+ All Categories
Home > Documents > What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four...

What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four...

Date post: 24-Aug-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
42
1 What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European welfare states? The socio-structural basis of the new politics of pension reforms Silja Häusermann [email protected] European University Institute, Florence Prepared for delivery at the 2009 conference of the Swiss Political Science Association, January 8 th -9 th 2009, St. Gallen, Switzerland Abstract Over the last decade, the main puzzle in the analysis of continental European welfare states has shifted from the explanation of stability to the explanation of change. Rather than being “frozen landscapes”, most continental welfare states have indeed undergone far-reaching retrenchment and restructuring, even in the field of pensions, which supposedly is the most „path dependent“ welfare policy. Moreover, even left- wing political parties and even trade unions have played a major role in cutting back existing pension rights in several countries. How can we explain the contents and coalitional dynamics of these reforms? This contribution reviews four existing hypotheses for the explanation of the recent welfare reforms, arguing that all of them leave major questions unanswered. It then proposes a fifth hypothesis, arguing that we need to link the analysis of policy-making by parties and unions with an analysis of the changing socio-structural constituencies these actors represent. When looking empirically at the profile and preferences of the electorate and membership of parties and trade unions, it can be shown that the recent reforms cater to new constituencies, rather than the blue-collar workers, who were the core beneficiaries of the industrial welfare state. However, since the left-wing electorate has become very heterogeneous, the left is increasingly divided in policy- reforms. Empirically, socio-structural transformations and the preference profiles of constituencies in Switzerland, Germany and France are analyzed by means of survey data. In a second step, an analysis of collective actor positions in the reform space shows how these micro-level transformations affect the coalitional dynamics in three major pension reform processes in the early 2000s. Methodologically, I use factor analysis to analyze the dimensionality of the policy space, and the configuration of actors in this space.
Transcript
Page 1: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

1

What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European

welfare states? The socio-structural basis of the new politics of pension reforms

Silja Häusermann

[email protected]

European University Institute, Florence

Prepared for delivery at the 2009 conference of the Swiss Political Science

Association, January 8th-9th 2009, St. Gallen, Switzerland

Abstract

Over the last decade, the main puzzle in the analysis of continental European welfare states has shifted from the explanation of stability to the explanation of change. Rather than being “frozen landscapes”, most continental welfare states have indeed undergone far-reaching retrenchment and restructuring, even in the field of pensions, which supposedly is the most „path dependent“ welfare policy. Moreover, even left-wing political parties and even trade unions have played a major role in cutting back existing pension rights in several countries. How can we explain the contents and coalitional dynamics of these reforms? This contribution reviews four existing hypotheses for the explanation of the recent welfare reforms, arguing that all of them leave major questions unanswered. It then proposes a fifth hypothesis, arguing that we need to link the analysis of policy-making by parties and unions with an analysis of the changing socio-structural constituencies these actors represent. When looking empirically at the profile and preferences of the electorate and membership of parties and trade unions, it can be shown that the recent reforms cater to new constituencies, rather than the blue-collar workers, who were the core beneficiaries of the industrial welfare state. However, since the left-wing electorate has become very heterogeneous, the left is increasingly divided in policy-reforms. Empirically, socio-structural transformations and the preference profiles of constituencies in Switzerland, Germany and France are analyzed by means of survey data. In a second step, an analysis of collective actor positions in the reform space shows how these micro-level transformations affect the coalitional dynamics in three major pension reform processes in the early 2000s. Methodologically, I use factor analysis to analyze the dimensionality of the policy space, and the configuration of actors in this space.

Page 2: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

2

Introduction1

Over the last decade, the main puzzle in the analysis of continental European welfare

states has shifted from the explanation of stability to the explanation of change. The

very influential neo-institutionalist literature of the 1990s argued that continental

welfare states are “frozen landscapes” (Esping-Andersen 1996), in which endogenous

dynamics of increasing returns and power asymmetries foster institutional inertia and

path-dependence, thereby making far-reaching change electorally risky and highly

unlikely (Pierson 1996, 2001). The arguments of this literature seemed very

convincing: the insurance-based and contribution-financed continental social policy

schemes create – by means of a policy feedback - their own constituencies of

beneficiaries and “regime stakeholders”, which oppose any retrenchment or re-

allocation of resources further down the road. Governments who want to transform

existing policies face a tremendously difficult task, because they face increasing

groups of reform opponents, which may punish them for retrenchment at the next

election. Hence, there exists a status quo-bias in the institutional architecture of

continental welfare states, whereby they become “trapped” in a vicious circle of

increasing problem load (high labor costs, low employment rates, economic

downturn, demographic ageing) and a structural inability to reform.

However, as convincing as this analysis was, far-reaching welfare state reforms in

most continental welfare states from the late 1990s onwards soon proved it wrong.

Even pension regimes, where institutional policy feedbacks are strongest, underwent

deep changes all over continental Europe. Not only have pension rights of the

standard insured been lowered, but most countries have genuinely restructured their

pension-architecture by devising entirely new “pillars”, such as capitalized pension

savings schemes, means-tested minimum pensions or specific pension rights for labor

market outsiders and women (see, e.g. the works of Vail 2004, Palier 2002, Natali and

Rhodes 2004 on France; Bonoli 2000, 2001 on Switzerland: Nullmeier and Rüb 1993,

Hering 2004 and Busemeyer 2005 on Germany; Rhodes 2001 and Natali and Rhodes

2004 on Italy; Chulià 2002 and Natali and Rhodes 2004b on Spain; and Schludi 2005,

Häusermann 2007 and Bonoli and Palier 2007 for comparative analyses of continental

1 I would like to thank Christoffer Green-Pedersen, Bruno Palier, Herbert Kitschelt, Jonah Levy, Mark Vail, Adrienne Héritier and Vivien Schmidt for helpful suggestions and comments. A previous version of this paper was presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, August 29th-31st, Boston, USA.

Page 3: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

3

pension regime change). The most surprising aspect of these reforms is the enactment

of considerable benefit cuts in the general public pension levels, because these cuts

were expected to encounter the opposition of almost all future and current pensioners

(Pierson 1996, Schludi 2005). In addition, the expansive reforms elements that were

enacted benefit mostly to higher income groups (as in the case of new savings

opportunities for capitalized pensions) or to new social risk groups, i.e. women and

atypically employed (as in the case of means-tested pension minima or pension credits

for the upbringing of children), which are generally only weakly represented in

political parties, trade unions and parliaments (Bonoli 2005, Häusermann 2007).

Hence, all these changes are precisely the kind of distributional reforms

institutionalists would not expect to happen. Therefore, the current literature

increasingly tackles the question of change, not stability. As Starke puts it: “the

scientific puzzle has gradually shifted from the question as to why welfare states have

not been dismantled to the question as to why (and how) cutbacks have nonetheless

taken place in democratic political systems.” (Starke 2006: 106).

How can we explain these changes? Why did and why could governments take the

electoral risks attached to these reforms plans? There are four existing hypotheses and

explanations in the literature, and I will review them in the first part of this

contribution. Two explanations deal with governments’ ability to avoid blame for

retrenchment, by hiding the reforms (e.g. Pierson 1996) and by discursive framing of

them (e.g. Green-Pedersen 2002, Stiller 2007). A third hypothesis relies on party-

competition: governments can cut back if voters have no opportunity to punish them

at the polls (e.g. Kitschelt 2001). And a fourth explanation focuses on the ability of

governments to selectively compensate some losers of the reforms (e.g. Natali and

Rhodes 2004b, Schludi 2005, Levy 1999). However, all of these explanations leave

major questions unanswered: Why and how can politicians fool voters? Why would

all voters be convinced by a similar discourse? How can governments construct

sufficient majorities for pension restructuring? And why would left-wing parties

propose retrenchment in the first place?

In this contribution, I propose a new explanation of policy change, which links the

changing architecture of continental pension schemes to socio-structural change of

Page 4: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

4

party electorates and trade union constituencies. The model of reform dynamics I

propose can be seen as a socio-structural complement to the arguments of

compensation and political exchange mentioned above. I would like to demonstrate

that these reform packages have an underlying structural rationale: we cannot make

sense of the specific content of these packages if we do not consider that party

constituencies and their preferences have changed over the last decades. Left-wing

parties today represent a heterogeneous amalgam of working- and middle-class

voters, which differ very strongly in their views as to how and for whom states should

provide public welfare. I argue that when looking at these socio-structural

transformations of the policy space, the recent reforms become much less surprising.

Rather, they do make sense even in electoral terms.

I focus my theoretical framework and my empirical investigation on pension policy,

because pensions are considered to be a “hard case” for reform. They entail a lot of

strongly vested interests and power asymmetries, and are most unlikely to change.

The contribution is structured as follows: In a first party, I review the four existing

explanations of pension regime change. In a second part, I will develop my argument

on the socio-structural changes that underpin the current pension reform dynamics.

After a brief section on data and methods, I will test and illustrate this fifth

explanation empirically in two steps: first, I will show the transformation of party

electorates and trade union constituencies by means of individual-level survey data

and secondly, I will show empirically how these changes played out in three major

pension reforms in Germany, France and Switzerland in the early 2000s.

1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental

welfare states

All four existing explanations of the recent reform dynamics in continental pension

regimes are very actor-centered. They all focus on the achievements of particularly

lucky, or strategically and rhetorically gifted leaders, and thereby they have a

somewhat heroic and voluntaristic undertone.

According to Pierson (1994, 1996), the reform of mature welfare states in a time of

permanent austerity becomes an exercise of blame-avoidance, because almost all

Page 5: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

5

voters are stakeholders of the mature social insurance schemes. Consequently,

governments must find ways to shift, avoid or deal with the blame that comes with

welfare retrenchment. The first two explanations for recent change suggest that some

governments find ways to enact unpopular reforms, and not be blamed for doing so.

1.1. The obfuscation argument: hiding the consequences of reforms

In the early articles in which Pierson outlined his neo-institutionalist

conceptualization of the new politics of welfare state inertia (Pierson 1994, 1996), he

also argued that one of the remaining means for governments to enact retrenchments

was “obfuscation”, i.e. the concealment of the negative consequences of reforms. The

argument suggests that strategically skilled elites would enact cutbacks not directly in

level of benefits (such as e.g. lowering the amount of a full pension), but via other,

more technical and less obvious reforms. Examples could be the lowering of pension

indexation, or the extension of the required contribution period for a full pension2.

The obfuscation-argument assumes that voters are much less aware of parameters

such as indexation and calculation formula than of other policy parameters such as the

age of retirement or the amount of a full pension.

Some evidence seems to confirm this assumption, since governments indeed started to

cut back pension indexation in the late 1980s before turning to the plain cutbacks of

pension levels (Pierson 1996, Schludi 2005, Häusermann 2007). However, there are

both theoretical shortcomings and empirical counterevidence to the obfuscation-

argument. Empirically, there have been very clear-cut pension cutbacks in many

countries over the last years. The increase of women’s retirement age to 65 in

Switzerland or the introduction of the legal age of retirement from 65 to 67 in

Germany are just two examples. Also in Germany, the target replacement rate has

been lowered from nearly 70% to less than 50% only between 2001 and 2005

(Häusermann 2007). These are reforms that were very visible, heatedly discussed and

yet implemented. But the theoretical counter-argument is even more important: it is

hardly convincing that in a democracy, governments and elites can “fool” voters with

cutbacks going unnoticed, because there are controls: the opposition parties, the

2 If pensions are not indexed on inflation of prices (or wages), they fall “automatically” in real terms over the years. Similarly, if the required contribution period for a full pension is extended from, say, 40 to 43,5 years (such as in France in the 1990s, see Palier 2002), this actually equals an increase in the legal age of retirement or – given that most contributors do not have sufficiently long careers anymore – a lowering in the pension levels.

Page 6: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

6

media, independent experts, interest organizations all have expertise in this field.

They know and they can evaluate what it implies not to index pensions or to increase

the number of required contribution years for a full pension. If we assume that politics

is made by strategic actors behaving rationally within the limits of their knowledge –

which Pierson clearly does assume -, it is unlikely that governments can obfuscate the

consequences of reforms. Hence, the obfuscation-hypothesis falls short in answering

several questions: why would voters be ignorant, and why is there no opposition,

expertise, and counter-evidence to the government reform proposals and strategies?

1.2. The framing argument: Convincing voters of the necessity of retrenchment

The second explanation of retrenchment also implies a somewhat heroic assumption

of policy leadership. In this perspective, reforms are the achievements of political

leaders, who manage to convince a majority of the electorate of the necessity of the

proposed changes. Most authors who rely on this hypothesis conceptualize policy

discourses in terms of framing strategies. Stiller (2007) analyzes German pension,

labor market and health policy reforms by referring to the “ideational leadership” of

strong politicians such as German ministers Walter Riester or Wolfgang Clement. In

the field of pensions, Riester managed to frame the introduction of the private,

capitalized pension pillar as a means to save the traditional PAYG-system. Similarly,

Hering (2004) observes that the Social Democratic government had a very strong

discourse on the need and inevitability of retrenchment, which changed the perception

of reforms in the public opinion. The interaction of strong problem load and the

reformist discourse created a window of opportunity for “creative opportunism” of

party leaders and governments (Hering 2004). Green-Pedersen also bases his

explanation of retrenchment policies in Denmark and the Netherlands on the ability of

governments to present cuts as legitimate. A strong party consensus on the direction

of reform allowed the Dutch government in the 1980s to implement retrenchment

(Green-Pedersen 2002). All three authors explain reform politics as a top-down

process, where leaders convince voters of the need for reform. Vis and van

Kersbergen (2007), by contrast, analyze leaders’ and voters’ preferences separately,

but they, too, suggest that reforms occur when both sides are convinced that it is

necessary and justified to cut back benefits. Based on prospect theory, they argue that

if both voters and governments are convinced by the necessity of reform, they may

Page 7: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

7

become risk-seeking and engage in reforms. Again, governments influence the

evaluation of the reform-necessity by the voters by framing reforms.

It is certainly true that policy leaders develop discourses to legitimize unpopular and

hurtful reforms. But it remains unclear why voters would adhere to these discourses,

if the reforms really cut back their own benefits. It is even less clear why all voters

would adhere to a same discourse or a single “frame”. As with the obfuscation-

argument, leaders are again assumed to be highly rational and even manipulative,

while the electorate is viewed as far less rational. One could argue that voters may

well believe in the overall necessity for reforms, but still oppose the cutbacks of their

very own, individual benefits. In addition, one would expect the opposition or trade

unions to develop counter-discourses in order to challenge the dominant frames.

To some extent, both hypotheses – “obfuscation” and “framing” - are somewhat

“apolitical”, since there is no political power struggle between reform winners and

reform losers over different policy options or over different discourses. Voters are

either fooled or convinced by leaders, and they let themselves be fooled or convinced.

Such explanations assume a strong rationality of political actors, but lack a

theorization of the response to framing or obfuscation strategies.

The third hypotheses one finds in the literature does not rely on blame-avoidance, but

on power relations. Actors can enact retrenchment, if they are in a position in which

they can afford taking the blame for it.

1.3. The electoral argument: Nixon goes to China

The third explanation of retrenchment suggests that governments may implement

unpopular reforms, if they have little to fear in electoral terms. There are two variants

of this hypothesis, one based on party competition (Kitschelt 2001, to some extent

Green-Pedersen 2002) and one based on issue-ownership (Ross 2000). Both theses

want to explain how we can understand that left-wing governments actually seemed

even more successful in enacting cutbacks than their conservative competitors.

Kitschelt’s argument is very straightforward: governments can afford retrenching if

voters have no alternative to turn to in the next elections. In Germany, the red-green

government that was in place between 1998 and 2005 managed to enact retrenchment

Page 8: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

8

reforms in many fields, notably pensions and unemployment insurance. These

cutbacks were similar to the ones the right-wing Kohl government tried to implement

in the mid-1990s. However, while the Kohl government suffered a dramatic defeat at

the polls in 1998, voters were somehow at a loss of alternatives when it came to

punishing left-wing governments3. They still perceived conservative parties as an

even bigger threat to the welfare state than the left-wing government parties. Fiona

Ross (2000) also builds on this idea of voters’ perception of specific party policies. In

line with saliency theory of party competition, she assumes that parties “own” specific

issues or policy fields, in which voters estimate that they are particularly competent.

Hence, if both left- and right-wing governments enact the very same reforms, they are

not perceived in the same way by voters4. This argument can be labeled “Nixon goes

to China”, referring to the fact that Nixon was the first American President to be able

to go to China, precisely because nobody suspected him to have any kind of approval

for the communist regime. In short, “voters do not trust rightist parties to reform the

welfare state, … Cuts imposed by the left may be viewed as trade-offs for increased

spending in other policy areas, absolute essentials, strategic necessities, or, at a

minimum, lower than those that would be experienced under parties of the right”

(Ross 2000: 164).

Both lines of this third explanation for changes convincingly explain why Social

Democratic governments in Germany and the UK were – at least in the short run -

able to implement some of the harshest welfare reforms of the last decades. However,

there are two things that these explanations cannot account for: firstly, in some

countries, right-wing governments successfully enacted policy retrenchment, as well.

France is a prime example, where the Balladur government in 1993 and the Raffarin

government in 2003 enacted considerable pension cuts (Palier 2002). Similarly,

pension cuts in Italy took place under technocratic and conservative, not left-wing

rule (Natali and Rhodes 2004b). In addition, the Nixon-goes-to-China logic may

explain why left-wing governments could enact retrenchment, but it leaves a very big

question mark as to why they would want to do so in the first place. As Starke notes:

3 Meanwhile, of course, the Social Democratic party split precisely because of this unpopular reform agenda of its government, and the „Linkspartei“ today represents the left-wing alternative voters were lacking in the early 2000s (Picot 2008). 4 With regard to the New Labour-reform agenda in Great Britain, Ross demonstrates that many reforms of the Blair-government attracted support, even though similar conservative proposals arouse strong opposition (2000: 161).

Page 9: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

9

“the underlying motivation for cutbacks is still little understood”. Ross (2000: 160)

refers to “genuine non-leftist preferences of certain party leaders” and that

governments changed their conceptions of viable policy options, but this seems both

ad personam and functionalist.

The fourth explanation of change does not build on blame-avoidance, either, but

rather on credit-claiming strategies. Governments target welfare reforms at particular

groups, in order to make them politically acceptable.

1.4. The strategic argument: “Vice-into-virtue” and selective package deals

The starting point of this fourth explanation of welfare reforms is that these reforms

are not just about retrenchment, but also about a genuine restructuring of the

distributive consequences of welfare regimes (Ross 2000: 158), entailing both losers

and winners. Again, this argument comes in two ways: selective compensation (Natali

and Rhodes 2004b, Bonoli 2000) and “vice into virtue” (Levy 1999).

The compensation-argument turns the focus of the new politics-literature away from

retrenchment only and tries to bring in the multiple goals and reform strategies that

characterize current welfare reforms. Natali and Rhodes (2004b: 5) identify four goals

that policy-makers may pursue: financial viability, economic competitiveness, equity

and effectiveness. Governments may tie reform packages that combine different

goals, thereby catering to different interests in specific ways. Trade unions in the

Italian pension reforms, for instance, could be compensated for retrenchment by

means of stronger organizational powers. Similarly, governments in France and Italy

mitigated opposition to pension cutbacks by excluding current pensioners – and

public sector pensioners in France - from the reforms. Bonoli and Palier (2007) have a

similar argument: most pension reforms in continental Europe are phased in over a

very long period of several decades. Thereby, current pension beneficiaries who are

expected to be among the most ardent defenders of the status quo are compensated

and their opposition diminished (see also Anderson and Lynch (forthcoming) for a

more elaborate analysis of the conditions under which pensioners’ interests influence

the positions of trade unions). Schludi’s (2005) account of the reforms of Bismarckian

pension regimes can be read in a similar way: governments make concessions to

potential veto players, such as trade unions, in order to mitigate their veto power.

Page 10: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

10

It is certainly true that most pension reforms exempt current pensioners from heavy

cutbacks, thereby shifting the entire burden of retrenchment to the young. However,

the active population still represents an electoral majority in all European

democracies, and the exemption of the elderly from cutbacks aggravates the benefit

cuts they suffer themselves. Hence, it remains difficult to understand why these

reforms can be enacted without major opposition. It seems unlikely that the

exemption of the elderly or some organizational competencies for trade unions suffice

to construct a sufficient majority for these reforms.

The second variant of the strategic argument resolves this question by arguing that the

recent reforms combine several beneficial effects into “modernizing compromises”

(Bonoli 2001) or “virtuous” policy reforms (Levy 1999, 2001), which simultaneously

enhance the efficiency and equity of continental welfare regimes. Thereby, the

reforms contribute to a more equitable and efficient welfare state, and thus enjoy

sufficient legitimacy. Levy’s argument starts from Esping-Andersen’s (1990)

observation that continental welfare regimes are highly inegalitarian: “they are

fiscally regressive, too generous in some areas while not generous enough in others,

discriminatory against women wage earners, and dissuasive of job creation” (Levy

1999: 245). Governments may target specific inequities or “vices” – such as over-

generous public sector pensions or universal child allowances that are paid even to

middle- and upper-class families – and reallocate spending to the truly needy (i.e. the

poor in Levy’s account (1999) and new social risk groups in Bonoli’s

conceptualization (2005)). Levy (1999, 2001) sees this “vice into virtue”-strategy as a

means for (left-wing) governments to provide resources to their own constituencies

without increasing overall government expenditures (Levy 1999: 247, 256).

Of course, the idea of welfare reforms, which allow overcoming the equity-efficiency

trade-off by taking money from those who don’t really need it and redistributing it to

the truly needy is appealing. However, in a perspective of distributional politics, it can

hardly be overlooked that there are not just winners of these reforms, but also losers,

namely the middle- and higher-income earners, who lose their benefits and privileges.

Moreover, these social strata tend to be more organized and better represented in the

political arena than the poor or the victims of new social risks (i.e. mostly women and

atypical, precarious workers). Hence, the question remains how governments can

possibly overcome the opposition of the powerful against these reforms? Again, how

Page 11: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

11

can they gain majorities for their reform packages? Why would the higher income-

classes agree to cutbacks of their own benefits?

In the next section, I would like to develop a fifth explanation of welfare reforms that

is very close to this fourth explanation, but complements it with a conceptualization of

actors’ motivations. I also hypothesize that governments focus on credit-claiming,

rather than on blame-avoidance, and they tie specific reform packages in order to

receive sufficient support in the electorate. However, I do not assume that

governments are heroic and opportunistic leaders who arbitrarily grant benefits to

specific groups. Rather, I suggest that political actors defend the relatively narrow

interests of their constituencies. And since the constituencies of the major parties –

particularly on the left – have deeply transformed over the last decades, the policies

these parties advocate have transformed, as well.

2. A socio-structural argument: new conflict lines underlying coalitional reform

dynamics

With the model of change I propose in this contribution, I would like to add a socio-

structural basis to the conceptualization of reforms in terms of policy-packages. In

much of the compensation- or political exchange-literature, decision-makers are

“creative opportunists” (Hering 2004), i.e. skillful leaders who deliberately choose

particular reform goals and combine them in a strategic way. Authors such as Natali

and Rhodes (2004b) analyze the strategies of governments as almost completely

detached from the interests of their actual party constituencies. Others, such as Levy

(1999) take it for granted that the left represents the poor and underprivileged, without

testing this assumption empirically. In contrast to these approaches, I would like to

point out that these package deals are not the fruit of fortuitous coincidences or

macchiavellistic policy-makers, nor are they miraculous win-win-solutions that

overcome hard distributional choices. Rather, post-industrial welfare reforms are

indeed to a large extent a zero-sum-game, since resources are scarce and the needs

and demands of different social groups diverge strongly. Therefore, these reforms can

be traced back to the interests of particular social groups, i.e. they have an underlying

socio-structural rationale.

Page 12: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

12

My argument is that the transition to post-industrial societies has transformed the

constituencies of political parties and the clientele of major trade unions. If we

understand these socio-structural transformations, we can better explain why the

collective actors enter seemingly “surprising” alliances and why they propose these

packages and political exchanges. In brief: there is a structural basis and explanation

for the recent welfare reforms.

Surprisingly, this transformation of party and union constituencies is oftentimes

overseen. Some of the most prominent literature on current Social Democracy and

left-wing policies (e.g. Rueda 2005, 2007; Levy 1999, 2001; Natali and Rhodes

2004b) still assumes that the left advocates the interests of the “average production

workers”, i.e. the male, industrial, low- or semi-skilled worker with a modest income

and a standard employment biography. However, in a post-industrial society, the

average production worker becomes an “endangered species”, i.e. he is certainly not

the average wage-earner anymore, nor is he necessarily the typical left-wing voter

(Kitschelt 1994). Recent studies even show that blue collar workers are as likely to

vote for populist right-wing parties than for the left (Oesch 2006, Bornschier 2007,

Häusermann and Walter 2008). A meaningful conceptualization of today’s party

constituencies and their interests requires an adaptation of the industrial class scheme

to post-industrial conditions.

The post-industrial transformation of the economy and labor markets in continental

Europe has been driven since the 1960s by mainly three trends (Oesch 2006):

Deindustrialization, i.e. job growth in the service sector and a decline of the

industries; the educational revolution, i.e. an expansion of the new middle-classes

(Kriesi 1997); and the feminization of the labor force, i.e. the massive entry of women

in the labor market. These trends have deeply transformed the class structure of the

labor market, by creating new classes of privileged or under-privileged workers,

horizontal differentiations of the middle-classes and – thereby – new conflict lines.

Oesch (2006) has developed such a new post-industrial class scheme that takes into

account not only the vertical stratification of opportunities and interests, but also the

horizontal differentiation with regard to work sectors and work logics5. This new class

5 The horizontal axis differentiates occupations in terms of the dominant work logic: an independent work logic implies a lot of autonomy and a focus on the economic goals of efficiency and profitability. People with a technical or organizational work logic are in jobs that are oriented towards the

Page 13: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

13

scheme is most helpful for the analysis of current party constituencies and interests.

Kitschelt and Rehm (2005) have collapsed the original 9 categories in 5 classes that

are meaningful in terms of their welfare-state preferences and values: capital

accumulators (CA), mixed service functionaries (MSF), low service functionaries

(LSF), blue collar workers (BC) and socio-cultural (semi-)professionals (SCP) 6.

My argument is that the constituencies of political parties have changed in terms of

these classes, and that these changes are key for explaining recent welfare state

restructuring. The transformations have probably been strongest on the left side of the

political spectrum: the left today draws mostly on a combination of blue-collar

workers (BC), low-skilled service sector workers (LSF) and high-skilled socio-

cultural professionals (SCP). Social democratic parties tend to be torn between two

poles: on the one hand, they still represent their “old” industrial constituency (BC), organizational goals of their employer or the production efficiency. By contrast, the work goals of people in interpersonal occupations are focused on the people/clients/patients, with whom they interact directly. The vertical axis represents the structuration of income- and skill-differences between different strata. For a classification of occupations see appendix figure A1. 6 Capital accumulators are higher-grade managers, employers, self-employed in liberal professions (physicians, lawyers etc.) and technical experts. They are highly skilled and tend to work in private industries or services. Socio-cultural (semi-) professionals, by contrast tend to work in non-profit or public organizations, or in the service sector. They are typically employed in client-interactive and “symbol-processing” jobs (teachers, therapists etc.) with large work-autonomy. On the low-skilled side of the vertical stratification, there is an important distinction between blue-collar workers and low service functionaries. This differentation coincides to some extent with a sectoral public-private divide; the low-skilled services are very frequently employed in the public sector (personal services), whereas blue-collar workers concentrate in private crafts and industry (metal industry, chemistry, mining and construction etc.). It should be noted, however, that low-skilled service employment is also strongly represented in retail commerce, hotels and restaurants and other private services. Finally, Mixed service functionaries are a residual category; they possess a rather heterogeneous profile in terms of skills and work logic.

Page 14: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

14

but since the 1970s, the “new left” also mobilizes strongly among higher-skilled

middle-classes, women, and public sector workers (Kitschelt 1994). These new

sections of the left electorate are neither the core beneficiaries of continental welfare

states (since many of them are female, atypically employed etc.), neither are they the

social groups with the strongest poverty risks. Hence, if social democratic parties start

advocating some sorts of cutbacks, this may not represent a “depoliticization of

policy-making” as stated by Natali and Rhodes (2004b: 23), but it may rather

correspond to the interests of a new part of their electorate. Green parties are a

particularly pronounced version of the new left: they attract mostly high-skilled,

female voters in interpersonal work relations and with a strong libertarian value

profile. By contrast, trade unions tend to remain more strongly rooted in the

industrial, rather than the service sector, and among male workers in standard

employment (Ebbinghaus 2006). However, the labor movement today has also

become very heterogeneous: different sectoral trade unions are likely to diverge in

their interests, depending on the skill-levels and job profiles they represent

(Häusermann 2007). Hence, when Natali and Rhodes interpret the labor movement as

“the self-appointed defender of the pensions status quo in all countries of continental

Europe” (2004b: 1), this assumption may be too simple. Finally, changes of party

constituencies have not only affected the left, but also the right. Blue collar workers in

continental Europe are increasingly likely to vote for right-wing, even far-right

parties, because of their very conservative value profile (Kriesi et al. 2006, Bornschier

2007).

Given these socio-structural changes, the left today represents a variety of social

groups with highly different preferences and goals regarding the welfare state. The

two extremes – blue-collar workers and the new middle-class electorates – differ on at

least three dimensions:

• Their position within the welfare state: The continental insurance schemes were

built for blue-collar workers with stable and full-time employment and a full

contribution period. Today, social risks are concentrated in all employment

categories that deviate from this standard scheme: part-time employed, temporary

employment, interrupted work biographies. These profiles are very common

among socio-cultural professionals and low service functionaries (Häusermann

Page 15: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

15

2007: 112ff.). Hence, these new risk groups may want to restructure welfare

states, whereas blue-collar workers are expected to defend the status quo.

• Blue-collar workers and the new middle-class voters of the left may also differ

with regard to the level of redistribution they claim: Socio-cultural professionals

tend to be rather highly skilled. They may be less inclined to strong state

interventionism than the lower skill- and income-classes.

• Thirdly, there may be a strong value-cleavage between these groups. The “new

left” is a result of the new social movements of the 1980s (Kriesi 1999, Kitschelt

1994), which mobilized on the basis of libertarian and universalistic values, and

which privileged policies such as (gender) egalitarianism, equal opportunities

policies etc.. These policy priorities are likely to diverge from the value-profile of

the male, industrial working class.

I contend that this restructuring of the socio-structural foundations of party systems

leads to new conflict lines, cross-cutting the old left. Post-industrial welfare politics

imply multiple policy goals and conflict dimensions, which divide actors in different

ways. Such a multidimensionality of the policy-space creates opportunities for

political exchange and variable actor alliances. Hence, if we want to understand why

governments tie the policy-packages that we observe, and why they manage to build

sufficient majorities for them, we need to take into account the socio-structural

foundation of the new politics of the welfare state. This argument also implies that the

restructuring of continental pension schemes is the expression of a more fundamental

restructuring of the underlying socio-structural coalitional basis of welfare state

policies.

3. Data and Methods

In order to test and illustrate my argument empirically, I analyze major pension

reforms in France, Germany and Switzerland. These three countries share both the

continental architecture of their welfare states and the structural transformations of the

labor markets in the wake of post-industrialization. Hence, I expect that the socio-

structural transformations of the policy space and the party electorates are similar.

Page 16: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

16

In a first part of the empirical analysis, I investigate the socio-structural basis of

political actors in the late 1990s in France, Germany and Switzerland, by analyzing

the constituencies of parties and unions. I also show the preference profiles of these

constituencies on both the economic dimension opposing state interventionism to

liberalism, and the cultural dimension, opposing libertarian to traditionalist values.

These analyses are based on data from the ISSP role of government III survey 1996.

In a second part of the analysis, I show how these transformations affect policy-

making, by tracing actor positions and coalitional dynamics in three major reform

processes of the early 2000s: the 2003 Raffarin pension reform in France, the 2003

occupational pension reform in Switzerland and the 2001 “Riester”-pension reform in

Germany. For the analysis of these reforms, I have drawn on several sources of data:

firstly, the main elements of each reform have been identified through documentary

analysis (mainly governmental reports and bill proposals, documentation of the

consultation procedure and parliamentary debates) and secondary literature. Secondly,

the positions of each actor on these reform elements have been coded on a scale

ranging from 0 to 2. While 1 means that the actor supports the bill proposal by the

government, 0 means that the actor favors a more generous and encompassing

coverage and, conversely, 2 means that the actor claims a less generous and

encompassing coverage of the risk or need at stake. The positions of the actors have

been coded on four aspects of each reform-element: 1) intervention: whether State

intervention is required to resolve the problem or not, 2) scope: who should be

covered by the policy-instrument at stake, 3) level: which level of benefits should be

adopted and 4) competence: at what state level the intervention should take place

(firms, sectors, substate level…). Hence, each actor has expressed at most four

positions on each reform-element. Since all four elements are strongly interrelated

(they form a single dimension in a principal component factor analysis) the average of

the four positions has then been used in the further empirical analyses.

As to the source for coding, I have mainly relied on actors’ statements in the official

pre-parliamentary consultation procedures, the minutes of hearings, and parliamentary

debates7. I have then complemented the coded data with more qualitative information

7 For the case of France, the positions of unions and employers had to be complemented by means of interviews and archival data, since – contrary to Germany and Switzerland - there are no regular consultations. With regard to actor selection, I have included all actors, who intervened in the

Page 17: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

17

drawn from documentary analysis, secondary literature and interviews with leading

representatives of the social partners8. Methodologically, I use factor analysis to

analyze the dimensionality of the policy space, and the positions of the actors with

regard to the salient conflict dimensions.

4. Empirical Analysis

In a first step of this empirical analysis, I will analyze party electorates and the

preference-profiles of socio-economic groups by means of survey data, before then

turning to the analysis of three specific reform processes.

3.1. Socio-structural change of party and trade union constituencies

The main change in the restructuring of party electorates relates to the fact that left-

wing parties are not blue-collar parties anymore. Today, they also attract (middle-

class) voters, and have a strong female and public sector electorate. The ISSP 1996

role of government III survey contains information about social classes, their

preferences in terms of party choice and union membership. In the following, I

present logistic regression analyses of the determinants of party choice in terms of

classes and other relevant socio-structural characteristics. The coefficients are

estimates of the odds of voting for a particular party or for being a union member (for

the party vote shares within classes, see tables TA1-TA3 in the appendix). The main

focus of the analysis is on the voting behavior of social classes. I hypothesize that

socio-cultural professionals and lower service functionaries have become equally

likely to vote for left-wing parties than blue-collar workers.

Table 1 provides the results for Switzerland.

consultation procedures. For the French case, I had to make a selection, since no official consultations take place. I have chosen CGT, CFDT and CGC on the side of trade unions and MEDEF and CGPME on the employer’s side. 8 France: interviews with representatives of the governmental conseil des retraites COR, the employer organizations MEDEF and CGPME, and the trade unions CGT, CGC and CFDT; Germany: interviews with representatives of the employer organizations BDA and ZDH and with the trade unions DBB, DGB, Ver.di, IG Metall and ULA; Switzerland, interviews with representatives of the governmental office BSV, the employer organizations SAV and SGV, the trade union SGB and the political parties CVP, FDP and SPS.

Page 18: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

18

Table 1: Party preferences of post-industrial risk groups: Switzerland

Support for the left Support for the right

Green Party

Social Democrats

Union member

Christian Democracy

Moderate right

Radical right

1.023 1.014 0.404*** 0.132* 3.581*** 0.786 Capital accumulators (0.87) (0.39) (0.13) (0.14) (1.62) (0.38)

0.699 1.061 0.760 0.724 3.184*** 1.019 Mixed service functionaries (0.44) (0.27) (0.16) (0.29) (1.26) (0.35)

1.433 2.006*** 0.908 1.248 2.637** 0.619 Socio-cultural Professionals (0.75) (0.45) (0.18) (0.42) (1.01) (0.22)

1.420 1.011 0.695 0.522 3.563*** 0.689 Low Service Functionaries (0.83) (0.28) (0.17) (0.28) (1.52) (0.30) Blue collar workers r r r r r r

0.916 2.021*** 1.039 0.951 0.430** Trade Union members (0.38) (0.33) (0.30) (0.24) (0.15)

1.269 1.512* 1.593** 0.785 1.040 0.915 Public sector employment (0.70) (0.36) (0.34) (0.38) (0.35) (0.41)

0.982 0.940* 1.173*** 1.068 1.115** 1.098* Income in 10 (national) deciles (0.07) (0.03) (0.04) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06)

1.193 0.848 0.951 0.434** 0.450*** 0.674 Gender

(0.50) (0.15) (0.16) (0.14) (0.12) (0.21) 0.025*** 0.188*** 0.138*** 0.055*** 0.023*** 0.061*** Constant

(0.02) (0.05) (0.03) (0.02) (0.01) (0.03)

Observations 1329 1329 1338 1329 1329 1329

Pseudo Rsquare 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.03 Values in parentheses are standard errors. *** p<= 0.01 level; ** p <= 0.05 level; * p <= 0.1 level. The dependent variable corresponds to the individual vote for this party Green Party: GPS, GB; Social Democrats: SPS; Christian Democracy: CVP, EVP, CSP; Moderate right: FDP, LdU, LPS; Radical right: SVP, FPS, SD, Lega; Data source: ISSP 1996 Role of Government III. Question wording: "Generally, do you feel affiliated or sympathize with a specific political party (without necessarily being a member)?"

In Switzerland, socio-cultural professionals are even more likely than blue-collar

workers to sympathize with the Green Party and the Social Democrats, and this

difference is statistically significant with regard to the social democratic party choice.

More than 50% of socio-cultural professionals opt for the social democratic party, as

compared to about 39% of the blue-collar workers (see table A1 in the appendix).

Low service functionaries – a class including many women and precariously

employed workers – are also 1.4 times more likely to vote for the Greens than blue-

collar workers. However, blue-collar workers are still the social class with the highest

propensity towards trade union membership. It seems that the labor movement

remains to some extent the stronghold of the old left. Finally, however, blue-collar

Page 19: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

19

workers are also most likely of all classes to sympathize with the right-wing Swiss

People’s Party. This is the item on which socio-cultural professionals and blue-collar

workers differ most clearly: only 9.3% of the former, but almost 23% of the latter feel

affiliated to the radical right.

Table 2 displays the results for Germany, where Social Democrats have more clearly

remained a worker’s party than in Switzerland.

Table 2: Party preferences of post-industrial risk groups: Germany

Support for the left Support for the right

Green Party

Communist Party

Social Democrats

Union member

Christian Democrats

Moderate Right

1.183 2.763 0.614 0.278*** 2.403** 2.068 Capital accumulators (0.53) (1.98) (0.24) (0.10) (0.88) (1.14)

1.342 0.588 1.288 0.672 1.851* 1.214 Mixed service functionaries (0.52) (0.49) (0.39) (0.20) (0.60) (0.70)

1.742 3.261* 0.662 0.373*** 0.993 2.732* Socio-cultural Professionals (0.68) (2.06) (0.22) (0.12) (0.35) (1.44)

0.546 1.511 0.799 0.525* 1.886* 1.693 Low Service Functionaries (0.30) (1.02) (0.29) (0.18) (0.68) (1.07) Blue collar workers r r r r r R

0.953 3.383*** 1.301 0.725 0.401** Trade Union members (0.26) (1.36) (0.29) (0.18) (0.18)

1.244 0.626 1.052 2.070*** 1.375 0.426** Public sector employment (0.35) (0.31) (0.26) (0.48) (0.35) (0.18)

1.109 0.823** 1.054 1.128** 0.928 1.119 Income in 10 (national) deciles (0.07) (0.08) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.09)

1.275 0.996 1.096 0.732 0.506** 1.193 Gender

(0.39) (0.49) (0.29) (0.19) (0.14) (0.48) 0.069*** 0.096*** 0.257*** 0.252*** 0.531* 0.037*** Constant

(0.03) (0.06) (0.10) (0.09) (0.20) (0.02)

Observations 521.000 521.000 521.000 602.000 521.000 521.000 Pseudo Rsquare 0.04 0.08 0.02 0.06 0.03 0.06

Values in parentheses are standard errors. *** p<= 0.01 level; ** p <= 0.05 level; * p <= 0.1 level. The dependent variable corresponds to the individual vote for this party Green Party: Grüne; Communists: PDS; Social Democrats: SPD; Christian Democracy: CDU/CSU; Moderate right: FDP; Data source: ISSP 1996 Role of Government III. Question wording: "If there is a general election next Sunday, which party would you elect with your second vote?"

Page 20: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

20

Indeed, the left vote in Germany is more differentiated between the different classes

and parties: Socio-cultural professionals are clearly more likely to vote for the Green

Party and for the (eastern) communist Party PDS than blue-collar workers. The odds

are stronger in the case of the communist party, but when we look at the actual

percentages of people sympathizing with these parties, it becomes clear that the

German Green Party in is the champion of the “new left”: almost 30% of all socio-

cultural professionals chose this party vs. only about 14% of blue-collar workers (see

table TA2 in the appendix). The Green Party in Germany is clearly a party with a

rather high-skill electorate (the party also receives the support of more than 20% of

capital accumulators). The east-German PDS, a Party that advocates a strong,

universalistic welfare state, also receives support by the socio-cultural professionals

but with 6.3% mean share of the total workforce, it remains a rather minor player. The

Social Democrats SPD have – as in Switzerland - also become a party that relies on

workers and high-skilled middle-class voters, but it seems that is has kept a more

pronounced blue-collar profile: 38% of the blue-collar workers indicate the SPD as

their party of choice, as compared to only 26% of socio-cultural professionals and

about 34% of low service functionaries9. Similarly, blue-collar workers remain much

more likely to be union members than all other classes. Almost 35% of the blue-collar

workers are unionized vs. more than 10 percentage points less for all other classes. In

sum, it seems that the left-wing electorate - composed of socio-cultural professionals,

low service functionaries and blue-collar workers - is more strongly partitioned into

different parties than in Switzerland, where these classes intermix within the social

democratic party.

Finally, in France, the differences of voting behavior are not very strong and most of

them are not statistically significant, but precisely this is a very telling result: socio-

cultural professionals are just as likely to vote for the Social Democrats than blue-

collar workers, and they are 1.5 times more likely to sympathize with the Green Party.

The Greens have a very heterogeneous electorate in terms of socio-cultural

professionals, mixed and low service functionaries, but not blue-collar workers.

However, with regard to the Social Democrats and the Communist Party, the three

“left-wing constituencies” are more or less equally represented: about 43% of blue- 9 Blue-collar workers may have stayed more consistently with the Social Democrats because there is no populist right-wing alternative in Germany (Bornschier 2007).

Page 21: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

21

collar workers, low service functionaries and socio-cultural professionals choose the

Social Democrats and about 10-11% feel close to the Communist Party.

Table 3: Party preferences of post-industrial risk groups: France Support for the left Support for the right

Green Party

Communist Party

Social Democrats

Union member

Centrist Right

Moderate Right

Radical Right

1.214 0.524 0.746 0.346** 3.135** 2.247 0.504 Capital accumulators (0.88) (0.35) (0.25) -0.15 (1.50) -1.72 (0.32)

1.971 0.826 0.838 0.496* 2.086* 2.428 0.163*** Mixed service functionaries (1.20) (0.41) (0.24) -0.2 (0.90) -1.69 (0.10)

1.583 0.457 1.020 1.771 2.054 2.811 0.178*** Socio-cultural Professionals (1.01) (0.24) (0.30) -0.64 (0.92) -1.97 (0.12)

3.475* 1.065 0.795 0.969 1.584 0.274* Low Service Functionaries (2.35) (0.63) (0.29) -0.47 (0.83) (0.20) Blue collar workers r r r r r r

0.920 3.246*** 1.315 0.283*** 1.396 0.496 Trade Union members (0.38) (1.18) (0.29) (0.12) (0.62) (0.32)

1.746* 1.879* 1.582** 4.556*** 0.637* 0.329*** 1.392 Public sector employment (0.59) (0.66) (0.29) (1.02) (0.16) (0.14) (0.58)

1.069 0.891 1.028 1.354*** 1.046 1.261 0.709** Income in 10 (national) deciles (0.15) (0.13) (0.08) (0.13) (0.10) (0.19) (0.12)

0.899 1.082 0.823 0.710 1.318 1.449 0.796 Gender

(0.33) (0.40) (0.17) (0.18) (0.34) (0.54) (0.40) 0.029*** 0.093*** 0.487** 0.041*** 0.102*** 0.014*** 0.587 Constant

(0.02) (0.06) (0.17) (0.02) (0.05) (0.01) (0.38)

Observations 614 614 614 653 614 555 614 Pseudo Rsquare 0.02 0.07 0.02 0.17 0.06 0.06 0.11

Values in parentheses are standard errors. *** p<= 0.01 level; ** p <= 0.05 level; * p <= 0.1 level. The dependent variable corresponds to the individual vote for this party Green Party: Verts; Communist Party: PCF; Social Democrats: PSF; Centrist right: UDF; Moderate right: RPR; Radical right: FN; Data source: ISSP 1996 Role of Government III. Question wording: "Which political party of movement do you feel close to?"

Interestingly, the French unions enjoy more support among the socio-cultural

professionals than among workers. Over 35% of the former say they are member of a

trade union as compared to only about 20% of blue-collar workers. This result reflects

the specific structure of the weak French labor movement system, which is

fragmented in a high number of unions with a specific occupational profile. In sum,

the French left is a very heterogeneous conglomerate of different classes.

Page 22: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

22

Most striking, however, is the strong support of blue-collar workers for the radical

right, the French National Front. Nearly 18% of blue-collar workers, as compared to

only 3% of socio-cultural professionals feel close to Le Pen’s Party. This is even

stronger than the working-class support for the radical right in Switzerland. This

tendency of working-class voters to sympathize with the right-wing anti-immigrant,

anti-women and anti-egalitarian parties tends to confirm the hypothesis that blue-

collar workers interested defend their privileges against new groups of potential

welfare beneficiaries (Rueda 2007, Häusermann and Walter 2008).

Overall, tables 1 to 3 clearly show that left-wing parties are not strongholds of the

blue-collar, low-skill and low-income working class anymore. Low service

functionaries and socio-cultural professionals – classes, which include large number

of middle-class voters, women, atypically employed and public sector employees –

have emerged as equally important constituencies. Hence, the electorate of the left has

become very heterogeneous. Its different segments are either partitioned on different

left-wing parties – Greens, Social Democrats, Communists –, or they mingle within

the social democratic movement.

I argue that the heterogeneity of the left-wing electorate confronts these parties with

considerable challenges, because the constituent classes have very different profiles in

terms of preferences and values. They want different things and sometimes, their

interests are even antagonistic. This is what I show in the next step.

Figures 2 to 4 display post-industrial classes and trade union members in the two-

dimensional policy space, which today characterizes western Democracies (Kitschelt

1994, Kriesi et al. 2006). The horizontal axis represents the economic cleavage,

measuring values with regard to state interventionism vs. liberalism. The vertical axis

measures values on the libertarianism-traditionalism dimension10.

10 The measurement of both axes relies on attitudinal data form the ISSP 1996 survey. The operationalization follows Kitschelt and Rehm (2005). The libertarianism – traditionalism dimension displays the results of a factor analysis (one analysis per country, all unidimensional, EV between 1.66 and 1.73) based on the following three variables: • V25: „Listed below are various areas of government spending. Please show whether you would

like to see more or less govenrment spending in each area. Remember that if you say „much more“, it might require a tax increase to pay for it. More or less government spending for : the environment.“

Page 23: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

23

• V28: As above, but „More or less government spending for: education.“ • V32: As above, but „More or less government spending for: culture and the arts.“ The Interventionism – Liberalism dimension displays the results of a factor analysis (one analysis per country, all unidimensional, EV between 3.1-4.1) based on the following ten variables: • V16: „What is your opinion on the following statement: It is the responsibility of the government

to reduce the differences in income between people with high incomes and those with low incomes.“

• V20: „Here are some things the government might do for the economy. Please show which actions you are in favour of and which you are against. Government action for the economy: Government financing of projects to create new jobs.“

• V23: As above, but „Government action for the economy: Support for declining industries to protect jobs. (F: Support industries in difficulties)“

• V24: As above, but „Government action for the economy: Reducing the working week to create more jobs.“

• V36: „On the whole, do you think it should be or should not be the government’s responsibility to: Provide jobs for everyone who wants one.“

• V38: As above, but „Provide health care for the sick.“ • V39: As above, but „Provide a decent standard of living for the old.“ • V41: As above, but „Provide a decent standard of living for the unemployed.“ • V42: As above, but „Reduce income differences between the rich and the poor.“ • V44: As above, but „Provide decent housing for those who can’t afford it.“

Page 24: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

24

The similarity of the location of classes in the policy-space across the three countries

is striking, and the evidence largely confirms our expectations. Three observations are

particularly relevant for our analysis: Firstly, the policy space in all three countries is

clearly two-dimensional, and the left-wing constituencies spread considerably across

this space: not only do they differ in their libertarian-traditionalist value profiles, but

Page 25: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

25

they also diverge with regard to their attitudes on state interventionism. Secondly, In

all countries, the socio-cultural professionals – as the most pronounced “new left”-

constituency – position themselves more strongly to the right than blue-collar

workers, low service functionaries and trade union members. Voters of the new left

are less supportive of the traditional forms of government intervention than the lower-

skilled classes. Thirdly, the most striking finding in figures 2 to 4 is the clear-cut and

strong antagonism between the libertarian value-profile of the socio-cultural

professionals and the traditionalist stance of the blue-collar workers. This means that

the two classes that represent the main electoral basis of the very same left diverge

completely when it comes to their value-profile. Libertarians favor individual self-

expression, (gender) equality, equal opportunities in terms of education etc, whereas

traditionalists value social order and stratification, traditional family structures and the

family/community rather than the individual. However, do these value differences

matter for welfare politics? I contend that they do, and increasingly so. Issues of

gender equality, societal modernization or the valorization of female labor become

more and more important in welfare state reforms (Bonoli 2005, Häusermann 2007).

Hence, the libertarian-authoritarian value-antagonism indeed influences the alliances

and policy-options the left can pursue, even in pension reforms, as will be shown in

the following section.

3.2. Conflict lines and political exchange in continental pension reforms

I suggest that the heterogeneity of their electorate becomes both a liability and an

opportunity for the left-wing parties in policy reforms. It may become a liability, if the

parties have to make difficult choices, privileging some constituencies over others. It

may also become an opportunity in terms of reform capacity, because the diversity

and the breadth of the interests of their electorate allow the left-wing parties to draft

new compromises and participate in a genuine restructuring of the welfare state,

rather than remaining in a purely defensive position, trying to avoid retrenchment.

The new role of the left in the formation of reform compromises appears clearly in the

major reforms of all three countries, Switzerland, Germany and France. In all cases of

reforms, the left was split in the reform-process, some left-wing actors supporting the

reform package and others rejecting it. In most cases, the position of the actors can be

Page 26: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

26

explained with reference to their electoral and membership basis, but strategic and

institutional considerations also play a role.

The Swiss reform of the occupational pension scheme in 2003 was an ambiguous

agreement (Palier 2005) that included very different reform elements. On the one

hand, mandatory occupational pension coverage should be extended to new risk

groups, mostly women and part-time employees. Also, gender equality was at stake

with the introduction of a widower’s pension along the lines of the widow’s pension.

And finally, the reform proposal included benefit retrenchment for all insured,

through a lowering of pension levels, more modest pension indexation and cutbacks

in widow’s pensions. This package thus comprised different elements that catered to

very different interests and constituencies. Therefore, it is not surprising that the

different reform elements divided the involved actors along several dimensions of

conflict. Table 4 displays the results of the factor analysis performed on the coded

actor positions. The two factors show that the alignment of actors with regard to the

first factor (recalibration, the expansive issues) differed strongly from the

configuration of supporters and opponents on the second factor (retrenchment).

Table 4: Switzerland, factor analysis on the 1st reform of the occupational pension

scheme BVG 2003

Issues of the reform debate Recalibration

(F1) Retrenchment

(F2) Lowering of access threshold for occupational pensions 0.819 0.326 Special conditions for part-time workers 0.919 0.149 Introduction of widowers' pension 0.827 0.144 Ceiling of insurable income 0.787 0.376 Cuts in the level of benefits 0.243 0.826 Increase of the retirement age 0.189 0.853 Eigenvalues 2.913 1.702 explained variance 0.490 0.280 Factor analysis run on the coded positions of the actors; all factors with Eigenvalue >=1; Varimax rotation;

The two-dimensional space emerging from the factor analysis can be displayed

graphically, and all actors can be located within that space on the basis of their factor

scores. Thereby, it is possible to position the actors on both dimensions and to show

the formation of the relevant alliances. Our focus in figure 5 is on the final reform-

Page 27: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

27

coalition that adopted the reform. All actors included in the ellipse eventually gave

their support to the reform package. As can easily be seen, the left was split.

The Green party, womens’ organizations, the Social Democratic party, and some

moderate trade unions (the CNG and the white collar union (VSA) representing a

particularly large female workforce) formed the recalibrating pole of the conflict. For

those actors, the objective of including part-time workers and women in the

occupational pension scheme became a priority, not least in terms of gender

equality11. They even accepted to support the whole reform package, including the

retrenchment elements, in order to pass the reform and save the extension of the

occupational pension scheme to new risk groups. For the blue-collar trade unions, by

contrast, the cutbacks were unacceptable. The main trade union SGB and the VPOD

refused the pension cuts categorically, and they rejected the whole reform package.

For them, the extension of insurance coverage to part-time workers and mostly female

low-income workers did not make up for the lowering of their own benefits.

11 Interviews FDP and SPS (Gutzwiller and Rechsteiner, both members of the parliamentary committee in charge of the 2003 reform of the second tier pension scheme), June 6th, 2002, Bern.

Page 28: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

28

Hence, the reform was eventually enacted by a very large and heterogeneous majority

of left-wing parties, moderate trade unions, employers and conservative parties. The

reform was a typical example of an “ambiguous agreement”, as described by Palier

(2005): different actors agree on a reform for very different reasons. The parties of the

new left and women’s organizations accepted the reforms for the recalibrating

aspects, since they were very important to the interests and libertarian values of their

electorate. Strongly feminized classes such as socio-cultural professionals or low

service functionaries outnumber the blue-collar workers in the ranks of the left-wing

parties, and therefore the expansive aspects of the reform were privileged over the

cutbacks. The right-wing parties and employers’ organizations, by contrast, supported

the reform in order to implement retrenchment of benefits. By means of this package,

they managed to construct the large majority that is necessary for reforms in the

consensual Swiss political system.

In Germany, the left-wing parties were themselves in government when they proposed

and implemented the 2001 pension reform, a system change that transformed the

pension scheme from a single-tier public PAYG-scheme to a multipillar regime,

including a means-tested basic minimum pension, a public pension insurance pillar,

and a private capitalized pension savings scheme. Thereby the red-green government

proposed a reform that included – as in Switzerland – both cutbacks and expansive

elements: the minimum pension is an expansive reforms that benefits mostly to those

groups who are punished by the insurance-system, i.e. people with interrupted and

incomplete contribution records, atypically and precariously employed, many of them

women. Along with the minimum pension were also introduced several elements that

benefit mostly to women (educational pension credits, splitting of benefits). The

introduction of capitalized pensions – with strong state subsidies for savers - is also an

expansive reform, which focuses mostly on the middle-and higher income-classes,

who can afford saving for their own pensions. The third axis of reform, however, a

drastic retrenchment of public pension levels, mainly cut back the benefits of the old

working class, whose members are too rich to need minimum assistance, but too poor

to save on their own. These very different reform elements again gave rise to a multi-

dimensional policy space. Table 5 shows the results of the factor analysis:

Page 29: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

29

recalibration, retrenchment and capitalization divided the actors in clearly distinct

ways.

Table 5: Germany, factor analysis of the reform of the German pension system 2001

Issues of the reform debate Recalibration

(F1) Retrenchment

(F2) Capitalization

(F3) Individualization of poverty relief 0.865 0.172 -0.051 Universal minimum pension 0.744 0.045 -0.231 Increase of educational pension credits 0.682 0.446 0.27 Splitting of benefits and contributions between spouses 0.872 -0.164 0.103 Lowering of widows' pension rights -0.165 0.926 -0.161 Cuts in the level of pension benefits 0.305 0.912 0.0013 Individual private and occupational pension savings plans -0.047 -0.97 0.948 Eigenvalue 2.649 1.956 1.064 explained variance 38% 28% 15% Factor analysis run on the coded positions of the actors; all factors with Eigenvalue >= 1; Varimax rotation;

I can only represent two dimensions meaningfully in figure 6. Therefore, this figure

shows the configuration of actors with regard to recalibration and retrenchment.

Actors within the ellipse – except for the FDP - supported the reform in the final vote.

Page 30: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

30

Once again and as expected, the Green Party turns out as the most ferocious advocate

of recalibration. The SPD took a more favorable position on recalibration than the

average union. However, the Green Party and the Social Democrats had shifted

considerably to the right with regard to the retrenchment dimension and advocated

heavy cuts. This led to a clear rift between the unions and the left-wing parties over

the cutbacks. Figure 6 also shows that the Christian Democrats (CDU/CSU), family

organizations, and the small business employers advocated conservative reforms on

recalibration. Indeed, the red-green government created incentives for mothers to

remain active in the labor force. The conservative actors rejected this dimension of the

reform, because it would call into question the traditional organization of families.

The Green Party and the employers clearly approved of the reform package, whereas

some trade unions (IG Metall, DGB), the welfare organizations of the civil society,

and the PDS rejected it. In between are the unions DAG, and IG Chemie, which

criticized retrenchment heavily, but eventually did not mobilize against the reform.

The SDP approved of the reform, but it was internally split. Finally, for the employers

(such as BDA), the reform was acceptable, because the savings it entailed outweighed

the costs implied by recalibration. Indeed, the main employers organization, the BDA,

stated that the recalibrating elements were “absolutely plausible” (“durchaus

nachvollziehbar”12).

Again, we can make much sense of these party positions when looking at their

electorates and constituencies. The blue-collar trade unions could not agree on the

reform, because their constituencies were clearly the main losers of the reforms.

White-collar unions with more skilled members (IG Chemie) or more female

members (DAG), by contrast, could also refer to the expansive reform elements as a

(partial) compensation of the cutbacks. Similarly, the Green Party, which is only

marginally rooted in the blue-collar workforce, privileged recalibration and

capitalization over retrenchment. The only puzzle is the position of the SPD, who still

represents a large and strong blue-collar constituency. Indeed, the party was deeply

torn on the reform between their “old” and “new” left wings. At the time of the

reform, the “new left” elite, who wished to become more attractive to the new middle-

classes, prevailed in the government. But eventually, these reforms led to an

12 Written statement of the BDA in the public hearing before the parliamentary committee, 8.12.2000, Ausschussdrucksache 14/1090: p. 196.

Page 31: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

31

alienation of the blue-collar workers from the SPD and to the formation of a new left-

wing alternative, the “Linkspartei” (Picot 2008).

For the case of France, we look at the 2003 pension reform that was proposed and

implemented by the conservative Raffarin-government. Again, it included a range of

very different reform elements. On the one hand, the government proposed to lower

the indexation of pensions and widow’s pensions in the main public pension pillar. On

the other hand, it also included expansive elements, such as an increase in the

minimum pension, more generous pensions for workers with long and precarious

careers, the increase of educational pension benefits for public servants and –

similarly to Germany – the introduction of individual capitalized pension savings

plans. In addition, the reform proposal also included a certain harmonization of

benefits in the public and private sectors. Again, the diversity of these elements

divided the actors along three distinct dimensions of conflict, as seen in Table 6.

Table 6: France, factor analysis on the "Raffarin" pension reform 2003

Issues of the reform debate

Recalibration/ Capitalization

(F1) Retrenchment

(F2)

Educational pension

credits (F3) Harmonization of the required contribution periods in public/private sectors 0.909 0.247 0.041 Lowering of retirement age for long career workers 0.838 0.225 0.386 Individual pension savings plans 0.829 0.367 -0.173 Increase of minimum pension 0.786 0.177 0.518 Lowering of widows' pensions 0.488 0.82 0.224 Indexation of pensions on prices 0.195 0.946 0.19 Increase of educational pension credits for civil servants 0.073 0.216 0.932 Eigenvalues 3.11 1.89 1.4 explained variance 44% 27% 20% Principal component factor analysis run on the coded positions of the actors; all factors with Eigenvalue >=1; Varimax rotation;

A first factor is composed by elements of recalibration and capitalization, whereas the

second factor represents the configuration of opponents and supporters with regard to

retrenchment. Finally, educational pension credits do not fit in with either of the other

issue categories and form a third factor. Since the latter is a rather minor element, I

only display the first two factors in figure 7.

Page 32: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

32

On the horizontal axis, figure 7 shows the alignment of actors with regard to the

cutbacks of benefits. The conservative parties, employers’ organizations, but also

representatives of the Socialist Party stressed the need for “financial consolidation” of

the pension scheme. The turn of the French Socialist to more right-wing positions on

pension cutbacks may be related to the fact that they mobilize equally well within the

new middle-class (socio-cultural professionals) than within the blue-collar workers.

The trade unions, however, were all similarly opposed to the cutbacks, defending the

main public pension insurance regime. However, the left became deeply divided on

the second axis, relative to recalibration (e.g. minimum pensions) and capitalization

(individual pension savings plans): while the old blue-collar union CGT and the

French Communist Party rejected these reform elements, more moderate trade unions

such as CFDT and CGC were much more in favor of these reforms. The distinct

profile of their membership explains this divergence: CFDT mobilizes strongly in the

service sector, with white-collar and female workers. And CGC is a rather high-skill

union of service and public sector workers. These constituencies belonged to the

beneficiaries of the expansive reform elements, while the traditional blue-collar

Page 33: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

33

constituencies did not. Hence, CFDT and CGC accepted a reorientation of the system

towards a more redistributive and targeted coverage of particular risk groups, such as

low-income workers, and a more egalitarian benefit structure between public and

private sectors. Thereby, the conservative government was able to divide the labor

movement on this reform, compensating the CGC and CFDT for the cutbacks. By

mitigating the labor protests against the reform, it could be implemented with the

support of a heterogeneous cross-class coalition.

One word needs to be added with regard to the interpretation of the location of the

Communist and Socialist Parties. Both represent blue-collar constituencies as well as

more middle-class voters, but remained firmly opposed to the reform, even though

part of their electorate could have benefited from it. Their opposition must, however,

also be seen in the light of the French majoritarian institutional framework:

Opposition parties consequently have to oppose all policies proposed by the

government, regardless of the reform content. Hence, the exclusion of the left-wing

parties from the reform-coalition is partly an effect of institutions and electoral

strategies, rather than of interest-representation.

In sum, the policy reform space in all three countries has clearly become

multidimensional. In addition, the left was split on the reform packages in all

countries. To a large extent, this split seems to coincide with the heterogeneity of

interests and constituencies that the different left-wing political parties and trade

unions represent. All Social Democratic and Green parties have become more open to

benefit cutbacks, a finding that coincides with the increasingly middle-class profile of

their voters. In addition, they privilege reform elements, which focus on new risk

groups, women, atypical workers, part-time employees or – with regard to

capitalization – middle-and higher income-classes. Depending on the set-up of the

reform package, these concerns outweigh the interests of their “old” constituency, the

blue-collar workers. Trade unions – especially in Switzerland and Germany – remain

more close to the interest of the standard male industrial worker, but the interests of

different unions have also become heterogeneous and in each of the three reforms

analyzed, parts of the trade unions have participated in the reform-coalitions.

Page 34: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

34

Conclusion

In this contribution, I showed that recent welfare state reforms in Switzerland,

Germany and France were the result of carefully drafted reform packages, which

comprise several dimensions of reform and conflict. Governments tied packages

including both pension benefit retrenchment and expansion, thereby splitting the left,

and constructing the required majorities for reform. In this interpretation, I agree with

the recent literature that explains welfare reforms as “modernizing reforms”,

“virtuous” compromises or strategies of political exchange (Levy 1999, Bonoli 2001,

2005, Natali and Rhodes 2004b). However, I argued in this paper that these reform-

packages are not arbitrarily designed by heroic governments or by strategic policy

entrepreneurs. Rather, they are linked to the interests and values of party and trade

union constituencies. Governments do not primarily succeed in implementing reforms

by framing retrenchment as necessary, by convincing voters of the needs for cutbacks,

by hiding reform consequences, or by constructing “virtuous” reforms that avoid any

distributional conflicts. Rather, they cut back benefits for some constituencies but not

for others, and they grant new benefits to clearly identifiable constituencies: there is a

socio-structural basis to the positions political actors take in the policy space and to

the kind of compromises they are willing to participate in.

In the Swiss case, the Social Democrats, Green Parties and some white collar and

service sector-trade unions participated in a reform that granted occupational pension

coverage to women and part-time workers, while at the same time cutting back the

benefits in the standard insurance scheme. In Germany, the red-green government

devised a reform which improves pension rights for the most precarious risk groups

(women, atypically employed, people with incomplete contribution records) and the

middle- and higher income levels (through capitalization), while cutting back pension

entitlements of the standard (middle-class) workers. And in France, white-collar,

high-skill and service-sector unions supported a reform by the conservative

government, which included expansive elements for a more needs-based system with

a complement of private pension savings, while cutting back benefit levels in the main

public pension insurance scheme. In each case, the positions of the left-wing actors

supporting the reform-packages can be related to the changing socio-structural basis

of these actors. In Switzerland, Germany and France, the left today relies as much on

socio-cultural professionals and low service functionaries than on the blue-collar

Page 35: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

35

workforce. These new constituencies include middle-class and high-skilled workers,

many women, most of them part-time or atypically employed, and public sector

workers. They have different interests and different values than the old working class,

and they do not belong to the range of core beneficiaries of the old insurance welfare

state. Hence, when confronted with the choice between the defense of the status quo

and a restructuring of the pension regime, they may privilege the latter, and so do

(part of) their representatives in the policy-making process.

In the theoretical part of this paper, I have argued that all four existing explanations of

the “unfreezing” of continental welfare states leave important questions unanswered.

In conclusion, I would like to propose an answer to these questions from the

perspective I have developed in this contribution. Firstly, the obfuscation argument

cannot explain why governments can “hide” retrenchment. Why are there no

opposition parties, no media, no trade unions or independent experts spelling out the

distributional implications of the reforms publicly? Similarly, the framing argument

implies that governments convince voters of the necessity of retrenchment. But it

lacks a theorization of the responses of those to whom this discourse is directed. Why

would the “losers” of reforms adhere to such a discourse? And why would the same

discourse convince such a diversity of addressees? My answer to both questions is

similar: voters are neither blind, nor ignorant or easy to convince: quite contrarily, the

collective actors and the voters do understand the distributional implications of the

reforms. However, the reforms do not include retrenchment only, and the cutbacks

included in the reforms do not hurt all voters equally. Rather, the reforms have

different distributional implications for different groups of voters, and pension politics

is more about power than about discourse. Overall, the old beneficiaries of the

industrial welfare state are among the main losers of recent pension restructuring. But

many new risk groups, women, middle- and higher income earners tend to see their

pension rights stabilized or even improved. For them, the expansive elements

outweigh the cutbacks, and this accounts for the formation of (very heterogeneous)

coalitions supporting these reforms.

The “Nixon goes to China”-argument may successfully explain why some left-wing

governments could afford taking some blame for retrenchment, but it has no

explanation as to the actual motivations of these governments to retrench or

Page 36: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

36

restructure. Why would Social Democrats cut back pensions? Similarly, the package-

deal literature does not answer the question how governments, who draft modernizing

compromises can gain the necessary majorities for their reforms. My answer lies in

the transformed electoral basis of these parties and in the distributional consequences

of their reforms. Left-wing governments do retrench existing benefits, because the

beneficiaries of the status quo are not their only, and in some countries not even their

most important constituency anymore. The new left-wing electorate may even be

penalized by the old “industrial” PAYG-insurance scheme (many women and service-

sector workers do not have complete contribution-periods), or it may simply be more

interested in certain forms of private savings (as for the middle- and higher income

classes). Hence, for the new constituencies of the left, it may make sense to

restructure the pension regime, transforming it from a public “bismarckian” insurance

scheme into a multi-pillar system combining minimum-rights, public insurance and

private capitalization. In addition, the new left electorate holds strongly libertarian

values, which collide with the industrial insurance scheme that privileges the male

standard worker and stable family relations. Gender equality in the pension scheme, a

more egalitarian benefit structure, or targeted benefits for new risk groups are

important demands for these constituencies.

This reasoning implies that the post-industrial welfare state that emerges from the

reforms of the last decades may differ from the old industrial welfare state not

primarily for functionalist (problem-pressure) or ideological reasons (neoliberalism),

but rather because the post-industrial society is different from the industrial society.

Socio-structural change affects political parties and interest organizations, and thereby

it affects policy-making. This is why I would argue that welfare state research needs

to pay more attention to electoral and socio-structural dynamics, which have so far

been mainly the subject of other research fields such as party system research or class

analysis. To be clear, the positions of political parties and interest organizations

cannot be inferred directly from the preferences and values of their constituencies.

This transmission is both imperfect and bi-directional. However, if we neglect the

socio-structural foundations of collective interest representation, we may develop a

conceptualization of policy-making that becomes too voluntaristic and detached from

actual societal change.

Page 37: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

37

Appendix

Figure A1: Classification of occupations in post-industrial class groups

based on Kitschelt and Rehm (2005: 23

Independent work

logicTechnical work logic

Organizational work

logic

Interpersonal work

logic

Technical experts

(CA) 21 Physical, mathematical

and engineering science

professionals

Higher-grade

managers (CA) 11 Legislators and Senior

officials

12 Corporate Managers

Professional/

managerial

Technicians (MSF) 31 Physical and

engineering science

associate professionals

Associate managers

(CA) 13 General Managers

Associate

professonal /

managerial

Petty bourgeoisie

without employees

(MSF) Self-employed >24

Skilled crafts (BC) 71 Extraction and building

trades workers

72 Metal, machinery and

related trades workers

73 Precision, handicraft,

printing and related trades

workers

74 Other craft and related

trades workers

Generally /

vocationally

skilled

Routine operatives

and routine

agriculture (BC) 61 Market-oriented skilled

agricultural and fishery

workers

92 Agricultural, fishery and

related laborers

81 Stationary-plant and

related operators

82 Machine operators and

assemblers

83 Drivers and mobile-

plant operators

93 Laborers in mining,

construction, manufacturing

and transport

Low/ un-skilled

Two-digit numbers in front of job descriptions are ISCO88-2d codes.

Socio-cultural semi-

professonals (SCP) 22 Life science and health

professionals

23 Teaching professionals

24 Other professionals

32 Life science and health

associate professionals

33 teaching associate

professionals

34 Other associate

professionals

Large employers, self-

employed

professionals and petty

bourgeoisie with

employees (CA) Self-employed <=24

Skilled office workers

and routine office

workers (MSF) 41 Office Clerks

42 Customer Service Clerks

Skilled service and

routine service (LSF) 51 Personal and protective

services workers

52 Models, salespersons and

demonstrators

91 Sales and services

elementary occupations

Page 38: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

38

Green

Party

Social

Democrats

TU

member

Christian

Democracy

Moderate

right

Radical

right

Capital accumulators 9.59% 35.62% 13.07% 8.22% 28.77% 17.81%

Mixed service functionaries 6.59% 32.97% 15.84% 13.19% 23.63% 23.63%

Socio-cultural professionals 7.59% 51.79% 25.84% 14.29% 16.96% 9.38%

Low service functionaries 10.67% 42.67% 16.67% 10.67% 24.00% 12.00%

Blue collar workers 6.12% 38.78% 27.08% 21.43% 11.22% 22.45%

Mean share in workforce 7.67% 41.72% 20.69% 13.96% 20.09% 16.56%

Number of observations 652 652 1634 652 652 652

Data source: ISSP 1996 Role of Government III. Question wording: "Generally, do you feel

affiliated or sympathize with a specific political party (without necessarily being a member)?"

Green Party: GPS, GB; Social Democrats: SPS; Christian Democracy: CVP, EVP, CSP; Moderate

right: FDP, LdU, LPS; Radical right: SVP, FPS, SD, Lega;

TA1: Party vote shares of post-industrial classes: Switzerland

Support for the left Support for the right

Notes: Values are the percentage of people in a particular class choosing this party / being a union

member (among the respondents who indicated a party preference).

Support for the right

Green

Party

Communist

Party

Social

Democrats

Union

member

Christian

Democrats

Moderate

Right

Capital accumulators 21.31% 5.46% 19.67% 15.94% 40.98% 12.57%

Mixed service functionaries 16.67% 5.24% 27.14% 21.79% 38.57% 12.38%

Socio-cultural Professionals 29.65% 8.41% 26.11% 24.39% 23.89% 11.95%

Low Service Functionaries 12.10% 6.45% 33.87% 22.58% 39.52% 8.06%

Blue collar workers 13.88% 6.05% 38.08% 34.78% 35.23% 6.76%

Mean share in workforce 19.04% 6.35% 29.39% 25.18% 34.96% 10.25%

Number of observations 1024 1024 1024 822 1024 1024

Data source: ISSP 1996 Role of Government III. Question wording: "If there is a general

election next Sunday, which party would you elect with your second vote?"

Support for the left

Table TA2: Party vote shares of post-industrial classes: Germany

Notes: Values are the percentage of people in a particular class choosing this party / being a

union member (among the respondents who indicated a party preference).

Green Party: Grüne; Communists: PDS; Social Democrats: SPD; Christian Democracy:

CDU/CSU; Moderate right: FDP;

Page 39: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

39

Green

Party

Communist

Party

Social

Democrats

Union

member

Centrist

Right

Moderate

Right

Radical

Right

Capital accumulators 4.91% 4.91% 35.58% 16.75% 17.18% 28.22% 9.20%

Mixed service functionaries 9.22% 9.71% 42.23% 13.85% 11.65% 21.84% 5.34%

Socio-cultural Professionals 8.76% 10.36% 43.82% 35.40% 13.94% 19.92% 3.19%

Low Service Functionaries 10.84% 9.64% 42.17% 12.61% 9.64% 19.28% 8.43%

Blue collar workers 3.70% 11.85% 42.96% 19.19% 7.41% 16.30% 17.78%

Mean share in workforce 7.52% 9.31% 41.53% 21.22% 12.53% 21.36% 7.76%

Number of observations 838 839 840 1037 844 845 846

Table TA3: Party vote shares of post-industrial classes: France

Support for the right

Data source: ISSP 1996 Role of Government III. Question wording: "Which political party of movement do you feel

close to?"

Notes: Values are the percentage of people in a particular class choosing this party / being a union member (among

the respondents who indicated a party preference).

Green Party: Verts; Communist Party: PCF; Social Democrats: PSF; Centrist right: UDF; Moderate right: RPR;

Radical right: FN;

Support for the left

Page 40: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

40

References Anderson, Karen M. and Julia Lynch (forthcoming). “Internal Institutions and the

Policy Preferences of Organized Labor: The Effects of Workforce Ageing on Union Support for Pension Reform”, Comparative Politics.

Bonoli, Giuliano (2000). The Politics of Pension Reform. Institutions and Policy Change in Western Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Bonoli, Giuliano (2001). “Political Institutions, Veto Points, and the Process of Welfare State Adaptation”, in Paul Pierson (ed.). The New Politics of the Welfare State. Oxford University Press.

Bonoli, Giuliano (2005). „The Politics of the new social policies: providing coverage against new social risks in mature welfare states“, Policy and Politics, 33(3): 431-449.

Bonoli, Giuliano and Bruno Palier (2007). “When Past Reforms Open New Opportunities: Comparing Old-age Insurance Reforms in Bismarckian Welfare Systems“, Social Policy and Administration 41(6): 555-579.

Bornschier, Simon (2007). The transformation of historical cleavages and the rise of right-wing populist parties in Western Europe. Ph.D. thesis, University of Zurich, Switzerland.

Busemeyer, Marius R. (2005). “Pension Reform in Germany and Austria: System Change vs. Quantitative Retrenchment”, West European Politics, 28(3): 569-591.

Chulià, E. (2002). „Pension Reforms in Christian Democratic Welfare Regimes“, Paper prepared for the 30th ECPR Joint Sessions, 6-11 April 2001, Turin.

Ebbinghaus, Bernhard (2006). „Trade union movements in post-industrial welfare states: opening up to new social interests?“, in Klaus Armingeon and Giuliano Bonoli (eds.). The Politics of Post-Industrial Welfare States. Adapting post-war policies to new social risks. London: Routledge.

Esping-Andersen, Gösta (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.

Esping-Andersen, Gösta (1996). “Welfare States without Work: The Impasse of Labour Shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social Policy”, in Gösta Esping-Andersen (ed.). Welfare States in Transition: National Adaptations in Global Economies. London: Sage.

Green-Pedersen, Christoffer (2002) The Politics of Justification: Party Competition and Welfare-State Retrenchment in Denmark and the Netherlands from 1982 to 1998. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.

Häusermann, Silja (2007). “Modernization in Hard Times. Post-Industrial Pension Politics in Germany, France and Switzerland”, Ph.D. thesis, University of Zurich.

Häusermann, Silja and Stefanie Walter (2008). “Restructuring Swiss welfare politics: post-industrial labor markets, globalization and attitudes towards social policy”, in Simon Hug and Hanspeter Kriesi (eds.). World Value Change in Switzerland. Zurich, unpublished manuscript.

Hering, Martin (2004). “Turning Ideas into Policies: Implementing Modern Social Democratic Thinking in Germany’s Pension Policy.”, in Giuliano Bonoli and Martin Powell (eds.). Social Democratic Party Policies in Contemporary Europe. London: Routledge.

Page 41: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

41

Huber, Evelyne and John D. Stephens (2001). Development and Crisis of the Welfare State. Parties and Policies in Global Markets. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

Kitschelt, Herbert (1994). The Transformation of European Social Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Kitschelt, Herbert and Philip Rehm (2005). „Work, Family and Politics. Foundations of Electoral Partisan Alignments in Postindustrial Democracies“, Paper perpared for delivery at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C., September 1-4,l 2005.

Kriesi, Hanspeter (1998b). The transformation of cleavage politics – The 1997 Stein Rokkan Lecture“, European Journal of Political Research, 33(2): 165-188.

Kriesi, Hanspeter (1999). “Movements of the Left, Movements of the Right: Putting the Mobilization of Two New Types of Social Movements into Political Context", in Herbert Kitschelt, Peter Lange, Gary Marks, John D. Stephens (eds.). Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Levy, Jonah (1999). “Vice into Virtue? Progressive Politics and Welfare Reform in Continental Europe”, Politics and Society, 27(2): 239-273.

Levy, Jonah (2001). “Partisan politics and welfare adjustment: the case of France”, Journal of European Public Policy 8(2): 265-285.

Lijphart, Arendt (1999). Patterns of Democracy. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.

Natali, David and Martin Rhodes (2004). “Trade-offs and Veto Players: Reforming Pensions in France and Italy”, French Politics 2(1): 1-23.

Natali, David and Martin Rhodes (2004b). “The ‘New Politics’ of the Bismarckian Welfare State: Pension Reforms in Continental Europe”, EUI Working Paper SPS No. 2004/10.

Nullmeier, Frank und Friedbert W. Rüb (1993). Die Transformation der Sozialpolitik. Vom Sozialstaat zum Sicherungsstaat. Frankfurt a.M.: Campus.

Oesch, Daniel (2006). Redrawing the Class Map: Stratification and Institutions in Germany, Britain, Sweden and Switzerland. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

Palier, Bruno (2002). Gouverner la sécurité sociale. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.

Palier, Bruno (2005). „Ambiguous Agreement, Cumulative Change: French Social Policy in the 1990s“, in Wolfgang Streeck and Kathleen Thelen (eds.). Beyond Continuity. Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.

Picot, Georg (2008). “Party Competition and Unemployment Benefits in Germany: How a Small Change in Electoral Demand Can Make a Big Difference”, Paper prepared for ESPAnet Doctoral Researcher Workshop, University of Bologna-Forlì, June 5-7, 2008.

Pierson, Paul (1994). Dismantling the Welfare State? Reagan, Thatcher, and the Politics of Retrenchment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Pierson, Paul (1996). „The New Politics of the Welfare State“, World Politics 48(2): 143-179.

Pierson, Paul (2000). “Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics”, American Political Science Review 94, 2: 251-267.

Page 42: What explains the „unfreezing“ of continental European ... · 1. Theoretical framework: Four explanations of the unfreezing of continental welfare states All four existing explanations

42

Pierson, Paul (2001). „Coping with Permanent Austerity: Welfare State Restructuring in Affluent Democracies“, in Paul Pierson (ed.). The New Politics of the Welfare State. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.

Rhodes, Martin (2001). „The Political Economy of Social Pacts: „Competitive Corporatism“ and European Welfare Reform“, in Paul Pierson (ed.). The New Politics of the Welfare State. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.

Ross, Fiona (2000). “’Beyond Left and Right’: The New Partisan Politics of Welfare”, Governance, 13(2): 155-183.

Rueda, David (2005). ““Insider-Outsider Politics in Industrialized Democracies: The Challenge to Social Democratic Parties”, American Political Science Review 99(1): 61-74.

Rueda, David (2007). Social Democracy Inside Out: Partisanship and Labor Market Policy in Advanced Industrialized Democracies. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.

Schludi, Martin (2005). The Reform of Bismarckian Pension Systems. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.

Stiller, Sabina (forthcoming). “Ideational Leadership and Structural Policy Change: Comparing German Welfare State Reforms”, in Michael Howlett and Giliberto Capano (eds.). The Drivers of Policy Change, European and North American Experiences. London: Routledge.

Vail, Mark I. (2004). “The Myth of the Frozen Welfare State and the Dynamics of Contemporary French and German Social-Protection Reform”, French Politics, 2: 151-183.

Vis, Barbara and Kees van Kersbergen (2007). “Why and how do political actors pursue risky reforms?”, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 19(2): 153-172.


Recommended