+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles...

Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles...

Date post: 07-Oct-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
53
Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles and Debt? Armando Gomes Gordon Phillips ABSTRACT We examine an comprehensive set of private and public security issuance decisions by publicly traded companies. We study private and public issues of debt, convertibles and common equity securities. The market for public rms issuing private securities is large. Of the over 13,000 issues we examine, more than half are in the private market. We nd that asymmetric infor- mation plays a large role in the choice of public versus private market, while risk is a more important determinant for the type of security. Our evidence shows that the sensitivity of public and private equity issuance decisions to asymmetric information is fundamentally dier- ent. Firms with high levels of asymmetric information and are less likely to issue public equity over public debt but more likely to issue private equity and private convertibles. Firms with low risk but still high asymmetric information are more likely to issue private debt. First version: September 2004 First Draft: Very Preliminary University of Pennsylvania and University of Maryland and NBER respectively. Gomes can be reached at [email protected] and Phillips can be reached at [email protected]. We alone are responsible for the conclusions and analysis in this paper.
Transcript
Page 1: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles andDebt?

Armando Gomes Gordon Phillips∗

ABSTRACT

We examine an comprehensive set of private and public security issuance decisions by publiclytraded companies. We study private and public issues of debt, convertibles and common equitysecurities. The market for public Þrms issuing private securities is large. Of the over 13,000issues we examine, more than half are in the private market. We Þnd that asymmetric infor-mation plays a large role in the choice of public versus private market, while risk is a moreimportant determinant for the type of security. Our evidence shows that the sensitivity ofpublic and private equity issuance decisions to asymmetric information is fundamentally differ-ent. Firms with high levels of asymmetric information and are less likely to issue public equityover public debt but more likely to issue private equity and private convertibles. Firms withlow risk but still high asymmetric information are more likely to issue private debt.

First version: September 2004First Draft: Very Preliminary

∗University of Pennsylvania and University of Maryland and NBER respectively. Gomes can be reached [email protected] and Phillips can be reached at [email protected]. We alone are responsible for theconclusions and analysis in this paper.

Page 2: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Why Do Public Firms Issue Public and Private Equity, Convertibles and Debt?

ABSTRACT

We examine an comprehensive set of private and public security issuance decisions by publiclytraded companies. We study private and public issues of debt, convertibles and common equitysecurities. The market for public Þrms issuing private securities is large. Of the over 13,000issues we examine, more than half are in the private market. We Þnd that asymmetric infor-mation plays a large role in the choice of public versus private market, while risk is a moreimportant determinant for the type of security. Our evidence shows that the sensitivity ofpublic and private equity issuance decisions to asymmetric information is fundamentally dif-ferent. Firms with high levels of asymmetric information are less likely to issue public equityover public debt but more likely to issue private equity and private convertibles. Firms withlow risk but still high asymmetric information are more likely to issue private debt.

Page 3: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Why Do Public Firms Issue Public and Private Equity, Convertibles and Debt?

1 Introduction

This study is a comprehensive examination of security issuance decisions by public Þrms in both private

and public security markets. We study both private and public issues of debt, convertibles and common

equity - a total of 6 different security-market choices. The market for public Þrms issuing private securities

is large. Of the over 13,000 issues we examine, more than half are in the private market, comprising

issuances of equity, debt and convertible bonds and preferred stock. Our comprehensive database allows

to assess the impact of asymmetric information, and moral hazard problems on Þrms�s security issuance

decision.

We explore several reasons that inßuence the market in which Þrms sell securities and the type of

securities Þrms issue. In particular, the existence of asymmetric information may induce Þrms to sell

securities to private parties who may have better information or whom may more efficiently produce

information. Also, Þrm risk may inßuence which security a Þrm issues to mitigate agency problems of

debt. Moreover, given that private security sales typically involve block sales of securities to few investors,

there may be beneÞts of concentrated ownership in monitoring the Þrm and mitigating agency problems

between shareholders and managers.

While many other studies have examined the impact of asymmetric information and agency problems on

security issuance decisions, our study examines these factors using security issuance decisions of multiple

types and in different markets, and uses novel proxies for the factors. Our study links three different

databases, a private equity and convertible database, a private debt database and the SDC new issue

database, to Compustat and CRSP to examine issuance decisions. We also link these databases to IBES

to use analyst earnings forecast data to construct measures of asymmetric information and use information

on the quality of corporate governance from both existing and hand collected sources from Þrms� charters

and bylaws.

Our results show that asymmetric information is a major determinant of the decision to use the private

markets. Firms with the higher analyst earnings forecast error and dispersion (our measures of asymmetric

information) issue private securities. Our results for the speciÞc type of security issued show that

conditional upon issuing in the public market, Þrms with higher analyst forecast error and dispersion are

1

Page 4: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

less likely to issue public equity and are more likely to issue public debt. Therefore, our results provide

qualitative support for the pecking order conditional upon issuing public securities. However, our study does

not support the simple version of the pecking order as presented by Myers and Majluf (1984). We Þnd that

conditional upon issuing in the private market the reverse of the pecking order holds, with private equity

and convertibles being more likely to be issued by Þrms with high levels of asymmetric information. These

results are broadly consistent with Fulghieri and Lukin (2001) who argue that incentives for information

production by private investors is higher the more information-sensitive the securities being issued are, and

predict a reversal of the pecking order when private offerings are attractive.

Previous empirical work on the importance of asymmetric information, risk and agency problems for

security issuance shows mixed results. Lucas and McDonald (1990) show that equity issues are timed

after stock price runups, evidence consistent with managers timing security issuance to take into account

asymmetric information. Our study contains direct evidence that asymmetric information is very im-

portant for security issuance decisions. Previous studies examining issuance decisions have used either a

subset of these data or identiÞed security issuance through the statement of cash ßows from Compustat.2

In particular, the statement of cash ßows from Compustat does not identify whether the equity or debt

issuance was in the public or private market. Identifying where the security is sold, in particular whether

the security is private equity or private convertibles, is important as we show that the sensitivity of the

probability of issuing equity to asymmetric information is fundamentally different in private versus public

markets.

We also show that risk and investment opportunities and the associated potential agency problems

among equityholders and debtholders are important in determining the choice of market and security -

debt, convertibles, or equity. We show that Þrms with the more risk and investment opportunities are

most likely to issue equity and convertibles. These results are consistent with Green (1984) and Brennan

and Schwartz (1988) who argue that management of a company with straight debt outstanding will have an

incentive to increase the risk of a Þrm, thus when there is doubt about the future policy of the company,

convertibles can reduce investment inefficiencies. We also Þnd that likelihood of private placements of

debt and convertibles relative to their public counterpart increase with increases in risk and investment

opportunities. This is as predicted by Blackwell and Kidwell (1988), and Diamond (1991), as private debt

2Recent studies that have used Compustat data and a Þrm�s statement of cash ßows to ascertain if the Þrm issues debt orequity include Hovakimian, Opler and Titman (2001), Frank and Goyal (2003), Korajczyk and Levy (2003), and Leary andRoberts (2004a,b), Lemmon and Zender (2002) and Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999). Conclusions made in these papers havebeen mixed.

2

Page 5: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

is concentrated with a few lenders who have more incentives to produce costly information and monitor

the Þrm than dispersed public bondholders, and moreover, is easier to renegotiate.

Our results for private versus public issuance of debt are largely consistent with previous empirical

evidence. For example, the private-public debt choice has been explored by Houston and James (1996),

Krishnaswami et al. (1999), and more recently by Denis and Mihov (2002). They largely agree that higher

risk and investment opportunities leads the Þrm to choose private bank debt over public debt. However,

considering all the security-market choices rather than a more limited choice set allow us to draw some

novel implications. In particular, we will show empirically that Þrms shift from public to private debt

as risk starts increasing but after a certain level of risk they shift toward private convertibles or equity.

Previous studies that have examined private equity are less common (Wruck (1989), Hertzel and Smith

(1993) and Allen and Phillips (2000)) and have only examined private equity separately, not including

public equity or other securities.

In addition to asymmetric information and risk, we also investigate the impact of corporate governance

and potential conßicts between managers and shareholders on security-market choice. We Þnd that corpo-

rate governance, while statistically signiÞcant, is economically not important. Firms with higher-quality

corporate governance are more likely to undertake a private placement than a public offering, however this

results is economically not very important. This result is perhaps not surprising given that theory provide

conßicting implications between the relationship between agency costs of equity and the use of disciplining

devices such as debt and private placements to would be monitors.3

While the security-market choice is potentially unrelated to the Þrms� corporate governance character-

istics, the market response to the security-market choice should not be ambiguous: the market should react

positively to a Þrm with bad governance that decides to self-discipline and negatively otherwise. We thus

estimate a new test of whether debt and private placements are indeed perceived by the market as valuable

disciplining devices. We Þnd that the market response is signiÞcantly more negative when low quality

governance Þrms issue public equity, the lowest disciplining security-market choice combination, and is

signiÞcantly more positive when high-quality governance Þrms issue private debt, the best disciplining

security-market choice combination.

The paper proceeds as follows. In the next section, we discuss the framework for our empirical analysis.

3For example, Grossman and Hart (1982) argue that Þrms with incentive problems should use debt to mitigate thoseproblems. A similar argument is made by Kahn and Winton (1998) for the use of private placements to stimulate monitoring.However, managers have discretion over issuance decisions and use of those disciplining devices may be plagued by the sameconßicts that it is trying to resolve (see Zwiebel (1996)).

3

Page 6: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Section II describes the data and econometrics. Section III presents the empirical results and discussion.

Section IV concludes.

2 Theoretical Background and Framework for Security-Market Choice

A substantial amount of theory has focused on the role of asymmetric information and agency problems as

primary determinants of the choice of security and market. In this section we review the main predictions

of these models, and review the existing empirical evidence. We also formulate a reduced form econometric

model that enable us to test the main predictions of the theories. This econometric model will allow us

to estimate the implied sensitivity of the Þrms� choices to proxies for asymmetric information, risk and

potential agency problems.

A. Theoretical Background and Prior Empirical Evidence

A1. Asymmetric Information

One large strand of the literature focuses on problems related to adverse selection due to ex-ante

information asymmetries between managers and investors. The classic articles are Myers and Majluf (1984)

and Myers (1984) who show that asymmetric information result in a pecking order for external Þnance

- with less informationally sensitive securities such as debt being chosen Þrst by Þrms with asymmetric

information. Moreover, this adverse selection problem may result in underinvestment because undervalued

Þrms may refrain to raise Þnance due to the dilution cost of selling underpriced securities. Several papers

that followed study security designs that may mitigate the problem. In particular, Brennan and Schwartz

(1987), Constantinides and Grundy (1989), Brennan and Kraus (1997), and Stein (1992) demonstrate that

convertible securities can be used to solve the adverse selection problem.

Private placements to one or few investors (as opposed to a public offering to several investors) is

another mechanism that resolves the adverse selection problem. In the context of debt offerings, this point

has been made by Boyd and Prescott (1986) and Diamond (1984) who argue that intermediaries such as

banks have a cost advantage in producing information because a public offering to dispersed investors leads

to either duplication of effort or a free-rider problem. In the context of initial public offerings of equity,

Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1999) and Maksimovic and Pichler (1999) model how asymmetric information

affects the choice between going public and private placements. Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1999) show

that Þrms with signiÞcant information asymmetry may prefer a private placement than going public,

because private investors can produce additional costly information, thereby reducing the informational

disadvantage, while such incentives are not present when shares are sold to dispersed investors. The cost of

4

Page 7: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

private placements though is that public offerings allow for better diversiÞcation of risks and more liquidity.

It may also give private investors a costly information monopoly or too much bargaining power (Rajan

1992).

The interaction between the security and market choice and asymmetric information is explored in

Fulghieri and Lukin (2001). They show that incentives for information production by private investors

depend on the degree of information sensitivity of the securities being issued. Issuance of more information-

sensitive securities provide greater incentives for information production by private investors, thus reducing

the extent of information asymmetry and conveying a more positive signal to uniformed investors. Fulghieri

and Lukin predict a reversal of the pecking order when the costs of producing information by private

investors are relatively low, with the likelihood of issuing equity relative to debt being positively related

to the degree of information asymmetry. However, the classic pecking order still hold when the costs of

producing private information are high, in which case the Þrm is more likely to make a public offering.

Overall, these theories suggest that private securities of a given type (debt, equity or convertibles) are

more likely to be issued than their public counterparts when the potential for adverse selection problems

are more severe. We also conjecture that the beneÞt of the private over the public market should be

more pronounced the more information-sensitive the security issued is. Moreover, conditional on a private

offering the reverse of the pecking order should hold, and conditional on a public offering we expect the

pecking order to hold. That is, the likelihood of issuing securities that are more information-sensitive is

increasing or decreasing with the degree of information asymmetry depending on whether the securities are

placed privately or publicly, respectively. The theories also have implications for the stock price market

reaction around issues depending on the security-market choice. First, the abnormal return should be

negatively (positively) related with the degree of information asymmetry for public (private) offerings.

Second, these relations should be stronger the more information-sensitive the security issued is.

Early studies that examine stock returns around offerings are consistent with theory predictions. Wruck

(1989), Hertzel and Smith (1993), Allen and Phillips (2000), Chaplinsky and Haushalter (2003), and Brophy

et. al (2004) Þnd positive stock market returns around private placements of equity and convertibles. This

result is in contrast to the negative returns around public offerings of securities found in Asquith and

Mullins (1986), Masulis and Korwar (1986), and Mikkelson and Parch (1986). Hertzel and Smith (1993)

and Wu (2003) Þnd support for asymmetric information being important for private placements of equity.

Their results support a certiÞcation role for outside investors with the discount to private placement as

compensation for the certiÞcation provided. It has not yet been tested whether the predicted relations

5

Page 8: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

between information asymmetry and returns in each market hold - we will test these relations in section 4.

Empirical work on the importance of asymmetric information for the security choice shows mixed

results. Helwege and Liang (1996) report that asymmetric information does not inßuence the choice

between public equity, private debt and public bonds. Hovakimian, Opler and Titman (2001) also examine

multiple security issuances and Þnd a limited role for asymmetric information. Frank and Goyal (2004) do

not examine the role of asymmetric information itself but examine the predictions of the static trade-off

theory on a large sample of Þrms, following tests by Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999) on larger Þrms. They

Þnd that larger Þrms exhibit some aspects of the pecking order, smaller Þrms who are likely to be subject

to problems of asymmetric information do not. Recent evidence by Leary and Roberts (2004b) also reject

the pecking order, and, in particular, why Þrms choose to issue equity over debt.4 However, Chang et

al. (2004) Þnd that likelihood of using equity versus debt is increasing on the number of analyst coverage

(their proxy for the degree of asymmetric information), consistent with pecking order predictions.

These papers though do not examine these relations separately for public and private offerings. They

rely on the statement of cash ßows to determine security issuance5, which does not contain information

about the breakdown between public and private offerings. However, since the theories make opposite

predictions for the relationship between security choice and asymmetric information, depending on the

market in which they are issued, these mixed Þndings may be the result of combining public with private

offerings for both equity and debt.

A2. Agency Problems between Debt-Holders and Equity-Holders

Agency conßicts among shareholders and debtholders are important determinants of security-market

choice. The literature have emphasized two classical type of moral hazard problems: the asset substitution

problem (Jensen and Meckling (1976)) and the debt overhang or underinvestment problem (Myers (1977)).

These problems are more severe for Þrms with volatile cash ßows and low proÞtability (riskier Þrms) because

the chances of entering in Þnancial distress are higher, and agency problems are particularly acute for Þrms

in Þnancial distress. Also, agency problems are stronger for Þrms with better investment opportunities

(often proxied by Tobin�s q and research and development expenditures) due to the higher potential cost

of passing up valuable investment opportunities and the greater ßexibility to undertake excessively risky

projects. Same considerations explain why these problems are likely to be greater for smaller Þrms.

4Leary and Roberts (2004b) examine whether information asymmetry is important in the timing of security issuancedecisions as predicted by the static pecking order theory and they do not Þnd asymmetric information is important. We donot test the timing of security decisions in our work.

5Helwege and Liang (1996) obtain information from the statment of cash ßow and other sources but do not identify privateplacements of equity.

6

Page 9: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

The simplest solution to these debt holder- equity holder incentive problems is to issue equity rather

than debt. However, equity may have other costs, such as adverse selection costs, and debt may have other

beneÞts, such as tax advantages, so Þrms have incentives to design debt in ways that minimize potential

conßicts of interest (see also the following subsection A3).

Green (1984) and Brennan and Schwartz (1988) propose that convertibles can mitigate agency costs

of debt. Convertibles provide incentives for managers not to undertake excessive risk because convertible-

holders have a call option on Þrm value, and the value of convertibles are relatively insensitive to shifts in

Þrm risk -so investment decisions are not as distorted as when the Þrm issue straight debt.

Private placement of debt is another solution to the problem (Blackwell and Kidwell (1988), Diamond

(1991)). Private debt is concentrated with a few lenders who have more incentives to produce costly infor-

mation and monitor the Þrm than dispersed public bondholders. Moreover, private debt is advantageous

when the Þrm enters in Þnancial distress because public debt is governed by the Trust Indenture Act of

1939, which makes renegotiation of public debt contracts more difficult than private debt (see Gorton and

Winton for a recent survey of the literature). Both considerations also apply to convertibles. Therefore,

private convertibles are also less exposed to incentive problems than public convertibles- however we have

not seem any references to this in the literature.

The implications of these theories are thus the following: equity and convertibles are more likely to be

issued by Þrms that are riskier and have more investment opportunities. Private placements of debt and

convertibles are more likely then public placements of debt and convertibles respectively in riskier and high

growth Þrms.

The empirical evidence support most of the predictions above. Mikkelson (1981) Þnd that convertibles

are issued by highly-leveraged, high growth Þrms. The private-public debt choice has been explored by

Houston and James (1996), Krishnaswami et al. (1999), Cantillo and Wright (2000), and more recently by

Denis and Mihov (2002). They largely agree that higher risk and investment opportunities leads Þrm to

choose private bank (or private non-bank debt) over public debt.

Allowing for all the security-market choices rather than a more limited choice set will allow us to draw

some novel implications. In particular, we will show empirically that Þrms shift from public to private debt

as risk starts increasing but after a certain level of risk they shift toward private convertibles and equity.

A3. Agency Problems between Managers and Shareholders

Agency conßicts among managers and shareholders can also create signiÞcant distortions. Several

papers following Grossman and Hart (1982) have used an ex-ante value maximization perspective to solve

7

Page 10: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

for the optimal mix of debt and equity. These papers predict that debt should be used to mitigate

incentive problems; debt increases efficiency because it prevents empire building managers from Þnancing

unproÞtable projects. The threat of takeover or loss of control is an alternative (or substitute) mechanism

to the use of debt in curbing managerial distortions. Indeed Jensen and Ruback (1983), and Shleifer

and Vishny (1989)) argue that agency problems among shareholders and managers are particularly severe

when managers can resist hostile takeovers. Therefore, an implication of the literature following Grossman

and Hart (1982) is that debt should be used even more as a disciplining device in Þrms with powerful

antitakeover defenses.

Managers however have discretion over leverage decisions and the use of debt itself may be plagued

by conßicts. Managers may prefer less than the optimal amount of debt due to a desire to reduce Þrm

risk to protect their underdiversiÞed human capital (Fama (1980)) or their dislike of performance pressure

associated with large interest payments (Jensen (1986)). Zwiebel (1996) focuses on takeover threats as a

driving force for the use of debt, and partially entrenched managers trade-off empire building ambitions

with the need to ensure sufficient efficiency to prevent control challenges (see also Novaes and Zingales

(1995)). The more antitakeover defenses the Þrm have the lower can the debt level be that discourage

control challenges, so the debt level should be negatively related to antitakeover defenses.

An alternative mechanism to deal with managerial excess is monitoring by large shareholders (Shleifer

and Vishny (1989)). A private placement of a block of shares to an investor that naturally becomes a

large shareholder is a direct way to improve monitoring and concentrate ownership (see also Kahn and

Winton (1998)). An even more powerful disciplining combination is a private placement of debt, as the

Þrm is simultaneously getting both the disciplining role of debt and the incentives for monitoring of a large

investor (Diamond (1991)). However, the choice of a private placement is also likely to be plagued by the

same managerial discretion problem we referred to above, leading to ambiguous predictions. Also note

that, similarly, the value of adding a monitor by means of a private placements is likely to be higher for

bad governance Þrms.

The theories then lead to the following conclusions: the likelihood of issuing debt and issuing privately to

large investors are increasing or decreasing with antitakeover defenses, respectively, if value maximization or

managerial discretion are the predominant force. Even though the security-choice is potentially ambiguous,

the market response is not, and should be consistent with value maximization. These observation allow us

to contribute a new test of whether debt and private placements are indeed valuable disciplining devices,

especially for Þrm with worse corporate governance. According to the value maximization view the worst

8

Page 11: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

security-market choice combination for a Þrm with bad governance is public equity (and the market reaction

should be particularly negative). On the other extreme, the best that a bad governance Þrm can do is to

issue private debt (and the market reaction should be particularly positive).

Empirical evidence the importance of managerial agency issues includes Berger, Ofek and Yermack

(1986) who show that leverage increases after entrenchment reducing shocks to managerial security. Wruck

examines the excess returns to private placements of equity and Þnds that these are highest when large new

blocks are sold as part of the security sale, which she interprets as being evidence of improved monitoring.

Hertzel and Smith (1993) and Wu (2003) do not Þnd evidence that private placements are motivated by

monitoring. Recent evidence by Barclay, Holderness and Smith (2003) claims, however, that discounts

to private equity are compensation to private blockholders for passively allowing management to become

more entrenched.

B. Reduced Form Model of Security-Market Issuance

We estimate several different models of security-market issuance decisions. These models allow us to

the relative importance of asymmetric information, and agency cost over issuance decisions.

Our reduced-form econometric model assumes that the Þrm that the Þrm wants to raise I to invest

in a project with positive NPV. Let the NPV of a Þrm when issuing security j be Vj(x) net of direct

and indirect issuance costs, where x is a vector of exogenous Þrm characteristics, and j = e, c, d, E,C,D

for private equity, private convertibles, private debt, public equity, public convertibles, and public debt

respectively. The Þrm chooses the securities-market Y = j such that Y = argmaxVj(x). We model the

(unobserved) value function as a linear function of observed relevant Þrm characteristics plus a random

noise. We will consider several different speciÞcations for the noise.

The multinomial logit model is one of the formulations we estimate which corresponds to the case in

which the noise of each choice are independent and identically distributed with extreme value distribution.

The multinomial logit model, while appealing due to its simplicity, turns out not to be a good model for

our problem. This model implies that choices between two alternatives are independent of the others�i.e.

the IIA assumption� which simply says that if one of the alternatives is removed from the model, the other

alternatives will have the same identical proportionate increase in probability of being chosen. It turns

out that when we remove private convertibles from the model, private equity disproportionately gains in

probability versus the other choices. Likewise when we remove private debt from the choice set, public

debt disproportionately gains in probability.

Given the failure of the independence of irrelevance alternatives assumption, the most general models

9

Page 12: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

we will estimate are nested logit models. We estimate two different nested logit models. Model 1: The

Þrms pick the security they wish (debt, convertibles, or equity) to sell Þrst and then choose the market,

(public or private), in which they sell that security- this model corresponds to a speciÞcation of the error

that allow for correlation among the same security choice but are uncorrelated across securities. Model

2: we change the nesting structure so that Þrms choose the market they wish to issue Þrst and then the

type of security second- this model corresponds to a speciÞcation of the error that allow for correlation

among choices in the same market but are uncorrelated across markets. All models are estimated using

the maximum likelihood method using the formulas for the probabilities of making each choices (see the

appendix for more details on the nested logit model and associated choice probabilities).

When specifying a parametrization for the value function Vj(x), we normalize value to the Þrm so

that we are estimating relative value of each security choice relative to one an arbitrarily chosen security

type. In our case we estimate the value relative to public debt, which we thus normalize to zero plus an

econometric error. We examine the relative values for each of our two nested logit models as follows:

Model 1: (nested logit with security Þrst, market second): The following parametrization emphasizes

the value from the security choice with an additional value of the market choice given the security choice.

aEx, aCx, is the value of choosing a particular security (debt normalized to zero) and Wpriv = apriv,jx is

the additional value from the public-private choice within that security choice, indexed by j=e,c,d. for

equity, convertibles and debt respectively.

Choice 1Equity Convertibles Debt

Choice 2 Private Ve = apriv,ex+ aEx+ εe Vc = apriv,cx+ aCx+ εc Vd = apriv,dx+ εdPublic VE = aEx+ εE VC = aCx+ εC VD = εD

Model 2: (nested logit with market Þrst, security second): In the following βjx is the additional value

from choosing a particular security, (j = e, c,E,C), relative to debt, with βprivx the additional value a

Þrm gets from making a decision to issue in the private markets.

Choice 1Private Public

Choice 2 Equity Ve = βex+ βprivx+ εe VE = βEx+ εEConvertibles Vc = βcx+ βprivx+ εc VC = βCx+ εCDebt Vd = βprivx+ εd VD = εD

The security-market choice are expected to be related to asymmetric information and agency costs of

debt and equity as predicted by the theories we discussed in the previous section.

10

Page 13: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Using the coefficients of the logistic models we can test the following hypotheses in addition to tests

whether speciÞc coefficients are signiÞcantly different from zero. In particular we test the following

hypotheses - written with respect to Model 2, market choice followed by security issuance.

Sensitivity to asymmetric of information and the conditional pecking order: Letting xk, represent the

asymmetric information facing the Þrm, and βkj be the sensitivity of security j with respect to variable

k, we can test the following hypotheses about the sensitivity of a particular security type to asymmetric

information conditional on either the public or private market:

Hypothesis 1: βkE < βkC < 0 & β

ke < β

kc < 0 if the pecking order holds in public and private markets

respectively. This hypothesis is tested can be tested using the coefficients of Model 2 where Þrms choose

the market prior to the security.

Also since equity is a security that is more informationally sensitive than convertible which is more

sensitive than debt, we expect that the choice of market given a security choice under Model 1 should

change as follows with a change in level of private information.

Hypothesis 2:akpriv,e ≥ akpriv,c ≥ akpriv,dThe relations above basically state that as the level of info asymmetry increases than the Þrm is more

likely to private equity over public equity versus private convertible over public convertibles, or private

debt over public debt.

Sensitivity to risk: Similar to Hypothesis 1 but with a focus on risk, we can use Model 2 to examine

the sensitivity of security issuance to risk. If agency cost of debt is important for Þrms we expect Þrms

with higher risk will choose equity over debt. Letting xr, represent the risk facing the Þrm, and βrj be the

sensitivity of the security j to risk we have that:

Hypothesis 3: βrE ≥ βrC ≥ 0,for public markets and βre ≥ βrc ≥ 0, for private markets.In other words, increases in risk increase the odds ratio PE

PC(i.e.,

d(PEPC

)

dxk= eβ

rE−βrC ≥ 1 ) and also the

odds ratio PCPD(i.e.

d(PCPD

)

dxk= eβ

rC ≥ 1). Similar tests apply to private issuers.

3 Data

A. Data

We study security issuance by public U.S. corporations from January 1995 to December 2003. The

data on securities issuance comes from three different databases: PlacementTracker Database of Sagient

Research Systems, SDC new issues database, and DealScan database of the Loan Pricing Corporation.

11

Page 14: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

We match the data obtained from these sources to Compustat and CRSP, to obtain information on Þrm

Þnancials and stock prices. Following standard practice in the literature, we excluded from our sample

Þnancial Þrms (SICs 6000-6999) and regulated utilities (SICs 4900-4999). Our Þnal sample matched to

CRSP and COMPUSTAT has 13,114 issues during the 1995-2003 period. The total amount raised was

over $2.9 trillion and the mean (median) amount raised by each deal is also sizable representing 23% (13%)

of the total Þrm value (see table 1). There are a total of 4,137 different Þrms in our Þnal sample, and the

median Þrm Þnanced 2 times during the period (most of the multiple issues are multiple debt offerings by

the same company).

The data source for public offerings of debt, equity and convertibles preferred stock and bonds (hence-

forth, convertibles) is the Thomson Financial SDC new issues database.6 The data on privately placed

common stock (or private equity deals) and privately placed convertibles are from the PlacementTracker

database of Sagient Research Systems. The company specialize in collecting data on private placements

of common stock and convertibles primarily from SEC Þlings such as 10-Ks, 8-Ks, and 13-Ds (coverage

started in 1995, hence the beginning of our sample).

A private placement is a private sale of unregistered securities by a public company to a selected group

of individuals or institutional investors without general investor solicitation. These sales are typically made

to a small number of investors (the median (mean) number of investors in our private equity offerings is

3 (5.4)) and are generally conducted in accordance to the �safe harbor� provisions of Regulation D of the

1933 Securities Act.7

Private placements of equity-linked securities are also commonly referred to as Private Investments

in Public Equity, or PIPEs, and the PlacementTracker database includes almost all such deals.8 After

matching with Compustat and CRSP, and excluding Þnancial companies and regulated Þrms, we have a

total of 1,242 private equity issues and 1,014 private convertible issues made respectively by 762 and 668

different companies.

Our sample of private corporate debt is from the DealScan database of the Loan Pricing Corporation, a

Reuters company. The database contains information on term loans and revolving credit lines made to U.S.

companies by banks or syndicates of lenders. We include in our sample only long-term commercial loans

6We excluded secondary offerings, in which the company is not issuing new shares, and short-term debt offerings (maturityless than one year).

7Regulation D is an SEC Rule that allows public companies to issue stock privately, without the need for public registrationprior to the sale, to an unlimited number of accredited investors and no more than 35 non-accredited investors.

8We do not include in our sample a few transactions classiÞed as common stock shelf sales and equity line arrangements,because they typically require a registration statement to be effective prior to the sale of the stock, technically making thempublic offerings.

12

Page 15: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

and revolving credit lines (thus, for example, we drop 364-day facilities and any other loan with less than

one year of maturity).9 Companies often borrow using multiple loans or traunches at the same time. In our

dataset, we aggregate all traunches into a single transaction or deal adding up the amount of all long-term

loans and revolving credit lines. Our Þnal sample involves 5,651 deals by 2,615 different companies over

the 1995-2003 period (mean (median) number of 2.2 (2.0) private debt offerings per company). The most

common type of private debt are revolving credit lines (78% of the deals) followed by term loans (18% of

the deals)-deal type was determined based on the type of the largest tranche in case of multiple traunches.

We also include in our dataset Rule 144-A convertible and debt issues, which are also private place-

ments of unregistered securities. However, these transactions are distinct for what we classify as private

deals because investors are QualiÞed Institutional Buyers (Q.I.B�s)- large institutional investors with over

$1billion under management-, and moreover, these transactions are typically made to a signiÞcant number

of investors. For example, the median (mean) number of investor in 144A-convertible offerings is 33 (41),

while in the private convertible offering it is just 2 (3.4). In addition, the company often agrees to register

the securities issued a few months after the offering, making these transactions more alike public offerings

than private offerings. Our sample for 144-A convertibles is obtained from the PlacementTracker database

(486 deals) and for the 144-A debt offerings is obtained from the SDC new issues database (927 deals)-we

exclude all such deals from DealScan to avoid double counting.

We aggregate multiple deals by the same company and of the same type (i.e., one of the 8 security-

market choices) that occur within the same month, as we believe that they are likely to be different

traunches of the same deal-the procedure serves to combine mostly multiple debt issues. The Þnal sample

is a total of 13,114 transactions with data in both Compustat and CRSP.

B. The Variables

Our focus is on the relation between the security and market choice and Þrm characteristics. SpeciÞcally,

we are interested on the security choice-equity, debt, or convertibles-and the market choice-private versus

public-a total of 6 choices. Because 144-A and public seem more alike than 144-A and private offerings

(see for example the results in table 2B) we aggregate 144-A and public offerings (we also do the analysis

excluding 144-A and the results are similar). We also consider a full 8 choice model in which we look

separately at the choice of 144-A convertibles and debt.

B1. Asymmetric Information

We match our dataset to IBES to use analyst earnings forecast as a proxy for asymmetric information.

9We also dropped credit lines whose primary purpose is to back-up commercial paper, as those credit lines are seldom used.

13

Page 16: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

The main idea is that the dispersion among analysts forecasts and analyst forecasting errors are two

measures that are positively correlated with the difficulty investors and analysts have in estimating Þrm

value, and thus are likely to be positively correlated with asymmetric information, and insiders� private

information.

We use the IBES summary history database, which provides a monthly snapshot of consensus earnings

forecasts.10 In our study we use analysts forecasts for the company�s upcoming quarterly earnings release.

We construct two proxies: an earnings surprise measure and a dispersion measure.

The earnings surprise measure used for each deal is the mean quarterly earnings surprise for the last four

quarters with earnings report date preceding the issue date. The quarterly earnings surprise is computed

as the absolute value of the difference between the median earnings estimate and the actual earnings

per share, normalized by the stock price at the end of Þscal quarter (we also consider the robustness to

alternative normalizations based on the book value of equity per share and earnings per share). A similar

approach is used to construct the dispersion measure: it is the standard deviation of outstanding earnings

forecasts normalized by the stock price, averaged over the last four quarters preceding the issue date.

This measure is only available if there are at least two outstanding earnings forecasts. The surprise and

dispersion measures are trimmed to remove the most extreme 1% observations. This serves to remove

outliers and potentially misrecorded data.

Summary statistics are reported in table 2A. Note that the surprise measure is available for 11,096

of the transactions (85% of total) and the dispersion measure for 9,796 (75% of total). The dispersion

measure is available for fewer deals as we require at least two earnings forecasts for this measure. Also,

note that the test for differences in means reveals that both surprise and dispersion are signiÞcantly higher

for private than public offerings, consistent with the view that there is more asymmetric information for

companies involved in private deals.

B2. Corporate Governance

Our proxy for the degree of agency costs of equity is the quality of corporate governance as reßected by

the provisions adopted by Þrms in their charters and bylaws. We follow the approach used by Daines and

Klausner (2001) to build a corporate governance measure. They focus on four key antitakeover provisions

on the charter and bylaws that erect signiÞcant barriers to a hostile acquisition: (1) dual-class shares;

10The dataset contains summary statistics of earnings forecasts, such as means, medians, standard deviation, and thenumber of estimates, computed every Thrusday before the third Friday of every month (the statistical period) based onearnings forecasts outstanding. We use the consensus information of the latest statistical period before the quarterly earningsreport date to construct our proxies.

14

Page 17: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

(2) a classiÞed (or staggered) board; (3) prohibition of shareholders voting by written consent; and (4)

prohibition of shareholders calling a special shareholder meeting. Daines and Klausner (2001) argue that

(2) and (3) are almost perfect substitutes so there is shareholder voting restriction if and only if (3) and

(4) are both in place.

We construct a rank level ordering measuring the quality of corporate governance following Daines

and Klausner (2001, pg.116): 1 (worst), if the Þrm has dual-class shares or have a classiÞed board and a

shareholder voting restriction; 2, if the Þrm has classiÞed board but not shareholder voting restriction or

dual-class shares; 3, if there is a shareholder voting restriction but not classiÞed board or dual class shares;

and 4 (best), if the Þrm has none of the restrictive provisions above.11

Our data on corporate governance provisions are from three different sources: the Investor Responsibil-

ity Research Center (IRRC) dataset on takeover defenses, SharkRepellent.net web site, and, for a randomly

selected sample of 2,000 deals not matched to any of the two datasets, we hand collected the information

from the Þrm�s charter and bylaws. The information we use to construct the governance measure is based

on the provisions prevailing in the charters and bylaws before the deal date.12 The use of takeover defenses

in our sample is similar to the results reported in Daines and Klausner (2001), Laura and Fields (2002),

and Gompers et al. (2003). The distribution of the corporate governance measure is, in increasing order,

31% (worst), 29%, 6%, and 34% (best), for the 10,371 deals with complete information.

B3. Firm-Specific Variables

We use several Þrm speciÞc variables from Compustat and CRSP. Our measure of risk is a Þrm�s

cash flow volatility calculated as the standard deviation of cash ßow (operating income before depreciation,

Compustat data number: data13) using up to twenty Þscal quarters prior to the deal date. As control

variables, we also include a financial distress indicator which is Altman�s Z-score equals to one if Z is less

than 1.81 (see Altman (2000)). We include the log of firm value ( log firm size) which is equal to market

value of equity plus book values of preferred stock and total debt (Compustat data numbers: data24*data25

+ data9 + data34 + data39). Other variables included are Tobin’s q, which is calculated as the market

value of the Þrm divided by the book value of assets (data6) and a Þrm�s debt/asset ratio, calculated as long

term debt divided by book value of assets (Compustat data numbers: data9/lagged data6), R&D divided

11Daines and Klausner (2001) also make a further reÞnement based on whether the charter require a 90 days or moreadvance notice for the nomination of board candidates. We chose not to use this provision because it is not available in theIRRC dataset (also we believe this provision is not as relevant as the other ones).

12IRRC data is available for 1990, 1993, 1995, 1998, 2000, and 2002. SharkRepellent.net does not record historical informa-tion, so we used the current information for 2,700 deals matched to SharkRepellent.net. However, since Þrms seldom changeprovisions in charters and bylaws, we believe that this procedure is not likely to introduce signiÞcant measurement errors.

15

Page 18: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

by lagged property plant and equipment, which is deÞned as the total of R&D plus advertising (Compustat

data numbers ((data45+data46)/lagged data8). ProÞtability is operating cash ßow before depreciation

divided by lagged assets (data13/lagged data6) All of these variables are computed for the last Þscal year

ending before the transaction date. Using CRSP data we calculate a Þrm�s cumulative abnormal return

250 day prior to the deal- the excess return relative to a benchmark portfolio of Þrms in the same size

decile at the end of the year previous to the transaction (we also used a risk-adjusted beta decile portfolios

for robustness). For each deal we also compute the abnormal excess return using windows of 1, 5, 10 and

21 trading days around each issue- the parameters of the market model were estimated in the prior 250

trading days ending at the beginning of the event window. For all constructed variables except Tobin�s

q and assets we eliminate outliers by dropping the top and bottom one-percent of the sample. We also

eliminate Þrms, after eliminating other outliers, whose lagged book value of assets are less than .1 million

dollars and whose Tobin�s q is in the 99th percentile or above.

B4. Market Variables

We include three market variables in our regressions to capture aggregate market conditions in the

public markets. We include the Aaa bond yield, a credit spread to capture a distress risk premium,

measured as the Baa less the Aaa bond yield- we use the value of these variables as of the end of the

previous month before the issue date. Finally to capture conditions in the public equity markets we

include the cumulative market return over the 250 days prior to the security issue date.

4 Results

A. The Sample

Table 1 summarizes our sample of public Þrms and their issue decisions by year and for the entire

period. We present data for eight different security types: public equity, convertibles, and debt, private

equity, convertibles and debt, and debt and convertibles issued on Rule 144-A.

Insert Table 1 here

Table 1 shows several important facts. First private equity and private convertible issues are a

substantial fraction of securities issued by public companies. This fraction has also been increasing over

time with the number of private equity issues exceeding public equity issues from the year 2000 to 2003,

the last year of our database. The number of private convertibles is greater than the number of public

16

Page 19: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

convertibles for all years since 1995. The table shows that while private debt issues are larger than public

debt issues, private equity issuers are smaller and issue equity of a smaller fraction of Þrm value. The size

of private equity issues and the size of issuers. has also grown sharply in the later years. In later years the

size of private equity issues on average is almost 25% of the size of an average public equity issue. Finally,

Table 1 shows that Rule 144-A debt and convertible issues are closer in size to public debt and convertible

issues.

Table 2A summarizes the Þrm- and market-speciÞc variables that we examine. We present summary

statistics in this table for the whole sample and also for each of the eight security categories. We present

means, standard deviations and the number of observations for each variable. Table 2B presents t-statistics

testing whether the means from Table 2A are different across issue types.

Insert Table 2A and Table 2B here

Tables 2A and 2B show several interesting and signiÞcant patterns across the variables. First, columns

one and two show our measure of asymmetric information, analyst earnings surprise and dispersion, are

both signiÞcantly higher (t-statistics for differences in means are presented in Table 2B) for securities issued

in the private market. Measures of corporate governance are also higher in the private equity, convertibles

and debt markets. Tables 2A and 2B also show that private Þrms are smaller, have higher cash ßow

volatility (our measure of risk), higher R&D ratios and higher Tobin�s qs. Firms that issue in the private

market, however, have lower proÞtability and higher measure of Þnancial distress despite having less debt.

While private convertible issuers are sharply different from public issuers, issuers of convertibles in the 144

market are not signiÞcantly different from public issuers. They are also closer to public debt issuers than

they are to private debt issuers.

The picture that emerges from these summary statistics is that public issuers in the private market

are smaller, highly valued, less proÞtable Þrms versus public issuers that have a higher measures of our

proxies for asymmetric information. This conclusion is true for public Þrms irrespective of the security

type. Issuers in the public equity and convertible markets issue after a period of high cumulative abnormal

returns - reinforcing the conclusions of Lucas and McDonald (1990). Interestingly, when we separate out

issues by the private and public markets, issuers of debt are more proÞtable - especially when compared

to issuers of private equity and private convertibles who have signiÞcantly negative operating cash ßows.

B. Stock Market Response

We now present the stock market reactions to these security issuance. Table 3A presents the cumulative

17

Page 20: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

abnormal returns from a market model over different event windows relative to the announcement date for

the security issuance. In each case the excess returns are calculated from parameters of a market model

using 250 days of data prior to the Þrst day in the event window.

Insert Table 3A here

Inspection of Table 3A reveals results consistent with previous event studies. The market reaction to

public convertibles, and public equity is negative while the market reaction to private equity is strongly

and signiÞcantly positive, consistent with Wruck (1989), Hertzel and Smith(1993), and Allen and Phillips

(2000). For private convertibles and private debt, we Þnd a signiÞcant positive market reaction, albeit

one that is lower than that of private equity.

Table 3B presents the results from cross-sectional regressions of the 21 trading-day cumulative abnormal

returns around the issue on public versus private market type, and Þrm and market characteristics. We

run regressions for equity, convertibles and debt separately to examine the differences across markets,

conditional on security type. We interact the earnings surprise and corporate governance variables with

security indicator variables to examine whether there is a different market response to these variables by

security type. Other variables are included as control variables.

Insert Table 3B here

Inspection of Table 3B reveals that the overall reaction to private equity is positive while the reaction

to public equity issues is negative as is evident in the coefficients on market choice indicators in column

1. In columns 1 and 3, the signiÞcant positive interaction variable between earnings surprise and private

issues in the equity and debt markets is consistent with the market valuing the new information conveyed

by private investors purchases of securities. The result that the markets reaction to public issues is

more negative (signiÞcantly so for convertible securities) as earnings surprise increases is consistent with

the stock market penalizing public issuers with high asymmetric information.

Inspection of the results in Table 3b also shows that the market response is signiÞcantly more nega-

tive when low quality governance Þrms issue public equity, the lowest disciplining security-market choice

combination, and is signiÞcantly more positive when high-quality governance Þrms issue private debt, the

best disciplining security-market choice combination. The market thus reacts positively to a Þrm with

bad governance that decides to self-discipline and negatively otherwise. Finally, the results also show that

Þrms that issue equity and convertible securities after a large runup in the public equity markets suffer a

negative reaction.

18

Page 21: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

C. Nested Logistic Regressions

In this section we present and discuss our models of security issuance. We estimate the two models

presented in section 2. First, we estimate the model where Þrms choose the security Þrst they will issue

(debt, convertibles or equity) and then choose whether or not to issue it in the private versus public

markets. Second, we estimate the model where Þrms choose the market Þrst in which they will issue

(private versus public markets) and then choose the security type (debt, convertibles or equity). We also

estimate and present an eight choice model where we include as a choice of market securities issued under

rule 144.

Before moving to a nested logit model, we estimated a simple multinomial model where Þrms simulta-

neously choose both the security and market. In order for this model to present valid coefficient estimates,

the choices must satisfy the independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA). This assumption holds if when

you omit one security category, the other security probabilities increase proportionately. We conducted

several different Hausman tests to examine whether this assumption held and found that it did not. We

found that the choices of public versus private in particular were not independent of each other. The

nested logit is an alternative that does not require this assumption between choices across choices that are

not in the same group. For comparison we present the results from the multinomial model in the appendix

(Tables A1 and A2) of this paper. Examining the coefficients of the multinomial model and comparing

them to the nested logit model, we can see that there are differences in magnitude between the models.

While the coefficients are different, the good news is that the signs and signiÞcance across the multinomial

and nested logit models for our key asymmetric and risk variables are similar.

Table 4 presents the results of nested logit where Þrms choose the security Þrst and then choose the

market in which they sell the securities. While there is not a test that tells us whether this model or the

model in which Þrms choose the market Þrst are correct, a test of whether the additional assumption of

independence (testing if the inclusion parameters are signiÞcantly different from one) was strongly rejected

for this model, given us additional evidence that the multinomial model is not appropriate versus this

model.

Insert Table 4 here

The results presented in Table 4 show that in the Þrst stage when Þrms choose securities, Þrms with a

high degree of asymmetric information are less likely to choose equity over debt. They are more likely to

choose equity and convertibles if they have high risk and investment opportunities. With respect to other

19

Page 22: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Þrm characteristics, Þrms are more likely to choose equity and convertibles if they are small and have low

operating cash ßows. These proxies have also been used to capture Þrm risk and investment opportunities

by other studies. Similar to the results by Lucas and McDonald (1990), the positive signiÞcant coefficient

on a Þrm�s past year CAR shows that Þrms are more likely to issue equity when the Þrm�s stock has risen

recently. The overall results are consistent with high risk and thus agency problems of debt causing Þrms

to be more likely to issue equity. The positive coefficients for the Aaa bond rate and the credit spread,

Baa-Aaa, are consistent with the Þrm choosing to issue equity the more costly debt becomes and the higher

the default risk spread.

Examining, the choice between public and private in the second stage, we see that higher degrees of

asymmetric information are also positively related to the decision to issue private securities - especially so

for equity. The ordering of the coefficients also statistically satisÞes Hypothesis 2 which states that as the

level of info asymmetry increases the Þrm is more likely to private equity over public equity versus private

convertible over public convertibles, or private debt over public debt. The coefficient on asymmetric

information for private equity is 1.45 which is statistically greater than .488, the coefficient on asymmetric

information for private convertibles, which in turn is statistically greater than coefficient for private bank

debt of .214.

The results for the second stage also show that high risk increases the tendency toward private debt

relative to public debt. Perhaps surprisingly, if one viewed the private market as providing increased

monitoring, better governance is associated with an increased tendency to issue private equity over public

equity. Smaller Þrms, Þrms with higher Tobin�s q and lower proÞtability are more likely to issue privately

for all security types, and Þrms in distress also more likely to issue private equity and convertibles relative

to their public counterparts. Finally Þrms that have had lower CARs over the past year are more likely

to issue privately. Thus the picture that emerges is that small Þrms whose stock market performance

recently has not been good and whose cash ßows are low are more likely to choose to issue privately.

Table 4b presents the results from the same model of security Þrst then market but uses analyst forecast

dispersion as the measure of asymmetric information. Inspection of the table shows that the results are

generally similar for nearly all coefficients. One exception is the coefficient on asymmetric information for

the choice of private debt becomes insigniÞcant. However, all other asymmetric information coefficients

remain similar in size and signiÞcance.

Insert Table 4b here

20

Page 23: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

The overall conclusions that emerge from Table 4 and Table 4b are consistent with the summary

statistics presented earlier. There are sharp differences between public and private issuers in all markets -

and an especially sharp distinction between issuers of public and private equity. Firms with a high degree

of asymmetric information are more likely to issue privately and issue private equity. Risk and investment

opportunities affects more the security choice with high risk Þrms issuing equity and convertibles. Risk

has a positive affect on the tendency to issue private debt over public debt but no signiÞcant effect for

equity and convertibles. Table 4b also shows that Þrms in distress are less likely to issue private debt

- results consistent the conclusion that private lenders and banks do not like to lend to Þrms already in

distress [ cite for what Andy Winton said].

Table 5 presents the results of nested logit where Þrms choose the public versus private market Þrst and

then choose the security second. Under this model we can also test the hypotheses tests on the pecking

order conditional on market choice.

Insert Table 5 here

The results presented in Table 5 show that in the Þrst stage Þrms with a high degree of asymmetric

information and high cash ßow volatility are more likely to sell securities in the private market. Most

results yield similar conclusions to those from in Table 4. Small Þrms, with high Tobin�s q, with worse

recent CARs and low proÞtability are more likely to choose to issue securities privately. The results for

R&D show that high R&D increases the tendency for Þrms to issue privately.

Columns 2 through 5 report the results conditional upon the market. We see that conditional on issuing

in the public market, public issuers are more likely to issue public debt relative to public convertibles and

public equity when asymmetric information increases. We test Hypothesis 1 formally and Þnd that the

coefficient for public equity is signiÞcantly lower than both public convertibles and public debt. Thus, the

results for public equity are consistent with the Myers�s pecking order in the public market. However the

coefficient on public convertibles is not signiÞcantly different from zero and thus public convertibles do not

satisfy the pecking order.

We also Þnd that conditional on issuing in the private market the opposite of the pecking order holds.

Hypothesis 1 thus does not hold for the private market. Private issuers are more likely to issue private

equity and convertibles when asymmetric information increases, a result that we Þnd puzzling. Distress is

the another variable that shows a different pattern for public and private markets. Firms issuing privately

are more likely to issue equity and convertibles if they have high measures of Þnancial distress. There is

21

Page 24: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

no signiÞcant relation between distress and security issuance in the public markets. The Þnal relation

that differs across the public and private markets, is that when the overall market CAR is positive, issuers

in the public market have a higher tendency to issue equity, while this effect is reversed in the private

markets. Private issuers are more likely to issue private debt versus private equity when the overall public

equity market has done well.

With respect to risk and our tests of Hypothesis 3, we Þnd that the ordering of highest sensitivity of risk

for equity, next highest for convertibles and lowest for debt does hold in the public market. In the private

market both equity and convertibles have a higher sensitivity to risk versus the benchmark of private debt,

but the sensitivities of private equity and private convertibles are not statistically signiÞcant from each

other. Thus we Þnd a strict ordering for sensitivity to risk holds in the public market as speciÞed by

Hypothesis 3, while a weak ordering holds in the private market.

Table 5b presents the results from the same model of market Þrst then security but uses analyst forecast

dispersion as the measure of asymmetric information. Inspection of the table shows that the results are

generally similar for nearly all coefficients. One exception is the coefficient is insigniÞcant on asymmetric

information for issuing privately in the Þrst stage. However, all other asymmetric information coefficients

for the second stage security decisions remain similar in size and signiÞcance. Notably the coefficient

on asymmetric information for public equity remains signiÞcantly negative and the coefficient on private

equity remains signiÞcantly positive.

Insert Table 5b here

The overall message that emerge from Table 5 and Table 5b reinforce the conclusion that the effect

of asymmetric information is quite different in the public and private markets and that issuers of public

and private securities are quite different. Firms with a high degree of asymmetric information are more

likely to issue privately and issue private equity. A striking difference is evident for the public market.

Conditional upon issuing in the public markets, Þrms with a high degree of asymmetric information are

more likely to issue public debt over public equity. In order to gauge the effect of information on security

issuance decisions, it is thus crucial that one does not combine private and public security issues.

Table 6 combines the private and public equity and also the private and public debt in order to examine

the impact of using a Þrm�s statement of cash ßows to infer security issuance. We combine the convertible

preferred stocks into the equity category and the convertible bonds into the debt category.

Insert Table 6 here

22

Page 25: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Examination of the results in Table 6 conÞrm that the distinction between the public and private

markets is very important. If we combine public and private equity and public and private debt, none of

our asymmetric information variables are important. In addition the governance variable is not signiÞcant

either. The Þnding of insigniÞcance for the asymmetric information variables is consistent with the results

of Helwege and Liang (1996). These results are perhaps not surprising as earlier in our speciÞcations that

treat public and private securities separately, we found opposite signs by type of market on these variables.

In addition, the results in this table for the risk variable and for R&D, and for many other variables, are

of much smaller magnitude

Table 7 presents the Þnal nested logit speciÞcation. In this table we expand the number of markets

to include debt and convertibles issued in the Rule 144-A market. In Table 6 we present the results for

security Þrst followed by the market. We do not present results for the model where issuers choose the

market Þrst followed by security type as they were very similar.

Insert Table 7 here

The results for equity and convertibles in Table 7 are similar to those in Table 4. Firms with a higher

measures of asymmetric information are less likely to issue equity but conditional upon issuing equity are

more likely to issue privately. The results for asymmetric information for issuing privately conditional

upon issuing debt become insigniÞcant and the results for asymmetric information for securities issued

under Rule 144-A are insigniÞcant Our explanation for the weaker results for issuing debt securities is

that we are splitting public debt securities into two categories in this table. The results for risk are

similar to the previous, with the additional result that Þrms that issue debt are more likely to issue Rule

144 versus public debt if they have high risk. Other results for securities issued under Rule 144 include

the result that these are smaller, less proÞtable, highly valued Þrms that issue in this market versus issuing

in the public debt markets. They are Þrms with less R&D versus those that issue debt publicly. Overall

the results are consistent with the Þrms issuing debt under Rule 144 being riskier than Þrms that issue in

the public debt markets but ones which do not have a different degree of asymmetric information.

D. Economic Significance of our Results

In this section we examine the economic signiÞcance of our results. For these economic effects we use

the estimated model and associated coefficients from our results in Table 4. We examine the economic

signiÞcance in two different ways. We Þrst present the marginal signiÞcance of our primary nested logistic

speciÞcations and then we graphically show the signiÞcance of our results. Table 8 presents the marginal

23

Page 26: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

signiÞcance of our results we compute the predicted probability at the Þrm level and then, holding all other

variables, at their individual sample values vary each speciÞc variable +/- one-half standard deviation. We

then average over all Þrms in the sample. The effect depends on where in the logistic distribution each

choice variable is located as our later graphs will show. If a given probability is either very high or very

low, or in the tails of the logistic distribution, variations in the right-hand side variables may not have as

large of an effect as is actually present. We explore this issue further in subsequent graphs.

Insert Table 8 here

Table 8 shows does show there is signiÞcant variation in the predicted probability of security issuance

as we vary each variable. If we increase our measure of asymmetric information, analyst forecast errors

by one-half standard deviation, the predicted probability of public equity decreases by 11.1 percentage

points and the predicted probability of private debt, private convertibles and private equity go up by 11.5

percentage points and a total variation across the six choices of 23.7 percentage points. Other variables

such as R&D to Net Fixed Assets, ProÞtability also have a large effect with total variation in the predicted

probabilities of a total of almost 20 percentage points. The results clearly show that security issuance

probability is highly sensitive to Þrm and market speciÞc variables. The table also shows that our measure

of corporate governance is not economically very important, despite being statistically very important in

previous regressions. Our explanation for this result is that, consistent with Zwiebel (1996), managers

have discretion over issuance decisions and use of these decisions as disciplining devices may be plagued

by the same conßicts that it is trying to resolve. Our results presented in Table 3b on excess returns do

show the market does react positively to a Þrm with low-quality governance that decide to self-discipline

(through the issuance of private debt) and negatively otherwise.

Table 9 shows how well the nested logit from Table 4 does in predicting the actual observed choice.

The table contains the observed choice in the rows and the predicted choice in each column. The predicted

choice is the maximum probability among the six choices in Table 4. The Þrst row is the actual predicted

count of those who actually choose the security in the row. The second row is the percentage the predicted

is of the actual number of issues of that security. The third row is the percentage of the predicted for that

security (of those issuing a particular security) of the total predicted for that security overall.

Insert Table 9 here

Table 9 shows that Table 4 does overall very well in predicting security issues for most securities. The

model does very well in predicting public debt (61 percent predicted correctly), private debt (77 percent

24

Page 27: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

predicted correctly) and private equity (53 percent predicted correctly). Perhaps not surprisingly the model

does less well in predicting convertible securities as they are a blend of equity and debt. Interestingly,

the model predicts many public equity issues as private debt, perhaps because private debt gives Þrms

ßexibility like public equity.

Graphically we show how our predicted results vary by security as we vary our two primary variables,

asymmetric information and risk, +/- 10 standard deviations, holding all other variables at their mean

values for that speciÞc security.

Figure1 shows the predicted probability of security issuance using coefficient estimates from our model

in Table 4 for each the six different security choices. Risk (volatility of cash ßows) is on the y-axis and

asymmetric information (earnings surprise relative to analyst forecasts) is on the x-axis. We hold all data

at security means and then vary risk and asymmetric information proxies from +/- 10 standard deviations

away from the mean value for each security type. PuE (PrE) is public (private) equity, PuC (PrC) is

public (private) convertibles, PuD (PrD) is public (private) Debt. Dark/medium/light shading within

regions represents predicted probability of that security greater than 50%/30-50%/0-30% higher than the

next highest security.

Insert Figure 1 here

Inspection of the graphs in Figure 1 reveal that predicted probability of securities are markedly different

for private and public securities. Firms with both high asymmetric information and high risk issue

private convertibles and private equity. Firms with lower risk but still high asymmetric information issue

private debt. Firms with high risk but low asymmetric information are more likely to issue public equity.

All of the graphs quite clearly show that Þrms move away from issuing public equity and issue other

securities as asymmetric information increases. The most important distinction for the decision to issue

securities privately is asymmetric information. Risk inßuences more the type of security that the Þrm

issues conditional upon issuing publicly or privately.

Figure 2 shows how these predicted probabilities vary by size. We construct three different size regions,

low, below the 33rd percentile, medium, between the 33rd and 66th percentile and high, above the 66th

percentile. We then again vary our asymmetric information and risk variables +/- ten standard deviations

away from their size-based mean values, keeping all other variables at the mean values for each respective

size group.

Insert Figure 2 here

25

Page 28: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Figure 2 clearly shows that as asymmetric information increases Þrms are more likely to issue privately.

Small Þrms with both high risk and high asymmetric information are more likely to issue private equity and

convertibles. Conditional upon issuing publicly, Þrms with the highest degree of asymmetric information

are more likely to issue public debt - consistent with the Myer�s pecking order. However, as before, when

issuing privately the security choice is more nuanced. Firms with low risk but high asymmetric information

are likely to issue private debt while Þrms with the highest levels of risk and asymmetric information issue

private convertibles for all three size classes.

IV. Conclusions

In this paper we analyze the public and private security issuance decisions by public companies. Using

a comprehensive database of public and private security issues we examine the impact of asymmetric

information, risk and corporate governance on security issuance decisions. We show private equity issues

are signiÞcant in number, especially for smaller Þrms that potentially have more asymmetric information

and higher risk. Our comprehensive sample shows that private equity and private convertible issues are

a substantial fraction of securities issued by public companies. This fraction has also been increasing over

time, with the number of private equity issues exceeding public equity issues from the year 2000 to 2003,

the last year of our database. The number of private convertibles is greater than the number of public

convertibles for all years of our database.

We analyze the factors that are related to the probability a Þrm chooses to issue public and private

equity, public and private convertibles and public and private debt. We have three main results on asym-

metric information, risk and security issuance decisions:

1. Firms that have a high degree of asymmetric information, measured by either analyst earnings

dispersion or analyst earnings forecast errors, are signiÞcantly more likely to issue securities in the

private market.

2. Firms with both high asymmetric information and high risk are most likely to issue private equity

and in particular private convertibles.

3. Conditional upon issuing in the public market, Þrms with high asymmetric information are more

likely to issue debt and less likely to issue equity. Thus, while Myers�s pecking order of Þnancing

decisions does not hold overall and is reversed in the private market, it does hold conditional upon

Þrms issuing securities in the public market.

26

Page 29: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

We have three main results on risk and corporate governance:

1. Firms with high risk, that are smaller, highly valued but with low cash ßows and high indicators of

distress are more likely to issue private equity.

2. Firms with high-quality corporate governance are more likely to issue in the private equity market.

However corporate governance is economically not very important to the issuance decision.

3. Our results do however show the market does react positively to a Þrm with low-quality corporate

governance that decides to self-discipline (through the issuance of private debt) and negatively to the

issuance of public equity.

Our results show that private markets are quite different from private markets on many different di-

mensions. The results are consistent with the private issues being sold to investors with better information

about or better ability to evaluate Þrm prospects. Our results are consistent with asymmetric information

being one of the most signiÞcant and economically important factors that inßuences security issuance de-

cisions. We also show that private equity is also more likely to be sold when Þrms have high risk and thus

potential agency conßicts. The results are consistent with private equity and convertibles being issued

given asymmetric information and to mitigate potential agency conßicts between equity and debt holders.

Firms with lower risk but still high asymmetric information are more likely to issue private debt.

27

Page 30: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Appendix

The most commonly used model is the multinomial logit model which assumes that the errors εij are i.i.d.

extreme value distribution (the cumulative distribution is e−e−εj). McFadden (1973) has shown under this

assumption for the errors the Þrm maximization behavior lead to

Pr[Y = j] =eβ

0jxiX

k∈Jeβ

0kxi

However this model assumes the errors are all i.i.d. which imply that the independence of irrelevant

alternatives holds. The economic content of this assumption is that omission of one of the categories will

lead to a proportionate increase in the remaining alternatives. Given the restrictiveness of this assumption,

we perform Hausman tests of whether this simple model is sufficient to describe the choices. We Þnd that

it does not pass this test.

A more general model that we thus consider is a nested logit model. Note that the value function can

be decomposed into two observed parts: For Model 2 presented in the text, the Þrst part is the value from

making the private-public choice Wpriv = β0privx (public has been normalized to zero), and the other part

is the additional value from making a speciÞc security choice within the nest Yj = β0jx (debt has been

normalized to zero); That is the value of choice j is Vj =Wk + Yj + εj .

To estimate the nested models presented in the text we have to make assumptions about the distribution

of the errors. We will allow for a generalized extreme value distribution (GEV). The most widely used

GEV model is a nested logit model. The more general distribution of the errors we consider, where the

errors have the following cumulative distribution:

exp³−(e−εe/λpriv + e−εc/λpriv + e−εd/λpriv)− (e−εE/λpub + e−εC/λpub + e−εD/λpub)

´For any two alternatives in two different nests, say private debt and public convertibles, the errors are

uncorrelated, the cov(εd,εC) = 0. But for two alternatives in the same nest the errors are correlated. The

parameter 1− λk can be interpreted as the correlation among choices in the same nest. So the parameterλk measures the degree of independence for the portions of the value for the alternatives within nest k (a

lower value indicating more correlation). λk = 1 means the alternatives are independent and multinomial

model is appropriate.

The probability that a choice j is made is P (j) = P (j|k).P (k), where k is the choice of branch (public,private) it can be shown that value maximization implies:

28

Page 31: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

P (e|priv) =eβ

0ex

1 + eβ0ex + eβ0cx;P (c|priv) = eβ

0cx

1 + eβ0ex + eβ0cx;P (d|priv) = 1

1 + eβ0ex + eβ0cx

P (E|pub) =eβ

0Ex

1 + eβ0Ex + eβ

0Cx;P (C|pub) = eβ

0Cx

1 + eβ0Ex + eβ

0Cx;P (D|pub) = 1

1 + eβ0Ex + eβ

0Cx

and

P (priv) =eβ

0privx+λprivIpriv

eλpubIpub + e

β0priv

x+λprivIpriv;P (pub) =

eλpubIpub

eλpubIpub + e

β0priv

x+λprivIpriv

where Ik are the inclusive value for nest k

Ipriv = ln(1 + eβ0ex + eβ

0cx) and Ipriv = ln(1 + e

β0Ex + eβ0Cx)

The inclusive values have an important economic interpretation: λkIk is the expected value that the

Þrm receives from the choice among the alternatives in the nest k.

Note that the odds ratio among to alternatives, say equity and debt, within the same branch, say

public, isPEPD

=Pr[Y = E]

Pr[Y = D]= eβ

0Ex,

so the coefficient eβ0Ek describe the change in the odds ratio associated with an increase in xk.

Note that the odds ratio among choices in different branches say PePEunder the nested formulation above

is a more complicated expression that is a function of all the alternatives.

Another nested logit speciÞcation is the one in which the Þrm Þrst choose the security and then the

market (model 1 in the text). In this case the errors have the following distribution

exp³−(e−εe/λE + e−εE/λE )− (e−εc/λC + e−εC/λC )− (e−εd/λD + e−εD/λD)

´Note that under this speciÞcation the odds ratio

PePE

=Pr[Y = e]

Pr[Y = D]= ea

0privex,

so the coefficient eakprive describe the change in the odds ratio associated with an increase in xk.

We estimate the parameters of these models using the maximum likelihood estimation.

29

Page 32: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

REFERENCES

Allen, Jeffrey, and Gordon M. Phillips, 2000, Corporate Equity Ownership, Strategic Alliances and Prod-

uct Market Relationships, Journal of Finance 55, 2791-2815.

Asquith, Paul, and David W. Mullins, 1986, Equity Issues and Offering Dilution, Journal of Financial

Economics 15, 61-89.

Barclay, Michael J., Clifford G. Holderness, and Dennis P. Sheehan, 2003, Private Placements and Man-

agerial Entrenchment, Working paper, University of Rochester.

Blackwell, David, and David Kidwell, 1988, An Investigation of the Cost Differences Between Public Sales

and Private Placements of Debt, Journal of Financial Economics 22, 253-278.

Boyd, John, and Edward C. Prescott, 1986, Financial Intermediary Coalitions, Journal of Financial

Theory 38, 211-232.

Brennan, Michael J., and Allan Kraus, 1987, Efficient Financing Under Asymmetric Information, Journal

of Finance, 1225-1243.

Brennan, Michael J., and E.S. Schwartz, 1987, The Case for Convertibles, Journal of Applied Corporate

Finance 1, 55-64.

Brophy, David J., Paige P. Ouimet, and Clemens Sialm, 2004, PIPE Dreams? The Stock Price Per-

formance of Companies Issuing Private Investments in Public Equity, Working paper, University of

Michigan Business School.

Boyd, John H., and Edward C. Prescott, 1985, Financial Intermediary-Coalitions, Journal of Economic

Theory 38, 211-232.

Cantillo, Miguel, and Julian Wright, 2000, How Do Firms Choose Their Lenders? An Empirical Investi-

gation, Review of Financial Studies 13, 155-189.

Chakraborty, Archishman, and Bilge Yilmaz, 2003, Asymmetric Information and Financing with Con-

vertibles, Working paper, Finance Department, The Wharton School.

Chang, Xin, Sudipto Dasgupta, and Gilles Hilary, Analyst Coverage and Capital Structure Decisions,

Working paper, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology.

Chemmanur, Thomas, and Palo Fulghieri, 1994, Reputation, Renegotitation, and the Choice Between

Bank Loans and Publicly Traded Debt, Review of Financial Studies 7, 475-506.

Chemmanur, Thomas, and Palo Fulghieri, 1999, A Theory of Going-Public Decision, The Review of

Financial Studies 12 (2), 249-279.

Page 33: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Denis, David J., and Vassil T. Mihov, 2002, The Choice Between Bank Debt, Non-Bank Private Debt

and Public Debt: Evidence from New Corporate Borrowings, Working paper, Purdue University.

Diamond, Douglas W., 1984, Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring, Review of Economic

Studies, 393-414.

Diamond, Douglas W., 1991, Monitoring and Reputation: The Choice Between Bank Loans and Directly

Placed Debt, Journal of Political Economy 99, 689-721.

Fama, E.F., and K.R. French, 2002, Testing trade-off and pecking order predictions about dividends and

debt, The Review of Financial Studies 15 (1), 1-33.

Frank, Murray Z., and Vidhan K. Goyal, 2003, Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure,

Journal of Financial Economics 67, 217-248.

Fulghieri, Paolo, and Dmitry Lukin, 2001, Information production, dilution costs, and optimal security

design, Journal of Financial Economics 61, 3-42.

Gorton, Gary, and Andrew Winton, Financial Intermediation, Handbook of the Economics of Finance,

459-460.

Green, Richard C., 1994, Investment Incentives, Debt, and Warrants, Journal of Financial Economics 13,

115-136.

Helwege, Jean, and Nellie Liang, 1996, Is there a pecking order? Evidence from a panel of IPO Þrms,

Journal of Financial Economics 40, 429-458.

Hertzel, Michael, and Richard L. Smith, 1993, Market discounts and shareholder gains for placing equity

privately, Journal of Finance 48, 459-485.

Houston, Joel, and Christopher James, 1996, Bank Information Monopolies and the Mix of Private and

Public Debt Claims, Journal of Finance 51, 1863-1889.

Hovakimian, A., T. Opler, and S. Titman, 2001, The debt-equity choice, Journal of Financial and Quan-

titative Analysis 36 (1), 1-24.

Johnson, Shane A., 1997, An Empirical Analysis of the Determinants of the Corporate Debt Ownership

Structure, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 32, 47-69.

Kaplan, Steven N., and Per Stromberg, 2002, Financial Contracting Theory Meets the Real World: An

Empirical Analysis of Venture Capital Contracts, Working paper, University of Chicago School of

Business.

Korajczyk, R., and A. Levy, 2003, Capital Structure Choice: Macroeconomic conditions and Þnancial

constraints, Journal of Financial Economics 68: 75-109.

Page 34: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Krishnaswami, Sudha, Paul A. Spindt, and Venkat Subramaniam, 1999, Information Asymmetry, Moni-

toring and the Placement Structure of Corporate Debt, Journal of Financial Economics 51, 407-434.

Leary, Mark, and Michael R. Roberts, 2004a, Do Firms Rebalance Their Capital Structures?, Working

paper, Duke University.

��, 2004b, Financial Slack and Tests of the Pecking Order�s Financing Hierarchy, Working paper, Duke

University.

Lewis, Craig M., Richard J. Rogalski, and James K. Seward, 1998, Agency Problems, Information Asym-

metries, and Convertible Debt Security Design, Journal of Financial Intermediation 7, 32-59.

Lucas, Deborah, and Robert McDonald, 1990, Equity Issues and Stock Price Dynamics, Journal of

Finance 45, 1019-1043.

Maksimovic, Vojislav, and Pegaret Picher , 1999, Private versus Public Offerings: Optimal Selling

Mechanisms with Adverse Selection, Working paper, University of Maryland College of Business and

Management.

Masulis, Ronald W,. and Ashok N. Korwar, 1986, Seasoned Equity Offerings: An Empirical Investigation,

Journal of Financial Economics 15, 91-118.

Mikkelson, Wayne, and Megan Partch, 1986, Valuation Effects of Security Offerings and the Issuance

Process, Journal of Financial Economics 15, 31-60.

Myers, Stewart C., and Nicholas S. Majluf, 1984, Corporate Þnancing and investment decisions when the

Þrm has information that investors do not have, Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187-221.

Myers, Stewart C., 1977, Determinants of corporate borrowing, Journal of Financial Economics 5, 147-

175.

Myers, Stewart C., 1984, The capital structure puzzle, Journal of Finance 39, 575-592.

Nachman, D.C., and T.H. Noe, 1994, Optimal Design of Securities under Asymmetric Information, Review

of Financial Studies 7, 1-44.

Rajan, Raghuram, 1992, Insiders and Outsiders: The Choice Between Informed and Arm�s-Length Debt,

Journal of Finance 47, 1367-1406.

Shyam-Sunder, Lakshmi, and Stewart C. Myers, 1999, Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models

of capital structure, Journal of Financial Economics 51 (2), 219-244.

Stein, Jeremy, 1992, Convertible Bonds as Back Door Equity Financing, Journal of Financial Economics

32, 3-21.

Page 35: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Stulz, Rene M., 1990, Managerial Discretion and Optimal Financing Policies, Journal of Financial Eco-

nomics 26, 3-27.

Titman, S., and R. Wessels, 1988, The determinants of capital structure, Journal of Finance 43, 1-19.

Wruck, Karen H., 1989, Equity ownership concentration and Þrm value: Evidence from private equity

Þnancings, Journal of Financial Economics 23, 3-28

Wu, YiLin, The Choice of equity-selling mechanisms, Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming.

Page 36: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Year Public PrivateDebt Convertibles Equity Debt Convertibles Debt Convertibles Equity Total

N 230 24 220 41 0 495 27 36 1,0731995 $MM 41,733 3,266 14,001 5,487 0 161,259 388 419 226,552

%FV 7% 20% 23% 36% 0% 32% 14% 12% 24%

N 251 33 266 51 15 652 102 49 1,4191996 $MM 55,961 6,058 16,529 9,500 2,530 194,596 1,460 245 286,879

%FV 11% 22% 26% 49% 24% 32% 20% 13% 26%

N 246 26 224 136 36 732 148 56 1,6041997 $MM 63,928 3,792 14,287 26,101 5,724 256,440 2,077 313 372,663

%FV 6% 21% 24% 32% 31% 33% 12% 14% 25%N 309 18 149 158 30 646 117 67 1,494

1998 $MM 97,694 4,496 15,002 44,180 8,715 150,742 873 516 322,219%FV 5% 11% 19% 28% 17% 36% 14% 11% 23%

N 197 22 172 108 32 602 125 151 1,4091999 $MM 81,994 12,015 23,761 41,910 8,589 130,367 2,621 1,724 302,981

%FV 6% 8% 21% 21% 15% 37% 13% 15% 24%N 143 22 158 42 56 603 149 197 1,370

2000 $MM 57,908 11,898 29,316 35,022 20,273 172,841 6,878 6,750 340,886%FV 4% 10% 23% 14% 15% 33% 14% 14% 22%

N 206 30 136 142 88 620 130 228 1,5802001 $MM 119,525 13,957 16,144 76,020 40,424 153,736 2,751 4,400 426,955

%FV 5% 7% 13% 20% 11% 30% 16% 16% 20%N 204 12 129 90 52 619 111 192 1,409

2002 $MM 87,896 8,205 16,371 27,338 19,580 139,039 3,909 2,680 305,018%FV 4% 5% 11% 20% 11% 28% 13% 12% 18%

N 164 15 169 148 173 646 95 256 1,6662003 $MM 80,849 9,765 18,581 42,850 45,869 153,642 2,093 4,032 357,681

%FV 5% 7% 21% 19% 20% 29% 19% 19% 22%

N 1,950 202 1,623 916 482 5,615 1,004 1,232 13,024Total $MM 687,487 73,451 163,992 308,408 151,703 1,512,661 23,049 21,080 2,941,832

%FV 6% 13% 21% 25% 17% 32% 15% 15% 23%%FV (med) 2% 8% 15% 15% 13% 21% 9% 9% 13%

Table shows the number of issues, the total gross proceeds raised in millions of dollars, and the mean amount raised as a percent of firm value(%FV) for each year and security-market choice. The source of information is SDC (all public issues and 144-A debt issues), DealScan (privatedebt), and PlacementTracker (private equity and convertibles and 144-A convertibles). Securities are included if from public companies matched toCompustat and CSRP (financials and regulated utilities are excluded)

Table 1Number and Gross Proceeds of Securities Issued by Year

144-A

Page 37: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Security/Market Analyst Analyst Corporate Cash flow R&D / Profitability Financial Tobin's q Cumulative Debt/Asset Firm ValueEarnings Earnings Governance Volatility PPE (OCF/Assets) Distress Ab. Return ($ Millions)Surprise Dispersion prior 250 days

Public Mean 0.7% 1.1% 2.3 2.4% 13.3% 18.1% 9.9% 1.6 3.8% 26.8% 26,855Debt Stdev 1.8% 4.8% 1.2 2.7% 29.2% 8.1% 29.9% 1.1 35.2% 14.7% 46,661 N 1,914 1,878 1,879 1,950 1,950 1,950 1,950 1,950 1,950 1,950 1,950Public Mean 1.7% 1.7% 2.2 4.2% 31.8% 12.6% 22.3% 2.0 44.1% 27.9% 9,735

Convertibles Stdev 4.0% 4.4% 1.3 5.5% 101.4% 18.4% 41.7% 1.9 118.4% 17.4% 24,076 N 188 180 177 202 202 202 202 202 202 202 202

Public Mean 1.6% 0.9% 2.4 7.8% 106.9% 11.5% 13.2% 2.6 80.1% 22.8% 1,562Equity Stdev 4.8% 2.4% 1.2 13.2% 225.7% 26.4% 33.9% 2.3 148.6% 22.4% 6,042

N 1,495 1,349 1,161 1,623 1,623 1,623 1,623 1,623 1,623 1,623 1,623144-A Mean 3.0% 2.0% 2.2 3.8% 11.1% 14.9% 31.6% 1.4 17.3% 37.5% 7,115

Convertibles Stdev 10.6% 5.5% 1.2 5.0% 32.3% 13.2% 46.5% 1.0 71.9% 21.2% 23,998N 862 804 752 916 916 916 916 916 916 916 916

144-A Mean 2.5% 1.8% 2.5 6.3% 110.8% 10.2% 17.4% 2.4 53.3% 23.4% 5,185Debt Stdev 9.2% 5.6% 1.2 11.0% 232.8% 22.0% 38.0% 2.5 156.5% 21.7% 13,009

N 468 457 443 482 482 482 482 482 482 482 482

Private Mean 3.7% 1.6% 2.3 4.8% 28.9% 15.7% 13.7% 1.4 4.8% 23.7% 3,004Debt Stdev 12.6% 5.2% 1.2 7.0% 87.4% 14.4% 34.4% 1.2 66.0% 19.8% 11,730 N 4,783 4,182 4,076 5,615 5,615 5,615 5,615 5,615 5,615 5,615 5,615

Private Mean 17.5% 6.4% 2.8 16.5% 165.2% -21.0% 31.4% 2.6 -0.9% 16.6% 353Convertibles Stdev 30.5% 11.9% 1.2 19.3% 262.2% 34.7% 46.4% 2.6 129.4% 21.2% 1,536

N 554 362 782 1,004 1,004 1,004 1,004 1,004 1,004 1,004 1,004

Private Mean 13.8% 4.7% 2.8 17.4% 242.3% -24.5% 26.5% 3.0 21.7% 12.8% 372Equity Stdev 26.4% 8.9% 1.2 22.7% 332.1% 35.9% 44.2% 2.9 126.3% 18.9% 1,919

N 766 528 1,051 1,232 1,232 1,232 1,232 1,232 1,232 1,232 1,232

Total Mean 4.1% 1.8% 2.4 6.9% 68.8% 8.6% 17.2% 1.9 18.5% 23.5% 6,416Median 0.7% 0.4% 2.0 3.3% 3.5% 13.8% 0.0% 1.3 -0.1% 20.5% 583Stdev 14.1% 5.7% 1.2 12.3% 181.5% 25.4% 37.7% 1.9 98.8% 20.4% 22,868

N 11,030 9,740 10,321 13,024 13,024 13,024 13,024 13,024 13,024 13,024 13,024

Summary statistics by security-market choice in the year prior to the issue. Analyst earnings surprise is the absolute value of of actual earnings less median analyst forecastdivided the price per share. Analyst earnings dispersion is the standard deviation of analyst earnings estimates divided the price per share. Corporate governance (orderedfrom 1 to 4) is based on whether the firm has dual class voting stock, classified board, restrictions on shareholders to call special meeting or on action by written consent.Cash flow volatility is the standard deviation of operating cash flow using up to twenty quarters prior to the issue. Financial distress is Altman's Z-score less than 1.81.Tobin's q is market to book value. Cumulative abnormal return is the excess return relative to a portfolio of firms in the same size decile. Debt to asset ratio is long termdebt divided by book value of assets. Firm value is market value of equity plus book values of preferred stock and total debt.

Summary StatisticsTable 2A

Page 38: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Analyst Analyst Corporate Cash flow R&D / Profitability Financial Tobin's q Cumulative Debt/ Firm Valuet-statistic for Earnings Earnings Governance Volatility PPE (OCF/Assets) Distress Ab. Return Assets ($ Millions)difference in means Surprise Dispersion prior 250 days

Private Debt 10.47 a 3.81 a 1.61 14.39 a 7.75 a -7.01 a 4.33 a -4.82 a 1.96 b -6.31 a -35.32vs Public Debt

Private Debt 1.52 -1.76 c 2.45 a 3.89 a 5.76 a 1.65 c -13.57 a 2.18 b -4.26 a -19.55 a -8.16vs 144-A Debt

144-A Debt 9.48 a 4.22 a -1.24 9.83 a -0.92 -8.09 a 14.79 a -5.73 a 6.49 a 15.86 a -12.16vs Public Debt

Private Convertibles 7.07 a 5.17 a 4.80 a 8.88 a 7.10 a -13.34 a 2.50 a 3.07 a -3.37 a -7.08 a -12.31vs Public Convertibles

Private Convertibles 10.26 a 7.37 a 4.04 a 10.79 a 3.87 a -18.14 a 5.71 a 1.64 -6.08 a -5.75 a -11.66vs 144-A Convertibles

144-A Convertibles 1.17 0.25 1.85 c 2.61 a 4.64 a -1.32 -1.53 1.83 c 1.11 -2.60 a -3.22Public Convertibles

Private Equity 17.15 a 14.54 a 7.48 a 14.11 a 12.95 a -30.72 a 9.15 a 4.30 a -7.51 a -12.69 a -6.63vs Public Equitya,b,c represent significance levels of 1,5,10 percent using a two-tailed test.

Table presents t-statistics for differences in means for summary statistics from Table 2A.

Table 2BSummary Statistics: Tests of Differences in Means by Market

Page 39: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Security- Day -1 to +1 Day -5 to +5 Day -10 to +10 Day -21 to +21Market Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median

Public -0.04% -0.15% 0.16% 0.11% 0.16% 0.05% 0.18% 0.08%Debt

Public -2.88% a -2.28% -3.65% a -2.92% -3.53% a -2.93% -1.78% a -2.25%Convertibles

Public -1.79% a -1.73% -3.32% a -3.32% -3.66% a -3.60% -6.24% -6.02%Equity

144-A -0.37% -0.54% 0.37% -0.18% 0.58% -0.01% 0.73% -0.33%Convertibles

144-A -0.29% -0.09% -3.60% a -4.05% -3.30% a -3.70% -1.53% -1.29%Debt

Private 0.44% a 0.12% 0.86% a 0.20% 0.68% a 0.17% 0.79% a -0.01%Debt

Private 1.89% a 0.28% 1.00% b -1.78% 1.03% b -1.45% -0.19% -2.47%Convertibles

Private 2.31% a 0.27% 4.19% a 0.65% 4.85% a 0.92% 5.09% a 2.05%Equity

a,b,c - Significantly different from zero using a two-tailed test at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Table presents the cumulative abnormal returns around security issues using 1, 5, 10, and 21 trading-day event windows. Excess returns are obtained from a market model estimated using the last 250trading days prior to the event window.

Table 3AMarket Reaction to Security Issuance

Page 40: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Equity Issues Convertible Issues Debt Issuescoef. t-stat coef. t-stat coef. t-stat

Public Market -4.45% a (-5.26) -1.40% (-1.47) -0.30% (-.58)

Private Market 2.82% c (1.75) -0.82% (-.44) -0.32% (-.74)

Analyst Earnings Surprise*Public Market -3.39% (-1.60) -2.81% c (-1.74) 0.35% (.50)

*Private Market 1.67% b (2.38) 0.28% (.36) 1.47% b (2.38)

Corporate Governance*Public Market 1.49% b (2.39) -0.04% (-.04) -0.03% (-.10)

*Private Market -0.44% (-.40) -0.46% (-.36) -0.64% b (-2.18)

Cash Flow Volatility 0.30% (.56) -1.73% (-2.18) -0.40% (-.64)

R&D / Net Fixed Assets 0.21% (.37) 1.56% b (2.07) 0.34% (.38)

Profitability -0.04% (-.06) 0.68% (.74) -0.35% (-.57)(Operating Cash Flow)

Financial Distress 5.12% a (2.80) 2.36% (1.15) 2.26% a (3.02)

Tobin's q -0.20% (-.34) -0.33% (-.48) -0.81% (-1.75)

Cumulative Ab. Stock Return -1.95% a (-4.14) -0.64% (-.67) -3.96% a (-8.75)(250 days before)

Debt/Asset Ratio -0.27% (-.50) -1.12% c (-1.63) 0.42% c (1.67)(Industry Adjusted)

Log Size 0.36% (.43) -1.39% (-1.27) -0.20% (-.77)(firm value)

Cumulative Market Return 0.79% (1.25) -0.48% (-.66) -0.17% (-.81)(250 days before)

Number of observations 1,845 1,128 6,354F-value 7.9 1.32 8.88Adjusted R2 6.53% 2.47% 4.07%a,b,c - Significantly different from zero at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Table presents regression of 21 trading-day cumulative abnormal returns around security issues on thevariables defined in Table 2A. All explanatory variables (except the dummy variable financial distress) havebeen normalized by their standard deviation. Robust t-statistics in parentheses.

Table 3BMarket Reaction to Security Issuance

Page 41: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

First Stage Second Stage: Public versus PrivateExplanatory Variables Security Decision Private Private PrivateAsymmetric Information Measure Convertibles Equity Equity Convertibles Debt Analyst Earnings Surprise 0.013 -0.782 a 1.452 a 0.488 a 0.214 a

(.140) (-3.910) (7.150) (3.820) (3.050)

Risk Measure Cash Flow Volatility 0.429 a 0.466 a -0.007 0.092 0.239 b

(4.050) (4.540) (-.170) (1.120) (2.190)Firm Characteristics Corporate Governance 0.113 a 0.033 0.251 a 0.072 0.049

(2.610) (.850) (4.000) (.850) (1.610)

R&D / Net Fixed Assets 0.788 a 0.768 a -0.067 -0.269 a 0.679 a

(4.660) (4.710) (-1.440) (-3.500) (4.260)

Profitability -0.831 a -0.627 a -0.634 a -0.427 a -0.179 b

(Operating Cash Flow) (-9.460) (-7.630) (-9.990) (-4.500) (-2.270)

Financial Distress 0.077 0.043 0.351 c 0.380 -0.400 a

(Z-score<1.81) (.560) (.330) (1.830) (1.540) (-4.210)

Tobin's q 0.834 a 0.909 a 0.283 a 0.302 a 0.525 a

(9.210) (9.770) (5.470) (3.840) (7.640)

Cumulative Abnormal Stock Return 0.412 a 0.512 a -0.342 a -0.675 a -0.176 a

(250 prior days) (7.140) (9.290) (-7.180) (-7.490) (-3.250)

Debt/Asset Ratio 0.062 0.119 a -0.027 0.182 b -0.041

(Industry Adjusted) (1.380) (2.900) (-.420) (2.140) (-1.230)

Log Size -0.670 a -1.688 a -1.224 a -2.683 a -1.481 a

(Firm Value) (-4.150) (-8.350) (-10.270) (-14.820) (-33.260)

Market Characteristics Aaa Bond Rate -0.163 a 0.322 a -0.081 0.799 a 0.273 a

(-2.600) (4.810) (-1.000) (6.620) (6.690)

Credit Spread: Baa - Aaa 0.143 c 0.340 a 0.218 b 0.164 0.254 a

(1.850) (4.580) (2.190) (1.160) (4.850)

Cumulative Market Return -0.071 0.119 b -0.562 a -0.181 -0.079 c

(Prior year) (-1.210) (2.120) (-6.360) (-1.550) (-1.880)

Constant -0.823 b -0.577 c -1.865 a -1.672 a 1.396 a

(-2.490) (-1.720) (-13.770) (-11.430) (19.650)a,b,c - Significantly different from zero at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Table 4

Table presents coefficient estimates from a nested logit regression testing the impact of asymmetricinformation and risk on firm public and private security choice by public firms. First stage is the decision ofsecurity type with coefficients representing tendency relative to debt. Second stage is the choice of marketconditional on security type, with coefficients representing tendency versus public issuance. All firm-specificvariables are lagged. The explanatory variables are as defined in Table 2A. Analyst earnings surprise is theabsolute value of actual earnings less median analyst forecast divided the price per share. (Robust Z-statistics are presented in parentheses.) Chi-squared statistic for test of overall significance is 13068 (p-value .001). Sample is 9327 security issues.

Choice of Security Issuance in Public and Private Markets

Page 42: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

First Stage Second Stage: Public versus PrivateExplanatory Variables Security Decision Private Private PrivateAsymmetric Information Measure Convertibles Equity Equity Convertibles Debt Analyst Earnings Dispersion 0.029 -0.382 a 0.738 a 0.251 a -0.017

(.600) (-4.160) (6.070) (3.000) (-.440)

Risk Measure Cash Flow Volatility 0.353 a 0.392 a -0.004 0.088 0.243 b

(3.460) (3.950) (-.100) (1.040) (2.270)Firm Characteristics Corporate Governance 0.120 a 0.038 0.215 a 0.080 0.056 c

(2.750) (.960) (3.080) (.850) (1.790)

R&D / Net Fixed Assets 0.742 a 0.703 a -0.091 c -0.195 b 0.694 b

(4.440) (4.320) (-1.760) (-2.450) (4.430)

Profitability -0.737 a -0.582 a -0.610 a -0.386 a -0.194 a

(Operating Cash Flow) (-8.920) (-7.450) (-9.550) (-4.020) (-2.630)

Financial Distress 0.153 0.048 0.465 b 0.684 a -0.360 a

(Z-score<1.81) (1.110) (.370) (2.160) (2.560) (-3.710)

Tobin's q 0.793 a 0.871 a 0.247 a 0.239 a 0.520 a

(8.870) (9.510) (4.280) (2.870) (7.680)

Cumulative Abnormal Stock Return 0.426 a 0.532 a -0.386 a -0.715 a -0.155 a

(250 prior days) (7.380) (9.850) (-6.760) (-6.790) (-2.800)

Debt/Asset Ratio 0.083 c 0.136 a -0.057 0.148 -0.019

(Industry Adjusted) (1.850) (3.320) (-.790) (1.580) (-.560)

Log Size -0.638 a -1.622 a -1.119 a -2.356 a -1.417 a

(Firm Value) (-4.060) (-8.380) (-9.090) (-12.460) (-32.340)Market Characteristics Aaa Bond Rate -0.148 b 0.299 a -0.109 0.906 a 0.269 a

(-2.340) (4.470) (-1.200) (6.710) (6.490)

Credit Spread: Baa - Aaa 0.137 c 0.289 a 0.227 b 0.236 0.257 a

(1.760) (3.850) (2.080) (1.520) (4.780)

Cumulative Market Return -0.083 0.035 -0.552 a -0.104 -0.067

(Prior year) (-1.400) (.610) (-5.870) (-.810) (-1.540)

Constant -1.064 b -0.813 a -2.199 a -2.045 1.164 a

(-3.490) (-2.650) (-15.360) (-12.250) (18.300)a,b,c - Significantly different from zero at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Table presents coefficient estimates from a nested logit regression testing the impact of asymmetricinformation and risk on firm public and private security choice by public firms. First stage is the decision ofsecurity type with coefficients representing tendency relative to debt. Second stage is the choice of marketconditional on security type, with coefficients representing tendency versus public issuance. All firm-specificvariables are lagged. The explanatory variables are as defined in Table 2A. Analyst earnings dispersionrepresents the standard deviation of analyst forecasts divided by price per share. (Robust Z-statistics arepresented in parentheses.) Chi-squared statistic for test of overall significance is 11858 (p-value .001).Sample is 8493 security issues.

Table 4BChoice of Security Issuance in Public and Private Markets

Page 43: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

First Stage Second StageMarket Decision Security Decision

Explanatory Variables Private Public Public Private PrivateAsymmetric Information Measure (vs. Public) Equity Convertibles Equity ConvertiblesAnalyst Earnings Surprise 0.247 a -1.034 a 0.027 0.122 a 0.165 a

(3.510) (-5.130) (.260) (2.950) (4.100)

Risk Measure Cash Flow Volatility 0.226 b 0.558 a 0.492 a 0.279 a 0.308 a

(2.080) (4.800) (4.040) (4.240) (4.580)Firm Characteristics Corporate Governance 0.046 0.034 0.110 b 0.217 a 0.149 a

(1.570) (.770) (2.260) (4.090) (2.630)

R&D / Net Fixed Assets 0.562 a 0.949 a 1.012 a 0.224 b 0.107(3.430) (5.830) (6.140) (3.890) (1.700)

Profitability -0.153 c -0.660 a -0.868 a -1.047 a -1.016 a

(Operating Cash Flow) (-1.820) (-7.100) (-8.760) (-14.760) (-14.020)

Financial Distress -0.386 a -0.025 -0.002 0.671 a 0.629 a

(Z-score<1.81) (-4.230) (-.180) (-.010) (4.390) (4.000)

Tobin's q 0.460 a 1.011 a 0.915 a 0.751 a 0.660 a

(5.800) (12.970) (11.650) (12.420) (10.140)

Cumulative Abnormal Stock Return -0.209 a 0.504 a 0.451 a 0.313 a -0.010 (250 prior days) (-3.670) (8.270) (7.000) (5.770) (-.140)

Debt/Asset Ratio -0.037 0.112 b 0.055 0.135 b 0.212 a

(Industry Adjusted) (-1.160) (2.430) (1.100) (2.450) (3.700)

Log Size -1.425 a -2.029 a -0.785 a -1.703 a -1.561 a

(Firm Value) (-22.300) (-26.700) (-11.960) (-17.720) (-15.720)Market Characteristics Aaa Bond Rate 0.269 a 0.407 a -0.158 a 0.062 0.175 b

(6.730) (6.670) (-2.520) (.890) (2.260)

Credit Spread: Baa - Aaa 0.243 a 0.401 a 0.190 b 0.343 a 0.078(4.750) (5.160) (2.360) (4.100) (.830)

Cumulative Market Return -0.091 b 0.121 -0.097 b -0.280 a -0.125 c

(Prior year) (-2.250) (1.950) (-1.510) (-4.000) (-1.650)

Constant 1.265 a -0.148 c -0.449 a -3.372 -3.359(9.210) (-1.650) (-5.120) (-31.000) (-30.740)

a,b,c - Significantly different from zero at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Table presents coefficient estimates from a nested logit regression testing the impact of asymmetricinformation and risk on firm public and private security choice by public firms. First stage is the decision ofmarket with coefficients representing tendency relative to the public market. Second stage is the choice ofsecurity conditional on market, with coefficients representing tendency versus debt issuance. All firm-specific variables are lagged. The explanatory variables are as defined in Table 2A. Analyst earningssurprise is the absolute value of actual earnings less median analyst forecast divided the price per share.Cash flow volatility is the standard deviation of cash flow using up twenty quarters prior to the securityissuance. (Robust Z-statistics are presented in parentheses.) Chi-squared statistic for test of overallsignificance is 13050 (p-value .001). Sample is 9327 security issues.

Table 5Choice of Security Issuance in Public and Private Markets

Page 44: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

First Stage Second StageMarket Decision Security Decision

Explanatory Variables Private Public Public Private PrivateAsymmetric Information Measure (vs. Public) Equity Convertibles Equity Convertibles Analyst Earnings Dispersion 0.010 -0.513 a -0.002 0.125 a 0.206 a

(.260) (-4.650) (-.040) (2.690) (4.720)

Risk Measure Cash Flow Volatility 0.220 b 0.512 a 0.440 a 0.211 a 0.231 a

(2.230) (4.430) (3.640) (3.280) (3.480)Firm Characteristics Corporate Governance 0.051 c 0.042 0.119 b 0.183 a 0.168 a

(1.750) (.910) (2.400) (3.070) (2.560)

R&D / Net Fixed Assets 0.519 a 0.934 a 0.994 a 0.162 a 0.140 b

(3.400) (5.710) (6.020) (2.710) (2.150)

Profitability -0.143 c -0.591 a -0.793 a -0.954 a -0.881 a

(Operating Cash Flow) (-1.890) (-6.650) (-8.370) (-13.320) (-11.950)

Financial Distress -0.336 a -0.063 0.023 0.725 a 0.888 a

(Z-score<1.81) (-3.680) (-.430) (.150) (4.160) (4.960)

Tobin's q 0.418 a 0.990 a 0.901 a 0.689 a 0.589 a

(5.570) (12.620) (11.470) (10.880) (8.450)

Cumulative Abnormal Stock Return -0.204 a 0.553 a 0.495 a 0.290 a -0.091 (250 prior days) (-3.550) (8.580) (7.340) (4.750) (-1.050)

Debt/Asset Ratio -0.015 0.136 a 0.077 0.110 c 0.170 a

(Industry Adjusted) (-.490) (2.840) (1.530) (1.800) (2.620)

Log Size -1.321 a -1.983 a -0.799 a -1.541 a -1.317 a

(Firm Value) (-21.630) (-26.240) (-12.280) (-14.920) (-12.170)Market Characteristics Aaa Bond Rate 0.260 a 0.402 a -0.154 b 0.031 0.275 a

(6.560) (6.330) (-2.410) (.400) (2.990)

Credit Spread: Baa - Aaa 0.244 a 0.359 a 0.193 b 0.288 a 0.112(4.790) (4.440) (2.340) (3.120) (1.040)

Cumulative Market Return -0.076 c 0.049 -0.112 c -0.369 a -0.096 (Prior year) (-1.860) (.750) (-1.690) (-4.740) (-1.100)

Constant 0.956 a -0.343 a -0.644 a -3.635 b -3.659(7.960) (-4.340) (-7.960) (-29.640) (-29.450)

a,b,c - Significantly different from zero at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Table presents coefficient estimates from a nested logit regression testing the impact of asymmetricinformation and risk on firm public and private security choice by public firms. First stage is the decision ofmarket with coefficients representing tendency relative to the public market. Second stage is the choice ofsecurity conditional on market, with coefficients representing tendency versus debt issuance. All firm-specific variables are lagged. Explanatory variables are as defined in Table 2A. Analyst earnings dispersionrepresents the standard deviation of analyst forecasts divided by price per share. Cash flow volatility is thestandard deviation of cash flow using up twenty quarters prior to the security issuance. (Robust Z-statisticsare presented in parentheses.) Chi-squared statistic for test of overall significance is 11838 (p-value .001).Sample is 8493 security issues.

Table 5BChoice of Security Issuance in Public and Private Markets

Page 45: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Analyst EarningsExplanatory Variables Earnings Forecast

Dispersion SurpriseAsymmetric Information Measure -0.039 0.009

(-1.110) (.310)

Risk Measure Cash Flow Volatility 0.170 a 0.135 a

(2.930) (2.840)Firm Characteristics Corporate Governance 0.028 0.030

(.810) (.920)

R&D / Net Fixed Assets 0.084 c 0.112 a

(1.830) (2.650)

Profitability -0.393 a -0.370 a

(Operating Cash Flow) (-7.350) (-7.760)

Distress 0.443 a 0.399 a

(Z-score in lowest quartile) (4.290) (4.120)

Tobin's q 0.436 a 0.442 a

(8.230) (9.030)

Cumulative Abnormal Stock Return 0.348 a 0.326 a

(250 prior days) (7.860) (8.100)

Debt/Asset Ratio 0.100 a 0.097 a

(Industry Adjusted) (2.640) (2.830)

Log Size -1.066 a -1.042 a

(market capitalization) (-19.680) (-20.920)Market Characteristics Aaa Bond Rate 0.209 a 0.177 a

(5.070) (4.620)

Credit Spread: Aaa - Baa 0.180 a 0.177 a

(3.440) (3.640)

Cumulative Market Return -0.015 0.011 (Prior year) (-.350) (.280)

Constant -1.561 a -1.568 a

(-34.680) (-36.100)Number of security issues 8,480 9,327 a,b,c - Significantly different from zero at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Table presents coefficient estimates from simple binomial logit regressions combining security issuesinto equity and debt groups with no indication of choice of market, nor choice of convertible securities.All firm-specific variables are lagged. All market-specific variables represent three months prior to thesecurity issuance. For the measure of asymmetric information, column 1 uses analyst earningsdispersion calculated as the standard deviation of the analyst forecasts divided by price per share.Column 2 uses the earnings forecast surprise calculated as the absolute value of the median forecastless the actual earnings divided by the price per share. Cash flow volatility is the standard deviation ofcash flow using up twenty quarters prior to the security issuance. (Robust Z-statistics are presented inparentheses).

Table 6Choice of Security: Debt versus Equity

Page 46: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

First Stage Second StageSecurity Decision Market Decision (vs. Public Market)

Explanatory Variables Equity Convertibles Private Private Private Section 144 Section 144Measures of Asymmetric Information (vs. Debt) (vs. Debt) Equity Convertibles Debt Convertibles Debt Analyst Earnings Dispersion -0.345 a 0.063 0.756 a 0.289 b 0.018 0.023 0.066

(-3.720) (1.080) (6.130) (2.360) (.400) (.200) (1.190)

Measures of Risk Cash Flow Volatility 0.744 a 0.692 a -0.005 0.135 0.756 a 0.078 0.761 a

(4.220) (3.730) (-.120) (.700) (4.580) (.420) (4.050)Firm Characteristics Corporate Governance 0.043 0.081 c 0.174 a 0.127 0.058 c 0.104 0.024

(1.250) (1.860) (3.060) (1.250) (1.950) (1.270) (.600)

R&D / Net Fixed Assets 0.694 a 0.596 a -0.085 0.112 0.657 a 0.339 c -0.202(4.320) (3.490) (-1.630) (.600) (3.290) (1.940) (-.690)

Profitability -0.754 a -0.914 a -0.604 a -0.418 a -0.425 a -0.007 -0.450 a

(Operating Cash Flow) (-7.250) (-7.980) (-9.410) (-2.780) (-4.520) (-.050) (-3.720)

Financial Distress 0.366 a 0.633 a 0.468 b 0.364 0.109 -0.554 a 0.919 a

(Z-score <1.81) (2.620) (3.930) (2.160) (1.040) (.900) (-1.920) (6.570)

Tobin's q 0.998 a 0.855 a 0.244 a 0.434 a 0.679 a 0.247 b 0.349 a

(9.130) (7.860) (4.170) (3.370) (8.370) (2.310) (2.990)

Cumulative Abnormal Stock Return 0.661 a 0.558 a -0.381 a -0.769 a 0.042 -0.080 0.368 a

(250 prior days) (10.060) (6.930) (-6.640) (-5.830) (.550) (-.890) (4.100)

Debt/Asset Ratio 0.220 a 0.102 c -0.060 0.335 a 0.097 b 0.214 b 0.273 a

(Industry Adjusted) (4.590) (1.760) (-.810) (2.590) (2.290) (2.030) (5.110)

Log Size -1.933 a -0.864 a -1.119 a -2.853 a -1.812 a -0.455 a -1.217 a

(Firm Value) (-8.000) (-4.330) (-9.020) (-12.760) (-33.340) (-3.300) (-18.060)Market Characteristics Aaa Bond Rate 0.258 a 0.003 -0.119 0.532 a 0.217 a -0.522 a -0.144 b

(4.180) (.030) (-1.310) (2.940) (4.480) (-3.700) (-2.230)

Credit Spread: Baa - Aaa 0.311 a 0.076 0.227 b 0.467 b 0.281 a 0.284 0.064(3.980) (.790) (2.060) (2.140) (4.450) (1.610) (.750)

Cumulative Market Return 0.004 -0.040 -0.561 a -0.317 c -0.099 c -0.229 c -0.119 c

(Prior year) (.060) (-.550) (-5.920) (-1.840) (-1.910) (-1.730) (-1.750)

Constant -0.254 -1.068 a -2.431 a -0.921 a 1.923 a 0.839 a -0.130(-.640) (-2.860) (-14.370) (-3.790) (19.160) (4.890) (-1.000)

a,b,c - Significantly different from zero at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Table presents coefficient estimates from a nested logit regression testing the impact of asymmetric information and risk on firm public and privatesecurity by public firms. First stage is the decision of security with coefficients representing tendency relative to the debt. Second stage is the choiceof market conditional on security type, with coefficients representing tendency versus public market issuance. All firm-specific variables are lagged.Explanatory variables are as defined in Table 2A. Analyst earnings dispersion represents the standard deviation of analyst forecasts divided by priceper share. Cash flow volatility is the standard deviation of cash flow using up twenty quarters prior to the security issuance. (Robust Z-statistics arepresented in parentheses.) Chi-squared statistic for test of overall significance is 13926 (p-value .001). Sample is 8493 security issues.

Choice of Security Issuance in Public and Private MarketsTable 7

Page 47: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

First Stage Second StageMarket Decision Security Decision

Explanatory Variables Private Section 144 Public Public Private Private Section 144Measures of Asymmetric Information (vs. Public) (vs. Public) Equity Convertibles Equity Convertibles Convertibles Analyst Earnings Dispersion 0.038 0.063 -0.483 a 0.019 0.130 a 0.211 a -0.016

(.850) (1.230) (-4.140) (.190) (2.830) (4.870) (-.130)

Measures of Risk Cash Flow Volatility 0.653 a 0.631 a 1.001 a 0.892 a 0.206 a 0.225 a -0.518 c

(4.020) (3.570) (5.710) (3.940) (3.330) (3.520) (-1.760)Firm Characteristics Corporate Governance 0.056 b 0.051 0.051 0.023 0.148 a 0.137 a 0.074

(1.990) (1.430) (1.220) (.330) (3.120) (2.600) (.830)

R&D / Net Fixed Assets 0.464 a -0.057 0.807 a 0.618 a 0.142 b 0.121 c 1.208 a

(2.530) (-.200) (3.960) (2.510) (2.450) (1.890) (2.840)

Profitability -0.364 a -0.596 a -0.834 a -1.046 a -0.915 a -0.848 a 0.517 a

(Operating Cash Flow) (-3.960) (-5.030) (-7.460) (-6.750) (-12.920) (-11.650) (2.570)

Financial Distress 0.076 0.797 a 0.458 a 0.849 a 0.761 a 0.914 a -1.423 a

(Z-score<1.81) (.660) (6.110) (2.750) (3.470) (4.430) (5.160) (-4.550)

Tobin's q 0.585 a 0.555 a 1.152 a 0.891 a 0.675 a 0.574 a -0.122(7.390) (4.660) (11.770) (7.260) (11.000) (8.390) (-.690)

Cumulative Abnormal Stock Return -0.0002 0.430 a 0.782 a 0.807 a 0.294 a -0.093 -0.528 a

(250 prior days) (.000) (5.240) (8.580) (7.410) (4.980) (-1.060) (-3.890)

Debt/Asset Ratio 0.103 a 0.272 a 0.282 a 0.060 0.130 b 0.189 a -0.113 (Industry Adjusted) (2.570) (5.690) (4.950) (.640) (2.140) (2.940) (-.970)

Log Size -1.725 a -1.173 a -2.461 a -0.924 a -1.590 a -1.360 a 0.861 a

(Firm Value) (-26.610) (-15.940) (-25.380) (-8.230) (-15.740) (-12.700) (5.790)Market Characteristics Aaa Bond Rate 0.202 a -0.190 a 0.334 a 0.209 c 0.008 0.255 a -0.455 a

(4.280) (-3.220) (4.760) (1.720) (.100) (2.790) (-3.010)

Credit Spread: Baa - Aaa 0.273 a 0.090 0.389 a 0.022 0.288 a 0.113 0.225(4.520) (1.190) (4.300) (.150) (3.170) (1.060) (1.180)

Cumulative Market Return -0.107 b -0.144 b 0.017 -0.021 -0.373 a -0.100 -0.057 (Prior year) (-2.180) (-2.410) (.230) (-.180) (-4.870) (-1.160) (-.390)

Constant 1.709 a 0.060 0.411 a -1.231 a -3.852 a -3.861 a 1.072 a

(12.980) (.330) (3.490) (-7.360) (-27.050) (-26.280) (4.790)a,b,c - Significantly different from zero at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Table presents coefficient estimates from a nested logit regression testing the impact of asymmetric information and risk on firm public and privatesecurity by public firms. First stage is the decision of market with coefficients representing tendency relative to the public market. Second stage isthe choice of security conditional on market, with coefficients representing tendency versus debt issuance. All firm-specific variables are lagged.Analyst earnings dispersion represents the standard deviation of the analyst forecasts divided by price per share. Cash flow volatility is the standarddeviation of cash flow using up twenty quarters prior to the security issuance. (Robust Z-statistics are presented in parentheses.) Chi-squaredstatistic for test of overall significance is 13929 (p-value .001). Sample is 8493 security issues.

Table 7bChoice of Security Issuance in Public and Private Markets

Page 48: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Public Public Public Private Private Private Total Debt Convertibles Equity Debt Convertibles Equity Variation

Analyst Earnings Surprise -0.8% 0.4% -11.1% 8.4% 1.4% 1.7% 23.7%

Cash Flow Volatility -4.6% 1.3% 2.3% -0.1% 0.7% 0.5% 9.4%

Corporate Governance -0.7% 0.3% -0.4% -0.1% 0.2% 0.7% 2.3%

R&D / Net Fixed Assets -9.8% 2.8% 3.0% 3.5% -0.1% 0.6% 19.8%

Profitability 5.1% -3.1% -1.9% 4.7% -2.1% -2.7% 19.6%

Distress 3.6% 0.7% 1.1% -8.3% 1.1% 1.7% 16.5%

Tobin's q -8.7% 2.3% 3.5% -0.3% 1.2% 2.0% 18.0%

Cumulative Abnormal Stock Return 0.0% 3.0% 5.0% -8.0% -1.0% 1.0% 18.0%

Debt/Asset Ratio 0.0% 0.2% 0.9% -1.8% 0.5% 0.1% 3.6%

Log Size 20.0% 2.8% -4.7% -8.5% -3.8% -5.8% 45.5%

Aaa Bond Rate -4.6% -3.1% 2.6% 4.0% 1.0% 0.2% 15.5%

Credit Spread: Baa - Aaa -14.5% -0.8% 5.1% 5.3% -1.1% 6.1% 32.9%

Cumulative Market Return 5.0% -1.0% 10.0% -6.0% -1.0% -7.0% 30.0%

This table illustrates the economic significance of our results. We compute the predicted probability for each deal inour dataset using the nested logit model of Table 4. Then we vary each specific variable by +/- 1/2 of its standarddeviation, and evaluate the change in each predicted probability, keeping all other variables fixed. We then averagethe marginal effects over all firms in the sample. The last column is the sum of the absolute value of the marginaleffects on each choice.

Table 8Economic Effects

Page 49: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Predicted ChoiceObserved Public Public Public Private Private Private ObservedChoice Debt Convertibles Equity Debt Convertibles Equity Count

Public Debt 1,582 10 19 962 1 1 2,57561% 0% 1% 37% 0% 0% 100%63% 14% 4% 18% 0% 0% 28%

Public Convertibles 161 28 57 341 0 19 60627% 5% 9% 56% 0% 3% 100%6% 38% 11% 6% 0% 3% 7%

Public Equity 92 12 266 656 6 81 1,1138% 1% 24% 59% 1% 7% 100%4% 16% 51% 12% 3% 11% 12%

Private Debt 674 14 88 2,925 21 57 3,77918% 0% 2% 77% 1% 2% 100%27% 19% 17% 56% 9% 8% 41%

Private Convertibles 10 3 33 177 119 180 5222% 1% 6% 34% 23% 34% 100%0% 4% 6% 3% 52% 25% 6%

Private Equity 9 6 58 190 81 388 7321% 1% 8% 26% 11% 53% 100%0% 8% 11% 4% 36% 53% 8%

Predicted Count 2,528 73 521 5,251 228 726 9,32727% 1% 6% 56% 2% 8% 100%100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%

Observed Predicted SecurityObserved Market Public Private Security Debt Convertibles Equity

Public 2,227 2,067 Debt 6,143 46 16552% 48% 97% 1% 3%71% 33% 79% 15% 13%

Private 895 4,138 Convertible 689 150 28918% 82% 61% 13% 26%29% 67% 9% 50% 23%

Equity 947 105 79351% 6% 43%12% 35% 64%

Predicted Market

Table 9Predicted versus Actual Choices

For each choice made by firms, this table shows the predicted choices made using the model and coefficients of Table 4. The predicted choice is the maximum probability over the six possible choices in Table 4. For each type of security issued, the first row gives the number predicted to choose the security given in the column header. The second row gives the percentage predicted to choose that security versus the actual choice. The third row gives the percentage of observed, predicted pairs divided by the overall number predicted to issue that security.

Page 50: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Choice of Security Issuance in Public and Private Markets

Security Issuance DecisionExplanatory Variables Public Private Public Private PrivateMeasures of Asymmetric Information Equity Equity Convertibles Convertibles Debt Surprise versus Analyst Estimates -1.043 a 0.356 a 0.034 0.399 a 0.237 a

(-3.100) (3.940) (.330) (4.460) (3.060)

Measures of Risk Cash Flow Volatility 0.551 a 0.552 a 0.483 a 0.581 a 0.267 c

(3.220) (3.100) (2.780) (3.260) (1.840)Firm Characteristics Corporate Governance 0.031 0.266 a 0.108 c 0.198 a 0.048

(.600) (3.670) (1.770) (2.530) (1.210)

R&D / Net Fixed Assets 0.933 a 0.868 a 0.994 a 0.751 a 0.640 b

(3.670) (3.420) (3.920) (2.930) (2.730)

Profitability -0.647 a -1.258 a -0.857 a -1.227 a -0.203 b

(Operating Cash Flow) (-5.590) (-10.200) (-6.970) (-9.850) (-2.060)

Financial Distress -0.017 0.289 0.000 0.246 -0.386 a

(Z-score < 1.81) (-.100) (1.410) (.000) (1.190) (-3.350)

Tobin's q 0.988 a 1.278 a 0.898 a 1.187 a 0.510 a

(9.130) (11.140) (8.090) (9.950) (5.300)

Cumulative Abnormal Stock Return 0.488 a 0.138 c 0.435 a -0.187 -0.186 a

(250 prior days) (7.270) (1.800) (5.990) (-1.580) (-3.200)

Debt/Asset Ratio 0.110 c 0.101 0.056 0.178 b -0.037 (Industry Adjusted) (1.920) (1.470) (.940) (2.440) (-.840)

Log Size -1.986 a -3.202 a -0.767 a -3.058 a -1.478 a

(market capitalization) (-24.300) (-21.590) (-10.330) (-20.450) (-26.040)Market Characteristics Aaa Bond Rate 0.401 a 0.343 a -0.160 a 0.456 a 0.277 a

(7.020) (4.640) (-2.630) (5.570) (7.420)

Credit Spread: Baa - Aaa 0.387 a 0.599 a 0.185 b 0.334 a 0.252 a

(5.140) (6.620) (2.360) (3.160) (5.320)

Cumulative Market Return 0.125 b -0.365 a -0.097 -0.209 a -0.086 b

(Prior year) (2.080) (-4.870) (-1.540) (-2.590) (-2.180)

Constant -0.166 -1.990 a -0.468 a -1.973 a 1.394 a

(-1.410) (-11.540) (-4.350) (-12.440) (15.120)a,b,c - Significantly different from zero at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Table presents coefficient estimates from a multinomial logit regression testing the impact of asymmetricinformation and risk on firm public and private security by public firms. Coefficients represent impact onprobability relative to public debt issuance. All firm-specific variables are lagged. All market-specificvariables represent three months prior to the security issuance. Surprise versus analyst estimates representsthe difference between actual earnings and median analyst forecast per share. Cash flow volatility is thestandard deviation of cash flow using up twenty quarters prior to the security issuance. (Robust Z-statisticsare presented in parentheses.) Chi-squared statistic for test of overall significance is 2249 (p-value .001).Sample is 9327 security issues.

Table A1

Page 51: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Security Issuance DecisionExplanatory Variables Public Private Public Private PrivateMeasures of Asymmetric Information Equity Equity Convertibles Convertibles Debt Analyst Earnings Dispersion -0.495 a 0.120 b 0.000 0.198 a -0.005

(-3.530) (2.010) (.010) (3.980) (-.150)

Measures of Risk Cash Flow Volatility 0.533 a 0.534 a 0.452 a 0.554 a 0.296 c

(3.040) (2.900) (2.550) (3.010) (1.900)Firm Characteristics Corporate Governance 0.037 0.242 a 0.116 c 0.228 a 0.054

(.690) (3.120) (1.870) (2.550) (1.330)

R&D / Net Fixed Assets 0.955 a 0.865 a 1.017 a 0.830 a 0.691 a

(4.350) (3.880) (4.600) (3.680) (3.330)

Profitability -0.636 a -1.280 a -0.861 a -1.203 a -0.234 a

(Operating Cash Flow) (-5.830) (-10.380) (-7.190) (-9.650) (-2.500)

Distress -0.044 0.424 c 0.030 0.537 b -0.339 a

(Z-score < 1.81) (-.270) (1.960) (.180) (2.410) (-2.860)

Tobin's q 0.992 a 1.261 a 0.910 a 1.160 a 0.519 c

(9.430) (10.960) (8.340) (9.420) (5.510)

Cumulative Abnormal Stock Return 0.537 a 0.149 c 0.477 a -0.247 -0.164 a

(250 prior days) (7.680) (1.700) (6.330) (-1.590) (-2.720)

Debt/Asset Ratio 0.136 b 0.100 0.079 0.170 b -0.016 (Industry Adjusted) (2.300) (1.320) (1.320) (2.110) (-.340)

Log Size -2.007 a -3.135 a -0.808 a -2.893 a -1.477 a

(Firm Value) (-23.790) (-18.970) (-10.650) (-17.630) (-25.450)Market Characteristics Aaa Bond Rate 0.394 a 0.312 a -0.157 a 0.558 a 0.273 b

(6.690) (3.790) (-2.540) (5.810) (7.210)

Credit Spread: Baa - Aaa 0.336 a 0.549 a 0.184 b 0.388 a 0.257 a

(4.310) (5.670) (2.290) (3.250) (5.320)

Cumulative Market Return 0.054 -0.445 a -0.113 c -0.164 c -0.072 c

(Prior year) (.880) (-5.460) (-1.730) (-1.800) (-1.730)

Constant -0.014 -1.988 a -0.437 a -2.032 a 1.381 a

(-.140) (-11.280) (-4.170) (-12.440) (15.620)a,b,c - Significantly different from zero at the one-percent (five, ten) level of significance.

Choice of Security Issuance in Public and Private MarketsTable A2

Table presents coefficient estimates from a multinomial logit regression testing the impact of asymmetricinformation and risk on firm public and private security by public firms. Coefficients represent impact onprobability relative to public debt issuance. All firm-specific variables are lagged. All market-specificvariables represent three months prior to the security issuance. Analyst earnings dispersion represents thestandard deviation of the analyst forecasts divided by price per share. Cash flow volatility is the standarddeviation of cash flow using up twenty quarters prior to the security issuance. (Robust Z-statistics arepresented in parentheses.) Chi-squared statistic for test of overall significance is 1956 (p-value .001).Sample is 8480 security issues.

Page 52: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between
Page 53: Why Do Public Firms Issue Private and Public Equity, Convertibles …finance.wharton.upenn.edu/department/Seminar/2004Fall/... · 2004. 9. 14. · conßicting implications between

Recommended