+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Week 3 Lesson1

Week 3 Lesson1

Date post: 03-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: sixd-waznine
View: 229 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 61

Transcript
  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    1/61

    LECTURE WEEK 3:ECONOMIC

    RETURNSOUTLINE OF LECTURE WEEK 3:

    Ricardian rent theory Classical rent theory

    Urban rent theory

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    2/61

    Ricardian land rent

    Ricardo introduced the crucial concepts in the theoryof land rent:

    1. Land varies in its natural endowment or advantagefor the user.

    2. Land of a given level of natural endowment oradvantage is fixed in supply.

    3. The land market is governed by competition amongland users.

    4. Land rent is determined by the differences in naturalendowment or advantage of land.

    5. Land has single use ( grow corn)

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    3/61

    Ricardian land rent

    The supply of land at each location fixed perfectly price

    inelastic.

    The demand for a particular site quite sensitive, or elastic,

    with respect to price.

    Numerous competitive sites, or substitutes, exist at adjoining

    locations

    Determining Rent : Land must be priced at each site so that its

    occupant is charged for the value of whatever locational

    advantages exist at that site.

    Understanding these advantages and how consumers

    evaluate them is the key to understanding the usage pattern

    of land and housing prices.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    4/61

    Ricardian land rent

    This is a theory of compensating differentials.

    Only demand considerations determine the relative

    value of land or housing at different locations.

    The supply of land does play a role, but only insetting the overall level of prices.

    The first theory of land rent by David Ricardo in his

    1821 Ricardos focus was on agricultural land.

    Useful to study it as a steppingstone to the modern

    theory of urban land rent

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    5/61

    Ricardian land rent

    The markets for land and housing: completely

    productdifferentiated.

    Each product sold in the market (every flat or

    location) unique.

    Urban land a completely differentiated

    product.

    Difficult to speak about the supply of land or

    demand for sites at any particular location

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    6/61

    Ricardian land rent

    Imposition of taxes on land will neither

    increase rents nor alter the use of land

    Price of land is high because the price of corn

    is high and not vice versa

    So price of land is high because the price (

    housing) is high, and not vice versa ( refer

    diagram 1 )

    So Ricardian argued that price of land and

    housing is wholly demand determined, so

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    7/61

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    8/61

    Ricardian land rent

    a) rent of land is solely demand determined,

    since supply is fixed, variations in rents can

    only occur through shifts in the demand curve

    DD, so the rent of land is HIGH because the

    price of corn is high and not vice versa

    b) taxes levied on rents will not alter either

    the rent paid or the quantity of land supply

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    9/61

    Ricardian land rent

    Supply of land is irrelevant, but supply of land

    is under control of the planning authorities

    and can be changed

    So Ricardian argument is based on assumption

    that the supply of land is fixed and

    unchangeable. An increase in the amount of

    land allowed by the planning system to beused for housing can therefore result in the

    price of land & housing

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    10/61

    Agricultural and land rent

    Ricardos fundamental insight was thatagricultural land is not all of the same level offertility.

    There is a fixed supply of land of the bestfertility, called No. 1 land.

    Land with a somewhat lower level of fertility

    called No. 2 land, fixed in supply too. Land with even lower levels of fertility (No. 3,

    No. 4, etc.) also fixed in supply

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    11/61

    Agricultural and land rent

    Assume that with equal employment of capital andlabor, No. 1, No. 2, and No. 3 land would yield a netproduce of 100, 90, and 80 units of corn per acre.

    The country under consideration young and has a smallpopulation.

    A sufficient amount of No. 1 land exists to feed theentire population, with some No. 1 land left over.

    The land rent is zero.

    The most fertile land is a free good: supply exceedsdemand, even at a price of zero.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    12/61

    Agricultural and land rent

    Say rent for No. 1 land is not zero but somepositive number.

    Only some of the land earns this rent.

    Some of the land is left vacant, and the vacantland earns 0 rent.

    Owners of vacant land are willing to rent out theirland for less than the assumed positive rentrather than earning nothing.

    The competitive bidding process will continueuntil rent is down to zero.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    13/61

    Agricultural and land rent

    As Ricardo put it, when, in the progress of

    society, land of the second degree of fertility is

    taken into cultivation, rent immediately

    commences on that of the first quality, andthe amount of that rent will depend on the

    difference in the quality of these two portions

    of land.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    14/61

    Agricultural and land rent

    Land rent exists because land varies in fertilityand land of a given fertility level is fixed inquantity

    Further, progress of society will bring No. 3land into cultivation:

    Rent for No.3 land = 0. (each acre produces 80units)

    Rent for No.2 land = 10. (each acre produces 90units)

    Rent for No. 1 land = 20. (each acre produces 100units)

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    15/61

    Agricultural and land rent

    No. 2 land remains a free good, commanding

    a zero rent, if not all of it is in use.

    But now all no. 1 land is in use.

    If it remains a free good, all farmers would try

    to acquire no. 1 land, and none would be

    interested in working on no. 2 land.

    The demand for no. 1 land exceeds the

    supply.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    16/61

    Agricultural and land rent

    This situation persists so long as farmer couldearn more working on no. 1 land than no. 2land.

    No. 2 land produces 90 units of corn per acreand is a free good.

    Equilibrium reached only if the rent for no. 1

    land exceeds the rent for no. 2 land just by 10units of corn: the advantage of no. 1 landover no. 2 land.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    17/61

    Agricultural and land rent

    Competition among farmers generates the

    result.

    A farmer who is cultivating No. 3 land would

    pay up to 20 units of corn to occupy No. 1

    land.

    The farmer who actually occupies No. 1 land

    must pay 20 units or lose his lease.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    18/61

    Neoclassical rent theory

    Assumption :

    a) Land had alternative uses like any other

    factor of production

    b) land supply is not fixed

    c) each piece of land had an opportunity cost-

    the rent that could be obtained in the most

    profitable alternative use ( rent of land enter

    into cost of production )

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    19/61

    Neoclassical rent theory

    Refer diagram 2 : The neoclassical approach is

    represented by diagram 2.2.

    Horizontal and vertical axis represent quantity

    of land and rent. Total supply of land is OS.

    Land now is assumed to be two uses, growing

    potatoes and corn

    Demand for potatoes is PP

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    20/61

    Neoclassical rent theory

    So the amount of land used for potatoes is

    indicated along the horizontal axis from left to

    right, starting from O. The remaining land can

    be used for growing corn, so the demand forcorn is indicated in the reverse direction along

    the horizontal axis from right to left, starting

    at S. Demand for corn is CC Equilibrium in the land mkt is determined at ss

    and dd intersect

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    21/61

    Neoclassical rent theory

    Rent is OR, OX is used for growing potatoes

    and XS for growing corn

    This diagram explanation is contrary to

    ricardian theory, suppose there is an increase

    in the demand for potatoes, with no change in

    the demand for corn, demand for land for

    potatoes will shift to P1P1, increased indemand for potatoes cause reduction in usage

    of land for corn, from SX to SX1 ( diagram 2.3)

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    22/61

    Neoclassical rent theory

    Rent paid for all land increased from OR to

    OR1 . Less corn is supplied to the market and

    now rent price already increased, therefore

    the price of corn will also rise, therefore theincrease in the rent of land is not caused by

    the rise in corn price but vice versa.

    So the Ricardian theory can be incorrect ifland has alternative uses and can be shifted

    from one use to another

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    23/61

    Neoclassical rent theory

    Conclusion: rent of land for particular use is

    not solely determined by the demand for the

    product, land taxes can affect the use of land.

    Land with higher taxes will result shift in theuse of land from the higher to the lower taxed

    use with the tax being passed on in the form

    of a higher price for the product of the landtaxed at the higher rate

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    24/61

    Planning controls and rent theory

    Ricardian theory seem to be more relevant if

    planning control is allowed ( if each piece of

    land can be regarded as having a single use

    which is allowed by the planning system)

    Refer diagram 4 ( 2.4-handout): Supply of land

    is OS. OX is allowed for housing and XS is

    allowed for agricultural. Demand for housingis HH and demand for agricultural is

    downward sloping from right to left

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    25/61

    Planning controls and rent theory

    Planning system separates the markets and

    different rents are charged in each market, RH

    and RA rent for housing and agricultural

    respectively.

    Supply is fixed by the planning system and

    price of rent is determined by the demand

    Thus the price of housing land is high because

    the price of housing is high and not vice versa

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    26/61

    Planning controls and rent theory

    The argument that supply of land can be

    changed does not affect the price of land can

    be explain using diagram 5 ( 2.5- handout)

    Initially land supply is fix at OX and demand

    for housing is HH. The pricing of housing land

    is OR. Let assume demand for housing shifts,

    demand will cause the price of land to rise andvice-versa. So price of land is demand

    determined

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    27/61

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    28/61

    Planning controls and rent theory

    affect house price and land prices more

    quickly than shift in supply. A fall in interest

    rates is likely to result in house price being

    higher within few months, on the other handan increase in supply of land for housing may

    take years to affect prices, especially large

    development of the site will be phased overmany years. So increase in supply unlikely

    affect price of housing in short-term

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    29/61

    Planning controls and rent theory

    If the land and property market were efficient

    then announcement of an increased in land

    supply would result in house buyers and

    builders immediately lowering their prices inanticipation, but property market is not an

    efficient.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    30/61

    Planning controls and rent theory

    Example where Ricardian and Neoclassical

    both are agree ( diagram 2.6 ): Land area OS.

    DD demand for industry. Amount of land use

    for industrial is OI. Price for industry use isOP1. HH demand for housing. Amount of land

    available for housing is IS, price of land use for

    housing is SPH

    Both market appears representing Ricardian

    Model

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    31/61

    Planning controls and rent theory

    Assume demand for housing and housing land

    increases, demand shifted to H1H1, price of

    housing land is higher than industrial land, so

    now more profitable to develop industrial landfor residential use, new equilibrium at E.

    This situation best represent neo-classical

    model

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    32/61

    Urban Land Theory

    As in agricultural land, a fundamental characteristics ofurban housing and land markets is that

    housing and land are more expensive at betterlocations and cheaper at less advantageous sites.

    This holds whether we consider

    natural locational amenities, such as lakes or anocean, or

    manmade locational advantages, such as distanceto employment

    or cultural centers.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    33/61

    Urban Land Theory

    To study how rent and locational advantage

    interact, we begin with a model of a very

    simple city,

    originally due to German geographer J.H.

    von Thunen in his 1826 classic Isolated State,

    the modern version of which appeared in

    W. Alonsos Location and Land use in 1964.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    34/61

    Urban Land Theory

    In this city, commuting or access to place of

    employment is the only locational advantage

    that is considered.

    The city is monocentric.

    It has only one employment center.

    Commuting to this center gives rise to what is

    called (Ricardian) location rent.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    35/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Assume that the density of development is

    fixed.

    This absence of any factor substitution may

    seem unrealistic, but we will be determining

    density in the following

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    36/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Households are identical, and the number of workers

    (commuters) per household is fixed.

    Household income (y) can be spent on commuting, housing,

    and nonhousing consumption (x)

    Employment is at a single center, called the Central Business

    District (CBD), to which households commute along a direct

    line from their place of residence.

    Commuting costs k dollars annually per km.

    The location of a household refers to its linear distance (d)

    from the employment center.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    37/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Housing has fixed and uniform characteristics atall locations.

    Housing rent is an annual amount R(d), whichvaries by location (commuting distance d)

    Housing is provided by combining a fixed amountof land per unit of housing (acres, q) togetherwith a fixed amount of housing capital (materialsand labor) that costs C (no factor substitution) to

    construct. Residential density, i.e. number of households

    per acre is 1/q

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    38/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Housing at any location is occupied byhouseholds who offer the highest rent; land isallocated to that use yielding the greatest rent.

    Consider two locations: d1 and d2. Suppose

    kd1 + R(d1) < kd2 + R(d2) .

    The household, say household A, who occupieslocation d1 spends less on commuting and rentaltogether than the household, say household B,who occupies location d2.

    Can this situation be equilibrium?

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    39/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Seeing this difference in commuting and housingexpenditure, household B would want to move tolocation d1.

    To compete for the lease at location d1,

    household B can offer to pay a little bit more thanwhat household A currently pays.

    So long as (1) remains, the process of thiscompetitive bidding continues.

    In equilibruim we must have kd1 + R(d1) = kd2 + R(d2)

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    40/61

    Urban Land Theory

    R(d1) R(d2) = kd2 kd1.

    Think about d1 < d2, so that location d1 is a more

    desirable location.

    It costs less to commute from this site to jobs thanwhat it costs to commute from location d2.

    The savings in commuting cost must be just offset by

    the higher rent. When the housing market is in

    equilibrium, increased rents as one moves towards

    the CBD must exactly offset the lowered commuting

    costs.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    41/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Since the quality and density of housing is assumedfixed across locations, the only variation possibleamong housing units is commuting distance.

    If housing rents do not exactly offset commuting costs,

    then consumers who live at farther locations wouldseek to move to closer ones.

    They do so by offering greater housing rent thancurrent occupants.

    Since housing is rented to the highest bidder, rents atthe closer locations would rise, while those at farthersites would fall

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    42/61

    Urban Land Theory

    When rents exactly offset commuting costs,

    households would no longer have an incentive

    to move.

    The market is then said to be in a equilibrium.

    Mobility aims to increase welfare is not

    possible when the housing market is in

    equilibrium

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    43/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Let the farthest location in the city be b and

    write R(b) = .

    For any d b, R(d) = R(b) + k (b d) = + k (b

    d)

    This is the bid rent function: the maximum

    rent that households would be willing to bid

    for each location d in city.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    44/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Suppose rents in all locations in city, except for

    one, say location d1, follow the above

    equation.

    How much households would be willing to pay

    to occupy housing in this location d1 ?

    If at location d1 , R(d1 ) < + k (b d1 )

    all households in the city would like to move

    to just this location.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    45/61

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    46/61

    Urban Land Theory

    In many cities throughout the world, land

    beyond the edge of development is used for

    agriculture.

    In this case, it earns some rural rent per acre

    (ra).

    In other situations, land is simply held vacant

    with little or no meaningful rural rent

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    47/61

    Urban Land Theory

    land owners seek the highest income from

    their land, just as housing is rented to those

    making the highest offer.

    As long as urban housing yields a rent for a

    site that exceeds that which the owner can

    receive from farming, land will be rented to

    urban households.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    48/61

    Urban Land Theory

    At the edge of the city (b) , then, urban landlordscan rent land for its

    agricultural value (opportunity cost) of ra per

    acre. With fixed density, a lot for each housing unit can

    be rented for raq

    The (annualized) cost for putting up a housing

    unit at the edge of a city has two components:

    the land rent raq

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    49/61

    Urban Land Theory

    the structure rent, which is the annualizedcost of constructing a unit c = iC, where i is theinterest rate

    This structure rent could be measured by theannual mortgage payment necessary to coverthe cost of constructing the unit.

    If property development is perfectlycompetitive where firms earn zero profit,

    R(b) = = raq + c

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    50/61

    Urban Land Theory

    R(d) = raq + c + k (b d)

    Housing rents at any location will equal the

    sum of

    construction cost

    the opportunity cost of land plus

    the difference between commuting costs atthe urban edge and those at the location in

    question.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    51/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Moving from the edge of the city, rents must riseas commuting costs decrease.

    To the extent that households maintain the samehousing and commuting expenditure :

    R(d) + commuting exp. = raq + c + k (b d) + kd =raq + c + kb

    Equilibrium housing rent at any interior siteabsorbs the savings in commuting that result by

    moving in from the farthest location currentlydeveloped in the city

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    52/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Only with these rents will households bewilling to live at any location within the city

    There are three components to housing rent:

    1. the rent necessary to convert a lot fromfarm land into urban land (raq)

    2. the rent on the structure that sits on the

    site 3. the location rent resulting from saved

    commuting costs, k (b d)

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    53/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Both the agricultural rent and the structure rentare constant across locations.

    The slope of the housing rent function with

    respect to distance, k, is due to the locationrent.

    Rents fall away from the city center (per km) byexactly the amount of additional commuting

    incurred by each household. This slope is known as the rent gradient in urban

    economics

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    54/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Those components of housing rent thatinvolves location and agricultural land areoften combined into

    a hypothetical rent for just urban land r (d) .

    Urban land rent can be thought of as aresidual:

    the land rent that is left after subtractingthe rent for the housing structure from thetotal rent.

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    55/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Housing rent is measured per housing unit,while land rent will be measured as rent peracre (unit of land).

    To convert housing rent R(d) into land rent, r(d),subtract the structure rent and then divideby land per unit (q),

    r (d) = ra+ k (b d)/q

    This is the same as multiplying housing-minus-structure rent by residential density (1/q)

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    56/61

    Urban Land Theory

    Urban land rent has two components.

    1. The first is the rent (per acre) for its

    alternative use (agricultural)

    2. the second is the savings in commuting

    costs per acre that result when housing is

    placed on the land

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    57/61

    Urban Land Theory

    At a density of 1/q, there are that many

    households per acre, each of which is saving k

    (b d) in commuting

    The gradient for land rent with respect to

    distance has a slope of k/q.

    The rent per acre of land falls by the increased

    total commuting of all who live in the 1/qunits built on the land

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    58/61

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    59/61

    Urban Land Theory

    When commuting is more costly (per km),

    interior housing and land rents will be higher

    relative to edge rents because the commuting

    cost savings at interior locations are higher

    When urban land has a more productive

    alternative use (higher ra), urban housing and

    land rents will also be greater, because thisland rent component of housing rent is higher

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    60/61

    Urban Land Theory

    When the density of urban housing is greater,

    the gradient for urban land rents will become

    steeper, with higher rents at the city center

    relative to those near the edge.

    The slope of the land rent gradient is k/q.

    If the amount of land used per housing unit, q,

    decreases, then the land rent gradientbecomes steeper

  • 7/28/2019 Week 3 Lesson1

    61/61


Recommended