+ All Categories
Home > Documents > WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf ·...

WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf ·...

Date post: 12-Sep-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
40
1 WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? PALASH DEB California State University San Marcos College of Business Administration San Marcos, CA 92096-001 Phone: +1-760-750-4210 e-mail: [email protected] PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue Washington, DC 20016 Phone: +1-240-676-3236 e-mail: [email protected] JONATHAN O’BRIEN University of Nebraska-Lincoln CBA 274, P.O. Box 880491 Lincoln, NE 68588-0491 Phone: +1-402-472-2466 e-mail: [email protected] In press, Strategic Management Journal (accepted 2015-11-19)
Transcript
Page 1: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

1

WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE?

PALASH DEB California State University San Marcos

College of Business Administration San Marcos, CA 92096-001

Phone: +1-760-750-4210 e-mail: [email protected]

PARTHIBAN DAVID American University

Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

Washington, DC 20016 Phone: +1-240-676-3236

e-mail: [email protected]

JONATHAN O’BRIEN University of Nebraska-Lincoln

CBA 274, P.O. Box 880491 Lincoln, NE 68588-0491 Phone: +1-402-472-2466

e-mail: [email protected]

In press, Strategic Management Journal (accepted 2015-11-19)

Page 2: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

2

WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE?

ABSTRACT

Research Summary: Cash can create shareholder value when used for adaptation to unfolding contingencies, but can also reduce value when appropriated by other stakeholders. We synthesize arguments from the behavioral theory of the firm, economic perspectives like agency theory, and the value-creation versus value-appropriation literatures to argue that the implications of cash for firm performance are context-specific. Cash is more beneficial for firms operating in highly competitive, research-intensive, or growth-focused industries that are typical of contexts requiring adaptation in the face of uncertainties. Conversely, cash is more detrimental to performance in firms that are poorly governed, diversified, or opaque, as are typical of contexts where stakeholder conflicts, information asymmetries, or power imbalances can encourage value appropriation by other stakeholders.

Managerial Summary: Cash can create shareholder value when used for adaptation to unfolding contingencies, but can also reduce value when appropriated by other stakeholders. While cash-rich firms have higher performance on average, with those in the 75th percentile having a market-to-book value 15 percent higher than those in the 25th percentile, we find that the performance benefits of cash depend on the context. Cash is more beneficial for firms operating in highly competitive, research-intensive, or growth-focused industries that are typical of contexts requiring adaptation in the face of uncertainties. Conversely, cash is more detrimental to performance in firms that are poorly governed, diversified, or opaque, as are typical of contexts where stakeholder conflicts, information asymmetries, or power imbalances can encourage value appropriation by other stakeholders.

Keywords: Cash, behavioral theory of the firm, adaptation, information asymmetry, value creation, value appropriation.

Page 3: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

3

“Conflicts of interest between shareholders and managers over payout policies are especially severe when the organization generates substantial free cash flow. The problem is how to motivate managers to disgorge the cash rather than investing it at below the cost of capital or wasting it on organization inefficiencies” (Jensen, 1986: 323).

“I have pledged – to you, the rating agencies and myself – to always run Berkshire with more than ample cash. We never want to count on the kindness of strangers in order to meet tomorrow’s obligations.” (Warren Buffet, quoted in Bershidsky, 2014).

INTRODUCTION

Is cash good or bad for firm performance? Media reports on the large cash stockpiles of

US firms have voiced conflicting opinions about the value of holding cash. While some

commentators argue that cash reserves can help firms avert another Lehman-like crisis or match

the intensity of their rivals’ research and development (R&D) efforts, others lament how CEOs

choose to earn a negative real return on idle cash that could be more productively invested

elsewhere. Concurrently, academic researchers are also divided on the issue of the performance

implications of cash.1 While many studies show that cash improves firm performance (Daniel et

al., 2004; Kim and Bettis, 2014), several find that cash is detrimental to performance (Dittmar,

Mahrt-Smith, and Servaes, 2003; Harford, Mansi, and Maxwell, 2008), while some find an

inverted “U” shaped association (Tan and Peng, 2003).

The mixed evidence suggests that firms may differ in the extent to which cash can

enhance or reduce firm performance, implying that context may shape the performance

consequences of cash. We therefore ask the question: when does cash create value and improve

performance, and when does it lead to value appropriation and impaired performance? Our

1 A large literature in management has studied organizational slack and distinguishes between three different types, namely available slack, absorbed slack, and potential slack (Bourgeois, 1981; George, 2005; Tan and Peng, 2003). Consistent with Kim and Bettis (2014), we focus on cash, the most liquid and common form of available slack, which provides high discretion to managers to quickly deploy for adaptation, but can also be easily appropriated by stakeholders.

Page 4: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

4

findings indicate that cash is beneficial in contexts where it is used for adaptation, but its benefits

are eroded in contexts where it can be easily appropriated by other stakeholders.

Our research is grounded in three distinct but complementary perspectives. The first is

the value creation and appropriation (VCA) framework (Coff, 1999). This perspective clarifies

how valuable resources can create value, but may fail to enhance firm performance to the extent

this value is appropriated by stakeholders other than shareholders. The second perspective is

Cyert and March’s (1963) behavioral theory of the firm (BTF). According to the BTF, cash has

the potential to enhance performance by facilitating the adaptation and innovation that confer

competitive advantage and by buffering the firm from environmental turbulence. Conversely, the

BTF also recognizes the possibility that cash can be a source of slack that is ‘up for grabs’, and

powerful stakeholders (including managers) may bargain hard to appropriate the value created by

cash, thereby undermining the performance benefits. Finally, some economic perspectives also

support the idea of value creation from cash, arguing that because of inefficiencies in capital

markets, cash-rich firms may have an advantage in more quickly adapting to environmental

changes (Faulkender and Wang, 2006), thereby enhancing performance. Other economics-based

approaches, such as agency theory, argue that free cash can be dissipated by managers for private

benefit, resulting in value appropriation from cash and undermining performance (Jensen, 1986).

In this paper, we combine these three approaches (i.e., namely VCA, BTF, and economic) to

provide a framework for understanding the contexts that shape the performance effects of cash.

Our paper makes two important contributions to the literature. First, using a framework

based in current theory, it highlights the primacy of context in determining the cash-performance

relationship. Our research builds on prior work that studied contextual moderators of the cash-

performance association (Bradley, Wiklund, and Shepherd, 2011; George, 2005) by proposing a

Page 5: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

5

dichotomous typology of contexts, namely value creation and value appropriation. We show that

cash creates more value in contexts where there is greater need for adaptation to unfolding

contingencies, while value tends to be appropriated in contexts where conflict over resources,

information asymmetry, and stakeholders’ bargaining power make it easier to appropriate.

Second, we also contribute to the literature by dovetailing the VCA perspective offered

by strategy scholars with the BTF and agency approaches adopted by extant studies on cash (Tan

and Peng, 2003), and then suggesting new contextual moderators of the cash-performance

relationship. These include three value creation moderators (or contexts), namely industry

competition, industry R&D intensity, and industry growth, and three value appropriation

moderators (or contexts), namely corporate governance, diversification, and corporate opacity.

While the corporate governance context for cash has been employed in some prior studies

(Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith, 2007; O’Brien and Folta, 2009), we put it into perspective by

situating it within a broader framework of contextual factors that promote either enhanced value

creation or stakeholder value appropriation.

Our empirical results show strong support for our hypotheses. We find that cash enhances

firm performance in all three value creation contexts, but that the benefits of cash are attenuated

in all three value appropriation contexts. These results contribute to the management literature by

showing how the VCA, BTF, and economic frameworks can be usefully integrated to better

understand the contingencies that determine when cash is good or bad for firm performance.

THEORY AND HYPOTHESES

Value Creation from Cash: Behavioral and Economic Approaches

The BTF posits that slack creates firm value by providing a cushion of resources that

allow firms to adapt in response to internal and external pressures (Bourgeois, 1981; Cyert and

Page 6: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

6

March, 1963). Cash is a form of available (or unabsorbed) slack that provides high discretion to

managers for reallocation to investments and stakeholders with a view to creating value. A

growing body of research using the BTF finds empirical support for the view that cash results in

improved financial performance (Daniel et al., 2004; George, 2005; Kim and Bettis, 2014).

Cash can create value by facilitating adaptation to complex environments and unfolding

contingencies that increase the firm’s exposure to risks and uncertainty (Levinthal, 1997). Over

time, new technologies may emerge, new products may be introduced, customer tastes and

preferences may change, suppliers may restrict supplies or increase prices, employees may leave

the firm, and the government may impose new taxes or change regulations. Such scenarios can

entail significant uncertainty, and cash can enable adaptation, for example, by providing the

means to delay decisions until such uncertainty is resolved (Kim and Bettis, 2014) and quickly

invest when needed. Behavioral theory also suggests other ways in which cash can be used to

adapt and create value. Cash can provide a buffer to protect a firm’s technical core against the

risks of failure arising out of exogenous shocks (Thompson, 1967), foster exploration and growth

via experimentation, innovation, and new entry (George, 2005; Mishina, Pollock, and Porac,

2004; Nohria and Gulati, 1996), and confer strategic advantages by serving as a deterrent against

actions by powerful competitors (Smith, Ferrier, and Ndofor, 2001).

From an economic perspective, the finance literature has echoed the BTF argument that

cash results in improved financial performance (Mikkelson and Partch, 2003). Similarly, the

behavioral idea of adaptation under uncertainty finds support in economic studies that extol the

virtues of large cash reserves in firms with riskier cash flows and higher susceptibility to adverse

shocks (Bates, Kahle, and Stulz, 2009; Keynes, 1936; Opler et al., 1999). Likewise, behavioral

conclusions about the strategic role of cash are supported by finance studies that suggest that “a

Page 7: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

7

cash-rich firm can use its war chest to finance competitive strategies” (Fresard, 2010: 1098).

Cash can also be used to fund product market choices (e.g., aggressive pricing, targeted

advertising, securing plant locations, building distribution networks) that influence competitors’

decisions, thereby increasing the cash-rich firm’s market share at the expense of its rivals

(Campello, 2006; Fresard, 2010). For firms unable to raise money externally due to market

frictions, cash can help them adapt to environmental contingencies, for example by taking

advantage of newly discovered strategic investment opportunities (Faulkender and Wang 2006).

Cash and Value Appropriation: Behavioral and Economic Approaches

Although stakeholders generally cooperate to create value within an organization, they

also compete to appropriate that value. Thus, while cash can help enhance value creation, it may

fail to benefit shareholders if it is appropriated by other stakeholders like managers, employees,

buyers, and suppliers (Brandenburger and Stuart, 1996; Coff, 1999; Cyert and March, 1963). The

BTF views an organization as being comprised of “a coalition of groups and interests, each

attempting to obtain something from the collectivity by interacting with others, and each with its

own preferences and objectives” (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978: 36). When a firm has substantial

cash reserves, stakeholder groups will vie for power, influence, rewards, and the allocation of

those resources (Cyert and March, 1963). This can increase political activity because “slack is

‘up for grabs’ and politically astute and motivated members of the dominant coalition will

engage in the political behaviors necessary to capture some of the uncommitted spoils”

(Bourgeois, 1981: 36).

Among all stakeholders, the role of managers is particularly salient in determining the

extent of value appropriation from cash. Managers sit at the head of a nexus of relationships

within the firm, and manage the complicated web by bargaining with the various coalitions

Page 8: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

8

(March and Simon, 1958). As a result, “management may be in a better position to appropriate

rent than all other stakeholders” (Ahuja, Coff, and Lee, 2005; Coff, 1999: 127). Powerful and

self-serving managers in cash-rich firms may also collude with other stakeholders to appropriate

value from shareholders by increasing their salaries, offering higher prices to suppliers and better

credit terms for customers, introducing generous perks for employees, and so on.

Furthermore, consistent with the ideas of ‘bounded rationality’ and ‘satisficing’ (March

and Simon, 1958; Simon, 1947), cash can facilitate sub-optimal behaviors by acting as “a

relaxing agent in the search process”, and “this relaxation will limit the strategic alternatives

considered by the organization” (Bourgeois, 1981: 36). Thus, while firms with resource

constraints will strive to optimize the utilization of their scarce resources, managers of cash-rich

firms are more likely to display laxity in spending cash (George, 2005). Cash can also make

managers complacent and optimistic, and promote biased decisions and a lack of entrepreneurial

initiative (Bromiley, 1991; George, 2005). These behavioral ideas are also supported by ‘quiet

life’ arguments in the economics literature that suggest that managers will be “reluctant to

undertake cognitively difficult activities” that may involve hard bargaining with stakeholders,

such as “facing down unions” or changing the contract terms of an influential supplier (Bertrand

and Mullainathan, 2003: 1067). Thus, managerial laxity and sub-optimal decisions may also lead

to diminished value created by cash and more value being appropriated by other stakeholders.

These behavioral implications of value capture by competing stakeholders, and the role

of managers in that process, are mirrored in economics-based approaches such as agency theory

(Berle and Means, 1932; Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Agency conflicts may arise due to

information asymmetry, motivating managers to keep cash reserves idle (thereby incurring

opportunity costs), or to invest them in negative net present value (NPV) projects that entail

Page 9: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

9

“waste, dissipation, and misallocation of cash to insiders’ own benefit” (Fresard and Salva, 2010:

360). As Jensen’s (1986) free cash flow hypothesis argues, agency costs associated with

managerial discretion to spend cash can also arise because cash enables entrenched managers to

avoid the scrutiny of capital markets, to have the flexibility to invest in projects that would

otherwise not be financed externally, and to retain funds within the firm rather than paying it out

to shareholders (Dittmar et al., 2003; Jensen, 1986; Opler et al.,1999; Pinkowitz, Stulz, and

Williamson, 2006). Moreover, recent management research supports and extends the agency

perspective regarding managerial opportunism to include other stakeholder groups like

employees, suppliers, and customers (Hambrick, Werder, and Zajac, 2008; Werder, 2011).

The Importance of Context for Value Creation and Appropriation

The above discussion suggests that cash will generally be used to adapt in contexts where

adaptation is critical for firm survival and success. Here, cash facilitates value creation for

shareholders and enhances firm performance by providing the slack needed to exploit unfolding

opportunities and avert potential threats. We call these the “value creation contexts”. Conversely,

in certain other contexts, stakeholders may be more inclined or able to appropriate value. This

may happen when there is a high potential for conflict over resources, when it is easy to conceal

appropriation because of information asymmetry, and /or when stakeholders gain power to

appropriate value for themselves. Because cash is more likely to be appropriated in these

contexts and less likely to enhance firm performance, we call these the “value appropriation

contexts”. Thus, the implications of cash for firm performance are largely context-specific.

Although value creation and value appropriation influences can occur simultaneously, we

treat them as independent (albeit potentially correlated) processes and focus on explicating the

circumstances that enhance each tendency. This approach enables us to present value creation

Page 10: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

10

and value appropriation as related yet distinct categories based on the salience of contingent

factors, and then study the performance outcomes of having cash under these different

circumstances. However, in a post hoc analysis section, we also consider interactions between

the two contexts. In that section, we examine whether a high need for adaptation may pressure

stakeholders to desist from appropriating value, or, conversely, if threats to firm survival actually

accentuate the tendency of stakeholders to appropriate value when conditions permit.

VALUE CREATION CONTEXTS

Holding other factors constant, certain contexts should make it more likely that cash will

be used for adaptation. Cash creates value and enhances firm performance when circumstances

induce managers to be more likely to use cash to make investments to respond to opportunities or

to counter threats. We examine three such contexts where the need for adaptation using cash is

especially high, namely industry competition, industry R&D intensity, and industry growth.

Industry Competition

Cash enables firms in highly competitive industries to adapt to the environmental

turbulence and rapid pace of change typical of such industries (Bettis and Hitt, 1995; Levinthal,

1997). Cash also provides a buffer that can absorb the impact of competitor activities such as

new market entry, price cuts, or an expansion of production capacity. Moreover, large cash

reserves may allow a firm to take advantage of positive-NPV investment projects without the

need to access external capital markets. As an example, cash-rich firms can use their funds to

acquire key competitors without having to rely on more costly or risky sources of capital.

Cash can also be a source of strategic advantage in competitive industries. In particular,

cash can be an effective deterrent against aggressive rival behavior, given the potent threat of

retaliation implicit in having large cash balances (Fresard, 2010; Kim and Bettis, 2014). At the

Page 11: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

11

same time, cash allows “firms facing uncertain future competitor investments to defer their own

decisions regarding counter investments until uncertainty can be adequately resolved” (Kim and

Bettis, 2014: 2057). Cash also enables firms operating in competitive contexts to improve market

shares via competitive postures such as “aggressive pricing”, as well as “the location of stores or

plants, the construction of efficient distribution networks, the use of advertising targeted against

rivals, or even the employment of more productive workers” (Fresard, 2010: 1098).

Managers of firms operating in competitive industries are under immense pressure to

maximize efficiency (Giroud and Mueller, 2011). That is because high competition affects the

survival prospects of each firm (Barnett, 1997), and so there is little margin for error. In this

context, the marginal value of an extra dollar of cash is likely to be high. Therefore, instead of

breeding managerial complacency, cash should instead motivate managers towards efficient

utilization that creates value. On a similar note, such contexts may also discourage stakeholder

conflicts, since stakeholder losses should bankruptcy occur are likely to exceed the uncertain

gains obtained by bargaining over cash. We can therefore hypothesize that:

Hypothesis 1: The positive association between cash and performance is strengthened in

competitive industries.

Industry R&D Intensity

R&D-intensive industries such as aerospace, computers, consumer electronics, and

pharmaceuticals are often characterized by uncertainty, complexity, rapid pace of technological

change, and a focus on innovation. For example, there may be market uncertainty due to a

change in customer demands, as well as technological uncertainty arising out of the quest for a

dominant technology, and firms in such industries may need to create several R&D options, each

with distinct investment trajectories (Oriani and Sobrero, 2008). It is here that cash can foster

Page 12: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

12

adaptation by providing firms the slack resources necessary to create such strategic options.

Similarly, cash can smooth out potential fluctuations in research spending during bad times, help

in the marketing of new products, and allow firms to take advantage of expansion opportunities

that can create value (O’Brien, 2003).

For firms in research-intensive industries, cash can also be a source of innovation that

provides a competitive advantage against rivals. Cash allows firms to engage in experimentation

and risk-taking in an environment where returns are often recoupable only in the long-run (Kim,

Kim, and Lee, 2008; Nohria and Gulati, 1996). Also, because of exchange hazards associated

with R&D investments (i.e., asset-specificity, uncertainty, and appropriability), boundedly

rational firm managers may not find appropriate resolutions for unfolding contingencies (David,

O’Brien, and Yoshikawa, 2008). These exchange hazards may not only make bankruptcy more

likely for firms in high-R&D industries, they may also make it costlier (Opler et al., 1999). In

these situations, large cash reserves can provide firms a buffer to absorb adverse shocks.

Furthermore, firms in R&D-intensive industries may have to pay a considerable premium to raise

capital externally (Himmelberg and Petersen, 1994; Levitas and McFadyen, 2009). Lenders, in

particular, may be reluctant to extend loans because the assets generated from research are firm-

specific and intangible, and thus cannot be used as collateral (Long and Malitz, 1985). Thus,

having cash reserves can help compensate for the difficulties in finding external financing.

Hypothesis 2: The positive association between cash and performance is strengthened in

research-intensive industries.

Industry Growth

Firms operating in high-growth industries generally have numerous attractive investment

opportunities, and often make strategic investments (e.g., entering into a strategic alliance) that

Page 13: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

13

take advantage of these opportunities (Park, Chen, and Gallagher, 2002). Other examples may

include investments in core products or technologies (platform investments), joint ventures,

greenfield operations, organizational capabilities such as information technology, and so on

(Grant, 2013). Using a real options logic (Myers, 1977), investment opportunities in high-growth

industries could be seen as growth options that the firm shares with other industry participants,

for example in an emerging market or technology, or in a particular industry segment (Tong and

Reuer, 2006). However, high-growth industries may also be characterized by uncertainties (Park

et al., 2002). For example, firms may not know in advance when, in what sequence, or to what

extent future growth opportunities will arise, and therefore may find it difficult to raise the

requisite capital at the precise time it is needed.

Having large cash holdings can facilitate adaptation for firms in high-growth industries.

Firms can use their cash resources to not only exploit emerging opportunities, but also to create a

buffer that minimizes the downside risks of uncertain investments. Cash will be even more

useful if the firm is additionally constrained in terms of its ability to obtain external funding for

its proposed investments (Denis and Sibilkov, 2009). As an example, cash would allow firms in

high-growth industries the flexibility to create growth options that involve making small initial

investments to create a portfolio of projects, without committing to the entire project (Grant,

2013; Tong and Reuer, 2007). This will result in value being created for the firm, given that firm

value is the sum of the value of assets in place and the value of growth options (Tong, Reuer, and

Peng, 2008). If a project needs to be modified or scaled up later, large cash reserves will also

provide the firm a superior ability (versus rivals) to do so without having to access capital

markets. Hence, relative to rivals, cash-rich firms are better positioned to take advantage of

potential industry growth.

Page 14: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

14

Hypothesis 3: The positive association between cash and performance is strengthened in

high-growth industries.

VALUE APPROPRIATION CONTEXTS

Three factors underpin value appropriation: a higher potential for conflict over resources,

which creates a motivation for appropriation; a greater likelihood that appropriation can be

concealed, which makes appropriation easier; and an increase in stakeholder power, which

enhances their ability to appropriate. If one or more of these factors exists, it enhances the

likelihood of appropriation relative to using cash for adaptation, and hence the performance

drawbacks of appropriation are more likely to prevail, ceteris paribus. Below, we identify three

value appropriation contexts: corporate governance, diversification, and corporate opacity.

Corporate Governance

Corporate governance can affect goal conflict over resources, stakeholder power to

appropriate value, and the ease of concealment of appropriation. Public corporations are

characterized by a separation of ownership and control and incomplete contracting (Berle and

Means, 1932; Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Divergent interests may cause owner-manager

conflicts over the allocation of scarce firm resources, increase the scope for information

asymmetry, moral hazard, and managerial self-dealing, and motivate managers to design

structures and processes that increase their power to appropriate resources. “Opportunism risks,”

however, can also arise from the conflicting interests of multiple other stakeholder groups, such

as customers, suppliers, and employees (Hambrick et al., 2008: 383). Here all stakeholder groups

become “opportunism interdependent in the sense that they have options to exploit other actors

opportunistically and at the same time bear the risk of being opportunistically exploited by other

actors” (Werder, 2011: 1348). In this scenario, goal conflicts can get accentuated and powerful

Page 15: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

15

stakeholders may be motivated to capture value from cash that is ‘up for grabs’, especially if

they can conceal self-dealing.

To mitigate the scope of value appropriation, firms put in place corporate governance

mechanisms, defined as “the formal structures, informal structures, and processes” that provide

oversight or facilitate incentive alignment (Hambrick et al., 2008: 381). These mechanisms may

include different forms of firm ownership (Connelly et al., 2010), board of directors (Daily and

Dalton, 1994), executive compensation (Core, Guay, and Larcker, 2003), and the market for

corporate control (Manne, 1965). However, managerial tendencies towards appropriation of cash

will be exacerbated if these mechanisms are weak. Indeed, prior studies have found that firms

with poor governance waste their cash resources in value-destroying acquisitions (Harford, 1999;

Harford et al., 2008), that “the value of an additional $1.00 of cash for a poorly governed firm is

between $0.42 and $0.88” (Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith, 2007: 600), and that weakly-governed

firms squander free cash flows on unprofitable sales growth (Brush et al., 2000). Along similar

lines, O’Brien and Folta (2009) suggest that strong governance enhances the association between

cash and firm value, while Werder (2011) asserts that firms should strengthen their governance

mechanisms to curb stakeholder opportunism. Hence, weak governance should allow

stakeholders to appropriate more value from cash reserves. Accordingly, we predict:

Hypothesis 4: The positive association between cash and performance is weakened in

poorly-governed firms.

Diversification

High levels of diversification also raise goal conflicts, bring about power imbalances, and

make it easier to conceal value appropriation. Internal power conflicts among various divisions

of a diversified firm can cause the misallocation of firm resources and result in the cross-

Page 16: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

16

subsidization of powerful but less efficient units (Rajan, Servaes, and Zingales, 2000). Hence,

fungible cash resources should encourage competing divisional managers in a diversified firm to

engage in intensive bargaining to appropriate that cash. Diversification also increases the

complexity of a firm’s operations, “obscures data relating to the efficiency of individual

divisions (firms only have to publish consolidated accounts)”, and therefore “exacerbates the

information asymmetry between management and stakeholders” (Hill and Jones, 1992: 149).

The complexity that results from diversification may also impose governance constraints

on the corporate headquarters in terms of monitoring and coordinating a diverse portfolio of

businesses (Ng, 2007; Zhou, 2011), and further accentuate information asymmetries between the

corporate center and divisional managers. These make it easier for both corporate and divisional

managers to engage in behaviors aimed at rent-seeking (Ndofor, Wesley and Priem, 2015).

Given access to discretionary cash reserves, managers of diversified firms will therefore be more

motivated to spend that cash for private benefit, resulting in value capture from cash.

Diversification may also result in increased managerial bargaining power as it increases

managerial entrenchment and makes it more costly for shareholders to replace managers who

often possess idiosyncratic skills (Coff, 1999; Kang, 2013). Also, because divisional managers in

a diversified firm have access to inside information about their divisions, it increases their

“bargaining power when they negotiate a compensation package with the CEO” (Scharfstein and

Stein, 2000: 2539). Applied to corporate cash resources, increased bargaining power will act as

an added incentive for both corporate and divisional managers to appropriate value from cash.

Hypothesis 5: The positive association between cash and performance is weakened in

firms with high levels of diversification.

Corporate Opacity

Page 17: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

17

Firms vary in the extent to which they disseminate inside information to outsiders such as

shareholders, analysts, regulators, or other stakeholders. While information asymmetries could

arise between various firm constituents, we focus here on the information asymmetry between

managers and other internal stakeholders on the one hand, and shareholders on the other. In

general, higher corporate opacity (i.e., lower corporate transparency) makes external market

scrutiny of managerial decisions difficult, and may exacerbate agency problems if insiders such

as managers or other opportunistic stakeholders take advantage of their preferential access to

information to obtain private benefits of control (Anderson, Duru, and Reeb, 2009).

When managers, acting either by themselves or in collusion with other stakeholders, have

access to high cash reserves, it reduces their reliance on external financing. This in turn reduces

external scrutiny of managerial actions by capital markets, and allows entrenched managers to

invest in negative-NPV projects, or, in more extreme cases, directly expropriate the cash via

increased salaries, perks, or transfer pricing (Dittmar et al., 2003; Fresard and Salva, 2010; Opler

et al., 1999; Pinkowitz et al., 2006). These ideas are also in line with Jensen’s (1986) free cash

flow hypothesis, which states that managers with access to free cash will dissipate it in value-

destroying investments, and Myers and Rajan’s (1998) idea that assets like cash are easy to

expropriate. Diminished external scrutiny can also encourage managerial laxity in utilizing cash

resources, in line with the ‘quiet life’ arguments we made earlier. Hence, other informed

stakeholders, such as employees or corporate trade partners, may also collude with managers to

bargain over available cash resources. Therefore, given the negative implications of corporate

opacity for monitoring of insider actions, there will be a greater likelihood of value appropriation

from cash by managers and other stakeholders in firms that have lower levels of disclosure.

Page 18: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

18

Hypothesis 6: The positive association between cash and performance is weakened in

firms that are highly opaque.

METHODS

Data and Sample

We constructed a panel dataset to test our hypotheses. Data was extracted for all publicly-

traded US firms in the COMPUSTAT North America database (including the ‘Segments’

database) between 1993 and 2012, and supplemented with data from Risk Metrics, Center for

Research in Security Prices (CRSP), and Institutional Brokers’ Estimate System (I/B/E/S). We

excluded firms that belong to the following industries: utilities, financial institutions,

governmental organizations, and non-classifiable establishments (O’Brien and Folta, 2009; Kim

and Bettis, 2014). We also dropped observations with missing data and firm-year observations

with asset values below USD 10 million (Kim and Bettis, 2014). All extreme values are

removed, and upper and lower bounds imposed on certain variables, as noted below.

Due to data availability of the moderators, our analysis was conducted on four different

sub-samples. For the regressions using the value creation moderators, the sample size is 9,298

firms and 65,784 firm-years. We call this the baseline file. The sample size for the diversification

moderator is somewhat smaller (7,951 firms and 53,669 firm-years) as some observations are

lost when using the Segments database. For the corporate opacity moderator, the sample was

even smaller (5,827 firms and 35,549 firm-years) due to merging data from COMPUSTAT,

CRSP, and I/B/E/S. Finally, the sample size is the smallest for corporate governance (1,969 firms

and 15,899 firm-years) because the Investor Responsibility Research Center (IRRC, now owned

by RiskMetrics) data on the G-index, which is used to measure governance, is not published

every year. Even though we follow prior research and replace missing G-index values with those

Page 19: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

19

from the most recent prior period (Core, Guay, and Rusticus, 2006; Humphery-Jenner, 2014),

governance data is still not available for a large number of firms and is only available up to 2006.

Dependent Variable

Market-based measures of firm performance are better able to capture the costs and

benefits to shareholders of holding cash (O’Brien and Folta, 2009; Kim and Bettis, 2014). Thus,

we use Tobin’s q as our metric of firm performance, the dependent variable. Tobin’s q denotes

the market value of a firm’s assets relative to replacement costs. However, given the difficulties

in estimating replacement costs, we follow common practice and use the market-to-book (M/B)

ratio as a proxy for Tobin’s q (Richard et al., 2009). The numerator is the market value of the

firm, defined as the book values of long-term debt and debt in current liabilities plus the market

value of equity plus preferred stock liquidation value minus deferred taxes and investment tax

credit; and the denominator is the book value of the firm’s assets. Like other studies (Alti, 2006;

Gatchev, Pulvino, and Tarhan, 2010), we employ ‘fiscal year end prices’ instead of ‘calendar

year end prices’ to compute the market value of the firm. Also, following other studies (Alti,

2006; Baker and Wurgler, 2002), we drop observations where the M/B exceeds 10.

Explanatory Variables

Our main explanatory variable is cash, defined as the ratio of cash and short-term

investments to the book value of total assets (Bates et al., 2009). All values of cash below zero

and above 1 are dropped. Industry competition is operationalized using the Herfindahl index,

defined as the sum of squared market shares of firms in an industry, where firm sales are used to

compute market shares (Giroud and Mueller, 2011; Vomberg, Homburg, and Bornemann, 2014).

Since the Herfindahl Index measures industry concentration, we subtracted this measure from 1

so that higher values equate to greater competition. Industry R&D intensity is defined as the

mean R&D intensity of all firms in the focal industry (Gentry and Shen, 2013). Firm R&D

Page 20: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

20

intensity is calculated as R&D expenses divided by sales. Following common practice, missing

R&D values are replaced with zeros (Hall, 1993) and the upper limit for R&D intensity is capped

at 1 (Kim and Bettis, 2014). To proxy for industry growth, we first computed the median M/B

ratio of each industry, the median of which across all industries was 1.08. We then created a

dummy variable that is equal to 1 if an industry’s median M/B exceeds 1.08, and zero otherwise.

Our results are substantially similar if we use the median industry values based on firms’ annual

sales growth. For industry-level variables, industries are defined at the four-digit SIC level.

Corporate governance is measured using the G-index, a summative index comprising 24

antitakeover provisions that assess the degree of restriction on shareholder rights (Gompers,

Ishii, and Metrick, 2003). The G-index is a widely-used proxy for corporate governance arising

out of managerial entrenchment (Giroud and Mueller, 2011; Humphery-Jenner, 2014), whereby

“[a] higher G-index is assumed to mean weaker shareholder rights and lower governance

quality.” (Core et al., 2006: 656). Prior research has employed various measures of

diversification (Robins and Wiersema, 1995; Speckbacher, Neumann, and Hoffmann, 2014).

Here we adopted Palepu’s entropy measure (Palepu, 1985) following studies like Kang (2013)

and Kim et al. (2013), and constructed this variable from the COMPUSTAT Segments database.

Our results are substantially similar if we replace the entropy measure with either a count-based

or a Herfindahl-type diversification measure.

Corporate opacity is measured using the opacity index developed by Anderson et al.

(2009). Four proxies for firm-level opacity are developed, namely trading volume, bid-ask

spread, analyst following, and analyst forecast errors. Trading volume is the natural logarithm of

the daily dollar trading volume for the year. Bid-ask spread is the ask price less the bid price

divided by the average of the bid and ask prices, averaged across all trading days in a year. Data

Page 21: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

21

for these two proxies is obtained from CRSP. Analyst following is the natural logarithm of the

number of analysts following each firm in a year, while analyst forecast error is the square of the

difference between the mean analysts’ earnings forecast and actual firm earnings, scaled by the

firm’s stock price. The data for analysts is obtained from I/B/E/S. These four proxies are then

individually ranked into deciles, “with the most opaque firms taking a value of ten and the least

opaque firms assuming a value of one. The four rankings are then summed and scaled by a factor

of 40 (total possible points) to provide an index that ranges from 0.1 to 1.0. Lower values denote

more transparent firms and higher values denote more opaque firms.” (Anderson et al., 2009:

209). In constructing the index, we follow these authors and assume that bid-ask spread and

analyst forecast errors increase opacity while trading volume and analyst following reduce it.

Control Variables

We use lagged Tobin’s q to control for serial correlation among residuals arising out of

the persistence of performance within a firm. Firm size is the natural logarithm of total assets.

Absorbed slack is the ratio of selling, general, and administrative expenses to sales (Bromiley,

1991). Absorbed slack values below 0 and above 1 are dropped. Potential slack is the leverage

ratio, or the ratio of total debt to total assets. Observations where leverage exceeds 1 are dropped

(Alti, 2006). So that increasing values denote high potential slack, the leverage ratio is subtracted

from 1. We control for firm profitability using an adjusted measure based on undistributed cash

flow, which is defined as operating income before depreciation less total income taxes less the

year-on-year changes in deferred taxes less gross interest expenses on total debt less the sum of

preferred dividend payable on cumulative preferred stock and dividend paid on noncumulative

preferred stock less the dividend declared on common stock (Kim and Bettis, 2014). This

variable is scaled by total assets. Firm R&D intensity and firm advertising intensity are defined

as R&D and advertising expenditures (respectively) scaled by sales, with all missing values

Page 22: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

22

replaced with zeros and the upper limit of the variable capped at 1. Firm capital intensity is

measured using capital expenditures scaled by total assets. Following Brush et al. (2000), we

define firm growth as the compounded annual growth rate in sales, calculated as the natural

logarithm of SalesJ,T divided by SalesJ,T-1 for firm J in year T. To control for the possibility of

decreasing marginal returns to cash, we added the square of cash as a control variable only in the

full models (e.g., model 1B) (Kim and Bettis, 2014). Across all models, we control for industry

Tobin’s q with the mean value of the dependent variable at the four-digit SIC level. Finally, we

control for year fixed effects to account for unobserved heterogeneity across time-periods.

Analyses

We took a number of steps to address important methodological issues that are common

in panel data analysis. First, unobserved heterogeneity arising out of multiple observations per

firm may be an issue, to attend to which we employ a firm fixed effects model. Hausman tests

we conducted confirmed the superiority of fixed effects model over random effects (p<0.001).

Second, a modified Wald test confirmed the presence of heteroskedasticity in our fixed effects

models, to address which we report robust standard errors that are White’s (1980)

heteroskedasticity-consistent. Third, both a Woolridge test (Woolridge, 2002) and an Arellano–

Bond test (Arellano and Bond, 1991) provide evidence of first-order autocorrelation in our panel

dataset. As suggested by Greene (2003), we account for this by introducing a dynamic fixed

effects model that includes the lagged dependent variable as a control variable in all our models

(see also, Barnett and Salomon, 2012; Gentry and Shen, 2013). Fourth, an examination of the

variance inflation factors (VIFs) confirmed the absence of multicollinearity in our datasets. Fifth,

Cook’s distance tests that were conducted also confirmed the absence of influential outliers.

Page 23: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

23

Endogeneity is another important methodological issue. It could arise due to omitted

variables that are correlated with both the dependent variable and one or more of the independent

variables, simultaneous causality, or errors-in-variables (Bascle, 2008). Instrumental variables

(IV) estimators are often used to address the issue of endogeneity, although these techniques are

inefficient due to large standard errors, and thus a variable should not be modeled as endogenous

unless tests indicate that endogeneity induces a statistical problem (see chapter 15 of Woolridge,

2003). We therefore approached this potential problem by first including firm-fixed effects in our

models. This can reduce endogeneity by factoring in time-invariant omitted variables, although it

cannot control for omitted variables that vary over time. We further ameliorate the impact of

endogeneity by including the lagged dependent variable in all our model specifications (O’Brien

and Folta, 2009). Furthermore, we also tested whether cash, our main independent variable,

created an endogeneity problem. Based on the literature, we identified three different instruments

for cash, namely: lagged cash, cash dividend paid, and tangibility (Fresard, 2008; 2010). Of

these, a Sargan test showed that only the cash dividend and tangibility instruments were

statistically valid. Therefore, using these two instruments, we next conducted a Davidson–

MacKinnon test of exogeneity. These tests were insignificant, indicating the absence of an

endogeneity problem and the appropriateness of our dynamic fixed effects regressions models.

RESULTS

Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics for our sample, while Table 2 presents the

results of our analysis of the value creation moderators, and Table 3 presents the results of our

analysis of the value appropriation moderators. Our results show that across all models in Tables

2 and 3, cash has a strong significant positive main effect on performance, indicating that cash

generally creates value. In terms of the control variables, the strong positive effects for both

lagged performance and industry performance are in line with expectations. Firm size is found to

Page 24: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

24

be negatively related to Tobin’s q, consistent with prior research (Welbourne and Andrews,

1996). Capital expenditures and sales growth are associated with higher performance, consistent

with Kim and Bettis (2014). Also, profitability and potential slack are both positively associated

with performance. Finally, we note that these models also have robust explanatory power, as the

adjusted R-square values in the full models (1B, 2B, and 3B in Table 2; and 4B, 5B and 6B in

Table 3) range from about 34 to 43 percent.

While we did not present hypotheses for the direct association between cash and

performance, our regressions demonstrate a positive association consistent with the findings

reported in Daniel et al.’s (2004) meta-analysis of the relationship between slack and

performance. On average, we find that cash-rich firms enjoy higher performance, with those in

the 75th percentile of cash holdings having a market-to-book value 15 percent higher than those

in the 25th percentile.Models 1A-1B in Table 2 test hypothesis 1, which predicted that the cash-

performance association is stronger in competitive industries. Model 1A contains the control

variables, while Model 1B incorporates the main effects for cash and industry competition as

well as the interaction term between the two. The interaction term is positive and statistically

significant (p < 0.001), providing support for Hypothesis 1. These results are also graphically

represented in Panel A in Figure 1. While performance generally improves as the level of cash

increases, the slope of change in performance is much sharper in more competitive industries.

This suggests that cash enables greater adaptation and value creation in competitive industries.

Models 2A-2B in Table 2 test Hypothesis 2, which argued that cash helps foster more

appropriate adaptation in research-intensive industries. The positive and significant (p < 0.001)

coefficient for the interaction between cash and industry R&D intensity supports this hypothesis.

As shown in Panel B, the cash-performance association is sharper in high R&D industries.

Page 25: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

25

Similarly, hypothesis 3, which predicted that cash is more beneficial in high-growth industries, is

supported by the positive and significant (p < 0.001) coefficient for the interaction between cash

and industry growth in Model 3B. Panel C illustrates these findings and reveals that the cash-

performance relationship is steeper in high-growth industries than in low-growth industries.

Hypotheses 4, 5, and 6 pertain to the value appropriation moderators, and are tested in

Table 3. Hypothesis 4, which argued that the positive cash-performance association is weakened

in poorly-governed firms, is supported by the negative and significant (p < 0.001) cash-

governance interaction term. Panel D graphically depicts these results. We also find that the

interaction between cash and diversification is strongly negative (p < 0.001), which supports

Hypothesis 5 which predicted that the cash-performance association is weaker in firms with

higher levels of diversification. Panel E illustrates these findings graphically. Finally, in regards

to Hypothesis 6, we find that the interaction between cash and corporate opacity is negative and

highly significant (p < 0.001), and therefore Hypothesis 6 is also upheld. These results are

depicted in Panel F. Thus, our empirical results provide strong support for all six hypotheses.

POST HOC ANALYSIS

Fully specified model. Since the data for our explanatory variables are drawn from different

sources, putting them all together in a fully-specified model restricts the sampling period to 1993

– 2006, and sharply reduces the sample size to 11,164 observations. Hence, due to this sample

size restriction and space limitations, we do not report such a model in our tables. We did,

however, run some additional analysis to see if our findings are robust to a fully specified model.

While including multiple interaction terms between cash and the six moderators in the same

model resulted in extremely high multicollinearity, including all six moderators in the model and

one interaction at a time did not create a problem. Thus, we tested a fully specified model with

Page 26: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

26

all of the moderators and tested the interaction terms one at a time. Despite the reduced sample

size, the results are qualitatively identical to our reported results except for the cash-opacity

interaction, which was insignificant. In sum, five of the six interaction results we presented in

Tables 2 and 3 are upheld in fully specified models with a vastly reduced sample size.

Three-way interactions. The slack afforded by large cash reserves can serve as a valuable

resource in facilitating adaptation. Thus, the performance benefits of cash should be particularly

apparent in contexts where the need for adaptation is high, which we term value creation

contexts. However, certain contexts may allow for greater value appropriation by stakeholders,

thereby eroding the performance benefits of cash. The interesting question is what happens when

these distinct forces interact, so that we have a context where the potential for both value-

creation and value-appropriation are high. Theoretically, the relationship is hard to predict a

priori, and hence our hypothesis development has focused on the ceteris paribus effects of the

value creation and value appropriation contexts. Nonetheless, in an unreported post hoc analysis,

we examined this question empirically with three-way interactions.

Speculatively, if the need for adaptation is high and the firm’s survival is threatened,

stakeholders may desist from appropriating value because doing so may impair adaptation and

therefore prevent the firm from creating value for all stakeholders. On the other hand, however,

if stakeholders lack a long-term commitment to the firm (and if the firm has not made one to

them), they may attempt to ‘get what they can’ out of an endangered firm while it is still afloat.

Alternatively, these factors may operate completely independently and hence there may be no

significant three-way interaction between cash, value-creation contexts, and value-appropriation

contexts.

Page 27: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

27

To test this, we created a ‘high adaptation dummy’ that equals 1 when all three value-

creation moderators exceed their respective median values, and zero otherwise. We then run

three regression models separately for the three value-appropriation moderators. As an example,

in the first regression model with governance as the moderator, we enter the three main effects

(cash, high adaptation dummy, and governance), the three two-way interaction terms among

these three variables, the 3-way interaction term (cash x high adaptation dummy x governance),

and all controls. We next run similar models replacing governance with diversification and then

opacity. Interestingly, the only three way interaction that was statistically significant was the

opacity interaction, which revealed a weak positive effect (β = 1.112; p < 0.05). This suggests

that the adaptation-related performance benefits of cash under high value-creation contexts

trump any negative performance effects associated with high corporate opacity. This leads us to

speculate that opacity represents a relatively weaker value-appropriation context, perhaps

because it derives from information asymmetry as the single underlying source of value-

appropriation. In contrast, governance and diversification derive strength from all three of the

sources of value appropriation we discussed earlier. Overall, our results suggest that the effects

of value creation and value appropriation contexts operate largely independent from each other.

DISCUSSION

More than three decades after the publication of Bourgeois’s (1981) seminal work on

slack, there is still debate about the association between cash and performance. This study was

motivated by the desire to resolve some of the ambiguity in current findings and provide a more

nuanced explanation of that relationship. Our results suggest that although cash improves

performance, the associated context can substantially moderate this relationship. Specifically, we

find support for our hypotheses that cash creates more value, and improves performance, when

Page 28: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

28

firms operate in industries that are highly competitive, research-intensive, or characterized by

high growth. Conversely, there is greater value appropriation from cash, and hence performance

suffers, in firms that are poorly-governed, more diversified, or opaque.

Our results show that cash is beneficial in contexts where there is a greater need for

adaptation. Interestingly, however, our results indicate that even in contexts where the threat of

stakeholder value appropriation is high, the cash-performance association is never strictly

negative. At worst, the performance benefits of cash are attenuated in such contexts, so that cash

either fails to enhance performance (as shown by the flat line for weak corporate governance in

Panel D in Figure 1), or results in a lower increase in performance (see Panel E for high versus

low diversification, and Panel F for high versus low opacity). Similarly, as seen in Panels A-C,

cash improves performance even under conditions of low industry competition, low industry

R&D intensity, and low industry growth. This suggests that even in these contexts, there is some

need for adaptation, although that need is lower relative to high value creation contexts.

Our findings also have substantive economic significance. Take industry competition, for

example. We find that relative to firms in industries with low competition, a 1-standard deviation

(sd) increase in cash for firms in industries with high competition is associated with a 3.18

percent increase in mean Tobin’s q. For the other interactions, the corresponding differences in

Tobin’s q for a 1-sd increase in cash are as follows: industry R&D intensity (4.01 percent),

industry growth (6.43 percent), corporate governance (6.03 percent), diversification (4.08

percent), and corporate opacity (3.68 percent). These effects are meaningful in relation to the

direct association between cash and performance, where we find that for the cash main effect, a

1-sd increase in cash causes a 14.19 percent increase in mean Tobin’s q.

Contributions

Page 29: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

29

Overall, our study underscores the importance of context in explaining the performance

consequences of cash. It integrates ideas from the behavioral theory of the firm, economic

perspectives like agency theory, and the value-creation versus value-appropriation literatures to

frame contexts using a schema that builds on largely ad hoc attempts at contextualizing the cash-

performance relationship. Moreover, this study also proposes novel moderators of the cash-

performance relationship. Finally, we also empirically examine what happens when we relax the

ceteris paribus condition of the two sets of contextual factors. While this is difficult to theorize a

priori, our post hoc empirical analysis indicates that value creation contexts operate largely

independently from the effects of value appropriation contexts, and vice versa.

Practical Implications

Our study has several practical implications. The increasing cash stockpiles of US firms

have attracted intense public scrutiny in recent years. Commentators and policy makers alike

have criticized these firms for hoarding cash that could have been productively invested outside

the firm to stimulate economic growth and create jobs (Plender, 2013). Others suggest that firms

hoard cash in overseas units to avoid paying high US taxes. On the other hand, managers often

justify their large cash holdings in terms of their ability to meet working capital needs and

provide enough savings for a rainy day. In this backdrop, our study shows that managers of firms

operating in technology-driven or competitive industries that are rapidly-changing, uncertain, or

have both a high upside potential for growth as well as a high downside risk of bankruptcy, have

a stronger rationale for hoarding cash. Our study thus provides a point of justification for the

large cash reserves of US technology behemoths like Apple, Microsoft, and Google, or US

pharmaceutical companies like Pfizer, Johnson & Johnson, and Merck. Our study also

underscores the need for commentators to avoid broad generalizations about the effects of cash

Page 30: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

30

without investigating how, and why, such effects may vary across contexts both internal and

external to the firm. For shareholders contemplating investment in a cash-rich firm, the

framework we propose should help them better predict whether cash reserves will create much

value for shareholders, something they can factor in as a key input into their investment decision.

Future Research

A direct extension of our study might be to examine how value creation versus value

appropriation contexts can moderate the effects of cash on corporate and competitive strategies

pursued by the firm. As an example, one may examine if cash promotes value-destroying

acquisitions in more opaque corporate environments. Future research can also undertake more

fine-grained empirical analysis that directly captures stakeholder behaviors. For instance, it could

be examined if under conditions of weak firm governance, suppliers bargain hard for immediate

cash payments, managers negotiate high cash bonuses, employees demand higher perks, and so

on, and then link these behaviors to firm performance. Separately, the literature can also benefit

from a systematic disaggregation of stakeholders, for example by type. Thus ‘relational’

stakeholders may be more invested in the firm than ‘transactional’ stakeholders, and therefore

may not capture value from cash even in contexts with high potential for value appropriation,

and vice versa (cf. David et al., 2010). Another way to disaggregate stakeholders could be into

individual and institutional (i.e., corporate) components, and then examine differences in

behaviors between these two groups. Finally, stakeholder reactions, and therefore the application

of our study in specific contexts to explain the cash-performance association, may be different in

countries like Germany and Japan that have traditionally been considered more stakeholder-

oriented than the USA, and future research can therefore test our findings using non-US samples.

Page 31: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

31

In this study we have explored some specific contingencies, and we hope this will spur

future research interest in studying other contextual moderators. This will also help ascertain if

our findings can be generalized to other contexts. Another possible avenue for research might be

to introduce cash as a moderator in already-known relationships between other strategic or

financial variables (like mergers & acquisitions, organizational learning, capital structure, etc.)

and performance. Alternatively, it would be interesting to examine how contexts impact the

accumulation of cash in the first place. For example, while any profitable firm should be able to

accumulate cash over time, we would expect firms to accumulate less cash over time if value

appropriation contexts are salient. Investigating these and related questions could be rewarding

ways of extending the current study.

Conclusion

Our study helps contextualize opposing arguments in prior research that cash can be

beneficial by fostering adaptation, but it can also be detrimental because cash is easily

squandered. We synthesize behavioral and economic arguments to show that while cash

generally enhances performance, the strength of that effect varies by context. Cash is most

beneficial for performance in contexts where the need for adaptation is high, as when firms

operate in industries that are highly competitive, research-intensive, or characterized by high

growth. Conversely, value-appropriation by stakeholders may attenuate the benefits of cash in

contexts characterized by stakeholder conflicts, information asymmetries, or acute power

imbalances, as are common in firms that are poorly-governed, more diversified, or more opaque

to outside investors. Our findings should help both managers and researchers better understand

when cash is most likely to benefit firms and when it is more likely to be wasted.

Page 32: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

32

REFERENCES

Ahuja G, Coff RW, Lee PM. 2005. Managerial foresight and attempted rent appropriation: insider trading on knowledge of imminent breakthroughs. Strategic Management Journal 26(9): 791 – 808.

Alti A. 2006. How persistent is the impact of market timing on capital structure? Journal of Finance 61(4): 1681 – 1710.

Anderson RC, Duru A, Reeb DM. 2009. Founders, heirs, and corporate opacity in the United States. Journal of Financial Economics 92(2): 205 – 222.

Arellano M, Bond S. 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies 58(2): 277 – 297.

Baker M, Wurgler J. 2002. Market timing and capital structure. Journal of Finance 57(1): 1 – 32. Barnett WP. 1997. The dynamics of competitive intensity. Administrative Science Quarterly

42(1): 128 – 160. Barnett ML, Salomon RM. 2012. Does it pay to be really good? addressing the shape of the

relationship between social and financial performance. Strategic Management Journal 33(11): 1304 – 1320.

Bascle G. 2008. Controlling for endogeneity with instrumental variables in strategic management research. Strategic Organization 6(3): 285 – 327.

Bates TW, Kahle KM, Stulz RM. 2009. Why do US firms hold so much more cash than they used to? Journal of Finance 64(5): 1985 – 2021.

Berle AA, Means GC. 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. Macmillan: New York.

Bershidsky L. 2014. Warren Buffett's giant pile of cash. Bloomberg August 4. http://www.bloombergview.com/articles/2014-08-04/warren-buffett-s-giant-pile-of-cash

[December 16, 2014]. Bertrand M, Mullainathan S. 2003. Enjoying the quiet life? corporate governance and managerial

preferences. Journal of Political Economy 111(5): 1043 – 1075. Bettis RA, Hitt MA. 1995. The new competitive landscape. Strategic Management Journal

16(S1): 7 – 19. Bourgeois LJ. 1981. On the measurement of organizational slack. Academy of Management

Review 6(1): 29 – 39. Bradley SW, Wiklund J, Shepherd DA. 2011. Swinging a double-edged sword: The effect of

slack on entrepreneurial management and growth. Journal of Business Venturing 26(5): 537 – 554.

Brandenburger AM, Stuart HW. 1996. Value-based business strategy. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 5(1): 5 – 24.

Bromiley P. 1991. Testing a causal model of corporate risk taking and performance. Academy of Management Journal 34(1): 37 – 59.

Brush TH, Bromiley P, Hendrickx M. 2000. The free cash flow hypothesis for sales growth and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal 21(4): 455 – 472.

Campello M. 2006. Debt financing: does it boost or hurt firm performance in product markets? Journal of Financial Economics 82(1): 135 – 172.

Coff RW. 1999. When competitive advantage doesn't lead to performance: the resource-based view and stakeholder bargaining power. Organization Science 10(2): 119 – 133.

Page 33: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

33

Connelly BL, Hoskisson RE, Tihanyi L, Certo ST. 2010. Ownership as a form of corporate governance. Journal of Management Studies 47(8): 1561 – 1589.

Core JE, Guay WR, Larcker DF. 2003. Executive equity compensation and incentives: a survey. Economic Policy Review 9(1): 27 – 50.

Core JE, Guay WR, Rusticus TO. 2006. Does weak governance cause weak stock returns? an examination of firm operating performance and investors’ expectations. Journal of Finance 61(2): 655 – 687.

Cyert RM, March JG. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Prentice Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

Daily CM, Dalton DR. 1994. Bankruptcy and corporate governance: the impact of board composition and structure. Academy of Management Journal 37(6): 1603 – 1617.

Daniel F, Lohrke FT, Fornaciari CJ, Turner Jr. RA. 2004. Slack resources and firm performance: a meta-analysis. Journal of Business Research 57(6): 565 – 574.

David P, O’Brien JP, Yoshikawa T. 2008. The implications of debt heterogeneity for R&D investment and firm performance. Academy of Management Journal 51(1): 165 – 181.

David P, O’Brien JP, Yoshikawa T, Delios A. 2010. Do shareholders or stakeholders appropriate the rents from corporate diversification? the influence of ownership structure. Academy of Management Journal 53(3): 636 – 654.

Denis DJ, Sibilkov V. 2009. Financial constraints, investment, and the value of cash holdings. Review of Financial Studies 23(1): 247 – 269.

Dittmar A, Mahrt-Smith J. 2007. Corporate governance and the value of cash holdings. Journal of Financial Economics 83(3): 599 – 634.

Dittmar A, Mahrt-Smith J, Servaes H. 2003. International corporate governance and corporate cash holdings. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 38(01): 111 – 133.

Faulkender M, Wang R. 2006. Corporate financial policy and the value of cash. Journal of Finance 61(4): 1957 – 1990.

Frésard L. 2008. Financial strength and product market behaviors: the real effects of corporate cash holdings. Working paper.

Fresard L. 2010. Financial strength and product market behavior: the real effects of corporate cash holdings. Journal of Finance 65(3): 1097 – 1122.

Frésard L, Salva C. 2010. The value of excess cash and corporate governance: evidence from US cross-listings. Journal of Financial Economics 98(2): 359 – 384.

Gatchev VA, Pulvino T, Tarhan V. 2010. The interdependent and intertemporal nature of financial decisions: an application to cash flow sensitivities. Journal of Finance 65(2): 725 – 763.

Gentry RJ, Shen W. 2013. The impacts of performance relative to analyst forecasts and analyst coverage on firm R&D intensity. Strategic Management Journal 34(1): 121 – 130.

George G. 2005. Slack resources and the performance of privately held firms. Academy of Management Journal 48(4): 661 – 676.

Giroud X, Mueller HM. 2011. Corporate governance, product market competition, and equity prices. Journal of Finance 66(2): 563 – 600.

Gompers P, Ishii J, Metrick A. 2003. Corporate governance and equity prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118:107 – 55.

Grant RM. 2013. Contemporary Strategy Analysis. John Wiley & Sons Ltd: West Sussex, United Kingdom.

Greene WH. 2003. Econometric Analysis. Prentice Hall International: Upper Saddle River, NJ.

Page 34: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

34

Hall BH. 1993. The stock market's valuation of R&D investment during the 1980’s. American Economic Review 83(2): 259 – 264.

Hambrick DC, Werder AV, Zajac EJ. 2008. New directions in corporate governance research. Organization Science 19(3): 381 – 385.

Harford J. 1999. Corporate cash reserves and acquisitions. Journal of Finance 54(6): 1969 – 1997.

Harford J, Mansi SA, Maxwell WF. 2008. Corporate governance and firm cash holdings in the US. Journal of Financial Economics 87(3): 535 – 555.

Hill CW, Jones TM. 1992. Stakeholder-agency theory. Journal of Management Studies 29(2): 131 – 154.

Himmelberg CP, Petersen BC. 1994. R & D and internal finance: a panel study of small firms in high-tech industries. Review of Economics and Statistics 76(1): 38 – 51.

Humphery-Jenner M. 2014. Takeover defenses, innovation, and value creation: evidence from acquisition decisions. Strategic Management Journal 35(5): 668 – 690.

Jensen MC. 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. American Economic Review 76(2): 323 – 329.

Jensen MC, Meckling WH. 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305 – 360.

Kang J. 2013. The relationship between corporate diversification and corporate social performance. Strategic Management Journal 34(1): 94 – 109.

Keynes JM. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Harcourt: New York.

Kim C, Bettis RA. 2014. Cash is surprisingly valuable as a strategic asset. Strategic Management Journal 35(13): 2053 – 2063.

Kim H, Kim H, Lee PM. 2008. Ownership structure and the relationship between financial slack and R&D investments: evidence from Korean firms. Organization Science 19(3): 404 – 418.

Kim SK, Arthurs JD, Sahaym A, Cullen JB. 2013. Search behavior of the diversified firm: the impact of fit on innovation. Strategic Management Journal 34(8): 999 – 1009.

Levinthal DA. 1997. Adaptation on rugged landscapes. Management Science 43(7): 934 – 950. Levitas E, McFadyen M. 2009. Managing liquidity in research-intensive firms: signaling and

cash flow effects of patents and alliance activities. Strategic Management Journal 30(6): 659 – 678.

Long MS, Malitz IB. 1985. Investment patterns and financial leverage. In Corporate Capital Structures in the United States, Friedman BM (ed). University of Chicago Press: Chicago, 325 – 352.

Manne HG. 1965. Mergers and the market for corporate control. Journal of Political Economy 73(2): 110 – 120.

March JG, Simon HA. 1958. Organizations. Wiley: New York. Mikkelson WH, Partch MM. 2003. Do persistent large cash reserves hinder performance?

Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 38(02): 275 – 294. Mishina Y, Pollock TG, Porac JF. 2004. Are more resources always better for growth? resource

stickiness in market and product expansion. Strategic Management Journal 25(12): 1179 – 1197.

Myers SC. 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 5(2): 147 – 175.

Page 35: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

35

Myers SC, Rajan RG. 1998. The paradox of liquidity. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(3): 733 – 771.

Ndofor HA, Wesley C, Priem RL. 2015. Providing CEOs with opportunities to cheat the effects of complexity-based information asymmetries on financial reporting fraud.Journal of Management 41(6): 1774 – 1797.

Ng DW. 2007. A modern resource based approach to unrelated diversification. Journal of Management Studies 44(8): 1481 – 1502.

Nohria N, Gulati R. 1996. Is slack good or bad for innovation? Academy of Management Journal 39(5): 1245 – 1264.

O’Brien JP. 2003. The capital structure implications of pursuing a strategy of innovation. Strategic Management Journal 24(5): 415 – 431.

O’Brien JP, Folta TB. 2009. A transaction cost perspective on why, how, and when cash impacts firm performance. Managerial and Decision Economics 30(7): 465 – 479.

Opler T, Pinkowitz L, Stulz R, Williamson R. 1999. The determinants and implications of corporate cash holdings. Journal of Financial Economics 52(1): 3 – 46.

Oriani R, Sobrero M. 2008. Uncertainty and the market valuation of R&D within a real options logic. Strategic Management Journal 29(4): 343 – 361.

Palepu, K. 1985. Diversification strategy, profit performance and the entropy measure. Strategic Management Journal 6(3): 239 – 255.

Park SH, Chen RR, Gallagher S. 2002. Firm resources as moderators of the relationship between market growth and strategic alliances in semiconductor start-ups. Academy of Management Journal 45(3): 527 – 545.

Pfeffer J, Salancik GR. 1978. The External Control of Organizations: A Resource Dependence Perspective. Harper and Row: New York, NY.

Pinkowitz L, Stulz R, Williamson R. 2006. Does the contribution of corporate cash holdings and dividends to firm value depend on governance? A cross-country analysis. Journal of Finance 61(6): 2725 – 2751.

Plender J. 2013. Apple, Google and Facebook are latter-day Scrooges. Financial Times December 29. http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/558894bc-68b0-11e3-bb3e 00144feabdc0.html#axzz3P3h33bVS [November 14, 2014].

Rajan R, Servaes H, Zingales L. 2000. The cost of diversity: the diversification discount and inefficient investment. Journal of Finance 55(1): 35 – 80.

Richard PJ, Devinney TM, Yip GS, Johnson G. 2009. Measuring organizational performance: towards methodological best practice. Journal of Management 35(3): 718 – 804.

Robins J, Wiersema MF. 1995. A resource-based approach to the multibusiness firm – empirical analysis of portfolio interrelationships and corporate financial performance. Strategic Management Journal 16(4): 277 – 299. Scharfstein DS, Stein JC. 2000. The dark side of internal capital markets: divisional rent-seeking

and inefficient investment. Journal of Finance 55(6): 2537 – 2564. Simon HA. 1947. Administrative Behavior. Macmillan: New York. Smith KG, Ferrier WJ, Ndofor H. 2001. Competitive dynamics research: critique and future

directions. In Handbook of Strategic Management, Hitt M, Freeman RE, Harrison J (eds.). Blackwell Publishers: London, 315 – 361.

Speckbacher G, Neumann K, Hoffmann WH. 2014. Resource relatedness and the mode of entry into new businesses: internal resource accumulation vs. access by collaborative arrangement. Strategic Management Journal.

Page 36: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

36

Tan J, Peng MW. 2003. Organizational slack and firm performance during economic transitions: two studies from an emerging economy. Strategic Management Journal 24(13): 1249 – 1263.

Thompson J. 1967. Organization in Action. McGraw-Hill: New York. Tong TW, Reuer JJ. 2006. Firm and industry influences on the value of growth options. Strategic

Organization 4(1): 71 – 95. Tong TW, Reuer JJ. 2007. Real options in strategic management. Advances in Strategic

Management 24(1): 3 – 28. Tong TW, Reuer JJ, Peng MW. 2008. International joint ventures and the value of growth

options. Academy of Management Journal 51(5): 1014 – 1029. Vomberg A, Homburg C, Bornemann T. 2014. Talented people and strong brands: the

contribution of human capital and brand equity to firm value. Strategic Management Journal.

Welbourne TM, Andrews AO. 1996. Predicting the performance of initial public offerings: should human resource management be in the equation? Academy of Management Journal 39(4): 891 – 919.

Werder A. 2011. Corporate governance and stakeholder opportunism. Organization Science 22(5): 1345 – 1358.

White H. 1980. A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity. Econometrica 48(4): 817 – 838.

Wooldridge JM. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. MIT Press: Cambridge.

Wooldridge JM. 2003. Introductory Econometrics. South-Western: Mason, OH. Zhou YM. 2011. Synergy, coordination costs, and diversification choices. Strategic Management

Journal 32(6): 624 – 639.

Page 37: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

37

TABLE 1

Descriptive Statistics and Correlations

Variable Mean S.D. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 1 Tobin’s q 1.41 1.12 2 Firm size 5.69 1.95 -0.01 3 Abs. slack 0.26 0.18 0.24 -0.26 4 Pot. slack 0.77 0.20 0.21 -0.14 0.23 5 Cash flow 0.06 0.13 0.15 0.18 -0.27 0.12 6 Firm R&D int. 0.04 0.07 0.25 -0.07 0.63 0.23 -0.15 7 Firm adv. int. 0.01 0.03 0.07 0.02 0.23 0.02 -0.02 -0.01 8 Firm cap. int. 0.07 0.08 0.05 0.01 -0.19 -0.05 0.11 -0.14 -0.05 9 Firm growth 0.11 0.34 0.19 0.01 -0.09 0.02 0.17 -0.02 -0.03 0.18 10 Ind. Tobin’s q 1.47 0.58 0.47 -0.13 0.40 0.22 0.02 0.38 0.07 -0.05 0.10 11 Cash 0.14 0.17 0.34 -0.14 0.42 0.44 -0.04 0.48 0.05 -0.16 -0.00 0.33 12 Ind. comp. 0.72 0.20 0.07 0.02 0.07 0.02 0.02 0.13 -0.01 0.16 0.06 0.14 0.06 13 Ind. R&D int. 0.04 0.05 0.25 -0.11 0.54 0.27 -0.08 0.71 -0.02 -0.19 -0.02 0.53 0.47 0.18 14 Ind. growth 0.50 0.50 0.34 -0.09 0.27 0.17 0.04 0.25 0.05 0.02 0.11 0.68 0.23 0.10 0.35 15 Corp. gov. 0.56 0.19 -0.12 0.25 -0.12 -0.09 -0.02 -0.10 -0.04 -0.05 -0.09 -0.13 -0.17 -0.05 -0.11 -0.11 16 Diversification 0.15 0.27 -0.10 0.22 -0.14 -0.07 0.02 -0.12 -0.04 -0.06 -0.03 -0.11 -0.13 -0.10 -0.12 -0.09 0.18 17 Corp. opacity 8.66 2.73 -0.27 -0.68 0.12 -0.05 -0.27 0.02 -0.05 -0.02 -0.08 -0.13 0.00 -0.01 0.02 -0.12 -0.18 -0.11 All means, standard deviations, and correlation values are based on the baseline file (9,298 firms and 65,784 firm-years), except those for corporate governance, diversification, and corporate opacity where the respective samples are used. Statistically significant correlations (p < 0.05), using two-tailed tests, are in bold. The actual means for the logged variables are: $2753.19 million (firm size) and 1.26 times previous year’s sales (firm growth). Industry growth is a dummy variable that takes on a value of either 0 or 1.

Page 38: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

38

TABLE 2

Fixed Effects Regression Results for Cash and Value Creation Moderators on Firm Performance

Variable Industry competition Industry R&D intensity Industry growth Model 1A Model 1B Model 2A Model 2B Model 3A Model 3B Intercept 0.996*** 0.982*** 0.996*** 0.996*** 0.996*** 0.989*** Controls Lagged Tobin’s q 0.324*** 0.311*** 0.324*** 0.312*** 0.324*** 0.312*** Firm size -0.222*** -0.214*** -0.222*** -0.213*** -0.222*** -0.214*** Absorbed slack -0.303*** -0.349*** -0.303*** -0.341*** -0.303*** -0.337*** Potential slack 0.202*** 0.042 0.202*** 0.045 0.202*** 0.053 Cash flow 0.687*** 0.676*** 0.687*** 0.673*** 0.687*** 0.673*** Firm R&D intensity -0.193 -0.202 -0.193 -0.147 -0.193 -0.171 Firm advertising intensity -0.148 -0.084 -0.148 -0.091 -0.148 -0.087 Firm capital intensity 0.356*** 0.519*** 0.356*** 0.505*** 0.356*** 0.523*** Firm growth 0.194*** 0.204*** 0.194*** 0.203*** 0.194*** 0.203*** Industry Tobin’s q 0.627*** 0.619*** 0.627*** 0.621*** 0.627*** 0.609*** Square of cash -0.491** -0.724*** -0.605*** Explanatory Cash 0.733*** 1.169*** 0.944*** Industry competition -0.031 Industry R&D intensity -1.753*** Industry growth -0.062*** Interactions Cash x Industry competition 0.677*** Cash x Industry R&D intensity 3.144*** Cash x Industry growth 0.548*** F-value 391.19 361.09 391.19 359.52 391.19 390.62 p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Adjusted R² 0.3338 0.3446 0.3338 0.3449 0.3338 0.3463 Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes YesN 65,784 65,784 65,784 65,784 65,784 65,784

The dependent variable is firm performance measured using Tobin’s q. The variables firm size and firm growth are logged. Year fixed effects are not reported for brevity. Unstandardized coefficients are used. Two-tailed tests are used, and statistical significance denoted using *** p < 0.001, ** p < 0.01, * p < 0.05.

Page 39: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

39

TABLE 3

Fixed Effects Regression Results for Cash and Value Appropriation Moderators on Firm Performance

Variable Corporate governance Diversification Corporate opacity Model 4A Model 4B Model 5A Model 5B Model 6A Model 6B Intercept 1.563*** 1.416*** 1.041*** 0.994*** 1.646*** 2.953*** Controls Lagged Tobin’s q 0.259*** 0.243*** 0.296*** 0.284*** 0.290*** 0.256*** Firm size -0.261*** -0.249*** -0.241*** -0.232*** -0.324*** -0.430*** Absorbed slack -1.152*** -1.218*** -0.363*** -0.422*** -0.683*** -0.602*** Potential slack 0.405*** 0.279*** 0.230*** 0.064 0.325*** 0.043 Cash flow 1.162*** 1.167*** 0.762*** 0.744*** 1.000*** 0.891*** Firm R&D intensity -0.207 -0.063 -0.084 -0.068 -0.152 -0.022 Firm advertising intensity 0.057 0.079 -0.026 0.048 0.009 -0.028 Firm capital intensity 0.215 0.566*** 0.432*** 0.620*** 0.242* 0.426*** Firm growth 0.224*** 0.240*** 0.217*** 0.229*** 0.280*** 0.284*** Industry Tobin’s q 0.652*** 0.640*** 0.704*** 0.694*** 0.686*** 0.658*** Square of cash 0.430 -0.454** 0.100 Explanatory Cash 1.881*** 1.295*** 1.441*** Corporate governance 0.005 Diversification 0.052* Corporate opacity -0.981***

Interactions Cash x Corporate governance -0.112*** Cash x Diversification -0.645*** Cash x Corporate opacity -0.862*** F-value 150.05 135.93 336.69 311.27 269.44 299.51 p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Adjusted R² 0.3895 0.4032 0.3404 0.3514 0.4042 0.4288 Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N 15,899 15,899 53,669 53,669 35,549 35,549

The dependent variable is firm performance measured using Tobin’s q. The variables firm size and firm growth are logged. Year fixed effects are not reported for brevity. Unstandardized coefficients are used. Two-tailed tests are used, and statistical significance denoted using *** p < 0.001, ** p < 0.01, * p < 0.05.

Page 40: WHEN IS CASH GOOD OR BAD FOR FIRM PERFORMANCE? …fs2.american.edu/parthiba/www/smj15.pdf · PARTHIBAN DAVID American University Kogod School of Business 4400 Massachusetts Avenue

40

Figure 1

Panels A, B, and C depict the moderators used for value creation, while panels D, E, and F depict the moderators used for value appropriation. In each panel, the y-axis denotes predicted firm performance while the x-axis plots the value of cash that varies between 0 and 1. The 99th and 1st percentiles are used to denote ‘high’ and ‘low’ values respectively.

Low Comp.

High Comp.

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

0 0.5 1

Perf

orm

ance

Cash

Panel A: Industry Competition

Low Ind. R&D

High Ind. R&D

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

0 0.5 1

Perf

orm

ance

Cash

Panel B: Industry R&D Intensity

Low Ind. Growth

High Ind. Growth

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

0 0.5 1

Perf

orm

ance

Cash

Panel C: Industry Growth

Low (Weak) Gov.

High (Strong)

Gov.

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

0 0.5 1

Perf

orm

ance

Cash

Panel D: Corporate Governance

Low Div.

High Div.

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

0 0.5 1

Perf

orm

ance

Cash

Panel E: Diversification

Low Opacity

High Opacity

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

0 0.5 1

Perf

orm

ance

Cash

Panel F: Corporate Opacity


Recommended