+ All Categories
Home > Documents > €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan...

€¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan...

Date post: 14-Aug-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
51
Youth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub- Saharan Africa Abstract In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market expectations and outcomes. We also perform a job matching exercise to understand youth labor market dynamics in Sub-Saharan Africa. Our results show that youth education is an influential factor of youth employment expectations and employment, ceteris paribus. Higher educational achievements have a great impact on expecting and securing better jobs, particularly in the technical and professional fields. Youth with low educational achievements, particularly primary education and lower, have a higher tendency to expect to be employed in occupations with low job complexity. Our results indicate a severe job-skill mismatch in all occupational categories, both before and after the youth’s transition into the labor market. Using education as the only selection criterion, we found that less than 10 per cent of employment expectations match with skills required while 55 per cent and 34 per cent are under or over educated for the jobs expected, respectively. Over and under education is a notable feature in youth labor markets in Sub-Saharan Africa. About 47 per cent of employed youth in the sample are over qualified for their respective jobs while 28 per cent are under qualified. 1
Transcript
Page 1: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Youth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa

Abstract

In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market expectations and outcomes.

We also perform a job matching exercise to understand youth labor market dynamics in Sub-Saharan

Africa. Our results show that youth education is an influential factor of youth employment

expectations and employment, ceteris paribus. Higher educational achievements have a great

impact on expecting and securing better jobs, particularly in the technical and professional fields.

Youth with low educational achievements, particularly primary education and lower, have a higher

tendency to expect to be employed in occupations with low job complexity. Our results indicate a

severe job-skill mismatch in all occupational categories, both before and after the youth’s transition

into the labor market. Using education as the only selection criterion, we found that less than 10 per

cent of employment expectations match with skills required while 55 per cent and 34 per cent are

under or over educated for the jobs expected, respectively. Over and under education is a notable

feature in youth labor markets in Sub-Saharan Africa. About 47 per cent of employed youth in the

sample are over qualified for their respective jobs while 28 per cent are under qualified.

JEL Classification : E24, J24, J60, J64

Keywords: wages, youth labor, unemployment, job search, job matching,

I. Introduction

Youth will be the most dynamic segment of the world population in upcoming years, particularly in

Sub-Saharan African countries that harbor very young populations. As seen during the Arab Spring in

2011, their influence, directly and indirectly, in the political, economic and social spheres will be

profound in the years ahead. Youth years are also a crucial time in life as young people start realizing

their aspirations, assuming economic independence and finding their place in society. However, this

phenomenon depends on numerous factors including adequate skill development prior to transition

1

Page 2: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

from school to work and a functioning local economy, among others. Recent global developments, in

particular, have made youth vulnerable to shocks. For example, the 2008 global financial crisis has

put further pressure on youth unemployment, reduced the quality of jobs, exacerbated labor market

inequalities among different demographics, particularly youth, made school to work transition both

longer and more insecure and increased detachment from the labor market. According to the Global

Employment Trends for Youth (ILO 2013), the weakening of the global recovery from the financial

crisis has further aggravated the youth employment crisis. Queues for available jobs have become

even longer for some unfortunate young jobseekers.

While having a young population enables countries to reap demographic dividends, it also becomes

a burden if sufficient policies are not enforced to ensure that the young are both employable and

employed. Youth unemployment is a critical issue not only in Sub-Saharan Africa but in most

emerging economies and to a certain extent, in developed countries. Understanding youth behavior

and the youth labor market is vital in order to implement policies that will best address youth

unemployment. Two particular issues that contribute to youth unemployment, among others, are

the limited access to learning opportunities as well as the mismatch of skills with respect to market

demand. The objective of this research is to investigate what influences youth labor market

expectations and if these expectations match with market demand. Investigation into what drives

youth labor market expectations and if these expectations match with market demand would help

us to understand the forces behind successful school to labor market transitions. Such an

investigation would also allow us to gauge into policies that may be necessary for strengthening

human capital and addressing youth unemployment.

We use the “School-to-work Transition Surveys (SWTS) 2012-2013” recently conducted by the ILO

for eight countries in Sub-Saharan Africa to investigate the relationship between youth labor market

expectations and outcomes. We combine the SWTS data sets with the “Labor Demand Enterprise

Surveys (LDES) 2012-2013” conducted by the ILO in our labor demand–supply matching exercise. To

2

Page 3: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

our knowledge, this is the first study that investigates school to labor market transition in Sub-

Saharan Africa using the aforementioned new data sets. The new data sets give this research an

edge over past studies and enable us to shed light on recent trends on the subject.

The remaining sections of the paper are organized as follows. Section II provides a brief literature

review of youth labor markets in Sub Saharan Africa. Section III will describe the model. Section IV

describes the data, and outlines the estimation methodology. An analysis of the estimation results is

provided in Section V, along with a robustness check of our results. Section VI discusses policy

implications of findings, and Section VII concludes the investigation.

II. Literature review

Literature on youth labor market expectations is very limited. The theory and empirical literature

that relate to the present research derives from two fronts. First is the theory on the impact of

cognitive and non-cognitive skills on employment and wages. In many studies, it is commonly

accepted that measured cognitive abilities are important determinants of educational and labor

market outcomes (e.g. Murnane et al. (1995), Cawley et al. (2000) and Cawley et al. (2001)). Using a

dynamic setting, Heineck (2011) investigated how cognitive abilities affect unemployment entry and

exit rates. According to Heineck, cognitive skills only weakly affect unemployment propensity and

contribute little to individual heterogeneity. However, they can aid employed males to stay out of

unemployment. Cognitive skills can also impact wages. For example, Capatina (2014), in a study of

the United States, found that returns to cognitive skills increase very sharply for high skill levels,

more gradually around mean levels, and decrease at low levels. Hanusek and Woessman (2008),

using a variety of data sources, including information on international tests conducted by the

International Association for the Evaluation of Educational Achievement (IAE) and from the OECD,

found that average levels of cognitive abilities are also associated with differences in economic

growth across countries. In this research, we will use the educational achievements of youth as a

reflection of outcomes of cognitive skills.

3

Page 4: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Past research also used family background as a control variable. For example, in a study of the British

education system, using longitudinal data from the National Child Development Study (NCDS), and

controlling for family background, school system and educational attainment, Weiss (2010) found

that both cognitive and non-cognitive abilities have an impact on earnings.1 The effects are especially

large at the bottom and top ends of the earning distribution. Calvès, Kobiané, and N’Bouké (2013),

using data from a retrospective survey conducted in Ouagadougou, found that private schools

accelerate chances of entry into the wage labor market due to differentials in the education

attainment and socio-economic origins of school-leavers from private and public schools. Lindquist,

Sol and Praag (2015) found parental entrepreneurship to increase the probability of children’s

entrepreneurship by 60 per cent. Findings from Dunn and Holtz-Eakin (2000) indicate that second

generation entrepreneurs are two to three times more likely to work in the same occupation as their

fathers.

Another strand of the literature related to this study is the growing empirical evidence on the

importance of non-cognitive abilities in determining labor market outcomes. For example, Heckman

and Masterov (2007), in an investigation of American children who grew up in disadvantageous

environments, established that parents play an important role in stimulating both the cognitive and

non-cognitive skills of their children. Cunha et al. (2006) found similar results using data from the

1979 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth in the United States. Both Cunha et al. (2006) and

Carneiro and Heckman (2003) showed that non-cognitive abilities are more malleable than cognitive

abilities in later stages of youth life. More able and engaged parents have greater success in

stimulating both types of skills. In a study of Britain, using controls for family structure, the home

1 The study uses two measures of non-cognitive ability. One measure is based on 8 questions asked to the child’s mother relating to whether her child is bullied by other children, destroys own or others’ belongings, is miserable or tearful, is squirmy or fidgety, is irritable or quick to fly off the handle, fights with other children, and is disobedient. The other measure is based on questions asked to the teacher of the child relating to 12 different syndromes, namely, anxiety for acceptance by children, hostility towards children, hostility towards adults, “writing off” adults and adult standards, withdrawal, unforthcomingness, depression, anxiety for acceptance by adults, restlessness, inconsequential behavior, miscellaneous symptoms, and miscellaneous nervous symptoms.

4

Page 5: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

learning environment and parent characteristics, Carneiro et al. (2007) found that an overall

measure of non-cognitive skills is important for a host of later outcomes, including education

attainment, employment status and wages.2 A significant aspect of their findings is that social skills

are more important for individuals from low socio-economic backgrounds than it is for individuals

from high socio-economic backgrounds, suggesting that investment in non-cognitive skills may

reduce income inequality. On the other hand, Macmillan (2013), using data from the British Cohort

Study (BCS), found non-cognitive skills and behavioral outcomes to play a more important role in the

intergenerational transmission of joblessness.3

One of the key issues concerning youth unemployment, especially in developing countries, is the

mismatch between the supply of and demand for jobs. This is mainly due to the prevalence of skill

mismatch, which is costly to employers, workers and the society at large (World Economic Forum

2014). For example, additional years of under-education, an issue that is prevalent particularly in

low-income countries, are detrimental to firm productivity (Kampelmann and Rycx 2012). According

to the ILO (2013), skill mismatch in youth labor markets has become a persistent and growing trend.

Lack of proper preparation for the transition from school to work underlies this mismatch.

Mengistae (1998), in a study on Ethiopian manufacturing firms, found on-the-job skill formation and

job matching to be significant sources of growth for both productivity and wages. Here, job matching

is by far the most important source of growth, both for productivity and wages. Acemoglu (1999)

and Mortensen and Pissarides (1999) examined the effects of skill-biased technical change using a

labor market matching process. Albrecht and Vroman (2002) applied a similar method for the United

States, United Kingdom and Europe in a matching model with endogenous skill requirements. They

found that skill-biased technical change increases wage dispersion both within and in between skill

groups, while increasing unemployment, particularly among low-skill workers. Shi (2002),

2 The study also uses data from NCDS to construct a measure of non-cognitive skills similar to the second non-cognitive measure used by Weiss (2010). 3 This study uses agreeableness, emotionality, extroversion, conscientiousness and intelligence as key non-cognitive measures.

5

Page 6: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

establishing similar results, found that skill-biased technological programs in the United States

generate concurrent increases in within-group inequality and skill premium, with the latter rising

more sharply. Kok (2014), in a study of the Netherlands, also found evidence for higher job-match

quality to be associated with higher wages.

Market behavior and demand could also influence the potential labor market entrants to invest in

their human capital. For example, in a labor market model that incorporates the possibility that

agents may invest in human capital before matching, Hatfield, Kojima and Kominers (2014) showed

that the worker-optimal stable matching mechanism incentivizes workers to make efficient human

capital investments.

III. The Model

One of the key takeaways from the literature review above is the influence of cognitive and non-

cognitive skills on educational and labor market outcomes, further strengthened by the family

background of labor market entrants. Taking these into account, and following Hanushek and

Woessmann (2008), as well as Carneiro et al. (2007), we developed a model that captures the effects

of parental attributes (such as level of education and occupation) as well as youth attributes (such as

level of education and area of residence) on youth labor market expectations, especially on

preferred occupations and type of work.

Consider for example, the model of the following form:

U ki=∝k+β' Xki+γ

' Y ki+εki (1)

where k = 1, ……., K is the economic sector (field) and i = 1, …….. N k is the number of individuals in a

specific sector (field). U i is a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if the youth’s employment

expectation is in a given field, or 0 otherwise. The vector X ki includes attributes that relate to the

youth (such as education, skills, health and area of residence) while vector Y ki includes attributes of

parents (such as level of education and occupation). ε ki is a random error term. This model enables

6

Page 7: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

us to establish links between parental and youth attributes, and employment expectations of the

youth in a particular field.

Once such links are established, we conduct a matching exercise to investigate whether youth

expectations, in terms of future occupation, are consistent with labor market demand. Such an

exercise would enable us to understand if youth have undue expectations or if they are well

prepared for the transition from school to work, especially considering the skills they have acquired.

While the results from the model in (1) would give a better understanding of the importance of

youth and parental attributes on youth employment expectations, a job-skill matching exercise will

allow us to further investigate the criticalities of such attributes in better preparing youth to secure

jobs that best match the skills they possess.

Consider a labor market where wage (w) depends on skills required for a particular job (β ) and

location (l ¿, while employer’s revenue depends on job complexity (α ) and the location(l). Given

their skills (s), including education level (e) and parental attributes (p), workers always want to

maximize their expected nominal wage in segment z relative to the minimum they could earn by

engaging in the least complex job in segment z. Thus, workers maximize their expected nominal

wage according to:

w (β , l )=max ¿¿ (2)

Where α reflects job complexity and c l represents the location cost.4 w ¿ (>0 for all z) is the wage for

the least complex job in segment z. The relation described in (2) indicates that the more complex

the job, the higher the wages.5 A worker’s skills (s¿ comprise of both education (e) and non-

cognitive skills. Workers and employers face the same location cost. We also assume the location

4 z could be job categories5 Workers’ nominal wage is given by: w (a ,l )=f (α)−cl. Revenue earned by the employer is given by: r (α ,l )=f (β )−c l

7

Page 8: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

cost to be higher in cities than in rural areas, as living costs are higher in cities. Similarly, the

employers maximize expected revenue, given the skill level of the workers (s¿, according to:

r (α ,l )=max ¿¿ (3)

r ¿ is the revenue generated by the least skilled worker in segment z. r ¿ > 0 for all z . From an

employer’s point of view, better skilled workers generate more revenue.

Job Matching Requirements

For a worker to agree to accept a job, the expected nominal wage, net of location costs, should be at

least equal to the minimum he can expect from the least complex job in a particular segment, given

the skills he possesses. On the other hand, the employer will hire a worker with the required skills

only if its return from hiring the worker is at least as high as that from employing the least skilled

worker in the given segment.

The aforementioned mutual agreements for job matching would require that two conditions are

satisfied:

Condition 1: Elw (α z|s , p )−c l≥w ¿ (4)

Condition 2: El r (βz|s )−c l≥r ¿ (5)

Since both the worker and the employer maximize their respective utilities (wages and revenue,

respectively, as discussed above), the gap between a worker’s skills and job complexity becomes as

small as possible. In fact when βz ,l=α z ,l, a perfect job-skill match occurs. Thus we assume the

relationship between the lowest paid wage, w ¿ for z at l, and that of lowest revenue, r ¿, is given

such that:

r ¿ (6)

Taking the above two conditions in (4) and (5) along with the relationship in (6) implies:

8

Page 9: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

El r (βz|s )−Elw (α z|s , p )=θ+ϵ (7)

Where θ ≥ 0 is a constant and ϵ is a random error term. We define match quality,Q z ,l, in segment z

such that E(Q z , l)=1 /E (βz , l−α z ,l) (i.e. the smaller the gap between skills and job complexity, the

better the quality of the match). Assume r and w are related in such a way that we can represent

(7) as:

El f (β z−α z|s , p )=δ+ϵ 1 (8)

where δ ≥0 is a constant and ϵ 1 is a random error term. We make the assumption that

f ( βz−α z|s , p ) is a multiplicative function of the form g (βz−α z ) . h(s , p).6 From (8), this would

imply:

El f ¿ (9)

where ϑ ≥0 is a constant. Or El(1Q z ,l

) . El h(s , p)=ϑ+ϵ 2. Rearranging the above, we have:

El (Q z ,l )=γ+Elh (s , p )+ε (10)

Match quality, Q z ,l is a function of workers’ skills, s, (cognitive, that includes the level of education (

e ¿ ,and non-cognitive) and parental attributes ( p¿. γ is a constant while ε is a random error term.

The relationship described in (10) allows us to investigate the relationship between workers’ skills, as

well as worker and parental attributes. It also allows us to match jobs and expectations on a certain

level of job complexity.

IV. Data and empirical strategy

This study uses cross-sectional data from “School-to-Work Transition Surveys (SWTS) 2012-2013”

recently conducted by the ILO in eight Sub-Saharan African countries (i.e. Benin, Liberia,

6 Workers maximize wages against job complexity, which in turn is a function of the wage rates. The more complex the job, the higher the wage rate.

9

Page 10: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Madagascar, Malawi, Togo, Uganda, United Republic of Tanzania and Zambia). Thus we have

observations for variables from only one point in time. A sample of 26,228 observations of employed

and unemployed youth is available for the analysis from these surveys. Our particular interest is on a

sub-sample of 7,114 observations of employed and unemployed youth who have expressed their

employment expectations. We also use another sub-sample of 2,549 observations of unemployed

youth and compare our results with the previous samples.

For cognitive skills, we use educational achievements of the youth while for non-cognitive skills we

use a measure of the health of the youth which indicates 1 if the youth does not have health

problems and 0 if the youth has any health issues.7 For parental characteristics, we use educational

and occupational status. A summary of basic statistics of the sub-sample is given in Table 1.

Approximately 52 percent of the sample is urban and 48 per cent is rural. The average age of the

youth is approximately 21.8 years. Male youths accounted for 58 per cent of the sample while the

remaining 42 per cent was represented by female youth. 17.7 per cent of the youth did not have any

education while 20.4 per cent and 30.5 per cent had primary and secondary education, respectively.

Only 2.4 per cent had a tertiary education. On average, 24 per cent of fathers and 41 per cent of

mothers had not received an education. Amongst the parents with education, fathers had an

average of secondary level education while mothers’ education lied in between primary and

secondary level.

Table 1 around here

The second cross sectional data set we use is the “Labor Demand Enterprise Survey (LDES)” for 2012

to 2013, conducted by the ILO in five countries in Sub-Saharan Africa (i.e. Benin, Liberia, Malawi,

United Republic of Tanzania and Zambia). The primary use of LDES is to understand the

characteristics of demand for labor by employers. Given the limitations of the survey, we are only

interested in two key variables, the most important characteristics that an employer looks for when

7 While the assumption of a multiplicative function makes transformation of (9) into (10) straight forward, we could also assume it to be an additive function with no significant impact on the final outcome.

10

Page 11: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

hiring a worker and job complexity, both of which enable us to compute skills and characteristics

necessary for a particular job, which in turn will be used to investigate match quality. The LDES

indicates several criteria used by employers in hiring managers, professionals and production

workers. For managers and professionals, the most important characteristics are job experience

(39.5%), education (32.6%), attitude (7.4%), expectations (5.1%), age (5.0%), gender (3.3%) and

marital status. Fairly similar expectations are reflected for production workers, with attitude and

expectations gaining little more weight than for managers and professionals. The SWTS data set does

not have information on job experience (since the target population is primarily youth undergoing

school to work transition), attitudes and expectations. As such, for the skills and other characteristics

required for a particular job in a specific job segment, βz, we use age, gender, education or training

and marital status characteristics of the preferred hiring criteria used by employers. We use “hard to

fill vacancies” as a proxy for job complexity. We classify the top 10 “hard to fill vacancies” into six

occupational categories: professional, services, administration, clerical, technical and other. The last

category, “other”, includes agriculture, craft, operational, elementary and armed forces. For this

analysis, we use a total of 3066 observations. Despite the limitations that arise from a small data set,

it nonetheless provides useful information for our purposes. The required educational level is coded

as follows: 1 = no education, 2 = primary, 3 = secondary (vocational), 4 = post- secondary

(vocational), 5 = secondary and 6 = university and postgraduate. We merge university and

postgraduate education into one category, as their importance in terms of “hard to fill vacancies” is

very low. The rankings of job complexity (“hard to fill”) and skills demanded are given in Table 2.

Since professional-level occupations demand higher qualifications, they are also the hardest to fill.

On the other hand, the most preferred skill level for production and elementary level occupations is

secondary education.

Table 2 around here

11

Page 12: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

We use the above information from the LDES to define a variable that corresponds to job complexity

as well as skills required for a particular occupation in the SWTS data set. Job complexity in the SWTS

data set is coded as follows: 6 = professional, (i.e. if the expected occupation of the youth is

professional), 5 = services, 4 = administration, 3 = clerical, 2 = technical and 1 = other (Table 2). For

skills required for managers and professionals, we code the preferred skills as follows: 6 = university

and postgraduate (i.e. if the youth has a university or post graduate education), 5 = secondary, 4 =

post-secondary (vocational), 3 = secondary (vocational), 2 = primary and 1 = no education. Similarly,

for skills required for production workers and elementary occupations, we code the preferred skills

as follows: 6 = secondary education (i.e. if the youth has a secondary education), 5 = secondary

(vocational), 4 = primary, 3 = post-secondary (vocational), 2 = university and postgraduate and 1 = no

education. Note that in this category of workers, undergraduate or postgraduate qualifications only

allow a score of 2. Essentially, such a level of education is not required for this category of work.

As discussed earlier, match quality occurs when the gap between skills and job complexity is

smallest. Match quality is computed as a weighted average of the gaps in employer expectations and

youth characteristics in relation to age, gender, education and marital status. The weights for each of

these characteristics based on employer preferences are: education (0.747), age (0.115), gender

(0.076) and marital status (0.062) for managers and professionals. The weights with respect to

production workers are: education (0.717), age (0.115), gender (0.095) and marital status (0.073).

V. Estimation results and analysis

We begin by investigating the relationship in (1) 8 using the sub-sample of employed and

unemployed youth who have expressed their employment expectations. Table 3 presents

multinomial logit regression results for the impact of youth characteristics and parental attributes on

each of the youth employment expectation categories. Given that agriculture is the primary source

of income for the majority, we use the employment expectation in agriculture as the base outcome.

8 These health issues relate to difficulties in eye sight, hearing, walking, remembering or concentrating and self-caring such as washing or dressing.

12

Page 13: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Since coefficients from multinomial logit regressions can be difficult to interpret, as they are relative

to the base outcome, we also compute marginal effects of changing their values on the probability of

observing each outcome. The results are given in Table 4. Estimation results point to several key

conclusions9:

(i) Low level of education (i.e. below secondary) or no education has significant and

positive effects on employment expectations in job categories that have low level of

complexity and low pay, such as the elementary, craft, operational and service sectors

but a negative effect on high complexity occupations such as those in the administration,

professional and technical sectors. For example, a one-unit increase in the probability of

a youth having no education will increase employment expectations by 1.3 units in the

operations job category and by 1.2 units in the elementary category, relative to

agriculture and holding all other variables constant. Such low education levels also tend

to reduce employment expectations in high complexity jobs, particularly in

administrative, professional and technical sectors. Similarly, a one-unit increase in the

probability of youth having a primary education will increase employment expectations

by 1.02 units in the crafts job category. Average marginal effects in Table 4 confirm the

direction of these results.

(ii) Secondary education has an even larger positive impact on job expectations in almost all

sectors, except administrative and technical. Post-secondary education has positive

effects on expectations in high complexity jobs but a negative impact on expectations in

low complexity jobs, although they are not significant. In general, average marginal

effects confirm these results and also highlight the impact of post-secondary education

on employment expectations in the high complexity professional and technical sectors.

For example, at the means of all covariates, post-secondary education is likely to

9 We remove the non-cognitive skill variable from estimations as our preliminary estimations indicated its weakness as a proxy.

13

Page 14: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

increase job expectations in the professional and technical categories by 19.6% and

6.6%, respectively.

(iii) Fathers with secondary education or higher seem to influence job expectations of their

children in high complexity jobs. A one-unit increase in the number of fathers with

secondary education or higher will increase employment expectations of youth in

occupations in the professional, technical, clerical and services categories by 1.3, 1.0, 0.9

and 0.7 units, respectively. The impact of their higher educational achievements on

employment expectations in low complexity jobs is insignificant. In contrast, mothers’

education does not exhibit a clear trend in influencing the employment expectations of

their children. This could be due to the low average level of education of mothers.

(iv) Parents seem to dislike their children expecting a job in the same profession in which

they are employed, perhaps because the majority of parents have low complexity and

low wage jobs and hold high expectations for their children, though average marginal

effects do not support this phenomenon.

We also estimated the model in (1) using the sub-sample of 2,549 observations from unemployed

youth. The multinomial logit regression results, with agriculture as the base category, are given in

Table 5. The results more or less confirm our original findings discussed above. Youth with low levels

of education, primary and below, tend to have a negative effect on employment expectations in the

administrative, professional and technical categories but a positive impact on expectations in low

complexity jobs, particularly in the operations and craft sectors. As previously established, secondary

education seems to have a highly significant impact on job expectations across the board, except in

the administrative sector. Marginal effects reported in Table 6 confirm this finding. Post-secondary

education has a positive and significant effect on employment expectations in the professional

category, but marginal effects in Table 6 do not confirm this relationship. Parents with post-

secondary education seem to influence employment expectations of their children in high

complexity jobs, especially in the professional, technical and administrative sectors. Once again, as

14

Page 15: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

previously concluded, parents do not want their children to expect jobs in the same profession in

which they are employed, most likely due to low pay.

Job matching and match quality

As per the discussion earlier on job market requirements, we define a job match as when a youth’s

level of skill, defined by their level of education, other characteristics and the type of employment

expectation or employment correspond with the skills and characteristics favored by the employer

as well as the job complexities identified by them.10 A perfect match occurs when the level of skill,

including other characteristics, and the level of job complexity are the same. This occurs when the

gap between skills required and job complexity is nearly zero. A close match occurs when the level of

skill and job complexity is one step higher or lower than the perfect matching score. This occurs

when the skill level has a score that is one step lower than that for job complexity or when the score

for job complexity is one step lower than that for skills.

We begin by using education as the only criterion considered by employers when hiring workers.

This means that the gap between the level of education a youth possesses and the level demanded

by an employer for a given level of job complexity will determine a job match. In Table 7, we provide

results for job matching for youth employment expectations. The results indicate a low perfect

match between youth employment expectations and job skills in almost all employment categories,

except low complexity sectors, particularly the “other” category which includes agriculture, crafts,

operations, elementary and armed forces. Lowest job matching occurs in the administrative sector.

Overall, only 10 per cent of youth job expectations match the skills required. About 42 per cent of

employment expectations could be considered either a match or a close match. A larger majority

(92%) of youth with expectations of securing a job in the professional sector does not have the

required skills or qualifications. Both over and under expectation relative to skills required seem to

dominate all employment categories. Overall, 34 per cent of youth are over educated in comparison

10 Similar results were found with the full sample.

15

Page 16: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

to their job expectations. This could very well be due to tight labor market conditions that compel

youth to adopt lower job expectations relative to the skills they possess. Similarly, over 55 per cent

of youth do not have the required skills or education demanded by employers.

Table 7 and 8 around here

We compare our results with actual job matching in the youth labor market using a sub-sample for

employed youth consisting of 13,213 observations. Table 8 provides estimates for the employed

youth, which indicates a job-matching rate of almost 25 per cent, much higher than the 9.7 percent

seen in relation to job market expectations.11 Youth seem to invest and prepare for job market skill

requirements despite having higher or lower expectations during the school-to-work transition

period given their level of skills before securing jobs. This is also reflected in a lower level of overall

under education (28%) for any given job. While almost 31 per cent of youth employment in the

professional sector indicates a perfect match, only 2.5 per cent in the service sector exhibits a

match. In the technical field, the job match level is only 15.4 per cent, similar to jobs in the

administration sector. The match for clerical jobs is also at a low of 5.8 per cent. In contrast, the

“other” category has a match of 32.7 per cent. Almost a quarter of jobs in the service sector are held

by youth with a slightly lower education level than is required while about 23 per cent is filled by

youth with a slightly higher level of education than required. More than 27 per cent of jobs in the

professional sector are held by youth with a slightly lower level of education than required. In fact,

the service sector has the most severe job mismatch, whereby nearly 75 per cent of jobs are held by

youth with lower skills than required. However, most occupational categories also indicate a heavy

presence of over-educated youth. More than 50 per cent of youth with technical and clerical jobs

are over qualified. Overall, about 40 per cent of youth in the sample are over qualified for their

respective jobs.

11 See Sparrenboom and Staneva (2014) for a detailed analysis of qualification mismatch.

16

Page 17: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

We now extend the “skills and other characteristics” variable to include age, gender and marital

status in addition to education when computing match quality, as described above. Our sample

indicated a mean of 0.07 for match quality with a standard deviation of 0.12, indicating a large gap

between skills and other characteristics demanded by employers and those actually possessed by

youth. To further investigate, we conducted an OLS regression for the model in (10) on sectoral

match quality using the whole sample (Table 9). Our results confirm the previously computed

results in Tables 3 through 6. Lower educational levels tend to increase job match quality in low

complexity jobs. While no education and primary education have negative effects on match quality

in the professional, technical, clerical and administrative fields, they have positive effects on match

quality in the craft, operational and elementary job categories. Contrary to the negative relationship

for primary education or lower, tertiary education tends to contribute to better job matching in high

complexity jobs. For example, tertiary education has a significant positive effect on job match quality

in the professional, clerical and administration job categories, in that order of impact. A 1 per cent

increase in the probability of a youth having a tertiary education increases job match quality by 0.14

per cent, 0.04 per cent, and 0.01 per cent in the professional, clerical and administrative fields,

respectively. While a father’s level of education has no significant impact on match quality in any

employment category, a mother’s level of education has a positive effect on job match quality in the

services sector but a negative effect in the agricultural sector. Interestingly, while fathers employed

in agriculture tend to negatively influence match quality in that sector, mothers tend to positively

affect match quality in that same sector. Mothers employed in the administrative and professional

sectors also tend to positively impact their children’s match quality in the same job category. Urban

residency has a significant and positive relationship with job match quality in the technical, clerical,

and operational sectors while having a negative effect in agriculture, with a one per cent increase in

the probability of being in urban areas leading to a 0.003-0.023 per cent increase in match quality.

Overall, job match quality tends to be very low, except in agriculture and services, as demonstrated

by means of 0.38 and 0.24, respectively. The lowest match quality is observed in the administration

17

Page 18: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

(mean of 0.0008), clerical (mean of 0.0054) and professional (mean of 0.0056) fields. The trend of

low match quality for high complexity job categories is somewhat similar to the characteristics we

have seen in Table 9 using only education as the selection criterion.

Table 9 around here

VI. Policy implications

The results of this study point to several key conclusions. Firstly, youth education can significantly

influence youth employment expectations and employment outcomes at later stages in life. Higher

educational achievements have a great impact on expectations and securing better jobs, particularly

in the technical and professional sectors. Employment expectations in the professional and technical

fields are mostly influenced by higher level of education (in this case post-secondary (tertiary)

education). Youth with low educational achievements (primary education or lower) have a higher

tendency to expect to be employed in agriculture or other elementary occupations. Secondly,

mothers’ level of education has no clear effects on youth employment expectations, though fathers

with secondary education or higher have a positive effect on youth expectations in high complexity

jobs.

Thirdly, a parent’s occupation has a negative influence on a youth’s employment expectations in the

same field. Fourthly, there is severe expected job-skill mismatch in every occupational category,

although this reduces slightly when the youth actually enters the labor market and secures a job. As

a result, most occupational categories indicate a heavy presence of under and over-educated youth.

Job-skill mismatch is a prevalent issue not only in Sub-Saharan Africa but also in other low-income

countries. Yet, Sparrenboom and Staneva (2014) found that job-skill mismatch is much wider in

scope in Sub-Saharan African countries.

These findings have several policy implications. The fact that youth education tends to significantly

influence youth employment expectations and employment clearly indicates the need for greater

18

Page 19: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

access to quality education12. While most sample countries seem to have a higher level of enrolment

in primary school, enrolment in secondary and post-secondary education is low, albeit improving.

Given the fact that secondary and tertiary education has a greater impact on youth employment in

the technical and professional fields, increased public investment in these sectors may result in

greater societal benefits.

There are three major issues related to job-skill mismatch. First is the lack of appropriate

qualifications that has led to a significant presence of youth with subpar skills, especially in the

professional, administrative and service sectors. Youth skill development, particularly in specialized

occupational categories and professional fields, is paramount to addressing this problem. The

second issue relates to the limited availability of suitable jobs as reflected by the heavy presence of

over educated youth in most occupational categories. Our results indicated that many educated

youths are employed in low complexity jobs relative to the skills they possess. Creation of jobs that

target the youth is equally as important as skill development for better youth employment. The third

issue relates to the limited impact of mothers’ level of education on children’s educational outcomes

and job-match quality. This may be due to the lower levels of educational attainment of mothers, on

average, slightly above primary education, as well as the lagging nature of parental education in Sub-

Saharan Africa, highlighting the importance of improved adult education programs.

VII. Conclusion

Sub-Saharan Africa has a very young population that will be the most dynamic demographic segment

in the coming years. Youth years are a crucial time in life as young adults begin to realize their

aspirations, assume economic independence and find their place in society. However, realizing this

depends on numerous factors including proper skill development prior to the transition from school

to work and a functioning economy, among others. This study investigated factors that drive youth

12 Note that there is no one to one relationship between the two sub-samples as they relate to employed and unemployed youth.

19

Page 20: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

labor market expectations and outcomes, with a particular focus on youth and parental attributes,

such as education, among others.

Using multinomial logit analysis, we found evidence that youth education greatly influences youth

employment expectations and employment, with higher educational achievements having a great

impact on expecting and securing better jobs, particularly in the technical and professional fields.

There is a higher tendency for youth with low educational achievements, primary education or

lower, to expect low complexity jobs. Our results do not give a clear indication on the impact of

mothers’ education on youth employment expectations. This could perhaps be due to low education

levels of parents as well as predominantly low complexity jobs held by parents. Educated fathers, on

the other hand, tend to influence youth employment expectations in high complexity jobs.

Meanwhile, a parent’s occupation has a negative effect on employment expectations in the same

field.

There is a severe job-skill mismatch in every occupational category, both before and after entering

the labor market. Youth employment expectations seem to be higher relative to the skills they

possess. Less than 10 per cent of youth employment expectations match with the skills required,

while 55 per cent of total youth are under educated for the jobs they expect. Similarly, youth also

seem to have lower expectations relative to their actual capabilities, with 34 per cent indicating

employment expectations below what they could have attained given the skills they possess. In the

sample with employed youth, more than 27 per cent of the jobs in the professional category are

held by youth with slightly lower education than required. The service sector has the most severe

job mismatch with nearly 75 per cent of jobs held by youth with subpar skills. Most occupational

categories indicate a heavy presence of over-educated youth, with about 47 per cent of youth in the

sample over qualified for their respective jobs. Increasing access to quality education and skill

development would effectively address these problems. An important aspect in skill development is

the importance of matching market expectations. Education and skills alone will not resolve youth

20

Page 21: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

employment issues, as they only address the supply side. A robust economy is key in attracting new

entrants to the labor market. Parents also have an important role in shaping the employment status

of their children. Thus, increasing the knowledge of parents on youth employment, particularly

parents with no or limited education, should be considered at the community level.

References

Acemoglu, D. (1999). Changes in unemployment and wage inequality: an alternative theory and

some evidence. American Economic Review, 89 (5), pp 1259-1278.

Albrecht, J. W., & Vroman, S. (2002). A matching model with endogenous skill requirements.

International Economic review, 43 (1), pp 283-305.

Annabi, N. (2017). Investments in education: What are the productivity gains. Journal of Policy

Modeling, 39(3), pp 499-518.

Calvès, A. E., Kobiané, J., & N’Bouké, A. (2013). Privatization of education and labor force inequality

in urban francophone Africa: The transition from school to work in Ouagadougou. World

Development, 47, pp 136-148.

Capatina, E. (2014). Skills and the evolution of wage inequality. Labour Economics, 28 (3), pp 41-57.

Carneiro, P., Crawford, C., & Goodman, A. (2007). The impact of early cognitive and non-cognitive

skills on later outcomes. CPP Discussion Paper no. 92, Center for Economics of Educations,

London.

Carneiro, P., & Heckman, J.J. (2003). Human Capital Policy. Working paper no. 9495, National Bureau

of Economic Research Cambridge, MA.

Cawley, J., Heckman, J.J., & Vytlacil, E. (2001). Three observations on wages and measured cognitive

ability. Labour Economics, 8 (4), pp 419-442.

21

Page 22: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Cawley, J., Heckman, J.J., Lochner, L., & Vytlacil, E. (2000). Understanding the role of cognitive ability

in accounting for the recent rise in the economic return to education. In K. Arrow, S. Bowles

and S. Durlauf (eds.), Meritocracy and economic inequality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University

Press.

Cunha, F., Heckman, J.J., Lochner, L., & Masterov, D.V. (2006). Interpreting the evidence on life cycle

skill formation. in E. A. Hanushek and F. Welch (eds.), Handbook of the economics of the

education. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Dunn, T., & Holtz-Eakin, D. (2000). Financial capital, human capital and the transition to self-

employment: evidence from intergenerational links. Journal of Labor Economics, 18, pp 282-

305.

Hanushek, E., & Woessmann, L. (2008). The role of cognitive skills in economic development. Journal

of Economic Literature, 46 (3), pp 607-668.

Hatfield, J. W., Kojima, F., & Kominers, S. D. (2014). Investment incentives in labor market matching.

American Economic Review, 104 (5), pp 436-441.

Heckman, J. J., & Masterov, D.V. (2007). The productivity argument for investing in young children.

Working paper no. 13016, National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge, MA.

Heineck, G. (2011). Do your brains help you out of unemployment? Economic Letters, 111 (1), pp 34-

36.

International Labor Organization. (2013). Global employment trends 2014: Risk of a jobless recovery?

International Labor Organization, Geneva.

Kampelmaan, S., & Rycx, F. (2012). The impact of educational mismatch on firm productivity:

Evidence from linked panel data. Economics of Education Review, 31 (6), pp 918-931.

22

Page 23: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Kok, S. (2014). Matching worker skills to job tasks in the Netherlands: sorting into cities and better

careers. IZA Journal of European Labor Studies, 3 (2).

Lindquist, M. J., Sol, J., & Praag, M. V. (2015). Why do entrepreneurial parents have entrepreneurial

children? Journal of Labor Economics, 33 (2), pp 269-296.

Macmillan, L. (2013). The role of non-cognitive and cognitive skills, behavioral and educational

outcomes in accounting for the intergenerational transmission of worklessness. Working paper

no 13-01, DoQSS, Institute of Education and Social Research, University of London.

Mengistae, T. (1998). Skill formation and job matching effects in wage growth: the case of

manufacturing workers in Ethiopia. Working paper no 98.19, CSAE, Oxford University.

Mortensen, D. T., & Pissarides, C.A. (1999). Unemployment responses to skill-biased technological

shocks: the role of labor market policy. Economic Journal, 109, pp 242-265.

Murnane, R. J., Willett, J.B., & Levy, F. (1995). The growing importance of cognitive skill in wage

determination. Review of Economic Statistics, 77 (2), pp 251-266.

Shi, S. (2002). A directed search model of inequality with heterogeneous skills and skills-biased

technology. Review of Economic Studies, 69, pp 469-491.

Sparremboom, T., & Staneva, A. (2014). Is education the solution to decent work for youth in

developing countries?: identifying qualification mismatches from 28 school to work transition

surveys. Work 4 Youth Publication Series No 23, International Labor Organization, Geneva.

Weiss, C. T. (2010). The effects of cognitive and non-cognitive abilities on earnings: different school

systems.

http://www.researchgate.net/publication/228592595_The_Effects_of_Cognitive_and_Noncog

nitive_Abilities_on_Earnings_Different_School_Systems (accessed February 7, 2015).

23

Page 24: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

World Economic Forum. (2014). Matching skills and labor market needs: Building social partnerships

for better skills and better jobs. Davos-Klosters, Geneva.

Zenou, Y. (2008). Job search and mobility in developing countries: theory and implications. Journal

of Development Economics, 86, pp 336-355.

24

Page 25: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Table 1: Summary Statistics

Variable Sample countries in SSA

Benin Liberia Madagascar Malawi Tanzania Togo Uganda Zambia

Name Symbol Mean Std. Dev.

Mean

Std. Dev.

Mean Std. Dev.

Mean Std. Dev

Mean

Std. Dev.

Mean

Std. Dev.

Mean Std. Dev.

Mean Std. Dev.

Mean Std. Dev.

Age AGE 21.813 4.320 24.20 3.62 22.84 5.91 21.557 4.624 21.616

3.92 20.657

3.36 21.57 4.003 21.571 3.930 21.078 3.739

Sex SEXX 0.424 0.494 0.574 0.495 0.445 0.497 0.475 0.503 0.286 0.453 0.427 0.495 0.431 0.496 0.305 0.461 0.483 0.500

Rural or Urban RURURB 0.524 0.500 0.653 0.477 0.758 0.429 0.442 0.500 0.286 0.453 0.569 0.496 0.711 0.454 0.299 0.459 0.441 0.497

No education EDUN 0.177 0.382 0.205 0.404 0.145 0.352 0.131 0.340 0.402 0.491 0.054 0.227 0.091 0.288 0.423 0.495 0.035 0.185

Primary education EDUP 0.204 0.403 0.241 0.428 0.130 0.336 0.360 0.484 0.253 0.435 0.339 0.474 0.154 0.362 0.227 0.419 0.078 0.269

Secondary education

EDUS 0.305 0.461 0.287 0.453 0.166 0.373 0.245 0.434 0.115 0.320 0.456 0.499 0.202 0.402 0.091 0.288 0.623 0.485

Tertiary education EDUT 0.024 0.152 0.086 0.281 0.009 0.093 0.032 0.179 0.005 0.071 0.016 0.126 0.032 0.175 0.039 0.195 0.007 0.086

Educated father EDUFATHER 3.386 2.109 2.314 1.657 3.393 1.990 3.459 2.094 2.944 2.240 3.452 2.056 2.775 1.695 3.073 2.370 4.717 1.702

Educated mother EDUMOTHER 2.567 1.951 1.564 1.134 2.423 2.045 2.868 1.543 2.110 1.931 2.675 1.697 1.988 1.274 2.363 2.254 3.853 1.916

Non-educated father

NOEDUFATHER 0.243 0.429 0.462 0.499 0.296 0.457 0.180 0.387 0.343 0.475 0.075 0.263 0.316 0.466 0.390 0.488 0.039 0.194

Non-educated mother

NOEDUMOTHER

0.413 0.493 0.703 0.458 0.581 0.494 0.131 0.340 0.591 0.492 0.161 0.368 0.470 0.500 0.604 0.490 0.097 0.296

Source: SWTS 2012-13

25

Page 26: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Table 2 : Job Complexity and Skills demandedJob Complexity Preferred Skills -education

Occupation Ranking Level of education Ranking(Managers/ Professional)

Ranking(Production workers/ elementary occupations)

Professionals 6 University and Post Graduate 6 2Service 5 Secondary 5 6Administrative 4 Post-secondary (Vocational) 4 3Clerks 3 Secondary (Vocational) 3 5Technical 2 Primary 2 4Other 1 No education 1 1

Note: Ranking scores for job complexity and skills range from 1 (least demanded) to 6 (most demanded)

Source: computed based on information from LDES 2012-13.

26

Page 27: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Table 3: Multinomial Logit Regression (Base Category: Agriculture)

Number of obs = 7114: LR chi2(126) = 3869.38: Prob > chi2 = 0.0000: Pseudo R2 = 0.2515: Log likelihood = -5757.6409

Category of Expected Employment Administration Professional Technical Clerical Services Craft Operations Elementary

Education Type

No education -1.4981** -3.9795*** -2.5728*** 0.5138 0.7753** 0.4593 1.3052** 1.1964***

(0.7032) (1.0724) (0.6503) (0.4032) (0.3706) (0.4607) (0.5359) (0.4426)

Primary -1.8602*** -2.1848*** -1.1184*** 0.1258 0.5195 1.0218** 0.0816 0.8459*

(0.6814) (0.5117) (0.4596) (0.3960) (0.3594) (0.4297) (0.5693) (0.4332)

Secondary -0.1087 0.9079** 0.3264 0.8353* 1.3471*** 1.7575*** 1.5966*** 1.7176***

(0.5626) (0.4477) (0.4778) (0.4634) (0.4343) (0.4967) (0.5512) (0.4934)

Post-Secondary 0.1692 0.6193 0.1220 0.1759 -1.1236 -0.4065 -24.302 0.5347

(1.2487) (1.1206) (1.1445) (1.1754) (1.2306) (1.3078) (157909) (1.2451)

Father's education

Primary 0.4407 0.2177 0.4773 0.1614 -0.0670 0.7540** -0.3421 0.0139

(0.5083) (0.3683) (0.3868) (0.3308) (0.3056) (0.3412) (0.4471) (0.3472)

Secondary and above 0.7347 1.3069*** 0.9938** 0.8910** 0.7250* 0.6662 0.3620 0.1903

(0.5614) (0.4277) (0.4570) (0.4230) (0.3984) (0.4525) (0.5080) (0.4487)

27

Page 28: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Mother's education

No education 0.4023 -0.6163 0.3154 0.1865 -0.7244 -0.0398 -0.6609 -0.4081

(0.8872) (0.5207) (0.5852) (0.5049) (0.4641) (0.5231) (0.6138) (0.5176)

Primary 0.6104 -0.5903 -0.3338 -0.2134 -0.8363 -0.6444 -0.0971 -0.3529

(0.9168) (0.5593) (0.6352) (0.5543) (0.5111) (0.5726) (0.6630) (0.5656)

Secondary and above 0.5790 -0.5468 -0.2122 -0.7420 -0.7389 -1.0745 -0.0667 -0.5985

(0.9603) (0.6229) (0.6928) (0.6393) (0.5885) (0.6738) (0.7378) (0.6545)

Father in the same profession -0.8043 -0.4210*** -0.4077*** -0.6262*** -0.3345*** -0.5627 -0.0485 -0.2836***

(0.5559) (0.1354) (0.1486) (0.1793) (0.0748) (0.0740) (0.0937) (0.0929)

Mother in the same profession -8.4726 -0.4692** -0.5314** -8.2593 -0.0206 -0.2550** -8.3272 -0.1395

(3919.0) (0.1917) (0.2193) (2289.6) (0.0803) (0.1036) (2755.3) (0.0997)

Constant -3.4770*** -0.6340 -3.2455*** -0.6659 1.7290 -1.9305** -3.7193*** -0.0545

(1.3154) (0.8683) (0.9746) (0.8463) (0.7789) (0.8999) (1.1067) (0.8893)

Table 4: Average marginal effects

Model VCE : OIM Number of Observations = 7114

Emp_exp_Type Administration Professional Technical Clerical Services Agriculture Craft Operations Elementary

Delta-method

28

Page 29: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Dy/dx

Education Type

No education 0.0020 -0.0178*** -0.0078** 0.1127*** 0.2939*** 0.0254*** 0.0398*** 0.0562*** 0.0938***

(0.0042) (0.0031) (0.0036) (0.0160) (0.0238) (0.0089) (0.0096) (0.0148) (0.0165)

Primary -0.0009 -0.0089* 0.0055 0.0602*** 0.1889*** 0.0201*** 0.0617*** 0.0118** 0.0536***

(0.0027) (0.0047) (0.0053) (0.0101) (0.0172) (0.0070) (0.0098) (0.0051) (0.0099)

Secondary 0.0058* 0.0853*** 0.0234*** 0.0546*** 0.1954*** 0.0056 0.0597*** 0.0278*** 0.0604***

(0.0034) (0.0106) (0.0061) (0.0090) (0.1516) (0.0050) (0.0098) (0.0063) (0.0100)

Post-Secondary 0.0338 0.1960*** 0.0666** 0.0831 0.0236 0.0319 0.0157 -0.0030*** 0.0532

(0.0217) (0.0508) (0.0338) (0.2496) (0.0318) (0.0386) (0.0166) (0.0009) (0.0344)

Father's education

Primary 0.0016 0.0005 0.0045 -0.0003 -0.0197** -0.0021 0.0148*** -0.0053 -0.0039

(0.0028) (0.0050) (0.0041) (0.0054) (0.0080) (0.0032) (0.0048) (0.0032) (0.0049)

Secondary and above 0.0011 0.0244*** 0.0071* 0.0132* 0.0155 -0.0052 0.0021 -0.0021 -0.0087*

(0.0026) (0.0055) (0.0042) (0.0070) (0.0095) (0.0035) (0.0048) (0.0037) (0.0050)

Mother's education

No education 0.0035 -0.0081 0.0133** 0.0235*** -0.0351*** 0.0040 0.0104 -0.0025 -0.0002

29

Page 30: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

(0.0027) (0.0085) (0.0058) (0.0076) (0.0121) (0.0038) (0.0071) (0.0039) (0.0062)

Primary 0.0036 -0.0115 -0.0012 0.0018 -0.0532*** 0.0023 -0.0078 0.0017 -0.0015

(0.0027) (0.0083) (0.0050) (0.0073) (0.0124) (0.0041) (0.0066) (0.0045) (0.0065)

Secondary and above 0.0061 0.0003 0.0055 -0.0044 0.0176 0.0061 -0.0101 0.0063 -0.0004

(0.0032) (0.0086) (0.0055) (0.0077) (0.0142) (0.0060) (0.0072) (0.0055) (0.0076)

Father in the same profession 0.0449 0.2057 0.1103 0.2008 0.4906 0.0704 0.1302 0.0589 0.1267

(3.4584) (15.003) (8.0283) (15.241) (35.341) (4.8315) (8.9423) (4.0478) (9.0572)

Mother in the same profession -0.0245 0.1303 0.0698 -0.1498 0.3703 0.0471 0.0896 -0.0433 0.0927

(26.068) (9.4396) (5.2600) (78.109) (27.300) (3.1373) (6.8017) (27.347) (6.8746)

Note: dy/dx for factor levels is the discrete change from the base level. Standard errors are in parentheses.

Table 5: Multinomial Logit estimation - sample of unemployed youth (Base category: Agriculture)Number of obs = 2549: LR chi2(112) = 1048.67: Prob > chi2 = 0.0000: Pseudo R2 = 0.1088: Log likelihood = -4293.0505

Category of expected employment Administration Professional Technical Clerical Services Craft Operations ElementaryEducation Type No education -0.9697 -2.3995*** -2.2575*** 0.2423 0.5779* 0.4688 1.4402*** 0.2662

(0.6702) (0.5613) (0.5763) (0.3539) (0.3234) (0.3858) (0.4670) (0.3556)

Primary -1.0442* -1.6085*** -0.9581** -0.0091 0.5986* 1.2816*** 0.7895* 0.2992

(0.6066) (0.4365) (0.4181) (0.3509) (0.3185) (0.3565) (0.4690) (0.3465)

Secondary 0.6177 1.2561*** 0.8183** 0.8190** 1.4231*** 1.7515*** 1.5901*** 0.9632**

(0.4988) (0.3887) (0.4121) (0.3990) (0.3758) (0.4099) (0.4674) (0.3972)

Post-Secondary 1.7598 1.5376*** 1.1848 0.4839 -0.2552 -0.0802 15.354 0.4461

(1.1696) (1.0777) (1.0923) (1.1330) (1.1397) (1.2693) (2225.0) (1.1437)

Father's education

30

Page 31: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Primary 0.5446 0.3156 0.3997 0.1971 0.0317 0.7792*** -0.2234 -0.0501

(0.4767) (0.3245) (0.3450) (0.2977) (0.2723) (0.3001) (0.4004) (0.3001)

Secondary and above 0.6267 1.0027 0.6210 0.5735 0.6027* 0.7266** 0.2857 0.3551

(0.5001) (0.3537) (0.3809) (0.3513) (0.3260) (0.3624) (0.4219) (0.3496)Mother's education

No education 0.6458 -0.2154 0.6864 0.5299 -0.2301 0.0068 -0.6254 -0.1256

(0.8425) (0.4286) (0.5142) (0.4234) (0.3742) (0.4244) (0.4932) (0.4020)

Primary 1.2431 -0.0412 0.5649 0.5998 -0.1232 0.0328 0.0413 -0.0290

(0.8673) (0.4729) (0.5618) (0.4750) (0.4252) (0.4730) (0.5498) (0.4548)

Secondary and above 1.2885 0.1416 0.6233 0.2357 -0.1196 -0.3974 0.1962 -0.4084

(0.9016) (0.5254) (0.6102) (0.5431) (0.4913) (0.5539) (0.6124) (0.5255)

Father in the same profession -0.8636 -0.4328*** -0.3480*** -0.5090*** -0.3057*** -0.0351 -0.1204 -0.3831***

(0.5555) (0.1122) (0.1116) (0.1246) (0.0600) (0.0599) (0.0846) (0.0882)

Mother in the same profession -5.9128 -0.5394*** -0.6060*** -0.7639*** 0.0569 -0.2973*** -5.9492 -0.2626***

(285.30) (0.1617) (0.2145) (0.2406) (0.0659) (0.0915) (222.48) (0.0923)

Constant -0.6823 1.8047* -0.5075 1.3936 4.0887*** 0.6198 -1.5167 3.7249***

(1.4606) (0.9502) (1.0579) (0.9309) (0.8537) (0.9533) (1.1604) (0.9184)

Note: Standard errors are in parentheses

31

Page 32: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Table 6: Average marginal effects - sample of unemployed youthModel VCE : OIM Number of obs = 2549

Emp_exp_Type Administration Professional Technical Clerical Services Agriculture Craft Operations Elementary

Delta-methodDy/dx

Education Type

No education -0.0214** -0.1446*** -0.0957*** 0.0213 0.1505*** -0.0105 0.0226 0.0623*** 0.0155

(0.0099) (0.0161) (0.0147) (0.0246) (0.0316) (0.0142) (0.0174) (0.0194) (0.0231)

Primary -0.0230*** -0.1311*** -0.0715*** -0.0245 0.1269*** -0.0146 0.1104*** 0.0179 0.0096

(0.0088) (0.0169) (0.0163) (0.0210) (0.0288) (0.0135) (0.0197) (0.0120) (0.0209)

Secondary -0.0139 0.0132 -0.0308* -0.0410** 0.0759*** -0.0394*** 0.0479*** 0.0123 -0.0241

(0.0087) (0.0197) (0.0164) (0.0182) (0.0243) (0.0110) (0.0148) (0.0084) (0.0169)

Post-Secondary 0.0549 0.1891 0.0564 -0.0313 -0.1650*** -0.0224 -0.0317 -0.0245*** -0.0255

(0.0380) (3.6058) (0.0440) (0.0449) (0.0502) (0.0329) (0.5799) (0.0055) (3.3553)Father's education

Primary 0.0081 0.0117 0.0128 0.0024 -0.0464* -0.0079 0.0634*** -0.0158 -0.0284

(0.0092) (0.0176) (0.0143) (0.0177) (0.0248) (0.0106) (0.0165) (0.0105) (0.0178)

Secondary and above 0.0001 0.0438*** -0.0002 -0.0019 0.0059 -0.0209** 0.0133 -0.0115 -0.0286

(0.0076) (0.0158) (0.0123) (0.0183) (0.0254) (0.0104) (0.0152) (0.0107) (0.0180)Mother's education

No education 0.0078 -0.0222 0.0374** 0.0614*** -0.0639** 0.0027 0.0066 -0.0195 -0.0102

(0.0073) (0.0234) (0.0151) (0.0196) (0.0322) (0.0133) (0.0224) (0.0131) (0.0232)

Primary 0.0179** -0.0153 0.0221 0.0560** -0.0634* -0.0017 -0.0025 -0.0010 -0.0122

(0.0088) (0.0242) (0.0152) (0.0218) (0.0348) (0.0148) (0.0233) (0.0155) (0.0251)

Secondary and above 0.0211** 0.0155 0.0301* 0.0237 -0.0296 0.0022 -0.0314 0.0119 -0.0435*

(0.0097) (0.0245) (0.0160) (0.0226) (0.0373) (0.0178) (0.0244) (0.0180) (0.0254)

Father in the same profession -0.0110 -0.0099 0.0000 -0.0223* 0.0057 0.0117*** 0.0265*** 0.0067*** -0.0073

(0.0115) (0.0098) (0.0058) (0.0124) (0.0111) (0.0021) (0.0038) (0.0025) (0.0080)

Mother in the same profession -0.1119 0.0185 0.0062 -0.0219 0.1978 0.0234 0.0356 -0.1914 0.0438

(5.9151) (1.4740) (0.7855) (1.2391) (2.9529) (0.4614) (1.2755) (7.6639) (1.3714)

Note: dy/dx for factor levels is the discrete change from the base level. Standard errors are in parentheses.

32

Page 33: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Table 7: Job Matching-skills only (youth employment expectations)

Occupation Perfect match (%)

Close match(slightly over- educated) (%)

Close match(slightly under-educated) (%)

Over educated(including close match) %

Under educated(including close match) %

Professional 7.78 0.00 37.43 0.00 92.22Services 5.01 22.55 23.05 22.55 72.44Administration 1.75 31.58 0.00 42.11 56.14Clerk 2.07 20.12 1.78 42.90 55.03Technical 9.09 3.64 3.64 48.48 42.42Other 18.81 0.96 27.95 53.24 27.95Overall 9.74 11.51 22.24 34.42 55.84

Source: author’s computations

Table 8: Job Matching – skills only (Employed youth)Occupation Perfect

match (%)Close match(slightly over- educated) (%)

Close match(slightly under-educated) (%)

Over educated (including close match) %

Under educated(including close match) %

Professional 30.92 0.00 27.58 0.00 69.08Services 2.55 23.46 25.75 46.92 50.53Administration 15.09 3.77 9.43 30.18 54.71Clerk 5.80 7.25 11.59 59.42 34.78Technical 15.38 5.29 9.13 61.05 23.55Other 32.69 0.51 19.97 47.85 19.46Overall 24.94 6.04 21.23 46.59 28.47

Source: author’s computations

33

Page 34: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

34

Page 35: €¦  · Web viewYouth labor market expectations and job matching: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Abstract. In this paper we investigate factors that influence youth labor market

Table 9: Match Quality (OLS estimates)Dependent Variable: Sectoral Match Quality

MQ_Admin MQ_Prof MQ_TechMQ_Clerica

l MQ_Services MQ_Agriculture MQ_Craft MQ_Operational MQ_Elementary

Education Level

No education -0.0006 -0.0090*** 0.0455*** -0.0041 -0.1347 -0.0901 0.0349 0.0074** 0.1658**

(0.0004) (0.0026) (0.0167) (0.0028) (0.0870) (0.1021) (0.0339) (0.0030) (0.0766)

Primary -0.0005 -0.0083*** 0.0199 -0.0040 -0.1042 0.0370 0.0321 0.0119*** 0.1525**

(0.0004) (0.0026) (0.0165) (0.0028) (0.0859) (0.1008) (0.0335) (0.0030) (0.0758)

Secondary 0.0002 0.0179 0.0269 0.0043 -0.0968 -0.0505 0.0734** 0.0140*** 0.1106

(0.0005) (0.0027) (0.0174) (0.0029) (0.0906) (0.1065) (0.0353) (0.0031) (0.0799)

Tertiary 0.0136*** 0.1266*** 0.0760 0.0379*** -0.1497 0.0405 0.0373 -0.0082 0.0975

(0.0013) (0.0076) (0.0493) (0.0084) (0.2552) (0.2992) (0.0997) (0.0089) (0.2253)

Father's education 0.0001 0.0000 -0.0021 0.0006 -0.0065 -0.0142 -0.0032 0.0001 0.0092

(0.0001) (0.0004) (0.0032) (0.0005) (0.0165) (0.2012) (0.0064) (0.0006) (0.0146)

Mother's education 0.0001 -0.0002 0.0001 0.0002 0.0312* -0.0443** -0.0014 0.0006 -0.0017

(0.0001 (0.0005) (0.0036) (0.0006) (0.0189) (0.0221) (0.0073) (0.0006) (0.0166)

Father_same profession 0.0025 -0.0031 -0.0605 -0.0064 0.1062 -0.2755*** -0.0222 0.0058 -0.0158

(0.0020) (0.0060) (0.0446) (0.0123) (0.1487) (0.0958) (0.0515) (0.0072) (0.2436)

Mother_same profession 0.0127** 0.0027 1.1067*** -0.0006 -0.0192 0.4557*** 0.0407 0.0174 -0.1457*

(0.0051) (0.0117) (0.0788) (0.0269) (0.0879) (0.1000) (0.1202) (0.0485) (0.0847)

Adj R-squared 0.0068 0.0148 0.008 0.0015 0.0021 0.0051 -0.0001 0.0055 0.0016

F( 11, 26216) 17.34 35.70 19.17 4.49 5.95 12.23 0.80 14.17 4.87

Prob > F 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Breusch-Pagan/Cook-Weisberg test

chi2(1) 125145 31234 2.6e+06 10005 32533 35310 22286 24413 29804

Prob > chi2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Mean (SD) 0.0008

(0.0238)0.0056

(0.1383)0.0113

(0.8927)0.0054

(0.1520)0.2476 (4.612)

0.3801 (5.411)

0.0550 (1.799)

0.0091 (0.1613)

0.1837 (4.070)

Note: Standard errors are in parentheses.

35


Recommended