+ All Categories
Home > Economy & Finance > Wang market confidence and momentum

Wang market confidence and momentum

Date post: 24-Jan-2015
Category:
Upload: 23tino
View: 63 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
 
Popular Tags:
33
1 Market confidence and momentum Kevin Q. Wang and Jianguo Xu Abstract We develop a model in which equity fundamentals are subject to random shocks. Investors learn about the shocks through noisy information. The model shows that momentum is more pronounced in a more confident market. We conduct tests of the prediction and find supportive evidence. Specifically, we find that market volatility negatively predicts momentum profits. This evidence supports the prediction since a more volatile market is likely to be less confident. The model also predicts that idiosyncratic shocks, not systematic shocks, produce momentum. This is consistent with empirical findings from a number of studies.
Transcript
Page 1: Wang   market confidence and momentum

1

Market confidence and momentum

Kevin Q. Wang and Jianguo Xu

Abstract

We develop a model in which equity fundamentals are subject to random shocks. Investors learn about the shocks through noisy information. The model shows that momentum is more pronounced in a more confident market. We conduct tests of the prediction and find supportive evidence. Specifically, we find that market volatility negatively predicts momentum profits. This evidence supports the prediction since a more volatile market is likely to be less confident. The model also predicts that idiosyncratic shocks, not systematic shocks, produce momentum. This is consistent with empirical findings from a number of studies.

Page 2: Wang   market confidence and momentum

2

Momentum refers to the phenomenon that an arbitrage portfolio comprised of a long

position on stocks that perform better and a short position on stocks that perform worse during

the past 3-12 months (the ranking period) earns a positive profit during the next 3-12 moths (the

holding period). This phenomenon, first documented by Jagadeesh and Titman (1993), has been

confirmed in many later studies. It has been found that momentum extends to later time periods

(Jagadeesh and Titman (2001)), exists in industry portfolios (Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999)),

value and size portfolios (Lewellen (2002)), and extends to markets other than the United States

(Rouwenhorst (1998)). It has also been found that equity indices also exhibit momentum

(Richards (1995, 1997), Chan, Hameed, and Tong (2000)). The momentum profit is “abnormal”

because it cannot be explained by known risk factors. Fama and French (1996) find that

momentum is the only anomaly that cannot be explained by their three-factor model. Momentum

is particularly annoying because the finding that historical returns help predict future returns

implies that financial markets is not efficient even in the weak form.

Time-varying return patterns of winners and losers in a momentum strategy are

impressive. Figure 1 shows the performance of a 6-6 momentum strategy for the 24 months after

ranking.1 Figure 2 depicts the momentum strategy in a slightly longer time horizon, including

pre-ranking, ranking, and post-holding periods. Together figures 1 and 2 suggest that the winner

(loser) stocks experience positive (negative) shocks. The price changes in the ranking period are

most impressive, suggesting that most of the shocks are incorporated into prices during the

ranking period. For the 6-6 momentum strategy and for the full sample of 1926-2007, the

ranking period winner-loser return spread is about 84% while the holding period return spread is

about 4%. Thus, about 95% of the price adjustments (run-up or run-down) have occurred during 1 A J-K momentum strategy refers to a strategy that ranks past J month returns and hold the portfolio for K months. Throughout this paper we focus on a 6-6 strategy unless otherwise stated.

Page 3: Wang   market confidence and momentum

3

the ranking period, with about 5% left for the holding period which gives rise to the appearance

of momentum profits. It is clear that in terms of the longer time window, momentum profits over

the holding period are of minor magnitude, relative to the huge winner-loser performance

difference over the ranking period. Nonetheless, monthly profit of about 0.7% is economically

significant and commands an explanation.

In this paper, we develop a model that is motivated by the evidence. We aim to

understand the roles of random shocks and investor learning in generating momentum profits.

We organize the thoughts into a model with two risky assets whose payoffs are subject to

random shocks. The representative investor learns about the shocks via noisy information. The

learning is not immediate due to noises in the information, which leads to gradual adjustment of

asset prices and appearance of underreaction. The model produces predictions about sources of

momentum and variations of momentum profits in different market conditions.

First, only idiosyncratic shocks lead to momentum. Systematic shocks that affect all

stocks do not produce momentum. Intuitively, systematic shocks are shared by all stocks and

thus do not affect cross sectional stock returns beyond risk loadings. Since momentum cannot be

explain by risk factors, it cannot be due to systematic shocks. This prediction is consistent with

earlier findings (e.g., Grundy and Martin (2001)) that momentum profit is stronger when stocks

are sorted on idiosyncratic past returns. Sorting on idiosyncratic returns better captures

idiosyncratic shocks than sorting on gross returns. This prediction is also consistent with the

finding of Hou, Peng, and Xiong (2005) that momentum is more pronounced among high R-

square stocks. Stocks with higher R-squares are likely to have experienced larger idiosyncratic

shocks which generate a larger momentum payoff.

Page 4: Wang   market confidence and momentum

4

Second, the model predicts that momentum should be more pronounced when market

confidence is higher. The intuition is that in a more confident market, investors react less to new

information, including information about random shocks. Therefore, shocks are incorporated into

price slower, which implies larger momentum profit. We empirically test this prediction and find

supportive evidence. Specifically, we find that momentum is more pronounced when volatility is

lower. Since lower volatility implies higher market confidence, this evidence supports our

prediction that a more confident market exhibits less momentum.

This finding that market confidence negatively predicts momentum can be related to the

finding of Cooper, Gutierrez and Hammed (2004) that momentum depends on market states.

They find that momentum only exists in “UP” markets. We control for market states and find

that the effect of volatility persists after controlling for market status. The explanation that

Cooper, Gutierrez and Hammed propose for their finding is that investors become more

overconfident after good market performance. Although our evidence does not contradict the

behavioral explanations, we argue that it is not necessary to introduce overconfidence to explain

momentum. After random shocks, especially as large as shown above, it is rational that investors

gradually update their opinions. As shown by Leroy (1973) and Lucas (1978), unforecastability

of asset returns is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition of economic equilibrium.

We emphasize that the appearance of momentum exists from the stand point of

econometricians who have information that is not available to investors. From the perspective of

real time investors who have to base their decisions on information available to them, they

cannot predict momentum and contrarian in equity prices. Thus, there is no tradable strategy

available for them (Lewellen and Shanken (2002)). Investors who trade on beliefs about

fundamentals cannot exploit momentum. In addition, momentum is by nature a statistical

Page 5: Wang   market confidence and momentum

5

strategy which is not available to individual investors who usually only hold a small number of

stocks in their portfolios. The remaining question is whether portfolio managers can benefit from

a momentum strategy. Even for professional traders or money managers, there are at least three

unfavorable features of a momentum strategy: 1) high turnover and transaction costs, 2) negative

skewness, and 3) costly and risky short selling. Furthermore, it is useful to emphasize that

momentum trading is not a risk-free arbitrage opportunity. For example, it is not profitable

during the 1990-1995 and 2001-2003 periods.

Our model differs from existing rational explanations for momentum. Berk, Green and

Naik (1999) propose that momentum arises from the persistence in expected returns. Johnson

(2002) argues that since the growth rate risk carries a positive price, high growth firms tend to

have high expected returns. Sorting on past returns tends to sort firms by recent growth rates.

Momentum arises because winners have higher expected returns than losers. In theory our model

does not deny expected return as an alternative explanation for momentum. However, it is

difficult to attribute the extremely high (low) returns of the winner (loser) portfolio during the

ranking period to expected returns. Even a casual look at Figure 2 suggests that non-expected

shocks are at work. We explore unexpected shocks as a source of momentum in this study.

The model also differs from existing behavioral explanations for momentum. Daniel,

Hirschleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998) develop a model in which investors are overconfident in

private information and this underreact to public information which produces momentum.

Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998) allow investors to suffer from the cognitive biases of

representativeness and conservatism. Investors in their model initially underreact and then

overreact when a pattern is observed in data. Hong and Stein (1999) allow investors to focus on a

subset of information. In their model, “newswatchers” focus on private information about future

Page 6: Wang   market confidence and momentum

6

fundamentals and ignore price history. “Momentum traders” look at price history only. Both

types of investors in their models have bounded rationality in the sense that they fail to take all

information into consideration. In comparison, we introduce random shocks to asset fundamental.

We assume investors are rational Bayesian learners with limited and imperfect information to

learn the true payoffs.

Our model and evidence is in spirit consistent with the arguments of Chan, Jegadeesh,

and Lakonishok (1996) that is momentum is due to slow travel of information. We contend that

instead of “slow travel of information”, momentum may be explained by “slow adjustment of

opinions”. Although seemingly identical, we contend that slow adjust of opinions is more

appealing because of two reasons. First, slow travel of information only applies to private

information. Public information reaches all information receivers immediately in today’s

financial markets. At the same time, whether momentum is due solely to private information is

unclear. In contrast, slow adjustment of opinions applies to both private and public information.

Second, our model can explain a set of accumulated evidence about momentum as discussed

above. More importantly, our model produces a new prediction that is empirically confirmed.

Therefore, our model is better in the sense of being able to explain more evidence and producing

new empirically testable predictions.

A comment on the difference between opinion and information is at demand. Varian

(1989) vividly asks: when someone conveys a probability belief to another agent, what should

the other agent respond? If he updates his posterior belief just as my probability belief, he has

interpreted my probability belief as information, or credible. If he does not update his posterior

at all, then he has interpreted my belief as opinion, or incredible. Very likely, he will partially

adjust his posterior based on my probability belief. In that case, he interprets my belief as

Page 7: Wang   market confidence and momentum

7

partially information and partially opinion. So the critical question is: when one makes a

pronouncement, is he conveying information or just conveying his opinion. Or more precisely,

how much of the pronouncement is information and how much is opinion? We can ask the same

question for any announcement. For any announcement, by a company or by a statistics bureau,

one can ask how much he can trust this announcement and how much he should update his

beliefs. Obviously all announcements, no matter how objective or numerical they seem to be, are

based on one set of methodology. The methodology itself is a set of opinions. Besides, even if

the methodology may seem to be very objective, there are always space for subjective

interpretations and discretionary judgments. At the end, we are reaching the sense that there

exists no “pure” information.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In Section I, we construct and solve the

model. Implications for price underreaction and momentum are derived. Testable predictions are

discussed. In Section II, we present empirical findings from our tests. Section III concludes.

I. The Model

A. Model structure

Consider a market with one safe asset and two risky assets. The safe asset pays a fixed

interest income at the end of each period. Investors can buy or sell the safe asset infinitely. For

simplicity, the interest rate is assumed to be zero. The risky assets, A and B, pay stochastic

payoffs, TBA ),( θθθ = .

There are two periods and three times, t=0, 1, 2. At time 0 risk neutral investors enter the

market endowed unit of each of the risky assets. At time 1 one signal is observed for each of

Page 8: Wang   market confidence and momentum

8

risky assets about its payoff. Investors trade to reach a new equilibrium. At time 2 the asset is

liquidated after realizing the payoff.

The risky assets are subject to a random shock at time 1, after which the payoff is

ηθ +=x , TBA ),( ηηη = . At time 1 a signal about each asset, T

BA sss ),(= , is observed

ε+= xs , (1)

where ε represents a vector of noises. Plugging x into (1) give

εηθ ++=s . (2)

Random variables, θ , η , and ε , are independent. The correlation between these two asset

payoffs is ),(),( BABA corrcorr ηηθθρ == . The noises are independent. All variables are

normally distributed: ),(~ θθµθ ΣN , ),0(~ ηη ΣN , ),0(~ εε ΣN , where ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=

B

A

µµ

µθ ,

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=Σ 22

22

θθ

θθθ σρσ

ρσσ, ⎟

⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=Σ 22

22

ηη

ηηη σρσ

ρσσ, ⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=Σ 2

2

00

ε

εε σ

σ. The precisions of these variables are

denoted by 1−Σ= θθτ , 1−Σ= ηητ , and 1−Σ= εετ , respectively.

Remark 1: The model is set up in its simplest form. Investors can buy and sell the safe

asset infinitely thus there is no wealth effect on prices of the risky assets. Two is the minimum

number of risky assets required to study cross sectional variations in risky returns such as

momentum. Two is also the minimum number of periods to study time series price behavior.

One way to interpret the liquidation at time 2 is that investors receive a decisive signal without

noise about the payoff. Extending the model into multiple periods with multiple assets and

assume investors observe a noisy signal each period does not add new insights. Investors are

Page 9: Wang   market confidence and momentum

9

assumed to be risk neutral because in this paper we do not consider risk aversion as an

explanation for price momentum or reversal. We do not model asset heterogeneity, therefore we

assume Aθ and Bθ , Aη and Bη , Aε and Bε have identical variances, respectively.

Remark 2: The timing of the model is as below. At time 0 the nature makes its first move

to pick values for Aθ and Bθ . At time 1 the nature makes its second move to pick values for Aη ,

Bη , Aε , and Bε . Investors know the joint distribution but not the value of these variables.

B. Equilibrium

For normal distribution, the posterior belief after observing the signals is given by the

standard formula (see, e.g., DeGroot (1970)).

)()()|( 1 ssxE xx εθε τµτττ ++= −

Plug in (1) and rearrange, we have:

ssxE x~)()|( 1

εεθ τττµ −++= , (3)

where θµεηθ −++=s~ is the information “surprises”.

From equation (3) it is clear that the error in initial expectation, θµθ − , and the shock to

the payoff, η , are equivalent in the belief updating formula. This is not surprising since an error

in initial beliefs constitute a “shock” when revealed. We could have assumed that investor’s

beliefs are rational in the sense that this difference equals zero. This assumption does not change

the model.

Expanding (3) gives:

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+−−+

+⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

BA

BA

B

A

B

A

ksskskks

sxEsxE

)1()1(

)|()|(

δµµ , (4)

Page 10: Wang   market confidence and momentum

10

where 22

2

)1()1(

εσσρσρδ++

+=

x

x , 2222

222

)1()1(

εε

ε

ρσσσρσσρ++−

+−=

x

xk are constants.

Risk neutrality implies that equilibrium prices equal the expected payoff at times 0 and 1.

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

B

A

B

A

PP

µµ

0

0

. (5)

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+−−+

+⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

BA

BA

B

A

B

A

ksskskks

PP

)1()1(

1

1

δµµ

. (6)

At time 2, the payoffs are realized and there is no uncertainty,

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛++

=⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

BB

AA

B

A

PP

ηθηθ

2

2

. (7)

We define return as the dollar price change during a time period, rather than the

percentage price change. This allows us to avoid dealing with the division operation in

calculating percentage returns. Equations (5), (6), and (7) jointly give

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+−−+

=⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

BA

BA

B

A

ksskskks

rr

)1()1(

1

1

δ , (8)

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+−−+

−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+−+

=⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

BA

BA

BBB

AAA

B

A

ksskskks

rr

)1()1(

2

2

δµηθµηθ

. (9)

Notice worthy is that in this model all returns are unexpected. Risk neutrality implies

zero risk premium and thus zero expected returns. Returns are driven by changes in expected

payoff which constitutes surprises to the market.

Page 11: Wang   market confidence and momentum

11

C. Price underreaction

Equation (4) describes the revision in expectations as a scaled weighted average of the

information surprises. The weights on the signal of the asset and the other asset are k and 1-k,

2222

222

)1()1(

εε

ε

ρσσσρσσρ++−

+−=

x

xk . Because 22222 )1( εεε ρσσσσρ ≥≥+− x , with the equalities hold when

1=ρ , we have ]1,5.0[∈k . So the weight on an asset’s own signal is at least as large as the

weight on the other asset’s signal. In the special case of perfectly correlated payoffs ( 1=ρ ), the

weights on both signals are equally split into one half. Another special case is when the assets are

independent ( 0=ρ ). In this case k=1, which means that the beliefs about the two assets are

updated independently on its own signal without taking into consideration the other signal. In

this case the model degenerates into a single risky asset model. We assume that ]1,0[∈ρ .

Although it is theoretically possible for ρ to be negative, equity returns are usually positively

correlated. We summarize this discussion in the following observation.

OBSERVATION 1: The weight investors put on asset’s own signal is at least one half. It

decreases with asset correlation.

The scaling factor, 22

2

)1()1(

εσσρσρδ++

+=

x

x , is between 0 and 1. The implication is that if the

initial expectation does not equal the true payoff at time 1, investors only partially adjust their

expectations after observing the signal. This is a natural result of Bayesian updating. It is also

straightforward that δ increases with ρ and decreases with 2εσ . The intuition is simple. If the

assets are more correlated, essentially there is less variation in the payoff and the signals provide

Page 12: Wang   market confidence and momentum

12

better information about the assets. And when the signals are less noisier, investors put more

weight on the signal and less weight on the prior expectation. In the special case that the signals

are completely revealing ( )02 =εσ , the scaling factor reaches unity.

OBSERVATION 2: If the initial expectations do not equal the true payoff, investors partially

adjust their expectations toward the true payoff. The speed of adjustment increases with asset

correlation and information quality.

An obvious yet important message from equation (4) is that if there is no difference

between investors’ initial expectation and the true payoff, on average investors’ posterior beliefs

will not be biased. That is, erroneous initial expectations or shocks are necessary for price

underreaction in this model. This partial adjustment of expectations toward the true value is

rational in the Bayesian sense. The deviation in posterior expectation from true asset value

comes from the initial error in expectations, which is partially corrected by the signal, or from

the random shock to the fundamental, which investors partially learn from the signal.

It is useful to compare this model to behavioral models. In this model we allow errors in

initial beliefs or random shocks. We assume investors are rational Bayesian learners with limited

and imperfect information to learn the true payoffs. In comparison, Daniel, Hirschleifer, and

Subrahmanyam (1998) allow investors to be overconfident in their own private information and

give themselves too much credit (too less blame) in case of success (failure). Barberis, Shleifer,

and Vishny (1998) allow the representative investor to suffer from the cognitive biases of

representativeness and conservatism. Hong and Stein (1999) allow investors to focus on a subset

Page 13: Wang   market confidence and momentum

13

of information. In their model, “newswatchers” focus on private information about future

fundamentals and ignore price history. “Momentum traders” look at price history only. Both

types of investors in their models have bounded rationality in the sense that they fail to take all

information into consideration.

Essentially, we allow investors to have errors in their expectations but do not allow

investors to make mistakes when using the Bayesian method. I also allow investors have random

errors in their expectations. But it is not easy to take advantage of such possible existence of

errors. This is completely consistent with the argument of Grossman and Stiglitz (1980). In the

end, market efficiency is not that price is correct, but no free lunch. Market efficiency does not

preclude profit from unique insight and hard work.

D. Momentum

Price underreaction is not equivalent to momentum. The former concerns the time series

autocorrelation of asset or portfolio returns. The later is a cross sectional phenomenon: past

winners continue to outperform past losers for some period of time. To have momentum, we

introduce cross sectional differences in the assets. Consider a shock to one of the stock, A.

Without loss of generality, assume 0>Aη . The expected shock to stock B is ABE ρηη =)( .

Without loss of generality, assume that initial expectation is not biased thus the shock is the only

source for different payoff. On average stock A will be the winner and stock B will be the loser

during period 1. A momentum strategy of buying A and selling B earns expected profit of

)]()([)]()([ 1212BBAA PEPEPEPEM −−−= .

Substitute in equations (9) and organize, we have

Page 14: Wang   market confidence and momentum

14

22

2

)1()1(

ε

ε

σσρσηρ

+−−=

xAM . (10)

Equation (10) says that momentum profit is jointly determined by the shock, Aηρ)1( − ,

and the underreaction to shock, 22

2

)1( ε

ε

σσρσ

+− x

. To understand the first term in equation (10),

Aηρ)1( − , we decompose the total shock Aη into Aρη and Aηρ)1( − . The former represents the

part that is shared by asset B because of the inter-asset correlation, and the latter represents the

part that is idiosyncratic to asset A. From now on we label the former as systematic shock and the

latter idiosyncratic shock. Equation (10) says that only the idiosyncratic shock help generates

momentum. Intuitively, systematic shock affects both assets thus does not help generate

momentum, which is a cross sectional phenomenon. This discussion is supported by the finding

of Grundy and Martin (2001) that sorting on idiosyncratic returns produces larger momentum

profit than sorting on raw returns. This is because idiosyncratic returns better capture

idiosyncratic shocks.

The second term 22

2

)1( ε

ε

σσρσ

+− x

determines the size of momentum for given

idiosyncratic shock. More intuition can be obtained by decomposing the variation of asset payoff

2xσ into 2

xρσ and 2)1( xσρ− . The former captures the variation that is shared by both assets,

while the latter captures the variation that is idiosyncratic to individual assets. Therefore, we can

label 2xρσ as the “systematic” variance while 2)1( xσρ− the “idiosyncratic” variance. The second

term in equation (10) says that given an idiosyncratic shock, the strength of momentum is

determined by the ratio of the variance of noise to that of noise plus idiosyncratic asset payoff.

Page 15: Wang   market confidence and momentum

15

Several observations follow from equations (10), which makes the model subject to

empirical scrutiny. First, expected momentum profit increases with the idiosyncratic shock,

Aηρ)1( − . If shocks to asset fundamentals can be directly identified, we should expect

momentum to be related to idiosyncratic shocks. However, this might not be possible for most

cases due to 1) shocks may simply be unobservable, and 2) the value implication of shocks may

be difficult to calculate. When shocks cannot be identified, we can infer shocks from price

changes. To the extent that more idiosyncratic shocks lead to more dispersed stock returns, we

expect momentum to be more pronounced when individual stock returns are more dispersed. In

equation (10) dispersion of stock returns is measured by the parameter ρ . It is obvious from

equation (10) that momentum decreases with ρ . This is consistent with the finding of Hou, Peng

and Xiong (2005) that momentum is more pronounced for stocks with low R-square, the returns

of which is more dispersed.

Second, momentum decreases with the variance of asset payoff 2xσ . Since 2

xσ inversely

measures the confidence of prior expectations, momentum increases with market confidence.

Intuitively, when investors are more confident in their initial beliefs, they adjust their

expectations less to new information, leaving more space for momentum profit. This argument

share some similarity with the one based on overconfidence. Investors may become too confident

in their initial beliefs if they are overconfident in private information. However, overconfidence

is not necessary for this to happen.

Third, momentum profit decreases with information quality. When information is more

precise, investors learn faster and the shock is incorporated into prices faster. In the extreme case

of perfectly revealing information, 02 =εσ , there will be no momentum. This implication

Page 16: Wang   market confidence and momentum

16

predicts that momentum should be more pronounced in a market when information quality is

lower. However, a caution needs to be exerted when drawing this prediction. In such a market

investors also tend to be less confident in their prior expectations because they do not have high

quality information. Since weak prior confidence lead to less momentum, the overall effect is

unclear.

So for a market in which stocks move more synchronously, momentum should be less

pronounced. If a bear market is more synchronous than a boom market, momentum should be

more pronounced in a boom market. If synchronicity displays a U shape with market returns,

momentum profit should display an inverse U shape with market returns. The evidence that

Japan does not have momentum and that in Japan stocks are very synchronous is consistent with

this argument.

II. Empirical evidence

The model produces the novel prediction that momentum should be more pronounced

when the market is more confident. In this section we empirically test this prediction in two steps.

We split the stock market of the United States from 1926 to 2007, for which period we have data,

into 5-year periods. We calculate the volatility and momentum for each subperiods and examine

whether there exists a relationship between volatility and momentum. Essentially, we consider

the subperiods as “markets” and look for volatility-momentum correlation among these

“markets”. Second, for each month, I calculate the 6-month momentum profit and correlated this

profit to the volatility prior to the formation of the momentum portfolio. The model predicts that

higher volatility lead to lower momentum profits.

Page 17: Wang   market confidence and momentum

17

A. Data and method

The data for the study are all NYSE and AMEX stocks listed on the CRSP monthly file.

Our sample period covers January 1926 to December 2007. Stocks are sorted at the end of each

month t into deciles based on their prior six month, t-5 to t, returns. The test-period profit is

calculated for t+2 to t+6. Because we need 6 months to calculate past and future returns, our first

momentum portfolio is for June 2006 and last momentum portfolio is for June 2007. We follow

the usual practice to one month between the ranking and holding period. We define each

momentum portfolio as long in the prior six month winners (highest decile) and short in the prior

six-month losers (lowest decile). We exclude stocks with a price at the end of the formation

period below $1 to mitigate microstructure effects associated with low-price stocks.

B. Raw momentum

Table I reported the momentum profit for the whole sample period of 1927-2006. To

compare with other studies, I also report momentum for three subsamples: 1927-1964, 1965-

1989, 1990-2006. The subsamples are selected as before, after, and the same as the 1965-1989

sample in the original Jagadeesh and Titman (1993) study.

For the whole sample period of 1926-2007, the average monthly profit is 0.65% per

month. This profit is highly significant. Momentum is more pronounced during the 1965-1989

period (1% per month) than during the earlier 1926-1964 period (0.43% per month) and the later

1990-2007 period (0.66% per month).

It is notice worthy that a momentum strategy has negative skewness for the whole sample

and all three subsamples. Generally, losing portfolios are more positively skewed while winning

portfolios are more negatively skewed. The momentum portfolio is significantly negatively

Page 18: Wang   market confidence and momentum

18

skewed for the whole sample and all three subsample (insert evidence about significance of

skewness). This finding is consistent with the finding of Harvey and Siddique (2000), The

momentum strategy is especially negatively skewed during the early period of 1926-1964. To the

extent that investors like positive skweness and do not like negative skewness for their portfolios,

the negative skewness of the momentum strategy helps explain why momentum profit is not

arbitraged away.

Figure 3 plots the accumulative momentum profit from July 1926. Upward slopes suggest

positive momentum profit while downward slopes suggest negative momentum profit. As can be

seen from this picture, momentum is positive for most of the times. However, momentum is

negative for the periods of 1930-1940, 1991-1994, 2000-2004, etc.

Figure 3 also plots market volatility during the 6-month portfolio ranking periods. The

clear pattern is that when volatility shoots up, momentum profit attenuates or even become

negative. For example, during the 1930s, market volatility is very high and momentum profit is

negative. The same pattern shows up in early 1990s and 2000s. This pattern provides a primitive

support to our prediction that momentum increases with market confidence.

C. Momentum across decade

Table II reports momentum within decades together with average market return and

volatility during each decade. The idea is to consider the market in different decades as different

markets. We aim to identify a correlation between volatility and momentum between these

“different markets”. Because Cooper et al (2004) find that market states help predict momentum,

we also calculate the average market return during each decade. Momentum profit is strong in

1940s, 1950s, 1960s, 1980s, and 1990s. It does not exist during 1930s and 2000s. For 1920s and

Page 19: Wang   market confidence and momentum

19

1970s, momentum profit is significant at the 5% but not the 1% level. Table II also report the

simple average of momentum and non-momentum periods. The cutting is based on both 5% and

1% significance levels. Either case, the evidence suggests that momentum periods have higher

market returns and lower volatility. The former is consistent with Cooper et al (2004). The latter

supports our prediction.

D. Momentum conditional on market volatility

Encouraged by primitive support of our prediction, this section we conduct a more

systematic test of our prediction that market volatility negatively predicts momentum. For each

month, market volatility is calculated using daily returns during the 6-month ranking period. We

rank months on this volatility measure into quintiles. Quintile 1 includes the lowest volatility

months and quintile 5 includes the highest volatility months. Table III reports the average

momentum profits conditional on this ranking. The results are reported for the full sample of

1926-2007 and for the three subsamples of 1926-1964, 1965-1989, and 1990-2007.

The clear pattern is that momentum profit is positive and significant for low volatility

months, quintiles 1, 2, and 3. For quintiles 4 and 5, the momentum profit is insignificant, positive

or negative. The difference between quintiles 1 and 5 is highly significant. In other words,

momentum is positive and significant for 60% of months with lower volatility. Momentum profit

does not exists for the other 40% months with higher volatility. The decreasing of momentum

from low volatility to high volatility months is nearly monotonic. The result is robust across

subsamples.

Cooper et al (2004) finds that market states, defined as aggregate market returns during

the past 36 months, help determine the existence of momentum. They define “UP” markets as

Page 20: Wang   market confidence and momentum

20

months for which the past 36 month market return is positive and “DOWN” markets as months

with negative past 36-month market returns. To disentangle the effects of market states and

volatility on momentum, we sort months based on market volatility into low, medium, and high

volatility months. We independently sort months based on markets states into bad, medium and

good. Then we calculate momentum profits for the 9 groups jointly determined by market state-

volatility ranks. Table IV reports the results.

Several observations emerge from Table IV. First, after controlling for market states,

higher volatility still leads to lower momentum profit. Second, in the highest volatility group,

momentum does not exist no matter the market state is bad, medium or good. Third, after

controlling for volatility, better market state does not lead to better momentum profit. In fact, in

low volatility months higher market return leads to lower momentum. In comparison, in high

volatility months higher market returns lead to higher momentum. This reverse of pattern can

possibly due to the possibility that market state is a partial proxy for market confidence. In a

confident market (low volatility), market states does not capture additional variation in

confidence. In contrary, in a unconfident market (high volatility), market states capture further

variation in confidence.

Table IV is not conclusive due to the opposite effect of market state on momentum when

volatility is low versus when volatility is high. Table V conduct a regression analysis of

momentum on market state and volatility. Individually, market state positively predict

momentum while volatility negatively predicts momentum. The former is consistent with the

result of Cooper et al (2004). The latter is consistent with the evidence in Tables II, III and IV.

In the full sample of 1927, market state is not significant after controlling for market volatility.

On the other hand, market volatility continue to be significant after controlling for markets states.

Page 21: Wang   market confidence and momentum

21

Regression on the subsamples of 1926-1964, 1965-1989, 1990-2007 suggests that the

insignificance of market state is mainly due to the early sample period of 1926-1964. Recall that

according to Table II, momentum is negative and significant at the 10% significance level.

Overall, Tables IV and V suggests that market volatility is a better proxy for market confidence

than market state.

Page 22: Wang   market confidence and momentum

22

III. Concluding Remarks

We develop a model that aims at idiosyncratic shocks and investor learning. We

emphasize that these are two important factors, which jointly contribute to the momentum effect.

On the one hand, there exist random shocks to asset fundamentals. The shocks have an

idiosyncratic component. Alternatively, errors in investors’ expectation serve the same function.

On the other hand, investors learn about fundamentals via noisy signals. The noise prevents the

shocks from being incorporated into price quickly, giving rise to momentum.

The model implies that in the presence of the random shocks and information noise,

investor under-reaction should be observed. This implication is consistent with the documented

evidence on post event price continuation. The model further predicts that such continuation

should be more pronounced when investors are more confident in their prior beliefs. We have

documented some preliminary evidence that is consistent with this prediction.

We plan to consider two issues in future work. First, it is important to have a detailed

analysis of volatility-based forecasts of the momentum payoff. We are in the process of

performing robustness checks and conducting further tests. Second, an important direction is to

consider feasibility to extend beyond the representative agent framework. Intuitively, the

momentum profits should be intimately linked to investor trading, and hence may be associated

with interesting trading patterns. How to introduce heterogeneity among investors into the model,

which can produce trading predictions, is an inviting direction for further research.

Page 23: Wang   market confidence and momentum

23

References:

Asness, Clifford, 1997, The interaction of value and momentum strategies, Financial Analyst

Journal 53, 29–36.

Barberis, Nicholas, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, 1998, A model of investor sentiment,

Journal of Financial Economics 49, 307–343.

Chan, Kalok, Allaudeen Hameed, and Wilson Tong, 2000, Profitability of momentum strategies

in the international equity markets, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 35,

153-172.

Chan, Louis K., Narasimhan Jegadeesh, and Josef Lakonishok, 1996, Momentum strategies,

Journal of Finance 51, 1681–1713.

Chui, Andy, Sheridan Titman, and K. C. John Wei, 2000, Momentum, ownership structure, and

financial crises: An analysis of Asian stock markets. Working paper, University of Texas

at Austin.

Conrad, Jennifer, and Gautam Kaul, 1993, Long-term overreaction or biases in computed returns?

Journal of Finance 48, 39–63.

Conrad, Jennifer, and Gautam Kaul, 1998, An anatomy of trading strategies, Review of Financial

Studies 11, 489–519.

Daniel, Kent, David Hirshleifer, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, 1998, Investor psychology and

security market under- and overreactions, Journal of Finance 53, 1839–1886.

Davis, James L., Eugene F. Fama, and Kenneth R. French, 2000, Characteristics, covariances

and average returns, Journal of Finance 55, 389–406.

DeBondt, Werner F. M., and Richard H. Thaler, 1985, Does the stock market overreact? Journal

of Finance 40, 793–805.

Page 24: Wang   market confidence and momentum

24

Degroot, Morris H., 1970, Optimal statistical decisions, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., Hoboken, New

Jersey

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1993, Common risk factors in the returns on stocks

and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3–56.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1996, Multifactor explanations of asset pricing

anomalies, Journal of Financial Economics 51, 55–84.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1998, Value versus growth: The international

evidence, Journal of Finance 53, 1975–1999.

Grundy, Bruce D., and Spencer J. Martin, 2000, Understanding the nature of risks and the

sources of rewards to momentum investing, Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming.

Hong, Harrison, Terence Lim, and Jeremy C. Stein, 2000, Bad news travels slowly: Size, analyst

coverage, and the profitability of momentum strategies, Journal of Finance 55, 265–295.

Hong, Harrison, and Jeremy C. Stein, 1999, A unified theory of underreaction, momentum

trading and overreaction in asset markets, Journal of Finance 54, 2143–2184.

Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman, 1993, Returns to buying winners and selling

losers: Implications for stock market efficiency, Journal of Finance 48, 65–91.

Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman, 2000, Cross-sectional and time-series

determinants of momentum profits, Working paper, University of Illinois.

Lee, Charles, and Bhaskaran Swaminathan, 2000, Price momentum and trading volume, Journal

of Finance, forthcoming.

Loughran, Tim, and Jay R. Ritter, 1995, The new issues puzzle, Journal of Finance 50, 23–51.

Moskowitz, Tobias J., and Mark Grinblatt, 1999, Do industries explain momentum? Journal of

Finance 54, 1249–1290.

Page 25: Wang   market confidence and momentum

25

Richards, Anthony J., 1995, Comovements in national stock market returns: Evidence of predict-

ability but not cointegration, Journal of Monetary Economics 36, 631-654.

Richards, Anthony J., 1996, Winner-loser reversals in national stock market indices: Can they be

explained? Journal of Finance 52, 2130-2144.

Rouwenhorst, K. Geert, 1998, International momentum strategies, Journal of Finance 53, 267–

284.

Page 26: Wang   market confidence and momentum

26

Table I. Momentum profit

For each month from June 1926 to June 2007, NYSE/AMEX stocks in the CRSP database are ranked into deciles based on their past 6-month returns, t-5 to t. A momentum strategy of buying winners (decile 10) and selling losers (decile 1) is formed. Returns within deciles are equal weighted to calculate the portfolio return. The average equal weighted monthly return for the next 6 month excluding the immediate following month, t+2 to t+6, is reported. t values are adjusted for autocorrelation using the Newey-West method. Also reported is the skewness of portfolio returns. The results are reported for the full sample and three subsamples. Subsamples are selected as before, after, and the same as the 1965-1989 sample in the original study of Jegadeesh and Titman (1993).

1926-2007 1926-1964 Return T Skewness Return T Skewness

Loser 0.0111 4.06 1.68 0.0130 2.91 1.99 2 0.0116 4.92 1.59 0.0124 3.18 1.83 3 0.0126 5.79 1.48 0.0128 3.57 1.74 4 0.0125 6.10 1.36 0.0125 3.69 1.61 5 0.0129 6.57 1.21 0.0129 3.96 1.43 6 0.0132 7.02 0.99 0.0131 4.20 1.19 7 0.0134 7.26 1.00 0.0133 4.37 1.23 8 0.0140 7.69 0.69 0.0140 4.73 0.91 9 0.0148 7.96 0.64 0.0146 4.91 0.94

Winner 0.0176 8.17 0.56 0.0173 5.10 0.86

W-L 0.0065 4.87 -2.45 0.0043 2.03 -2.95 1965-1989 1990-2007 Return T Skewness Return T Skewness

Loser 0.0075 1.95 0.23 0.0120 3.38 -0.06 2 0.0109 3.30 0.21 0.0108 3.92 -0.32 3 0.0125 4.05 0.08 0.0121 5.03 -0.57 4 0.0129 4.43 0.06 0.0118 5.45 -0.47 5 0.0131 4.78 -0.10 0.0124 6.13 -0.39 6 0.0139 5.21 -0.04 0.0124 6.55 -0.46 7 0.0140 5.33 -0.10 0.0126 6.78 -0.63 8 0.0148 5.49 -0.15 0.0130 7.00 -0.58 9 0.0156 5.47 -0.22 0.0142 7.24 -0.76

Winner 0.0174 5.16 -0.10 0.0186 7.58 -0.45

W-L 0.0100 5.21 -0.65 0.0066 3.08 -0.85

Page 27: Wang   market confidence and momentum

27

Table II. Momentum across decades

The 1926-2007 period is split into decades. The decade 1920 includes year 1926 to 1929. The decade 2000 include year 2000-2007. NYSE/AMEX stocks in the CRSP database are ranked into deciles based on their past 6-month returns. A momentum portfolio of buying the winners and selling the losers is formed and held for 6 months skipping the immediate next month. Within each decade the average momentum profit are reported. The t values are adjusted for autocorrelation using the Newey-West method. Also reported are the average monthly return and volatility for the value weighted market index. Simple average of momentum profit, t value, market return, and market volatility across momentum and non-momentum decades based on the 1% and 5% significance levels are also reported.

Decade Momentum t Market return Volatility 1920 0.0102 2.25 0.0130 0.055 1930 -0.0103 -1.72 0.0050 0.104 1940 0.0078 3.79 0.0087 0.044 1950 0.0093 6.64 0.0146 0.032 1960 0.0118 5.10 0.0073 0.036 1970 0.0064 1.99 0.0062 0.049 1980 0.0122 6.44 0.0139 0.048 1990 0.0098 3.63 0.0142 0.039 2000 0.0022 0.79 0.0033 0.042

Average 0.0066 3.21 0.0096 0.050

Momentum and non-momentum decades: 5% significance Non-momentum -0.0041 -0.47 0.0042 0.073 Momentum 0.0096 4.26 0.0111 0.043

Momentum and non-momentum decades: 1% significance Non-momentum 0.0021 0.83 0.0069 0.063 Momentum 0.0102 5.12 0.0117 0.040

Page 28: Wang   market confidence and momentum

28

Table III. Momentum on market volatility

For each month during June1926-June 2007, NYSE/AMEX stocks in the CRSP database are ranked into deciles based on their past 6-month returns. A momentum portfolio of buying the winners and selling the losers is formed and held for 6 months skipping the immediate next month. For each month we calculate market volatility as the standard deviation of daily market return during the ranking period. Months are independently ranked into quintiles based on this volatility measure. The average momentum profit and autocorrelation adjusted t values within each quintile are reported. The results are reported for the full sample and three subsamples: 1926-1964, 1965-1989, and 1990-2007. Volatility Rank Loser Winner W-L T (Loser) T (Winner) T (W-L)

1926-2007

Low 0.0069 0.0189 0.0119 2.02 5.75 7.69 2 0.0091 0.0214 0.0122 3.44 7.96 9.34 3 0.0044 0.0137 0.0093 1.35 4.54 6.69 4 0.0139 0.0174 0.0033 2.65 4.03 1.43

High 0.0210 0.0166 -0.0044 2.48 3.06 -1.01 High-Low 0.0140 -0.0022 -0.0163 2.32 -0.51 -5.00

1926-1964

Low 0.0101 0.0191 0.0090 2.40 5.17 5.74 2 0.0139 0.0237 0.0098 3.60 5.46 4.43 3 0.0079 0.0186 0.0107 2.00 4.64 6.31 4 0.0130 0.0115 -0.0015 1.48 1.67 -0.42

High 0.0204 0.0128 -0.0076 1.36 1.31 -1.02 High-Low 0.01 -0.0063 -0.0166 0.93 -0.84 -2.88

1965-1989

Low -0.0021 0.0168 0.0189 -0.33 2.45 6.44 2 0.0007 0.0171 0.0164 0.16 3.85 7.65 3 -0.0015 0.0084 0.0099 -0.30 1.62 4.65 4 0.0203 0.0243 0.0040 2.74 4.20 1.07

High 0.0200 0.0207 0.0007 2.36 3.20 0.16 High-Low 0.0220 0.004 -0.0182 2.74 0.54 -4.38

1990-2007

Low 0.0122 0.0206 0.0083 3.68 6.25 3.77 2 0.0060 0.0167 0.0107 1.10 3.63 5.68 3 0.0068 0.0182 0.0113 1.31 4.30 3.74 4 0.0085 0.0171 0.0087 0.97 3.03 1.51

High 0.0263 0.0202 -0.0061 3.58 4.83 -1.29 High-Low 0.014 -0.0004 -0.0144 2.15 -0.09 -3.20

Page 29: Wang   market confidence and momentum

29

Table IV. Momentum on market states and volatility

For each month during June1926-June 2007, NYSE/AMEX stocks in the CRSP database are ranked into deciles based on their past 6-month returns. A momentum portfolio of buying the winners and selling the losers is formed and held for 6 months skipping the immediate next month. For each month we calculate market volatility as the standard deviation of daily market return during the ranking period. Months are equally ranked into 3 groups based on this volatility measure. For each month we also calculate market state as the return on the value weighted market index during the past 36 months following Cooper et al (2004) and independently rank months into 3 groups based on this market state measure. The average momentum profit and t values within each market state-volatility group are reported.

Market Volatility Low Medium High High-Low Market State

Bad 0.0157 0.0085 -0.0101 -0.0258

5.45 3.84 -2.15 6.22

Medium 0.0128 0.0127 0.0037 -0.0091 8.05 8.56 0.80 2.02

Good 0.0084 0.0090 0.0046 -0.0038 4.90 4.66 1.43 1.40

Good-Bad -0.0073 0.0005 0.015 -2.76 0.20 3.49

Page 30: Wang   market confidence and momentum

30

Table V. Regression of momentum on market state and volatility

For each month during June1926-June 2007, NYSE/AMEX stocks in the CRSP database are ranked into deciles based on their past 6-month returns. A momentum portfolio of buying the winners and selling the losers is formed. For each month we calculate market volatility as the standard deviation of daily market return during the ranking period. For each month we also calculate market state as the return on the value weighted market index during the past 36 months following Cooper et al (2004). Momentum profit is regressed on market state and volatility. t values are adjusted for autocorrelation using the Newey-West method.

1926-2007 1926-1964 1965-1989 1990-2007

Intercept -0.00033 0.02 0.013 0.011 0.017 0.011 -0.09 5.39 3.67 2.07 3.51 1.97

Market State 0.72 0.44 0.34 0.82 0.67 2.38 1.71 0.91 2.69 2.50

Market Volatility -0.34 -0.26 -0.23 -0.40 -0.27 -3.22 -3.29 -2.28 -3.60 -2.45

# of months 984 984 984 468 300 216 Adj. R-square 0.064 0.089 0.107 0.091 0.149 0.121

Page 31: Wang   market confidence and momentum

31

Figure 1. Accumulative return of winners and losers post ranking. The upper blue dashed (lower black solid) line is the accumulative return on the winner (loser) portfolio from month 1 to month 24 after portfolio ranking. Winners (losers) are NYSE/AMEX stocks ranked into the top (bottom) 10% on the past 6 month returns. Returns are demeaned by the average return of all NYSE/AMEX stocks.

Page 32: Wang   market confidence and momentum

32

Figure 1. Accumulative return of winners and losers around ranking. The upper blue dashed (lower black solid) line is the accumulative return on the winner (loser) portfolio from month -24 to month 24 around portfolio ranking. Winners (losers) are NYSE/AMEX stocks ranked into the top (bottom) 10% on the past 6 month returns. Returns are demeaned by the average return of all NYSE/AMEX stocks.

Page 33: Wang   market confidence and momentum

33

Figure 3. Accumulative momentum profit and market volatility. The black solid line (left axis) is the accumulative momentum profit from June 1926 to June 2007. Momentum profit is the return on a portfolio buying past 6 month winners and selling past 6 month losers and held for 6 month. The dashed blue line (right axis) is the smoothed market volatility, calculated as the standard deviation of daily returns on a value-weighted market portfolio during the 6 months ranking period.


Recommended