+ All Categories
Home > Documents > UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political...

UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political...

Date post: 20-Jun-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
31
1/31 Paper prepared for the ”International Joint Workshop for Doshisha and partner universities”, March 1-2, 2012, Kyoto February 2012 Work in progress – comments welcome – do not quote Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political consequences of expanding non-regular labour in Japan Steffen Heinrich Institute of Sociology / Institute of East Asian Studies University of Duisburg-Essen [email protected] Abstract: How political factors influence the incidence and scope of labour market reforms in advanced democracies has long been a popular research topic among politics scientists. Only recently, however, have scholars begun to consider the consequences of these reforms for politics itself. Studies on continental European countries suggest that policy preferences of non-regular and regular employees differ considerably and that this divide may constitute a new political cleavage which is intensifying the more people occupy non-regular jobs. In addition, this may turn into a strategic dilemma for political parties who struggle to respond to increasingly conflicting demands of core constituencies. The 2009 general election in Japan indicates that non-regular jobs and employment status-related welfare have indeed become salient for electoral politics, though word is still out whether this reflects the growing labour market dualism of the last two decades or is mainly due to the exceptional economic circumstances of the Lehman shock of 2008. This paper seeks to explore the role of employment status for policy preferences of workers and partisan politics in Japan. The paper consists of three parts: It first discusses the extent of institutional divisions between different employment statuses in Japan and how these may influence policy preferences in regard to employment regulation, welfare and state intervention from a theoretical perspective, drawing from economics, political science and sociology literatures. It will then analyse World Value Survey (WVS) and Japan General Social Survey (JGSS) data to understand the actual importance of status-related differences for preference formation in Japan. Third, it compares policy proposals during the 2009 general election with regard to employment to assess the relevance of labour market dualism for voter mobilisation. The study reveals that Japan confirms the pattern of labour market dualism found in several European countries yet it also highlights important empirical and theoretical differences. Keywords: Non-regular employment; party politics Japan, welfare, labour market policy; insider-outsider
Transcript
Page 1: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

1/31

Paper prepared for the ”International Joint Workshop for Doshisha and partner universities”, March 1-2, 2012, Kyoto February 2012

Work in progress – comments welcome – do not quote

Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political consequences of expanding non-regular labour in Japan

Steffen Heinrich Institute of Sociology / Institute of East Asian Studies

University of Duisburg-Essen [email protected]

Abstract: How political factors influence the incidence and scope of labour market reforms in advanced democracies has long been a popular research topic among politics scientists. Only recently, however, have scholars begun to consider the consequences of these reforms for politics itself. Studies on continental European countries suggest that policy preferences of non-regular and regular employees differ considerably and that this divide may constitute a new political cleavage which is intensifying the more people occupy non-regular jobs. In addition, this may turn into a strategic dilemma for political parties who struggle to respond to increasingly conflicting demands of core constituencies. The 2009 general election in Japan indicates that non-regular jobs and employment status-related welfare have indeed become salient for electoral politics, though word is still out whether this reflects the growing labour market dualism of the last two decades or is mainly due to the exceptional economic circumstances of the Lehman shock of 2008. This paper seeks to explore the role of employment status for policy preferences of workers and partisan politics in Japan. The paper consists of three parts: It first discusses the extent of institutional divisions between different employment statuses in Japan and how these may influence policy preferences in regard to employment regulation, welfare and state intervention from a theoretical perspective, drawing from economics, political science and sociology literatures. It will then analyse World Value Survey (WVS) and Japan General Social Survey (JGSS) data to understand the actual importance of status-related differences for preference formation in Japan. Third, it compares policy proposals during the 2009 general election with regard to employment to assess the relevance of labour market dualism for voter mobilisation. The study reveals that Japan confirms the pattern of labour market dualism found in several European countries yet it also highlights important empirical and theoretical differences.

Keywords: Non-regular employment; party politics Japan, welfare, labour market policy; insider-outsider

Page 2: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

2/31

1. Introduction

At first glance the notion that employment status could be a decisive factor for political

preferences of workers may not be obvious. It seems highly unlikely for instance that

female secondary wage earners (the majority of part-time workers – paato - in Japan)

and male temp agency workers (haken-shain) in manufacturing have much in common.

Moreover, non-regular employment often is a temporary mode of employment (e.g. until

a full time job is found) or is preferred simply because it allows avoiding long working

hours and the many social obligations connected to regular full-time jobs in Japan. Since

the burst of bubble economy and especially after the Asian crisis of 1997, however, more

and more scholars argue that non-regular employment has increasingly become a

substitute for regular jobs, causing a gradual erosion of working conditions especially

for young and female employees. Most recently, the financial and economic crisis in

2008 revealed that the growing non-regular workforce has been subject to drastic

downsizing in 2008 and 2009, much more so than workers with permanent contracts.1

The 2009 general election indeed provides some clues that labour market

dualism is politically salient in Japan: The Democratic Party of Japan (DPJ) won a historic

victory on a policy platform that emphasised the need to battle inequalities in society

and in the labour market in particular. According to Rueda and others labour market

inequalities are particularly prevalent and political significant in countries that generally

In addition, many only then realised that non-regular workers are often not entitled to

unemployment benefits or social assistance in spite of working for several years. In

short, the global financial crisis demonstrated to a wider Japanese public that

employment status matters for two vital concerns of any salaried employee, the level of

social protection and employment security. Viewed against this background, the

assumption of diverging political interests between privileged regular workers and

disadvantaged non-regular workers no longer seems quite so far off.

1 For instance, within three months nearly two thirds of temp agency workers (including so called registered-type haken) lost their jobs. In many cases this also meant that all entitlements to company housing and other essential fringe benefits had to be given up. The high number of homeless former temp agency workers led a group of activists to organise a tent village (the ‘haken mura’ or temp agency worker village) in front of the Ministry of Wealth, Labour and Welfare in central Tokyo to demonstrate to the public the social hardships endured by laid-off temp agency workers and to encourage an official response by the government. The Japanese media reported intensely on the incident, see Shinoda (2009).

Page 3: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

3/31

offer a high level of employment stability (e.g. strict rules against dismissals, long-term

employment practices) and of social welfare (protection against social risks). Such

countries are prone to develop a distinct second tier of non-core jobs which are more

flexible but also less well integrated into systems of social security. Non-core workers

are often used to instil additional flexibility into a firm’s workforce while avoiding

fundamental changes to the status of core employees or standard employment practices

(Kalleberg 2003). Many countries in Western Europe fall under this category, most

notably Spain, the Netherlands and Germany where labour market reforms in the last 20

years have multiplied the number of people employed by temp agencies and/or who

hold fixed-term contracts. A similar tendency is observable in several East Asian

countries, e.g. South Korea, Taiwan and Japan. While often less strictly regulated than

European countries in the 1980s, here too labour market reforms have facilitated the

use and expanded the number of non-regular workers, such as the 1999 reform of temp

agency work in Japan.

This paper seeks to explore the impact of this expansion for contemporary

Japanese politics. For this purpose it will extend the literature that has so far only

analysed continental European countries which are known for their extensive welfare

states and high social protection for regular employees, to Japan, which features a

comparable pattern of labour market dualism and a strong work-welfare nexus, but

offers a very different context with regard to overall welfare arrangements and political

dynamics. The paper proceeds as follows: The next section will introduce and discuss

different insider-outsider models drawing from sociology, economics and political

science literatures. The theoretical insights are then put into the context of Japanese

labour market and welfare arrangements to derive a set of concise hypotheses with

regard to potential consequences for preference formation and partisan politics.

Hypotheses are then tested in two separate analyses. First data from the World Value

Survey (WVS) and the Japan General Social Survey (JGSS) is used to examine the

importance of employment status for preference formation. Secondly, a qualitative

assessment of how parties have dealt with issues of employment protection and social

welfare in the aftermath of the global financial crisis, comparing party manifestos for the

2009 election, will shed light on the actual relevance of insider-outsider divisions for

partisan politics.

Page 4: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

4/31

2. The political consequences of growing labour market dualism

The questions whether and why the preferences of different worker groups diverge has

attracted a lot of attention by scholars in recent years (Burgoon and Dekker 2010;

Emmenegger 2010; Häusermann and Schwander 2009; King and Rueda 2008; Rueda

2007). Most report substantial empirical evidence for a gap between preferences of

insider and outsider workers with regard to employment regulation but also with

regard to social policy and redistribution. A point of controversy in all political models of

insider-outsider labour markets however concerns the definition of labour market

insiders and outsiders. For Lindbeck and Snower (1988) insiders include basically all

workers in permanent jobs and the unemployed (looking for a job) constitute the

outsider group. While outsiders generally hope to become insiders at some point and

thus prefer lower thresholds (e.g. lower employment protection) which could increase

the chances of finding such a job, insiders want to maximise protection to secure their

attained status and thus prefer higher thresholds. As unions are mostly representing the

interests of insiders, they will promote employment protection in collective bargaining

and policy-making processes, thus effectively deepening the insider-outsider division.

More recent studies have portrayed non-regular job-holders as outsider workers

(part-time, fixed-term, employed by temporary work agency) because particularly in

conservative welfare states, where welfare and work are closely linked, non-regular jobs

usually offer considerably less employment security and lower levels of social protection.

Also, workers with permanent contracts and substantial fringe benefits may benefit

from a more flexible second tier of jobs as this can provide additional protection against

dismissal for themselves (e.g. firms are likely to dismiss non-regular workers first) while

outsiders prefer lower thresholds to insider jobs and a more equal provision of benefits

and welfare. This definition is usually justified on the basis that in many countries there

is now a much bigger group of non-regular employees than in the past and they now

constitute a substantial part of the overall workforce (e.g. more than half of all female

employees in Japan) yet face similar disadvantages compared to regular employees.

Who are the real labour market outsiders?

However, all social phenomena are multi-causal and complex and this certainly applies

to the position of individual workers. Emmenegger for instance has shown that

secondary wage earners often side with insider partners (Emmenegger 2010) even

Page 5: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

5/31

though personally they may face additional social risks and precarious working

conditions. Also, new forms of non-regular employment usually coincide with existing

socio-economic cleavages. For instance, most jobs for temp agency workers require little

or no previous job training. University graduates may be more likely to get fixed-term

contracts but may have good prospects of getting permanent contracts in the

foreseeable future. Hence, they may perceive their outsider status as temporary and

unproblematic. Also, there are several “new social risks” which can apply to workers

independent of their employment status: Deindustrialisation, for instance, may reinforce

divisions between those with sought-after skills and losers those with little or outdated

skills (see Kitschelt and Rehm 2006). Some also assume that there is a connection

between the stability of a job (or perceived insecurity) and political preferences which

could be linked to differences between prospering and shrinking industries (Burgoon

and Dekker 2010).

In addition, there are several other factors specific to Japan which need to be

taken into account. Life-time employment as the regular standard form of employment

certainly dominate the popular as much as the academic perception of Japanese

employment, yet many scholars caution that even in its heyday it may have covered only

about 40% of the total workforce (e.g. Ono 2007). For the remainder, employment

security and fringe benefits have been considerably less generous and stable throughout

their work life. There is also a traditional labour market segmentation in Japan that runs

along firm size (e.g. Estévez-Abe 2008; Rebick 2005). As in most countries, large firms

tend to offer considerably better working conditions and higher fringe benefits than

smaller ones. Yet in Japan this tendency is elevated by the fact that there is little

centralisation in Japanese industrial relations. This means Japanese differences in

working conditions are likely to be larger than in systems where bargaining on working

conditions and wages is centralised like in Scandinavian countries, and they should

become larger in times of economic uncertainty or recession.

While this study does not deny the socio-economic factors just described

influence preference formation, it will apply a definition following the nominal

categories of non-regular employment in Japan as close as possible. This can be justified

on the grounds, that recent reforms have led to a massive expansion of jobs that face

similar risks, which could mean that there is now a large social group which is politically

Page 6: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

6/31

aware of its common interests. Then again, it is likely that several cleavages just

described now coincide with non-regular employment status, e.g. labour market reforms

arguably have eradicated incentives to give for example non-skilled workers regular

contracts. Indeed, studies of non-regular employment have shown that non-regular

employment usually coincides with low pay, little job security and limited access to

welfare (see figures 1 and 2). Last but not least research on the importance of recent

dualisation trends for policy preferences in Japan and elsewhere in East Asia is still in its

infancy. It therefore seems sensible to first explore whether fundamental assumptions of

current scholarship on employment status hold for Japan before more theoretical

consideration are integrated.

The study will define all regular workers (seishain) with permanent contracts as

insiders, and part-timers (paato), temp agency workers (haken), workers on fixed-term

contracts (keiyaku) and/or in marginal jobs (arubaito) as outsiders. Although not all

non-regular work necessarily coincides with precarious working conditions (and not all

regular employment is necessarily secure), this approach is the best approximation for

assessing the political impact of the expansion of non-regular work in recent years.

Some labour market researchers may object that solo-self employment should be

regarded as an additional form of precarious non-regular employment, as many salaried

employees have been forced into self-employment due to outsourcing and cost

reduction strategies pursued by firms since the 1990s (e.g. Song 2010). On the other

hand, Japan traditionally has had a relative large group of self-employed which suggests

that this form of employment is particularly heterogeneous. For these reasons, they are

excluded from the analyses for now.

Why insiders and outsiders disagree

According to Rueda, employment status matters for the preferences of employees on a

range of issues. This includes redistribution, active and passive labour market policies

and employment protection. In all cases, he argues, the preferences of “insiders and

outsiders are fundamentally different” (2007: 212). With regard to employment

protection he follows Lindbeck and Snower who argue that insiders wish to maximise

employment protection as this secures their status with regard to employment but also

wages, while outsiders prefer lower protection as this effectively lowers the threshold

for getting an insider job (e.g. they may offer to work for a lower wage). With regard to

Page 7: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

7/31

spending on labour market policies, he argues that those who benefit are more likely to

support them. Insiders facing in general lower social risks, should therefore be more

critical of government spending on welfare, job creation and active labour market

policies. Outsiders, on the other hand, should show a clearer preference for more

spending as they are more likely to rely on such schemes at some point.

A similar argument can be made for redistribution and public welfare. Japanese

welfare arrangements resemble to some extent conservative welfare states in Europe

because the level of social protection and entitlements depends to a large extent on the

job an individual holds. Insider jobs privilege a specific group of workers with regard to

social protection while most outsider jobs do not offer social protection that matches

those of insiders. Palier and Thelen (2010) and others argue that even many of the

disparities currently discusses are not new, they have been reinforced through recent

welfare reforms. The gap between those who have contributed for some time to systems

of social insurance and those without sufficient contributions and thus benefits has

arguably widened. This may also be true for Japan where those outside generous

corporate welfare schemes face a relative rigid “residual” means-tested public welfare

system (see e.g. Abe 2003). Moreover, recent pension reforms have, as in most other

countries, strengthened the role of private provision which may elevate disparities

further.2

In addition to socio-economic preferences, it seems likely that structural

disadvantages experienced by non-regular groups of workers also impact how well the

feel integrated into . If Lindbeck and Snower are correct, the existing mechanisms for

participation and influence orkers are dominated by insiders. Not only do labour unions

tend to promote the interests of insider groups, outsiders may also not be adequately

represented in corporate bodies for labour-management consultations. This should

increase their dependence on public regulation and state intervention; hence they may

prefer a stronger state role in labour affairs, e.g. in setting and enforcing minimum

working standards and for distributing welfare entitlements more equally.

Partisan politics and labour market dualism

2 Coverage alone does of course not provide a complete picture of the entitlements an individual will receive. For example the public pension insurance in Japan was never intended to provide more than a basic pension.

Page 8: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

8/31

In Western Europe welfare policy and redistribution are strongly associated with social

democracy. The post-war period until the 1970s is often dubbed the golden era of social

democracy because social democratic parties then were relatively influential and

successful in expanding welfare policies and in implementing redistributive policies.

Although the degree of re-distribution varies considerably even across European

countries and such policies have not exclusively been backed by one party, generous

welfare and high employment protection are usually understood as core social

democratic policies. Since the 1970s however a “new politics of the welfare state”

(Pierson 2001) fuelled by austerity and globalisation has prompted social-democratic as

well as non-social democratic governments to implement unpopular reforms such as

welfare retrenchment and labour market “deregulation”. As a consequence, most

countries have liberalised temp-agency work and fixed-term employment during the

1990s and 2000s (OECD 2004), yet at the same time they have usually kept strict

dismissal regulation for standard employment.

Political scientists usually explain this conspicuous pattern with the political

strength of unions who have tried hard to protect their core constituency, which also,

even though it is gradually becoming smaller, constitutes a vital electoral basis for social

democratic parties. The “asymmetric reforms” (Miura 2001) of deregulating non-regular

employment while maintaining high employment protection for regular jobs, thus

appears like a political compromise between securing the continuous support of labour

and answering growing calls for enhanced labour market flexibility. Rueda (Rueda 2005,

2007), however, sees here a strategic dilemma because by furthering non-regular

employment, social democratic parties are effectively dividing their core constituency of

labour into two distinct groups with conflicting political demands. The larger this divide

becomes and the larger the group of non-regular workers, Rueda argues, the harder it

will be for these parties to mobilise across this divide. This matters because unlike

unions who may be able to survive by siding with insiders, political parties’ electoral

success crucially depends on their ability to mobilise voters across several cleavages.

Rueda cautions, however, that these cleavages are latent, that is, they may not matter

for the electoral decisions if there is not an imminent conflict polarising the positions of

workers. Indeed, in some countries “outsider jobs” can be relatively uncontroversial,

such as temp agency work in the Netherlands, which however is highly contentious in

Page 9: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

9/31

Germany and Japan (see Shire and Van Jaarsveld 2008). Therefore insider-outsider

divisions may not matter everywhere and all the time to the same degree. This means to

assess whether insider-outsider divisions are politically salient in a country, one needs

to address two aspects: first, are labour market issues important to voters and, secondly,

feel parties the need to respond accordinlgy e.g. by proposing specific policies to narrow

the gap between insiders and outsiders?

3. Socio-economic and political insider-outsider divisions in Japan

In order to apply the theoretical insights discussed so far to the Japanese case, the

severity and prevalence of insider-outsider divisions in Japan needs to be explored in

more detail. As has been pointed out earlier, the Japanese welfare arrangement differs in

many aspects to those prevalent in continental European countries (see also Esping-

Andersen 1990, 1997) and there are also specific factors which influence the position of

individual position of an employee. An even bigger difference is perhaps that Japan lacks

a powerful social democratic party which can claim to have successfully implemented a

policy of income re-distribution and welfare expansion comparable to Europe. On the

contrary, since the 1970s the LDP, the dominating political force between 1955 and

2009, has repeatedly stressed that European-style welfare is neither necessary nor

desirable for Japan. Instead it promoted the model of a “Japanese-style welfare society”

(nihon-gata fukushi shakai) in which social protection is achieved mainly through

corporate and private welfare provision, emphasising employment over entitlements.

Public spending on welfare still is low in Japan in international comparison although it

has increased noticeable in recent years. Some authors argue that policies such as public

works and high entry barriers to domestic markets therefore should be seen as

essentially social policies with the goal of ensuring high employment (Estévez-Abe 2008;

Kasza 2006) as this avoids the development of large groups depending directly on

welfare state entitlements.

Furthermore, the relative failure of socialist and social-democratic parties since

1955 is thus usually not explained with diverging preferences of Japanese workers or

labour market segmentation but with structural reasons such as doctrinal ideology on

parts of the JSP (Japan Socialist Party), an unfavourable electoral system, or with the

wide participation of the majority in economic growth. Yet, since the early 1990s the

situation arguably has changed fundamentally. Japan may now be much closer to the

Page 10: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

10/31

situation in several European countries because as high economic growth ended and

firms started to restructure, existing inequalities have arguably been reinforced, also

through reforms by Japanese governments in the 1990s and 2000s. Like in many

European countries these reforms led to more labour market flexibility but left

employment protection intact for regular employees.3

This is confirmed by studies of Japanese welfare arrangements. Abe (2003) for

instance argues that the Japanese welfare state in general is marked by a strong division

between “main-stream” and “residual” programs. Unemployment insurance and health

care, for instance, are main-stream programs following a social insurance logic aiming at

universal coverage of workers; social assistance and even unemployment payments, on

the other hand, are residual as entitlements are limited and generally means-tested.

Figure 1 shows, however, there is also a disparity between different employment

statuses. For example, there is a clear gap between regular (permanent full-time) and

non-regular jobs across the whole spectrum of social protection. Furthermore, non-

regular employees are more likely to depend on residual state programmes as their jobs

tend to be less stable and wages considerably lower (figure 2). To some extent the gap

between workers can be explained with the principle of family insurance, that is, many

non-regular workers, in particular part-timers, are likely to be covered by the social

security arrangements of their spouse. These workers may thus prefer a job where they

do not have the obligation to pay social contributions themselves. Also, they may not

mind the comparatively low pay as higher pay may increase their tax rate.

Recent discussions in Japanese

media and academia about growing social inequalities in Japan (e.g. kakusa shakai and

waakingu pua) signal that socio economic issues have indeed become more politically

salient (see also Tiberghien 2011). So even if Japan lacks a comparable history of

redistributive policy and welfare expansion underpinned by a strong social-democratic

current, the nominal differentiation between different employment groups looks

actually very similar to what Rueda and others describe for Western Europe.

4

3 Although high employment protection in Japan initially was created through case law, consecutive governments have refrained from imposing legislation that would overrule or abolish the criteria set by courts.

This hints at

4 On the other hand, even secondary wage earners may prefer better access to entitlements and an autonomous welfare status. There is no consensus in the literature yet about which view dominates.

Page 11: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

11/31

potential relevance of household status, i.e. whether workers are primary or secondary

wage earners.

In domestic discussions about labour market dualism, it is often pointed out that

young workers and female workers are particularly disadvantaged in Japan. Young

workers are at a bigger risk to be affected by labour market disparities almost

everywhere, yet the formalised recruitment process of many Japanese firms may

constitute a particularly large penalty for the young in Japan. Typically, students spend

the last year of their studies mainly on job search to make sure they secure a job

contract before finishing their studies. In recent years the process and the competition

for jobs seems to have intensified as students tend to start even earlier than in the past

with their job hunt (shuushoku katsudo). Many seem to worry that if they fail they will be

judged second rate by employers and this will impact their whole working career, since

they may not be able to increase their wage parallel to their age, as is the norm in

traditional career jobs, and thus not be able to sustain a family. The growing worries of

young Japanese and the relevance of employment status is also confirmed by Shirahase

(2010) who finds that the probability of young workers identifying themselves as

middle class increases significantly once they hold a permanent work contract.5

Women have historically enjoyed relative high participation rates in Japan even

before the deregulation started in the 1990s. However, they seem to be more

disadvantaged than their peers in Scandinavia or the US when it comes to career

prospects and wage equality (e.g. Osawa 2002). Most jobs traditionally held by women

fall into the so called ippanshoku category (clerical-track) which offer very limited career

prospects and thus little wage hikes. Men on the other are much more likely to hold

sougoushoku (career-track) jobs, where wages typically increase with age. These

traditional differences between male and female employees seem to persist even now

(see for instance the basic survey on wage structure published by the MHLW in 2010

which shows that wage levels of female employment remains relative flat throughout

5 A recent study shows that the so called ‘lost generation’ of the 1990s, which particularly suffered under dramatically reduced job offers by firms, has closed the gap in regular employment that existed in the late 1990s with the generations before and after the Asian crisis. Yet, still fewer of them work in large firms so it is likely they on average earn less and enjoy fewer benefits. See the 2011/2012 edition of the bi-annual report “Labour situation in Japan and analysis”, p. 9. http://www.jil.go.jp/english/lsj.html (accessed in June 2011).

Page 12: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

12/31

their work life). This means there may be a strong gender-specific pattern behind

preferences which may or may not coincide with outsider status as in other countries

(Robson et al 1999). Furthermore, female employees have long been seen as occupying

non-essential peripheral jobs and thus has have been more frequently been subject to

restructuring than male employees (e.g. Kezuka 1993; Osawa 2002). It comes as no

surprise therefore, that women are much more likely to occupy non-regular jobs (see

annex, figure 5).

Figure 1 Employment status and participation in social security programmes in Japan

Source: MHLW (2003): Comprehensive survey of employment diversification [Shuugyou keitai no tayouka ni kan suru sougou jittai chousa].

0%

25%

50%

75%

100%

Unemployment insurance

Health insurance

Social insurance (Old-age, disability and survivor

pension)

Corporate pension

Pension contributions

Bonus payments

Regular worker

Fixed-term employee

Temp agency worker

Part-time worker

Page 13: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

13/31

Figure 2 Annual income by employment status (Japan)

Source: Toda (2007), p. 27. Are there social-democrats in Japan?

If Japan lacks a powerful social democratic party at least nominally, this raises question

whether and how Japanese partisan politics may be affected by growing labour market

disparities. At least with regard to the reform process which has led to an expansion of

non-regular in Japan, several authors have put forward similar arguments, that is,

reform processes themselves have had a polarising effects as the interests of non-

regular workers were widely ignored by unions, employers and politicians (e.g. Miura

2001; Nakamura 2007; Yun 2010). It appears that unions suffering from ever lower

unionisation rates and exclusion from political decision-making, managed to protect

their members mainly by allowing deregulation of non-regular work. This is also visible

if one looks at decision-making and bargaining processes within firms: surveys suggest

that non-regular workers are hardly integrated into traditional labour-management

bodies and largely ignored by enterprise unions.6

6 For example, the Survey on Labour-management communication (roushi komyunikeeshon chousa), conducted by the Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare, shows that company unions show little interest in non-regular workers and collective bargaining rarely addresses their concerns.

Although Rengou, the largest umbrella

association for trade unions in Japan, has recently tried to rejuvenate the shuntou

process (spring wage offensive) by emphasising the working conditions of non-regular

employees, observers are very sceptical that this really mirrors stronger interests for

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Regular employment

(seiki no shokuin)

Part time employment

(paato)

Marginal work (arubaito)

Temp agency work (haken)

Fixed-term employment

(keiyaku)

More than 4 mil. YEN (>34.000 EUR)

3-4 mil. YEN (25.500-34.000 EUR)

2-3 mil. YEN (17.000-25.500 EUR)

1-2 mil. YEN (8.500-17.000 EUR)

Less than 1 mil. YEN (<8.500 EUR)

Page 14: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

14/31

the fate of outsiders, as the shuntou process has lost most of its relevance (Weathers

2008). In sum this means that outsider workers are not well integrated into the

traditional systems of decision-making and worker participation in Japan. This suggests

that they depend more on state regulation and intervention than insiders and thus may

support more state-run welfare rather than arrangements centred on firms.

This uneven participation by worker groups may have important implications for

political parties, even if they do not resemble traditional European social democracy.

Since 1993 the Japanese party system has gone through a phase of re-alignment leading

to system with two dominant parties which increasingly compete on policy platforms

(which were virtually unknown before 2003). Unlike under the old SNTV-system where

even small percentages guaranteed representation, the new electoral system in use

since the 1996 general election encourages voter mobilisation across socio-economic

groups. This means parties have to appeal to a relative heterogeneous group of potential

voters and labour market dualism may make such efforts even more difficult. The

Democratic Party of Japan (DPJ, minshuu-tou) as the second major player in Japan’s

emerging two-party system is considerably closer to unions and traditional labour than

the LDP.7

The tiny social-democratic party (SDP, shamin-tou) and the Japan Communist

Party (JCP, nippon kyousan-tou) may be too small and their voter appeal too limited as to

consider them functional equivalents of social democratic parties in Europe. Moreover,

the Koumei party (CGP, which calls itself ‘New Komeito’ in English) which is said to have

been close to the interests of the lower middle-class (Song 2010: 1022) at least until its

re-formation in 1998, depends mainly on the organisational capabilities of the Sokka

Gakkai sect. Its outreach must therefore be considered limited.

Even if it is not a social-democratic party by name, it clearly targets the left-of-

centre vote and traditional labour. So it is most likely, that if a strategic dilemma exists it

should affect the DPJ more than the LDP.

Hypotheses

7 For instance, in the first DPJ-government aft the 2009 election, half of the DPJ’s cabinet members had a background in trade unions, see Heinrich (2010). However, the fact that the DPJ formed a coalition with the conservative Kokumin Shin-tou (“Nation’s New Party”), a tiny party led by LDP-defectors, and the left-wing Social Democratic Party at the same time, has invited criticism of programmatic blurriness.

Page 15: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

15/31

Based on the above two sets of hypotheses can be drawn up, one for preference

formation and the second one for partisan politics. First of all, if Rueda’s dictum of

fundamentally different preferences holds for Japan we can expect to find that

H1: Japanese insiders should have stronger preferences for employment security than

outsiders.

H2: Insider and outsider worker groups differ in their preferences in regard to social

policy. While insiders should feel already relatively well protected thanks to corporate

welfare and outsiders will show a clear preference for more public welfare spending as

they are likely to find public welfare inadequate.

With regard to the state role, most insiders should see their employer as the more

important institution while outsiders, lacking a comparable benefactor, should prefer a

stronger state role. We can thus expect that:

H3: Outsiders should welcome a more active role of the state in welfare matters since

they lack adequate representation and influence in industrial relations and enjoy fewer

corporate benefits if any. Hence, they will support redistributive policies more than

insiders.

With regard to partisan politics, it may be difficult to confirm that specific

political parties face a strategic dilemma. However, it seems likely that the global

financial crisis of 2008 and the recent debates on social inequality have made labour

market dualism a politically salient topic which has forced parties to address related

issues. This should be mirrored in the policy platforms proposed by parties for 2009

election as this was clearly influenced by the impact of the crisis. Furthermore, outsiders

may feel more disadvantaged due to the fact that they suffered more from adjustment

processes than insiders. Hence, with regard to partisan politics one can expect that

H4: The global financial crisis has increased the salience of labour market dualism and

also the polarisation between insider and outsiders as outsiders were more likely to

become unemployed and/or suffer from inequalities in welfare provision.

4. Employment status and policy preferences

For the sake of comparability with previous research and due to data limits, the

following analysis will use the same or at least similar survey questions. In particular

Page 16: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

16/31

questions on employment security, spending on labour market policies and re-

distributive policies have shown clear differences between insiders and outsiders in

European countries, so they are useful to establish whether a similar pattern is visible in

Japan at all. In addition, political alienation will be addressed as it seems particularly

important for understanding the political impact of a dual labour market structure in

Japan and how employment status interacts with other disparities. It must be stressed,

however, that none of the surveys allows to study potential rifts between insiders and

outsiders directly. For instance, to assess preferences for employment protection the

question “How important is employment security in a job for you?” is used, which is

likely to also reflect different motives for working and not only status and policy

differences. Identifying insider and outsider workers can also be very challenging as

most of the larger international surveys such as the ISSP and the WVS, do not provide

detailed information on employment status which can distort important differences. For

example, some part-timers may enjoy an insider-like status while some full-time

employees may hold fixed-term contracts and thus may consider themselves to be

“outside” of standard employment.

Perhaps because of such difficulties, research so far has shown a surprising lack

of interests for national differences. Given the fact that even Western European

countries vary greatly in terms of welfare arrangements, the even greater versatility in

terms of labour market arrangements certainly deserves more attention. Figure 3

demonstrates that such differences can be substantial. Using a simple definition whereas

all “full-time workers” are defined as insiders and all “part-time workers” (based on

WVS data) are considered outsiders; we find substantial and significant differences

between worker groups in Germany, in line with the findings in current scholarship. In

Japan, however, the situation seems to be very different: there is nearly no difference

between the worker groups. This could be interpreted as evidence that insider-outsider

divisions are generally smaller in Japan. Yet it could also be due to the fact that this

definition of insiders and outsiders is inadequate to capture the actual cleavage within

the depended employed workforce in Japan. For instance, many full-time jobs can be

non-regular (e.g. fixed term) while many part-time jobs can similarly stable as full-time

jobs. In order to study potential disparities closer to the actual categories, data from the

Japan General Social Survey (JGSS) will be used as it includes very detailed information

Page 17: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

17/31

on the employment status of respondents and other important variables, and also offers

a considerably larger sample than the WVS.

Figure 3 Preferences for redistribution (medians for 11-point scale, World Value Survey 2006)

Following Rueda, first the question of preferences in regard to employment

protection will be addressed first (table 1).8

In order to get a better understanding of how important employment status is

vis-à-vis other labour market attributes specific to Japan, the following variables are also

included: gender (since more than half of all female employees are employed in the non-

regular sector, figure 2, annex), secondary wage earner status (secondary wage earners

To ensure a better empirical fit with actual

employment statuses in Japan, insiders are defined here as regular workers (excluding

executives) with full-time permanent contracts (常時雇用の一般雇用者). Outsiders are

created from the groups of temporary employment (which includes paato or part-time,

arubaito or marginal and naishoku or occasional jobs) and temp work agency workers

(派遣社員). The operationalisation of all variables is described in detail in table 7

(annex).

8 The JGSS has been conducted since the early 1990s and is usually conducted bi-annually. Changes in questionnaires make it necessary to include several waved in the analysis. For instance questions on employment security and spending on employment policies included only until 2003. For all other questions data from the latest available survey, conducted in fall of 2008, are used. This has the additional advantage that potential polarising effects of the global financial crisis should already be visible.

Page 18: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

18/31

may align themselves with their insider spouse), firm size (working conditions can vary

considerably) and age (younger workers may be more aware of the risks associated with

their employment status) and security of the currently held job (as a proxy for

differences between occupations and industries).

Table 1 Preferences on employment security

Job security is very important for me

Job security is important for me

Job security is not important/not

important at all for me Chi 2 test (p)

Employment status Insider worker 60,0% 39,3% 0,7%

*** Outsider worker 54,3% 43,7% 2,0% Job security

Insecure status 57,9% 41,3% 0,8% n.s.

Secure status 57,2% 41,6% 1,2% Wage status

Outsider & primary wage earner 48,0% 49,3% 2,6% n.s. Outsider & secondary wage

earner 55,7% 42,2% 2,0%

Firm size Employed in small firm 56,9% 41,9% 1,2%

n.s. Employed in large firm 58,4% 41,1% 0,5%

Age Young workers (<36y) 53,0% 45,2% 1,8% *** Older workers (>35y) 60,5% 38,7% 0,8%

Sex Male employee 56,6% 41,7% 1,7%

** Female employee 54,4% 44,3% 1,3% * Statistically significant at the 0.05 level; ** at the .01 level; *** at the .001 level; “n.s.” = not significant. Source: JGSS 2000-2003.

Table 1 for the most part confirms what Rueda and other have found for

European countries. Japanese insiders show a stronger preference for job security than

outsiders. Notable differences are also visible with regard to age which, however, may

not be surprising as young workers tend to be more flexible as they usually do not yet

enjoy a high status with regard to corporate welfare and wages. The penalty that job

changers usually face in Japan due to the age- and firm-related structure of fringe

benefits does not yet apply to them. There also seems to be an effect connected to the

household status. Secondary wage earners among outsider workers apparently feel

stronger about job security than outsider with primary wage status which may be

related to the fact that the latter are under higher pressure to find a better job while the

former are interested in keeping their current job rather than hoping for higher pay or

better working conditions.

Also the second question on whether workers support spending on job creation

policies and unemployment, seems to confirm Rueda’s argument of different

preferences of insider and outsider workers (table 2). Outsider workers support more

strongly government spending than insider workers. Yet noticeable differences are also

Page 19: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

19/31

visible between workers with secure or insecure jobs, and young and older workers. The

latter observation is interesting as it suggests that younger workers apparently do not

believe they can profit from such policies while older workers are distinctly more

supportive. To explore such links, however, more in-depth and multivariate analyses

would be required which are outside the scope of this paper for now.

Table 2 Preferences for spending on employment policies (job creation and unemployment)

Government spends too much on employment

policies

The amount the government spends is

about right

Government spends too little on employment

policy Chi 2 test (p)

Employment status Insider worker 4,0% 22,6% 73,3% *** Outsider worker 2,5% 18,0% 79,5%

Job security Insecure status 2,7% 17,3% 80,0%

*** Secure status 4,2% 24,4% 71,4%

Wage status Outsider & primary wage earner 1,1% 16,1% 82,8%

n.s. Outsider & secondary wage earner 0,8% 16,7% 82,5%

Firm size Employed in small firm 3,8% 24,0% 72,3%

n.s. Employed in large firm 3,7% 23,6% 72,7% Age

Young workers (<36y) 4,6% 26,7% 68,8% *** Older workers (>35y) 3,1% 18,6% 78,3%

Sex Male employee 4,1% 24,7% 71,3%

*** Female employee 2,7% 19,8% 77,5% * Statistically significant at the 0.05 level; ** at the .01 level; *** at the .001 level; “n.s.” = not significant. Source: JGSS 2000-2003.

However, table 3 suggests that there is a patterns linking attributes of labour

market discrimination to preferences for welfare spending, which however runs counter

to previously formulated expectations. If respondents are asked a more general question

about welfare and have to choose between higher taxes or higher welfare, those in

weaker employment positions tend to prefer lower taxes. The dual nature of Japanese

welfare arrangements which privilege a certain group of workers, may explain why

outsiders do not expect to profit in terms of public welfare and thus are more concerned

about pay/tax levels. However, this argument could also be reversed, as hypotheses H1

and H3 suggest: outsiders should support public welfare as they are more likely to

depend on it than insider workers. Then again, this finding may not be unique to Japan:

studies have also found for the US and other liberal welfare states that workers in less

stable and low paid jobs do not necessarily support more public welfare (e.g. Mehrtens

III 2004). The gap between this and the previous question suggests, however, that

preference formation is more complex than is commonly acknowledged in the literature

on labour market dualism. There may also be a connection to class. At least in

Page 20: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

20/31

continental Europe it is widely assumed that middle class voters benefit much more

from public welfare state arrangements than other voters. This may make them much

stronger supporters of expansive welfare than other classes, yet evidence in European

countries is mixed so far (see e.g. Marx and Picot 2011).

Table 3 Preferences with regard to welfare and taxes

Fully agree with statement A: Even if

taxes have to be increased, welfare

should be improved

Agree more with A Agree more with B

Fully agree with statement B: Taxes should be lowered even if welfare has to be cut as a result

Chi square test (p)

Employment status Insider worker 21,5% 53,5% 20,0% 5,0% ** Outsider worker 16,2% 47,8% 27,7% 8,3%

Job security Insecure status 19,5% 45,4% 29,3% 5,7%

n.s. Secure status 20,1% 51,7% 21,1% 7,1%

Wage status Outsider & primary wage earner 20,6% 36,5% 36,5% 6,3%

n.s. Outsider & secondary wage earner 16,3% 53,0% 25,3% 5,4%

Firm size Employed in small firm 19,1% 48,3% 25,1% 7,2%

** Employed in large firm 22,1% 54,4% 17,7% 5,9%

Age Young workers (<36y) 20,2% 46,9% 23,8% 9,0%

* Older workers (>35y) 19,6% 53,3% 22,1% 5,0% Sex

Male employee 21,8% 49,3% 22,2% 6,7% ** Female employee 16,0% 51,9% 25,2% 6,9% * Statistically significant at the 0.05 level; ** at the .01 level; *** at the .001 level; “n.s.” = not significant. Source: JGSS 2008.

As for preferences with regard to re-distributional policies, table 4 suggests only

minor differences between workers with different employment status. Again this allows

for different explanations. For instance, this may be related to the fact that the gap is

rather narrow because a societal consensus exists that more re-distribution is necessary.

Yet this challenges the commonly accepted idea that citizens in Japan view the state role

differently than most Europeans. For instance, Dore has famously argued that British

workers are more likely to turn to the state while Japanese workers would rather turn to

their employer.9

9 Cole sums up Dore’s argument in the following way: “In Britain, if the individual cannot survive, he turns to the politically defined community, not to the enterprise. National collectivist solutions were sought to problems of worker security and poverty. No comparative observations are made for Japan, but the presumption is that Japan represents a government-oriented economy, yet one in which employers accept their responsibility to secure the welfare of their employees.” See Cole (1978), p. 249.

Here, however, it appears that there is strong support for an expanded

state role and more state activity.

Page 21: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

21/31

Table 4 Should the government do more to close the gap between poor and rich families?

Strongly agree with statement: It is the responsibility of the

government to reduce differences

Somewhat agree Somewhat disagree Strongly disagree Chi 2 test (p)

Employment status Insider worker 39,3% 48,6% 9,3% 2,8%

** Outsider worker 44,8% 46,9% 5,9% 2,4%

Job security Insecure status 44,5% 45,6% 6,6% 3,3%

n.s. Secure status 40,7% 47,1% 8,9% 3,4%

Wage status Outsider & primary wage earner 50,0% 42,0% 6,0% 2,0%

n.s. Outsider & secondary wage earner 44,9% 47,6% 5,8% 1,8%

Firm size Employed in small firm 44,3% 45,0% 7,4% 3,4%

*** Employed in large firm 35,3% 51,3% 10,3% 3,1%

Age Young workers (<36y) 34,4% 46,6% 14,3% 4,7%

*** Older workers (>35y) 44,0% 48,6% 5,6% 1,8% Sex

Male employee 45,1% 43,6% 8,1% 3,2% ***

Female employee 40,5% 52,1% 5,7% 1,6% * Statistically significant at the 0.05 level; ** at the .01 level; *** at the .001 level. N.s. = not significant. Source: JGSS 2008.

With regard to redistribution preferences, the mixed evidence found so far

suggests clearly that Rueda and others likely miss important structural differences in the

Japanese labour market and, possibly, elsewhere as well. This is particularly true for the

issue of tax policy, which is a highly controversial issue in all countries, but arguably

particularly contentious in Japan - as the current but also previous discussions on tax

hikes imply. However, as the relationship between welfare, taxes and public attitudes

has not yet been studied in detail more research and theory-building would be required.

Last but not least, the question of political alienation shall be addressed. If

assumptions of a lack of political participation of lower income workers are correct, then

we are likely to find differences also based on employment status. This should be

underlined by discrimination that extends from the corporate to the national political

arena. And indeed, at least in 2008 the level of political alienation of outsider workers is

visibly higher than for insider workers. Young, female, and employees of small firms all

tend to be more sceptical about their political influence than those in large firms and

with permanent jobs. This seems to confirm H4 insofar as political participation appears

polarised, although it is not a direct confirmation that the global financial crisis is

responsible. However, viewed together these initial findings do not fully comply with

Rueda’s argument, that the preferences of insiders and outsiders are fundamentally

different. Rather, it appears that there is generally a high level of support for more

Page 22: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

22/31

welfare and public spending but that if faced with a choice workers with higher social

risks tend to reject more public welfare.

Table 5 Political alienation

Strongly agree with statement: People

like me have no say in what the

government does

Agree Disagree Strongly disagree Chi 2 test (p)

Employment status Insider worker 18,1% 36,2% 30,3% 15,5%

*** Outsider worker 28,1% 41,5% 23,3% 7,2% Job security

Insecure status 26,6% 34,5% 30,5% 8,5% *

Secure status 20,1% 37,5% 28,9% 13,5% Wage status

Outsider & primary wage earner 27,4% 37,1% 27,4% 8,1%

n.s. Outsider & secondary wage earner 28,1% 43,7% 22,2% 6,0%

Firm size Employed in small firm 22,5% 36,7% 27,9% 12,9% * Employed in large firm 16,6% 37,3% 32,2% 13,8%

Age Young workers (<36y) 26,7% 38,6% 24,9% 9,7%

** Older workers (>35y) 19,4% 37,6% 29,2% 13,8%

Sex Male employee 18,1% 34,4% 32,2% 15,3%

*** Female employee 26,3% 40,0% 25,7% 8,0% * Statistically significant at the 0.05 level; ** at the .01 level; *** at the .001 level. N.s. = not significant. Source: JGSS 2008.

5. Partisan politics and the 2009 general election in Japan

As the previous section has shown, insider-outsider conflicts exist and are politically

salient in Japan; at the same time they do not fully resemble the pattern that has been

observed in Germany for instance. In contrast to Germany, however, employment issues

and social inequalities played a central role in the 2009 election campaign. Polls

conducted for the Nikkei Shimbun, for instance, show that shortly before the 2009

election employment was among the top three concerns for voters, and the second most

important concern for voters in their 20s (the other two topics being social security and

pensions, and the economy, see Nikkei, July 23, 2009: 2).10

10 In 2009 more than 40% of all survey respondents cited these issues. A note of caution is at order here, however as Japanese newspapers rarely publish any details on polls, e.g. the number of people surveyed. A comparison with the same Nikkei poll shortly before the 2005 election (Nikkei, August 28, 2005: 2) at least suggests that employment had not been a major concern before 2009 as it was not even among the top 5 concerns of voters.

This shows that employment

has finally become a salient political issue in Japan.

Page 23: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

23/31

The DPJ in particular made employment one of its central campaign issues. In its

electoral manifesto entitled “regime change” (seiken koutai 政権交代), the party

promised to „to re-balance the excesses of deregulation in order to improve the stability

of the daily lives of workers.“11 Among the specific policies the manifesto envisioned

were a general ban of temp agency work in manufacturing, a ban on temp agency work

with contracts of less than 2 months and “day temp agency work” (hiyatoi haken 日雇い

派遣), the implementation of a general principle that ensures equal treatment of temp

agency workers with “comparable” workers (派遣先労働者), and a provision which

would allow temp agency workers who have been employed beyond the legal limit for

such work, to declare themselves directly employed by the firm where they work. In

addition the DPJ promised to improve unemployment insurance (koyou houken 雇用保

険)12

11 Source:

, so that unemployed workers would be able to continue paying their premiums for

health insurance. And it promised to raise minimum wages to a national average of

1.000 Yen per hour. Perhaps even more dramatic than the statements in the manifesto

were meetings of three oppositional parties, the DPJ, the SDP and the People’s New

Party (PNP) in the first half of 2009, in which all three parties agreed to ban temp agency

work in manufacturing and to expand the safety net for workers once in power (Nikkei

August 18, 2009; Asahi May 13, 2009). According to media reports these meetings were

unprecedented in the more recent Japanese political history in that opposition parties

made relatively exact policy promises. The SDP and JCP manifestoes were particularly

strong on labour market dualism and reflected all major issues that had been discussed

in recent years such as the disparity society (kakusa shakai 格差社会), working poor and

mistreatment of temp agency workers. Both parties envisioned changes to regulations

governing fixed-term, temp agency and part-time employment in order to restore

http://www.dpj.or.jp/ (accessed in May 2011). The sudden salience of dualism is also visible in the fact that the DPJ did not refer to it in previous elections. The 2005 manifesto describes the gap between regular and non-regular employment mainly from a gender perspective which requires more child-care facilities. Source: http://www.dpj-kochi.jp/2005seisaku.pdf (accessed in November 2011).

12 “The financial basis of the unemployment insurance is to be strengthened in line with employment diversification.”

Page 24: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

24/31

“worker dignity”, to facilitate the transition to regular jobs and to “stop the deterioration

of employment”.13

Although formally DPJ formally addressed dualisation a more thorough reading

reveals subtle differences. The LDP’s manifesto (改めます。伸ばします。) foresaw a

ban to “day temp agency work”

14, and a “revision of the temp agency law” yet it did not

specify whether this would require legislative changes. In contrast to the DPJ, however,

it emphasised a sound economic development and improvement of job placement

services. LDP politicians also became increasingly critical of re-regulation so that the

initially strong calls for reform of the temp agency sector within the LDP faded

noticeably until the election. The CGP very much followed the example of the LDP by

emphasising vocational training and placement as main elements of a “safety net” for

workers while not proposing any specific measures. Tellingly, on the question of temp

agency work in manufacturing, the CGP promised to review the issue within the first

year of government, “considering the opinions of stakeholders”.15

Although electoral manifestoes should be treated with caution when assessing

the extent of a possible re-orientation in labour politics as they are not binding and

completely ignore the fact that coalitional bargaining will inevitably lead to

compromises, it is telling all parties responded to issues of labour market dualism in

2009 and that a relatively clear divide between right-of-centre and left-of-centre parties

is visible. However, there seems to be no real dilemma for parties instead the three left-

of-centre parties seem to use them to underline their status as opponents of the

“Koizumi deregulations”. Nothing in the manifestos suggests that parties feel torn

between conflicting worker interests. Hence, there is little to support Rueda’s argument

13 Quote from the SDP „manifesto“: “パート・契約社員・非常勤・嘱託・派遣など有期雇用を正規雇

用 に 転 換 し 、 雇 用 の 劣 化 を 防 止 し ま す 。 ” Sources: http://www.sdp.or.jp/ and http://www.jcp.or.jp/ (last accessed in May 2011). The JCP’s manifesto also strongly mirrored issues connected to dualisation and entailed very similar proposals.

14 “In particular, we plan for non-regular workers in unstable employment environments a ban on „daily temp agency work, to promote a change toward permanent employment, and a ‘revision of the temp agency law’ to create a better work environment. In addition we prepare an ‘employment safety net’ which concerns, among other, vocational training as well as placement.” Source: http://www.ldp.or.jp/ (accessed in May 2011).

15 Instead of “day temp agency work” the manifesto singles out registered-type temp agency work: “With regard to the equal treatment of regular and non-regular workers, the manifesto promised better protection for non-regular workers through better access to “social security”, mentioning pensions, health insurance and unemployment insurance. Source: http://www.komei.or.jp/ (accessed in May 2011).

Page 25: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

25/31

of a strategic dilemma faced by parties targeting salaried employees particularly in the

lower income range. Yet, this does not necessarily mean that insider-outsider divsisions

do not exist in Japan. Rather the present Japanese political situation and in particular the

economic situation of 2009 seem to emphasise mutual interests (such as a better safety

net) instead of issues which could potentially divide and polarise groups of different

employment status. This is also underlined by the fact that insiders are even more likely

to support higher taxes. It may only be once issues with more potential for polarisation

are put on the political agenda (e.g. employment protection for regular workers), that

the latent conflict between employment groups will finally become visible. So contrary

to H4, it looks like the crisis has, if at all, narrowed the latent gap between insiders and

outsiders at least temporarily. On the other hand, the LDP and New Komei-tou have

since resisted all attempts at re-regulation of non-regular work, which suggests, that

polarisation may gradually unfold.

6. Preliminary conclusions

Purpose of this paper has been to investigate whether the massive expansion of non-

regular employment in Japan has had a structural (read lasting) impact on preference

formation of voters and thus for partisan competition and labour policy-making or is

likely to develop such an influence in the foreseeable future. It has demonstrated that

the issue of labour market regulation has indeed become politically salient in recent

years which is most visible if one considers the intensity with which the DPJ-led

government has addressed the issue even though it did not fulfil many of the legislative

promises it had made during the 2009 election campaign. Yet, this paper also suggests

important differences to European countries and, most importantly, a much more

complex formation process of preferences than is usually recognised in the literature.

For instance, salience is important as labour market regulation has not been an issue of

major concern for Japanese voters. Moreover, among younger voters, clearly one of the

most concerned groups with regard to labour market dualism, this does not lead to a

major re-orientation with regard to welfare policy or redistribution. If at all, they seem

to support less spending and less redistribution than other groups. For these reasons the

dilemma for governments may thus be rather small despite the existence of clear

disparities.

Page 26: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

26/31

In more general terms, it is interesting to note that there is little evidence for

fundamentally different preferences between worker groups but rather moderate

differences in the strength of preferences. Some may interpret this as a sign that the

Japanese way of labour market dualism is much less problematic than that found

elsewhere or that present scholarship or the massive media attention for social

inequalities is simply exaggerating. Yet given the experience in other countries it is more

likely linked to the fact that insiders and outsiders actually have similar expectations vis-

à-vis the Japanese state, preferring more state-centred intervention to make up for

growing instability on the labour market. As the Japanese state is so far much less visible

in welfare provision than say in Germany but the stability of employment and corporate

welfare have become increasingly uncertain in a similar manner as in other advanced

countries, more publicly-run welfare may be in the interest of all workers. At the same

time, there is a clear bias toward low taxes especially among disadvantaged workers, so

the issue of consoling more welfare with low taxes may constitute a much bigger

strategic dilemma for Japanese parties. This point would certainly justify more in-depth

research.

A second interesting observation concerns the different degree of political alienation.

The Japanese case indicates that status-centred employment mechanisms may have a

lasting impact on the integration into the political system. It seems clear that male

employees in secure jobs in large firms feel more confident about their political voice

than workers in smaller ones. This may have to do with the fact that they have better

informational and financial resources that help them to form preferences while for

outsiders information and opportunity costs are considerably higher. This suggests that

much more theoretical and empirical work is required about when and how differences

between labour market insiders and outsiders become relevant. Since social democracy

has never been a strong movement in most developed East Asian countries, a better

conceptualisation of the impact of non-regular expansion on partisan politics is needed.

This too points to several promising future research perspective on in East Asia, Europe

and across regions.

Page 27: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

27/31

7. Annex

Figure 4 Employment regulation in selected OECD countries (1985 to 2008)

Source: Own compilation based on the OECD’s EPL (employment protection legislation) indicator (OECD 1994, 2004; Venn 2009). Latest available data in bold. Higher numbers indicate a higher level of protection/regulation. The figure compares the oldest with the most recent data available. Note that the direction of reforms within this period has not been linear in all cases and that additional provisions that apply to collective dismissals have only been integrated since 1998. Also, in earlier versions of the indicator Japan’s level of regular employment protection was assessed closer to that of Germany both in 1985 and in the 2000s. See annex A for details on the indicators’ components and a critical assessment. Figure 5 Regular and non-regular employment in Germany and Japan (percentage of employed persons)

GER 2008DEN 2008

ESP 2008

FRA 2008

ITA 2008

JAP 2008

NED 2008

SWE 2008UK 2008

US '85-'08

GER 1985DEN 1985

FRA 1985

ITA 1985

NED 1985

SWE 1985

UK 1985

ESP 1985

JAP 1985

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

0 1 2 3 4

Reg

ulat

ion

of n

on-r

egul

ar w

ork

Employment protection for regular workers

82,0%

63,0%

2,1%

16,6%

3,0%

12,6%

2,3%

1,2%

7,2%

8,7%

0% 25% 50% 75% 100%

Men

Women

Germany

Regular (Normalarbeitsverhältnis) Part-time (Teilzeit) Marginal (geringfügig)Temp agency (Leiharbeit) Fixed-term (befristet)

Page 28: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

28/31

Note: Percentages are indicative only. The Japanese survey asks respondents how employers refer to their employment status. This and the fact that many employees do not have a formal work contract make a certain level of misinterpretation likely. In Germany, overlaps between different forms of non-regular workers are not addressed in official statistics. While part-time, marginal and temp-agency employment can be identified reasonably well, overlaps between them remain under-researched. The data has been adjusted for overlaps (i.e. subtracting all marginally employed part-time employees from the part-timer group) based on a special investigation of the Mikrozensus. Direct comparisons between different forms of employment across countries should be done with caution, see text. Data for Japan is from 2009 and 2008 for Germany. Sources: MHLW (2010): Labour Force Survey [roudou ryoku chousa] and Mikrozensus as cited in Statistisches Bundesamt (2009): Niedrigeinkommen und Erwerbstätigkeit.

82,2%

46,3%

2,9%

32,4%

5,7%

7,7%

1,3%

3,5%

5,8%

6,8%

2,2%

3,2%

0% 25% 50% 75% 100%

Men

Women

Japan

Regular worker (seiki no shokuin/juugyounin) Part-time (paato)Marginal employment (arubaito) Temp agency worker (hakenshain)Fixed-term employee (keiyakushain) Other non regular

Page 29: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

29/31

Table 6 Operationalisation

Variable Operationalisation

Employment status

Insider: Regular employee excluding executives Outsider: Temporary worker, dispatched worker, unemployed

Wage earner status

Primary wage earner: Own income is largest source of income (2000-2003: own income was ticked but not income of spouse) Secondary wage earner: Spouse/partner's income is largest source of income (for 2000-2003: spouse’s income was ticked but not own income)

Firm size Small: employers with less than 299 employees Large: Employers with more than 299 employees

Employment (in)security

Secure workers Those who chose "unlikely" or "very unlikely" to question on likelihood of dismissal within the next 12 months Insecure workers: Those who chose "likely" or "very likely"

Young workers

Young workers: workers with either an outsider or insider job not older than 35 years Older workers: workers with either an outsider or insider jobs older than 35 years

8. References

ABE, AYA K. (2003): Low-income people in social security systems in Japan. The Japanese Journal of Social Security Policy 2 (2): 59-70.

BURGOON, BRIAN and DEKKER, FABIAN (2010): Flexible employment, economic insecurity and social policy preferences in Europe. Journal of European Social Policy 20 (2): 126-141.

COLE, ROBERT E. (1978): The late-developer hypothesis: An evaluation of its relevance for Japanese employment practices. Journal of Japanese Studies 4 (2): 247-265.

DORE, RONALD (1973): British factory - Japanese factory. Berkeley: University of California Press. EMMENEGGER, PATRICK (2010): Gendering insiders and outsiders labour market status and

preferences for job security. Working Papers on the Reconciliation of Work and Welfare in Europe (02).

ESPING-ANDERSEN, GOSTA (1990): The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

--- (1997): Hybrid or unique? The Japanese welfare state between Europe and America. Journal of European Social Policy 7 (3): 179-189.

ESTÉVEZ-ABE, MARGARITA (2008): Welfare and capitalism in postwar Japan: Party, bureaucracy, and business. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

HÄUSERMANN, SILJA and SCHWANDER, HANNA (2009): Identifying outsiders across countries: Similarities and differences in the patterns of dualisation. Working Papers on the Reconciliation of Work and Welfare in Europe (09).

HEINRICH, STEFFEN (2010): Facing the 'dark side' of deregulation? The politics of two-tier labour markets in Germany and Japan after the global financial crisis. In: Greener, Ian, Holden, Chris and Kilkey, Majella (eds.): Social Policy Review 22. Bristol: The Policy Press: 149-172.

KALLEBERG, ARNE L. (2003): Flexible firms and labour market segmentation. Effects of workplace restructuring on jobs and workers. Work and Occupations 30 (2): 154-175.

KASZA, GREGORY J. (2006): One world of welfare. Japan in comparative perspective. Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press.

Page 30: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

30/31

KEZUKA, KATSUTOSHI (1993): Atypische Beschäftigungsverhätlnisse in Japan. WSI-Mitteilungen (9): 611-616.

KING, DESMOND and RUEDA, DAVID (2008): Cheap labour: The new politics of 'bread and roses' in industrial democracies. Perspectives on Politics 6 (2): 279-297.

KITSCHELT, HERBERT and REHM, PHILIPP (2006): New social risks and political preferences. In: Armingeon, Klaus and Bonoli, Giuliano (eds.): The politics of post-industrial welfare states. Adapting post-war social policies to new social risks. London: Routledge: 52-82.

LINDBECK, ASSAR and SNOWER, DENNIS J. (1988): The insider-outsider theory of employment and unemployment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

MARX, PAUL and PICOT, GEORG (2011): Die sozialpolitischen Präferenzen der Mittelschicht. Sozialer Fortschritt 60 (12): 289-295.

MEHRTENS III, F. JOHN (2004): Three worlds of public opinion? Values, variation, and the effect on social policy. International Journal of Public Opinion Research 16 (2): 115-143.

MIURA, MARI (2001): Globalization and reforms of labour market institutions: Japan and major OECD countries. Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo, Domestic Politics Project No. 4 F-94.

NAKAMURA, KEISUKE (2007): Decline or revival? Japanese labour unions. Japan Labor Review 4 (1): 7-22.

OECD (1994): The OECD jobs study: Evidence and explanations, II. The adjustment potential of the labour market. Paris: OECD Publishing.

--- (2004): OECD employment outlook 2004: Recent labour market developments and prospects. Paris: OECD Publishing.

ONO, HIROSHI (2007): Lifetime employment in Japan: Concepts and measurements. SSE/EFI Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance 624.

OSAWA, MARI (2002): Twelve million full-time housewives: The gender consequences of Japan’s postwar social contract. In: Zunz, Olivier, Schoppa, Leonard and Hiwatari, Nobuhiro (eds.): Social contracts under stress. The middle classes of America, Europe, and Japan at the turn of the century. New York: Russell Sage Foundation: 255-277.

PALIER, BRUNO and THELEN, KATHLEEN (2010): Institutionalizing dualism: Complementarities and change in France and Germany. Politics & Society 38 (1): 119-148.

PIERSON, PAUL (2001): Post-industrial pressures on mature welfare states. In: Pierson, Paul (ed.): The new politics of the welfare state. Oxford: Oxford University Press: 80-106.

REBICK, MARCUS (2005): The Japanese employment system: Adapting to a new economic environment. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

ROBSON, PAUL; DEX, SHIRLEY; WILKINSON, FRANK and CORTES, OLGA SALIDO (1999): Low pay, labour market institutions, gender and part-time work: Cross-national comparisons. European Journal of Industrial Relations 5 (2): 187-207.

RUEDA, DAVID (2005): Insider–outsider politics in industrialized democracies: The challenge to social democratic parties. American Political Science Review 99 (1): 61-74.

--- (2007): Social democracy inside out. Partisanship and labour market policy in industrialised democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

SHINODA, TORU (2009): Which side are you on? Hakenmura and the working poor as a tipping point in Japanese labour politics. The Asia-Pacific Journal 14 (3).

SHIRAHASE, SAWAKO (2010): Japan as a stratified society: With a focus on class identification. Social Science Japan Journal 13 (1): 31-52.

SHIRE, KAREN A. and VAN JAARSVELD, DANIELLE D. (2008): The temporary staffing industry in protected employment economies: Germany, Japan and the Netherlands. Sloan Industry Studies Working Papers (WP-2008-24).

SONG, JEYEOUN (2010): Japan's labour market reform after the collapse of the bubble economy: Political determinants of regulatory changes. Asian Survey 50 (6): 1011-1031.

TIBERGHIEN, YVES (2011): The political response to the inequality problem in Japan since 2006. Paper presented at the Annual convention of the Association of Asian Studies (AAS), April 2, Honolulu, Hawaii.

Page 31: UQAM - Flexible jobs but polarised politics? The political …centre-mcd.uqam.ca/upload/files/Publications/Veille... · 2012-06-04 · 2/31 1. Introduction At first glance the notion

31/31

TODA, HIROMI (2007): The increase of non-regular workers and social security [Hiseiki koyou-sha no zouka to shakai hoshou 非正規雇用者の増加と社会保障]. Reference (673): 21-44.

VENN, DANIELLE (2009): Legislation, collective bargaining and enforcement: Updating the OECD employment protection indicators. Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers (89).

WEATHERS, CHARLES (2008): Shuntou and the shackles of competitiveness. Labor History 49 (2): 177–197.

YUN, JI-WAH (2010): Unequal Japan: Conservative corporatism and labour market disparities. British Journal of Industrial Relations 48 (1): 1-25.


Recommended