial Organization 25 (1): 71-86.

Kortum S. 1993. Equilibrium R&D and the patent – R&D ratio: US evidence. The American Economic Review 83 (2): 450-457.

Kortum S, Lerner J. 1999. What is behind the recent surge in patenting? Research Policy 28 (1): 1-22.

Lambert DE. 2004. Supply chain management: processes, partnerships, performance. Sarasota, FL: Supply Chain Management Institute.

Lerner J. 1994. The Importance of Patent Scope: An Empirical Analysis. The Rand Journal of Economics 25 (2): 319-333.

Levin RC, Cohen WM, Mowery DC. 1985. R&D appropriability, opportunity, and market structure: new evidence on some Schumpeterian hypotheses. The American Economic Review 75 (2): 20-24.

Li H. 2001. How does new venture strategy matter in the environment – performance relationship? Journal of High Technology Management Research 12 (2): 183-204.

Loury GC. 1979. Market structure and innovation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 93 (3): 395-410.

Malerba F, Orsenigo L. 2002. Innovation and market structure in the dynamics of the pharmaceutical industry and biotechnology: towards a history-friendly model. Industrial and Corporate Change 11 (4): 667-703.

Malmberg C. 2005. Trademark statistics as innovation indicator – a micro study. Working paper No 2005/17, Centre for innovation, Research and Competence in the Learning

30

Economy. Available at: http://www.circle.lu.se/upload/CIRCLE/workingpapers/200517_Malmberg.pdf.

Manigart S, Baeyens K, Van Hyfte W. 2002. The survival of venture capital backed companies. Venture Capital – An International Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 4 (2): 103-124.

Mann RJ, Sager TW. 2007. Patents, venture capital, and software start-ups. Research Policy 36 (2): 193-208.

McAfee RP, Mialon HM, Williams MA. 2004. What is a barrier to entry? The American Economic Review 94 (2): 461-465.

McGee JE, Dowling MJ, Megginson WL. 1995. Cooperative Strategy and new venture performance: the role of business strategy and management experience. Strategic Management Journal 16 (7), 565-580.

Mendonça S, Pereira TS, Godinho MM. 2004. Trademarks as an indicator of innovation and industrial change. Research Policy 33 (9): 1385-1404.

Miles R, Snow C. 1978. Organizational strategy, structure, and process. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Miller D. 1986. Configurations of strategy and structure: towards a synthesis. Strategic Management Journal 7 (3): 233-249.

Miller D. 1991. Generalists and specialists: two business strategies and their contexts. In Shrivastava P, Huff A, Dutton J. (eds), Advances in Strategic Management. JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, 7, 3-41.

Munari F, Toschi L. 2011. Do venture capitalists have a bias against investment in academic spin-offs? Evidence from the micro- and nanotechnology sector in the UK. Industrial and Corporate Change 20 (2): 397-432.

Neter J, Wasserman W, Kutner MH. 1985. Applied linear statistical models: regression analysis of variance, and experimental design. Richard Irwin, Inc., Homewood, IL.

Onkvisit S, Shaw JJ. 1989. Service marketing: image, branding, and competition. Business Horizons 32 (I): 13-18.

Porter ME. 1980. Competitive strategy – techniques for analyzing industries and competitors. Free Press, New York.

Ramello GB. 2006. What’s in a sign? Trademark law and economic theory. Journal of Economic Surveys 20 (4): 547-565.

Ramello GB, Silva F. 2006. Appropriating the signs and meaning: the elusive economics of trademark. Industrial and Corporate Change 15 (6): 937-963.

Sahlman WA. 1990. The structure and governance of venture capital organizations. Journal of Financial Economics 27 (2): 473-521.

31

Sandner PG, Block JH. 2011. The market value of R&D, patents and trademarks. Research Policy 40 (7): 969-985.

Schefczyk M, Gerpott TJ. 2001. Management support for portfolio companies of venture capital firms: an empirical study of german venture capital investments. British Journal of Management 12 (3): 201-216.

Scherer FM. 1984. Innovation and growth. Schumpeterian perspectives. Cambridge MIT Press, MA.

Schmalensee R. 1978. Entry deterrence in the ready-to-eat breakfast cereal industry. Bell Journal of Economics 9 (Autumn): 305-327.

Scott J. 1993. Purposive diversification and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.

Schrader R, Siegel DS. 2007. Assessing the relation between human capital and firm performance: evidence from technology-based new ventures. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 31 (6): 893-908.

Schumpeter JA. 1950. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

Sorenson O, Stuart TE. 2008. Bringing the context back in: settings and the search for syndicate partners in venture capital investment networks. Administrative Science Quarterly 53 (2): 266-294.

Sutton J. 2007. Sunk Costs and Market Structure. Cambridge MIT Press, MA.

Tan TC. 2001. A framework of supply chain management literature. European Journal of Purchasing & Supply Management 7 (1): 39-48.

Teece DJ. 1986. Profiting from technological innovation: implications for integration, collaboration, licensing, and public policy. Research Policy 15 (6): 285-305.

Wagner S, Cockburn I. 2010. Patents and the survival of internet-related IPOs. Research Policy 39 (2), 214-228.

Waring GF. 1996. Industry differences in the persistence of firm-specific returns. The American Economic Review 86 (5), 1253-1265.

WIPO. 2004. WIPO intellectual property handbook: policy, law and use. Available at: http://www.wipo.int/about-ip/en/iprm/

WIPO. 2011. Intellectual property – some basic definitions. Available at: http://www.wipo.int/about-ip/en/studies/publications/ip_definitions.htm.

Wortman MS, Spann MS, Adams M. 1989. The interface of entrepreneurship and marketing: concepts and research perspectives, in: Hills G, LaForge RW, Parker BJ. (eds), Research at the marketing/ entrepreneurship interface: 117-137. Chicago, University of Illinois.

32

Wright M, Lockett A, Clarysse B, Binks M. 2006. University spin-out companies and venture capital. Research Policy 35 (4): 481-501.

33

TABLES TO BE INSERTED IN THE TEXT

TABLE 1 Descriptive statistics: Industry categories

Industry category % of start-ups

in sample

% start-ups filing a trademark first or a

patent first

Start-ups’ customer type

(in %)

Average R&D intensity (in %)

Average advertising

intensity (in %) Average C4 ratio

Biotechnology 6.5 trademark: 35.2 Consumer: 27.2 44.2 1.0 41.3

patent: 64.8 Business: 72.8

Communications and media 14.1 trademark: 61.2 Consumer: 7.3 11.0 1.3 37.8

patent: 28.8 Business: 92.7

Computer related 47.9 trademark: 72.4 Consumer: 14.3 12.5 1.6 34.6

patent: 27.6 Business: 85.7

Medical/ life science 11.6 trademark: 39.4 Consumer: 37.8 10.0 1.0 33.5

patent: 60.6 Business: 62.2

Non high-tech 10.4 trademark: 73.5 Consumer: 35.1 14.4 1.3 30.4

patent: 26.5 Business: 64.9

Semiconductor/ other elect. 9.5 trademark: 30.9 Consumer: 1.6 12.2 1.6 50.2

patent: 69.1 Business: 98.4 Notes: N = 4,703 start-ups (Customer type is based on 1,438 start-ups). Data sources: VC data from VentureXpert (accessed October 28, 2011); trademark data from United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO); patent data from PATSTAT Worldwide Patent Statistical Database (OECD/European Patent Office); R&D and advertising intensity from COMPUSTAT; C4 ratio from US Census Bureau. Sample includes start-ups that filed first IP during the period 1998-2007.

TABLE 2 Descriptive statistics

Variables Mean S.D. Median Min. Max. Skewness

Trademark or patent 0.61 1 0 1

C4 ratio 36.4 18.0 34.9 0.7 91.6 0.3

VC dummy 0.40 0 0 1

Business to consumer dummy 17.0 0 0 1

R&D intensity 14.2 73.0 11.7 0 2,456.7 25.3

Advertising intensity 1.4 1.7 1.2 0 32.4 4.6

Start-up age (in years) 2.3 4.8 1.0 0 86.1 6.8 Notes: N = 4,703 start-ups (Business to consumer dummy regards 1,438 start-ups). Data sources: VC data from VentureXpert (accessed October 28, 2011); trademark data from United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO); patent data from PATSTAT Worldwide Patent Statistical Database (OECD/European Patent Office); R&D and advertising intensity from COMPUSTAT; C4 ratio from US Census Bureau. Sample includes start-ups that filed first IP during the period 1998-2007.

29

TABLE 3 Correlations

Variables 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 VIFs a

1. Trademark or patent

2. C4 ratio -0.094* 1.14

3. VC dummy 0.133* 0.024 1.20

4. Business to consumer dummy 0.049* -0.104* -0.072* 1.17

5. R&D intensity -0.031 0.007 -0.016 0.009 1.02

6. Advertising intensity 0.051* 0.188* 0.027 0.058* -0.014 1.09

7. Log (Start-up age) 0.179* -0.034 0.354* -0.042 -0.009 -0.012 1.24

8. Industry: biotechnology -0.138* 0.072* -0.040* 0.062* 0.108* -0.061* -0.065* 1.45

9. Industry: communic. and media 0.004 0.032 0.052* -0.105* -0.018 -0.019 -0.031 -0.107*

10. Industry: computer related 0.229* -0.100* 0.051* -0.073* -0.022 0.100* 0.060* -0.252* -0.389* 2.34

11. Industry: medical/ life science -0.159* -0.059* -0.064* 0.183* -0.021 -0.093* -0.049* -0.095* -0.147* -0.348* 1.71

12. Industry: non high-tech 0.089* -0.114 -0.030 0.162* 0.001 -0.031 0.118* -0.090* -0.138* -0.327* -0.124* 1.66

13. Industry: semicond/ other elect. -0.198* 0.248* -0.014 -0.142* -0.009 0.037 -0.073* -0.085* -0.131* -0.311* -0.117* -0.110* 1.59 Notes: N = 4,703 start-ups (Business to consumer dummy regards 1,438 start-ups). Data sources: VC data from VentureXpert (accessed October 28, 2011); trademark data from United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO); patent data from PATSTAT Worldwide Patent Statistical Database (OECD/European Patent Office); R&D and advertising intensity from COMPUSTAT; C4 ratio from US Census Bureau. Sample includes start-ups that filed first IP during the period 1998-2007. * Significance level p ≤ 0.01 a VIFs relate to Model 5, Table 4; VIF of Business to consumer dummy is reported from Model 3, Table 5.

30

TABLE 4 The effect of market structure and VC funding on start-up’s initial IP (Hypothesis

1 and 3)

Dependent variable: Trademark(=1) or patent(=0) Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5

Independent variables

C4 ratio -0.012† -0.012* -0.005† (0.006) (0.006) (0.003)

VC dummy 0.385**

0.405**

0.402** (0.070)

(0.073)

(0.074) R&D intensity -0.001 -0.001* -0.001 -0.001* -0.001

(0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000)

Advertising intensity 0.093

0.127†

0.090

0.125†

0.071** (0.063) (0.070) (0.062) (0.070) (0.026)

Log (Start-up age) 0.535**

0.535**

0.434**

0.430**

0.339** (0.048) (0.049) (0.043) (0.045) (0.049)

IP applic. year dummies (10 cat.) p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 US region dummies (17 cat.) p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01

Industry: biotechnology -0.982** (0.159) Industry: computer related 0.481** (0.130) Industry: medical/ life science -0.887** (0.214) Industry: non high-tech 0.439** (0.160) Industry: semiconductors/ other elect. -1.110** (0.174)

N start-ups 4,703 4,703 4,703 4,703 4,703 N NAICS sectors (6-digit) 333 333 333 333 333 Chi-squared (model fit) 486.59** 489.60** 520.49** 527.66** 1,433.41** Pseudo R-squared 0.055

0.062 0.060 0.067 0.125

Increases in model fit (LR-test) a 44.22** 30.33** 46.98** 365.83** Notes: Standard errors are clustered on 6-digit NAICS sectors (in parentheses). Reference group for IP application year: 2001; reference US region: ‘Silicon Valley’; reference industry: ‘communications and media’. Data sources: VC data from VentureXpert (accessed October 28, 2011); trademark data from United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO); patent data from PATSTAT Worldwide Patent Statistical Database (OECD/European Patent Office); R&D and advertising intensity from COMPUSTAT; C4 ratio from US Census Bureau. Sample includes start-ups that filed first IP during the period 1998-2007. a Likelihood ratio tests relate to the preceding nested model. † Significance level p < 0.1. * Significance level 0.05 > p ≥ 0.01. ** Si gnificance level p ≤ 0.01. Two-sided tests are used.

31

TABLE 5 Subsample analysis: Effect of customer type on start-up’s initial

IP (Hypothesis 2)

Dependent variable: Trademark(=1) or patent(=0) Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Independent variables

C4 ratio -0.015** -0.014* -0.004 (0.006) (0.006) (0.003)

Business to consumer dummy 0.579* 0.608* (0.247) (0.251)

R&D intensity -0.001* -0.001** -0.001* (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Advertising intensity 0.202*

0.200*

0.107† (0.089) (0.093) (0.059)

Log (Start-up age) 0.345**

0.355**

0.262** (0.078) (0.076) (0.075)

IP applic. year dummies (10 cat.) p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 US region dummies (17 cat.) p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01

Industry: biotechnology -1.068* (0.522) Industry: computer related 0.568** (0.189) Industry: medical/ life science -0.486 (0.334) Industry: non high-tech 0.576 (0.328) Industry: semiconductors/ other elect. -1.203** (0.294)

N start-ups 1,438 1,438 1,438 N NAICS sectors (6-digit) 174 174 174 Chi-squared (model fit) 269.06 275.11** 559.29** Pseudo R-squared 0.069 0.074 0.129 Increases in model fit (LR-test) a 9.00** 96.29** Notes: Standard errors are clustered on 6-digit NAICS sectors (in parentheses). Reference group for IP application year: 2001; reference US region: ‘Silicon Valley’; reference industry: ‘communications and media’. Data sources: VC data from VentureXpert (accessed October 28, 2011); trademark data from United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO); patent data from PATSTAT Worldwide Patent Statistical Database (OECD/European Patent Office); R&D and advertising intensity from COMPUSTAT; C4 ratio from US Census Bureau. Sample includes start-ups that filed first IP during the period 1998-2007. a Likelihood ratio tests relate to the preceding nested model. † Significance level p < 0.1. * Significance level 0.05 > p ≥ 0.01. ** Significance level p ≤ 0.01. Two-sided tests are used.

32

TABLE 6 Additional analysis: Using average R&D- and advertising intensity based on at least 5

firms

Dependent variable:

Full sample Trademark(=1) or patent(=0)

Subsample: start-ups with customer type information

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5

Independent variables

C4 ratio -0.018** -0.006† -0.020** -0.005 (0.007) (0.003) (0.007) (0.005)

VC dummy 0.407**

0.399**

(0.088)

(0.086)

Business to consumer dummy 0.547*

0.596* (0.264)

(0.275) R&D intensity -0.029* -0.017 -0.019* -0.010 -0.008

(0.012) (0.013) (0.008) (0.012) (0.012)

Advertising intensity 0.132

0.142

0.094**

0.223†

0.148* (0.096) (0.092) (0.032) (0.114) (0.075)

Log (Start-up age) 0.551**

0.436**

0.360**

0.328**

0.252** (0.054) (0.055) (0.056) (0.088) (0.086)

IP applic. year dummies (10 cat.) p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 US region dummies (17 cat.) p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01 p < 0.01

Industry: biotechnology -0.712**

-0.860 (0.172)

(0.566)

Industry: computer related 0.540**

0.650** (0.126)

(0.201)

Industry: medical/ life science -0.863**

-0.374 (0.204)

(0.336)

Industry: non high-tech 0.409*

0.760† (0.180)

(0.388)

Industry: semiconductors/ other elect. -1.036**

-1.151** (0.209)

(0.305)

N start-ups 3,966 3,966 3,966 1,181 1,181 N NAICS sectors (6-digit) 216 216 216 126 126 Chi-squared (model fit) 396.04** 528.16** 1,593.79** 398.12** 751.94** Pseudo R-squared 0.064 0.079 0.132 0.077 0.132 Increases in model fit (LR-test) a 81.38** 285.97** 81.30** Notes: Standard errors are clustered on 6-digit NAICS sectors (in parentheses). Reference group for IP application year: 2001; reference US region: ‘Silicon Valley’; reference industry: ‘communications and media’. Data sources: VC data from VentureXpert (accessed October 28, 2011); trademark data from United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO); patent data from PATSTAT Worldwide Patent Statistical Database (OECD/European Patent Office); R&D and advertising intensity from COMPUSTAT; C4 ratio from US Census Bureau. Sample includes start-ups that filed first IP during the period 1998-2007. a Likelihood ratio tests relate to the preceding nested model. † Significance level p < 0.1. * Significance level 0.05 > p ≥ 0.01. ** Significance level p ≤ 0.01.

33

Two-sided tests are used.


Recommended