+ All Categories
Home > Documents > WP3.3 Model development and adaptation - uni-bonn.de · WP3.3 Model development and adaptation ......

WP3.3 Model development and adaptation - uni-bonn.de · WP3.3 Model development and adaptation ......

Date post: 12-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: lyminh
View: 231 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
34
1 Common Agricultural Policy Regionalised Impact – The Rural Development Dimension Collaborative project - Small to medium-scale focused research project under the Seventh Framework Programme Project No.: 226195 WP3.3 Model development and adaptation – Improvement of CAPRI Deliverable: D3.3.1 Literature review in modelling price transmission in PE models H.P. Witzke, W. Britz, N. Borkowski U Bonn Revised version 28-Jan-2011
Transcript

1

Common Agricultural Policy Regionalised Impact –

The Rural Development Dimension

Collaborative project - Small to medium-scale focused research project under

the Seventh Framework Programme

Project No.: 226195

WP3.3 Model development and adaptation –

Improvement of CAPRI

Deliverable: D3.3.1 Literature review in modelling price transmission in PE

models

H.P. Witzke, W. Britz, N. Borkowski

U Bonn

Revised version 28-Jan-2011

2

1. INTRODUCTION 3

2. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND OF PRICE TRANSMISSION 3

2.1. SPATIAL ARBITRAGE AND THE TAKAYAMA-JUDGE MODEL 3

2.2. TEMPORAL SCALE 5

2.3. PRODUCT HETEROGENEITY AND THE ARMINGTON ASSUMPTION 6

2.4. MARKET POWER 7

2.5. SPATIAL, GROSS TRADE AND NET TRADE MODELS 8

2.6. POLICY INSTRUMENTS INFLUENCING TRADE AND PRICE TRANSMISSION (TARIFFS, EXPORT SUBSIDIES,

INTERVENTION BUYING) 8

2.7. WELFARE IMPLICATIONS OF DIFFERENT PRICE TRANSMISSION SPECIFICATIONS 10

3. SPECIFIC ECONOMETRIC RESEARCH ON SPATIAL PRICE TRANSMISSION 12

3.1. MAINSTREAM DEVELOPMENT AND FINDINGS 12

3.2. SPECIAL ISSUES 14

4. PRICE TRANSMISSION IN ECONOMIC MODELLING OF AGRICULTURAL MARKETS 16

4.1. TAKAYAMA-JUDGE TYPE MODELS FOR HOMOGENEOUS GOODS 17

4.2. NON-SPATIAL PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM MODELS FOR HOMOGENEOUS GOODS 18

4.3. ARMINGTON STYLE MODELS FOR HETEROGENEOUS PRODUCTS 21

4.3.1. ECONOMETRIC RESEARCH AND RESULTS ON ARMINGTON PARAMETERS 22

5. CONCLUSIONS FOR CAPRI 24

6. SUMMARY 26

7. REFERENCES 27

3

1. Introduction

CAPRI is an economic simulation model for agriculture with a focus on Europe. Developed since 1996

and operational since 1999, its main task is to simulate ex-ante impacts of changes in the Common

Agricultural Policy (CAP) and other shocks on economic, environmental and social indicators related

to agriculture at different spatial scales, from globe to 1x1 km pixel clusters. An important element in

any such analysis are changes in agricultural producer prices which drive to a larger extent allocation

decisions at farm level and farm income. In the enlarged EU, sizeable quality differences and transport

distances between deficit and surplus regions could allow for larger differences in producer prices.

Empirical analysis is necessary to better understand price formation in the enlarged union and thus to

evaluate costs and benefits of common EU safety prices in the EU and the functioning of related

intervention measures.

The CAPRI market model developed from a simple net-trade model capturing EU-15 and the Rest-of-

the-world in its first operational version to a large spatial global trade model for agricultural products.

But the national price formation mechanism has not changed: Member State prices move in parallel

with common EU15 / EU10 / Bulgaria & Romania prices due to fixed percentage margins relative to

these regional aggregate prices. A task in the CAPRI-RD project, drawing on a request from the

project’s call text, refers to improving the price transmission mechanism along with an improved

modelling of market interventions. As a first step, deliverable 3.1.1 presented in here provides a

literature review on the theoretical background of price transmission and how it is modelled in

established tools for agricultural policy impact assessment. Based on that analysis, an improved

methodology for CAPRI will be developed and then later implemented in CAPRI’s code base.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 gives a short overview on economic theory relating to

spatial and temporal price transmission. The next section 3 reviews, based on available model

descriptions and paper, how price transmission is modelled in different agricultural market models.

Conclusions for CAPRI are drawn in section 4, followed by a summary.

2. Theoretical background of price transmission

2.1. Spatial arbitrage and the Takayama-Judge model

The Takayama-Judge model (1971) characterises a simultaneous equilibrium in markets for several

commodities, regions and time points. It assumes fixed per unit transport and inter-temporal storage

4

costs and unlimited transport and storage facilities. It is based on maximizing a quasi welfare function

defined as the sum of producer and consumer surpluses in each market minus transport and storage

costs, comparing point in times based on a social rate of time discount factor. The constraints define

market clearing conditions for each region and point in time. The first order conditions (FOCs) take the

Kuhn-Tucker form stating that price differences between regions cannot exceed per unit transport costs

– so called spatial arbitrage condition – and price differences between time points cannot exceed per

unit storage costs – so-called temporal arbitrage condition:

Pis ≤ Pir + Tirs

where Pir is the price of product i in region r (or time period r) and Tirs is the unit cost to bring the good

from region (period) r to region (period) s. Trade costs are often assumed symmetric (Tirs = Tisr) but

this is not necessary. The spatial arbitrage condition is also called the weak law of one price whereas it

is called the strong law of one price if it is assumed to hold with equality (Fackler, Goodwin 2001, p.

978). The latter neglects the case of price differences being smaller than transport (and more generally

transaction) costs for the move from region r to region s. Major assumptions underlying most versions

of the model are price taking, fully informed agents and homogenous products.

A model based on the spatial arbitrage condition including a set of potentially trading regions will

show for each pair of regions one of three possible regimes:

(1) no trade at all, because the price difference is smaller than transport costs,

(2) positive trade from region r to region s and Pis = Pir + Tirs,

(3) positive trade from region s to region r and Pis + Tisr = Pir.

An implication of the model is that, in case of a ‘small’ increase in region r demand in regime (2), there

would be a decline in exports from region r to region s and prices would increase in both regions

exactly by the same amount (with Tirs given). In case of a medium increase in demand of region r there

may be a ‘regime switch’ with the exporter r moving from regime (2) to the autarchy case (1) and

P1is < P1

ir + Tirs => P1is - P0

is < P1ir - P0

ir

In the case of switching regimes price changes are not fully passed on from the region where the shock

originates to neighbouring regions. Finally there may be, in case of a strong increase in demand of

region r, a full trade reversal with the exporter r moving from regime (2) to the importer case of regime

(3).

These regime switches may provoke large changes in predicted bilateral trade flows in spite of only

small changes in prices and domestic quantities. This ‘jumpy’ behaviour may be realistic for fairly

5

homogeneous goods and highly disaggregated commodities. Already for moderately aggregated

commodities, say all ‘wheat’, we observe some stability of trading patterns. However, if unit transport

cost rise with the volume of trade (Fackler, Goodwin 2001, p. 985) prices will not be fully passed on to

neighbouring regions even if trade regimes do not change and the model will predict a more stable

trade pattern.

The standard version of the model in empirical applications features inverse linear supply and demand

functions. It can be shown that inverse linear demand function cannot represent regularity conditions

for utility maximization under a budget constraint. The resulting error depends on the size of the

income effect of the simulated price changes, so that the model might be defended in applications for

agricultural products in developed countries with their low budget shares.

2.2. Temporal scale

The previous introduction has neglected the fact that, for several reasons, spatial arbitrage takes time:

• delivery lags during transport,

• time for assessment of market opportunities and deciding on optimal actions,

• time to find trading partners, negotiating conditions and setting up contracts.

These delays also create uncertainty if the prices finally received by an exporter are unknown at the

point of decision making and expectations have to be formed therefore. Even without risk aversion this

prevents perfect price transmission in most circumstances and the equilibrium condition in line with

exports from region r to region s becomes (Fackler, Goodwin 2001, p. 989)

δ E[Pist+1] = Pirt + Tirst

if there is a delivery lag of one period and the discount factor is δ. A positive transitory supply shock in

region r would be passed on to region s in the next period (as a part of the ‘excess supply’ if shipped to

the other region) whereas a transitory shock in region s would have only effects on region s, in the case

that agents in region r do not anticipate this shock. Storage creates additional linkages among prices of

different periods (Wright 2001).

Econometric work on price transmission therefore has to consider a wide range of possible dynamics

and the appropriate empirical analysis of such dynamics is the key of a whole literature that will be

reviewed in more detail in section 4.

6

2.3. Product heterogeneity and the Armington assumption

Spatial and temporal arbitrage conditions link price differences in space and time to transport and

storage costs under the assumption of homogenous goods. A key outcome of that model is that trade in

a particular good takes always place in one direction only, if at all, such that any pair of regions falls

exactly into one of the three trade regimes. Most statistics however tell otherwise. Why is that the case?

The most frequent explanation is product heterogeneity which seems obvious when looking at

commodities such as cars. Product differentiation by car producers leads to a situation where bi-lateral

exports and imports between car producing countries are the rule rather then the exemption. Some

consumers in most countries will buy foreign brands even if cheaper domestic cars are offered, due to

differences in size, features, design, image etc. If aggregate commodity groups such as “products from

manufacturing” are analysed, the effect becomes even more significant.

One might argue that for clearly defined agricultural products, such as raw sugar, product heterogeneity

does not exist. However, there are two problems with this argument. Firstly, many agricultural products

such as e.g. beef do show sizeable quality differences, as a look at the supermarket counter for meat

proves. And secondly, many multi-commodity models are based on the FAO concept of primary

product equivalents such that consumption and trade of wheat also includes trade in derived products

such a Pasta and Pizza. As the shares of processed products in total trade will vary according to regions,

wheat is not homogeneous anymore even if we neglect quality differences in the raw product, arising

from different protein contents, for example.

When products are heterogeneous, the law of one price need not hold any longer, whether in the weak

or in the strong form. Marginal costs may differ for each regional variant of a product. The same holds

for marginal willingness to pay, giving the starting point for the so-called Armington (1969)

assumption which is by now widely applied in trade modelling. In general, this implies that consumers

consider French and German cars as different products, thus multiplying the number of products with

the number of regions. To avoid specifying very large demand systems with thousands of parameters

the typical application is based on a CES utility function to explain the distribution of total demand for

a commodity (group) to different origins, assuming that each origin represents a different product

quality. That leads in the overall model to a separable, two stage budgeting problem where the top level

determines the budget shares for product groups, and the bottom level distributes these budget shares to

different origins. The Armington assumption is applied in nearly all CGE models in the last years (an

exception: Fischer et. al 1988). The rather simple sub-utility function features solely n+1 parameters:

the so-called substitution elasticity and n so-called share parameters for each origin. With the

7

substitution elasticity given, the remaining parameters allow calibration of the model without further

assumptions to any given strictly positive set of trade flows and related prices.

In most CGE models, the Armington assumption on the demand side is complemented by a CET

function on the supply side which assumes that producers differentiate their products by destination.

Coming back to the example of cars, the average price and quality of cars produced in Germany for

export to Japan might be different from those shipped to France or sold domestically. The CET

formulation draws on the same functional form as the CES utility function and can, again, be simply

calibrated against a set of strictly positive export flows and related prices once the transformation

elasticity has been chosen.

2.4. Market power

Product heterogeneity may also facilitate the exertion of market power on regional or national markets

that often are supplied by a few firms only whereas the number of firms is larger on a European or

global scale. A common expectation is that market power causes margin-squeezing price changes (a

drop in output prices or an increase in input prices) being quicker and more completely transmitted

than margin stretching changes (increases of out put prices, decreases of input prices). In this way

market power is seen as one reason for asymmetry in price transmission besides costs of price

adjustment, political and institutional or storage effects, both vertically as well as spatially

(Meyer, Cramon-Taubadel 2004).

However, this assessment is largely based on assumptions of middlemen using their market power to in

crease margins temporarily or permanently in case of price changes. Formal models partly confirm this

intuition but sometimes also give opposing results. A variety of situations may arise that each have

different implications for spatial price transmission: Regional markets may be separated and regional

suppliers, potentially monopolists in ‘their’ region, compete with each other in a wider oligopoly. The

kind of price transmission then depends on the conjectures of the competitors responses to a change in

the own price. Another situation arises if one monopolist or an oligopoly serves several markets at the

same time, perhaps as common on the sugar market. If all suppliers are experiencing the same shocks

prices may by synchronised (Faminow, Benson 1990; Koontz et al. 1993; Koontz and Garcia 1997),

but in case of regional differences in demand elasticities, price setting behaviour will differ as well

(pricing-to-market). Still another situation arises, if a competitive market and an imperfectly

competitive market are linked spatially.

To sum up: Market power involves considerable complications of economic relationships between

regional markets but concluding evidence (see section 4) has not yet emerged and is unlikely be put

8

forward quickly. Large scale modelling typically ignores these complications, a simplification that is

probably defendable given the current state of knowledge.

2.5. Spatial, Gross trade and net trade models

Both Takayama-Judge type models and those applying the Armington assumption are so-called spatial

models which comprise endogenous bi-lateral trade flows. Another model class are net trade models

where only the difference between domestic supply and demand can be determined. Conceptually, net

trade models are based on the homogenous good assumption and resemble in that respect the

Takayama-Judge type models. However, they lack the explicit transport cost minimization component

dealing with bi-lateral trade flows. Rather, in net trade models, domestic prices in each region are

linked to a key (world market) price via price transmission functions which might capture trade and

transaction costs as well as policy interventions such as export taxes and subsidies or import tariffs.

Explicit bi-lateral trade flows between regions are absent from the model. One might argue that a linear

price transmission equation in a net trade model summarizes the spatial arbitrage condition from spatial

modelling as long as the set of non-zero trade flows is constant and hence there are no switching

regimes. In that case, the price differences between any one pair of regions do not change even if the

size of flows might, so that one might also relate any regional price to one (averaged or not) key price.

That point will be picked up again in individual model descriptions below: Very often the form of the

price transmission equation suggests that a switch from the net importer to net exporter status cannot be

captured appropriately as the price transmission equation is independent of net trade.

In some cases a non-spatial net trade model is converted to a non-spatial gross trade model by

additional behavioural equations which determine either the level of imports and exports or both. These

equations may include simplified trade policy instruments such as total TRQs (for the rest of the world)

and export subsidies (e.g. in Witzke, Tonini 2008 or Bouamra-Mechemache et al. 2002) but evidently,

they cannot account for bilateral trade preferences. Another problem is theoretical in nature: Separate

behavioural functions permit having different export and import prices, thus acknowledging product

heterogeneity. However, it may be criticized that these prices are unrelated as the exporting regions and

importing regions in the rest of the world could also trade with each other.

2.6. Policy instruments influencing trade and price transmission (tariffs,

export subsidies, intervention buying)

The influence of policy instruments on price transmission has stimulated key contributions in the

agricultural economics literature that rendered the concept of price transmission elasticities popular

(Tyers, Anderson 1992, Mundlak, Larson 1992). For the case of exports from region r to region s the

9

simple spatial arbitrage condition for homogeneous goods from section 3.1.1 (regime 2) may be

generalised as follows:

Pis ≤ Pir + Tirs(Pis,Pir) + τirs(Pis,Pir) – σirs(Pis,Pir)

where Tirs(Pis,Pir) now also covers those transaction costs that vary with the value of the goods

(insurance), τirs(Pis,Pir) is a tariff levied by country s that might depend on the prices (for example in the

case of a simple ad valorem tariff), and σirs(Pis,Pir) is an export subsidy that is granted by country r. If

the sum of transactions cost and tariffs net of export subsidies is positive and independent of prices,

absolute price changes from country r would be fully passed on to country s, assuming that the

arbitrage condition holds with equality and no other impediments affect trade. This would imply a price

elasticity εirs = (dPis/dPir) * (Pir/Pis) = 1 * (Pir/Pis) < 1. Conversely, in the case of transactions costs,

tariffs and export subsidies all proportional to Pir we would obtain a price transmission elasticity equal

to one. A relevant case is also that import tariffs decrease, as Pir is increasing, reflecting the desire of

importing country s to stabilise domestic producer prices.

An extreme case of such a stabilisation policy is the system of variable levies of the CAP before

tariffication in the Uruguay round. However, even now we have the special case of cereals where the

applied EU tariffs are cut at 155% of the intervention price. Effectively, this rule has reintroduced the

old flexible levy system for the cereals concerned. Export subsidies were also used in the old CAP as a

stabilisation instrument but they have been largely reduced to zero for most products. Both for tariffs as

for export subsidies a full analysis would have to consider quantitative constraints in border policies as

well, i.e. tariff rate quotas and WTO export subsidy commitments. However, for CAPRI-RD, the most

interesting issues are the implications of CAP stabilisation policies on intra EU price transmission, as

extra EU price transmission is well covered in the CAPRI market module already.

If stabilisation policies take the form of buying into intervention stocks to defend a certain minimum

price Pirmin in an EU Member State r, this may effectively disturb the arbitrage with another Member

State s:

Pis ≤ max(Pir*, Pir

min) + Tirs

where Pir* is the hypothetical equilibrium price without intervention buying. This basically reflects the

situation in potential export region Hungary for maize in 2004-06 relative to potential import region

Spain (where tariffs and export subsidies are irrelevant). Intervention buying had increased market

prices in Hungary to that point where arbitrage to the deficit region Spain became unprofitable. Instead,

it was cheaper to import from the US (region u) in Spain, in spite of tariffs applied. This situation was

due to an exceptional combination of high Tirs , due to poor infrastructure for transport from Hungary

10

to Spain, and a low Pir due to good harvests that usually would have triggered intra EU arbitrage (see

Commission 2006, p. 18).

Similar intra EU trade and price effects may also be triggered if exports subsidies tend to support the

prices in particular Member States. This may be part of the EU market management, for example if

export subsidies are granted on purpose to support markets that are hit by a regional loss of consumer

confidence related to animal diseases. However, region specific effects of export subsidies may also be

a consequence of traditional trade linkages (example: Denmark as an established overseas exporter of

pork).

It is unclear whether stabilisation policies (via intervention buying or export subsidies) that affect the

regional market prices need to be considered explicitly in an empirical analysis of intra EU price

transmission. It might be argued that their effect is fully incorporated in the observed market prices

such that their explicit consideration is not necessary. This is different from measures such as the pre

1993 Monetary Compensatory Amounts (MCAs) that amount to intra EU tariffs or export subsidies

τirs(Pis,Pir) – σirs(Pis,Pir) and clearly need to be accounted for (Zanias 1993). Whereas intervention prices

are sometimes incorporated in empirical analyses of extra EU price transmission (Listorti 2009),

studies of intra EU price transmission with explicit acknowledgement of intervention prices or export

subsidies have not been encountered in the literature. It is clear that the updated specification of CAPRI

needs to reflect a regional application of stabilisation instruments. However, rather than becoming part

of the price transmission equation, such policies could also be reflected by the rules to regionally

allocate intervention buying in CAPRI. The solution will be developed as part of the CAPRI-RD

Deliverable 3.3.2.

2.7. Welfare implications of different price transmission specifications

Different specifications of the transaction costs determining intra EU price differences (Tirs(Pis,Pir))

have some implications for appropriate welfare analysis in CAPRI. In a general equilibrium framework,

any income created when transforming agricultural raw materials and distributing them to final

consumers would evidently be accounted for in the sectors concerned and contribute to the total

welfare effects of any policy. In partial equilibrium modelling, effects on the marketing and

distribution sectors are usually neglected. This is consistent with constant margins equal to constant

marginal costs and zero profits but it would lead to an inconsistent welfare analysis if marketing

margins are not constant, for example in the commonly assumed case that marketing services require

costs that are a given percentage of the raw product’s price (or marginal cost). This point is most easily

demonstrated in graphical form.

11

Figure 1: Market equilibrium with two specifications for marginal costs in the marketing sector

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16

Demand

MC(marketing1)

MC(marketing2)

MC(beer)

MC(total1)

MC(total2)

P(equilibrium)

Assume this is a graphical representation of the German market for a Dutch beer variety. The marginal

cost curve for this beer variety is the bottom line starting at 5 Euro per unit, MC(beer). However, to

penetrate the German market also requires increasing transport cost and other cost (promotion,

distribution etc.) such that the total marginal cost curve becomes MC(total1) = MC(beer) +

MC(marketing1). Alternatively, MC(marketing2) represents the case of constant marginal costs in the

food chain per unit of beer delivered in Germany which leads to total marginal cost curve MC(total2)

such that the market equilibrium settles at an equilibrium price of 33 Euros and 6 units of beer.

Now assume that Germany would ban the sales of this beer variety, say for violation of the German

purity law. The welfare loss of such policy would be the triangle bordered by the vertical axis, the

demand curve and either MC(total1) or MC(total2). In the case of constant margins, i.e. with

MC(marketing2), the correct welfare effect could have been calculated as well from the loss of

consumer surplus and producer surplus neglecting the marketing sector altogether, that is integrating

along MC(beer) only. However, this simplified procedure would neglect some welfare effects (the loss

of profits in the marketing sector) if in reality MC is increasing, i.e. with MC(marketing1).

Note that increasing marginal costs in the marketing sector are a plausible assumption for transaction

cost Tirs and more general specifications than assumed in Figure 1 are conceivable, for example a linear

12

form but MC(marketing1) constant * MC(beer) or nonlinear forms for MC(marketing1) that are

entirely unrelated to MC(beer).

Note also that Figure 1 may be interpreted more generally as depicting the situation of more aggregate

goods that are consumed and produced in both countries such that the demand curve is an excess

demand curve and the MC(total) curves are excess supply functions of the exporting region. The

conclusion for partial equilibrium modelling remains: All specifications other than constant margins

require additional terms in the welfare accounting. An explicit discussion of this point has not been

encountered in the literature, but for Witzke, Tonini (2008) it motivated a return to constant margins in

the feed industry. The issue also needs to be considered in CAPRI-RD deliverable 3.3.2.

3. Specific econometric research on spatial price transmission

In this section, we will briefly review the vast area of econometric research on spatial price

transmission. While econometric estimations are sometimes also undertaken as a part of the

specification of full partial equilibrium models, the price transmission relationships are only a small

subset of thousands of other equations in such a context. Evidently, specialised econometric research

on price transmission may investigate more thoroughly whether and to what extent spatial distant

prices influence each other.

Complete price transmission is often taken as a sign of market efficiency. Vice versa, lags or missing

market integration hint at welfare losses by suboptimal allocation (Rapsomanikis et al. 2003). Price

transmission elasticities determine the direction, magnitude and distribution of welfare and market

effects of trade policy scenarios in global agricultural partial equilibrium models. Thus there is a

continuous interest in the quality of their estimation (Sharma 2002).

3.1. Mainstream development and findings

Early studies investigating price transmission often used simple measures of correlation and regression

analysis. However, after several authors having demonstrated the shortcomings of these approaches,

most of the recent econometric studies, at the latest since the 1990ies, apply some form of dynamic

vector autoregressive regression technique. This should acknowledge the time series character of the

data, often found non-stationary in the levels, and their usually unclear causal structure

(Rapsomanikis et al. 2003).

One line of pure time series research works by testing for Granger Causality. In his paper Granger

(1969) defined a first time series to Granger-cause a second one if it its lagged values show significant

influences in a regression of the second variable on lags of both the first and the second variable. An

13

application in Europe was done by Gordon et al. (1993) for the British and French Lamp Market. They

find the prices integrated but with considerable time-lags which they attribute to political reasons and

quality differences in the regional meat qualities. In an international context there are some studies

confirming Granger causality for spatial distant prices (e.g. Gupta, Mueller 1982; Alexander, Wyeth

1994). Granger causality merely reveals whether two markets are integrated in the sense that shocks are

transferred between regions. It does neither say something about the driving forces behind that nor

about the extent (related to the magnitude of coefficients).

Several authors criticise studies relying on Granger causality as this Vector Auto Regression

framework usually neglects non-stationarity of time series concerned. If time series are non-stationary

the natural econometric pendant to market integration is cointegration analysis (Rapsomanikis et al.

2003). One of the first applications was by Ravaillon (1986). His model regresses the current price of a

peripherical region on lagged prices of this region as well as on current and lagged prices of a central

market. In case of long run integration the regression may be cast into an error correction form. This

approach became one of the standard techniques in price transmission research (Faminow, Benson

1990; Dahlgran, Blank 1992). Whether international commodity markets are spatially integrated based

on such methodology is a contentious issue (Ardeni 1989).

Most recent studies have found price series non-stationary and hence used error correction formulations

in order to test for the LOP in the long run. Zanias (1993) uses a cointegration approach to investigate

the integration of European soft wheat, milk, potato and pork markets. He finds that the highly political

determined milk market is the least integrated, while the wheat market is highly integrated after

allowing for monetary compensatory amounts. Hereby, he confirms Sexton, Kling, and Carman’s

thesis (1991) that non-tariff barriers and imperfect competition are important drawbacks for market

integration. Sanjuán and Gil confirm the integration of pork and lamb markets in the EU (2001).

Another type of analysis has been carried out by Fousekis (2007). Instead of estimating the

transmission coefficients, he uses a clustering algorithm on the error correction adjustment parameters

to test for price clubs in European poultry and pork meat markets. He finds significant clubs where the

weak version of the LOP holds, contradicting the idea of an EU wide common market. Viju, Nolan,

Kerr (2006) approach the question for integrated European markets in another way: They ask whether

the rye, soft wheat, barley, oats and potato markets of Austria, Finland and Sweden were less integrated

with the European Market before their entrance than afterwards. Their study confirms that increasing

integration, however, just for rye and barley between Austria and Germany.

Hockmann and Vönecki (2009) investigate the integration of the Hungarian butter market with the

European one by means of cointegration and impulse response analyses. They find integration between

14

European butter prices which is however weaker between old and new Member States than among the

old ones.

3.2. Special issues

The bulk of econometric research on spatial price transmission falls into the ‘level 1’ category (Barrett

1996), where only information on prices is used, basically regressing one set of prices on another set or

investigating their common evolution in vector autoregressive systems. Given that transaction cost data

(on Tirst) is evidently more difficult to compile, ‘level 2’ studies that also make use of those are less

frequent. An exception is Goodwin, Grennes, Wohlgenant (1990) who find support for the (strong) law

of one price in an analysis of US export products if they acknowledge rational expectations and

transport cost data. ‘Level 3’ analyses that consider trade data together with price data are also quite

rare. Typically the trade flow information is only used to identify the appropriate regime and related

arbitrage condition (eg. Barrett, Li 2002).

Baffes (1991) shows in another ‘level 2’ study that one reason for long run failure of the LOP (as in

Ardeni 1989) can be the omission of transaction costs. In his study, he finds a significant relationship

between price differentials and transport costs. Transaction costs create a band in which the prices

move independently of each other as transaction costs are prohibitively high and therefore direct

arbitrage does not happen. In fact, on the background of the theory presented above, this is an evident

point. Other studies acknowledge transactions costs without needing data on them. This applies to

some so-called switching regression models as Sexton, Kling, and Carman (1991) that allow for an

unknown band where prices do not co-move and estimate the relation outside this bandwidth. Baulch

(1997) criticised earlier approaches ignoring transaction costs as suffering from omitted variable biases

and time series drawbacks. He improves on Sexton, Kling, and Carman (1991) by including (some)

data on transaction cost rather than treating them as unobservable and distinguishes three trade regimes.

Apart from transport costs, most components of transaction costs such as search and information costs

are difficult to measure. As long as they are constant per traded unit, stationary and additive they may

become part of the error term and constant. However, if they are large or volatile they may mask

existing price relations. If transaction costs yet reveal to be non-stationary or multiplicative, the applied

models must be either non-linear or include thresholds (Conforti 2004).

Barrett and Li (2002) clearly distinguish between market integration and spatial competitive

equilibrium: Markets might be integrated without trade even if costs of transport are prohibitively high

for example, if both trade with a third region. Conversely, even if there is trade, markets might still not

be in equilibrium if there are potential rents to be earned that are left unexploited. By means of a

15

mixture distribution model approach, they assign market relationships to these regimes and a

probability of them being integrated is defined per period. A clear benefit of their approach is that it

does not depend on time series characteristics of the underlying series and considers trade data.

Disadvantages are precisely these data needs, a huge number of coefficients due to the consideration of

bilateral trade and the lack of values for the degree of transmission (Fackler, Tastan 2008).

Apart from transaction costs there are more reasons why even the weak version of the LOP might be

rejected in a price series analysis even if it would hold in reality. The assumption of product

homogeneity is the most prominent example.

An important influence stems from policies: On agricultural markets, intervention prices, export

subsidies or non tariff barriers have a crucial effect on price transmission (Rapsomanikis et al. 2003).

While EU intervention may disturb price integration (as discussed in Section 3.6), it may also create

integration if applied in many regions at the same time (Zanias 1993). Several studies have tested for

structural political influence (Goletti and Babu 1994, Alexander and Wyeth 1994) or split the sample

according to changes in policy regimes (e.g. Brooks, Melyukhina 2005, Viju et al. (2006). Benjamin,

Guéguen, Houée (2003) and Listorti (2009) include the intervention price as an explicit variable in the

price transmission equation for the EU to a selected “world” price.

While transaction costs may be an impediment to measuring existing integration between markets,

market power may cause market integration to be confirmed although there is none (Faminow,

Benson 1990). This mostly applies to vertical price transmission but also holds spatially. Indeed the

first applications of price transmission analysis were in the scope of market definition and antitrust

regulations (Fackler, Goodwin 2001, p. 973).

Empirical studies often suffer from a lack of appropriate proxies for market power. Peltzmann (2000)

tests the number of competitors and the Herfindahl-Hirschmann-Index and finds that they give

contradicting effects. Another problem is that market concentration often stays constant over a long

time meaning that there is hardly any variation in this determinant. McCorriston (2002) proposes

comparing different vertical structures in European Countries but there are a lot of other influences

making inference from such a comparison difficult.

Abdullai (2000) estimates cointegration of three markets in Ghana and finds asymmetries in price

transmission between the central market and both peripheral ones. However, he does not definitely

attribute this to sub-optimal market structures but also to inventory adjustment. Liu (2008) considers

Finnish and German pork prices. The pork market chain in Finland is rather concentrated on processor

level. It is found that German and Finnish pork prices are highly integrated but that large shocks are

transmitted asymmetrically. As expected, it appears that processors in Finland transmit margin

16

squeezing price changes quicker than margins stretching changes in order to increase average profit. In

spite of integration Liu found a very sluggish adjustment to of Finnish prices to a shock of the German

price (3% per week). This evidence is noteworthy because most papers only report various stationarity

or cointegration tests, but hardly ever a price transmission coefficient (or elasticity). Serra and Gil

(2006) also allow for asymmetry in their estimation that focuses on the effect of the size of the trading

partner: They state that price transmission is symmetric between Spain and German, being the leading

pork producers in the EU, while it is asymmetric in favour of Germany concerning Denmark and

France. Market power is mentioned as one possible explanation for this finding but asymmetry in

market infrastructure (tailored toward specific trade directions) and inventory management may also

play a role.

A final issue needs to be mentioned that will be important in an application tailored to CAPRI. A large

part of the empirical research on dynamic relationships of prices from different regions uses sub-

annual data, monthly or even weekly, simply because this is the only way to obtain a sufficient set of

observations needed for a specification of rich dynamics. If these dynamics are only strong over a few

months corresponding models specified with an annual frequency will be much simpler. These effects

of temporal aggregation have been investigated in Cramon-Taubadel, Loy, Musfeldt (1995) at the

example of pig markets where they found that contemporaneous relationships gain in importance over

lagged relationships and that R2 statistics were increasing when moving from weekly to quarterly data.

Other statistical effects are that with a higher frequency the statistical power of tests tends to increase,

whereas a longer span of the data horizon (in years) increases the likelihood of structural breaks (Wang,

Tomek 2007). If sub-annual data have been used for estimation, it is always possible to move to the

annual scale by temporal aggregation, as in Listorti and Esposti (2008). As the first explorations of

intra EU price transmission equations for CAPRI-RD will be based on monthly data, these issues will

be relevant for deliverable 3.3.2.

4. Price transmission in economic modelling of agricultural

markets

The following section reviews how domestic prices are linked to international ones for some widely

used economic simulation models focusing on agriculture. As discussed above, an important distinction

must be a made between approaches based on the homogenous good assumptions and such ones

treating imported and domestic goods as non-perfect substitutes. The review suggests that almost all

established Multi-Commodity Models (MCMs) are based on the homogenous good assumptions,

17

whereas CGEs and CAPRI are based on product heterogeneity. Accordingly, the section first reviews

the standard MCMs and draws some conclusions for the group, before discussing GTAP and CAPRI.

4.1. Takayama-Judge type models for homogeneous goods

An important group of applied spatial equilibrium models of the Takayama-Judge type (see McCarl,

Spreen 1980) are single market models for agricultural commodities. If these commodities are

considered homogeneous goods the Takayama-Judge approach may be preferable to an Armington

style model that better fits the case of differentiated products. Furthermore, behavioural functions of

single commodity models often depend on the own price of the commodity in question only, such that

full demand systems are avoided which simplifies the application of a Takayama –Judge model (no

need to watch for symmetry of demand functions used in the objective function).

An influential study on the pending expiry of the EU milk quota system has been carried out by

Bouamra-Mechemache, Jongeneel and Réquillart 2008 (see also Bouamra-Mechemache and Réquillart

and 2005). While considerable efforts have been made to estimate the key parameters of the “EDIM”

model econometrically it appears that only the own price elasticity has been used in the final market

model (thus avoiding to cope with symmetry), even though the model covers all dairy products (14,

including 6 types of cheese). The spatial model either represents net trade flows only or treats one of

imports and exports as exogenous. Due to the difficulty to handle ad valorem tariffs in a quasi welfare

maximisation (Rutherford 1995) the analysis treats all tariffs as specific tariffs although an explicit

trade policy representation (e.g. regarding some TRQs) is also mentioned as one of the assets of this

approach. The practical problem with an explicit welfare maximisation is that the commodity prices are

determined as shadow values of market balance constraints such that ad valorem tariffs cannot

explicitly be multiplied with those. Calibration problem is solved for behavioural functions with an ad

hoc variation of the PMP methodology while the calibration problem for the trade matrix is not

discussed.

The latter is addressed in the recent analysis of the banana market in Anania (2010) that investigates

different reform options for the EU banana CMO. This relies on a calibration method related to PMP to

specify the matrix of transport costs Tirs in such a way that net trade and prices are exactly calibrated.

However, the observed trade matrix is only one among many optimal solutions such that the

methodology cannot ensure its exact calibration (Anania, Drogué, Paris, 2009).

Another example is Nolte et al. (2010) that presents sugar reform scenarios. Rather than as a standard

welfare maximisation, the model is solved as an MCP problem which may accommodate missing

integrability due to non-symmetric behavioural functions but may also handle ad valorem tariffs.

18

Finally, there are also a few examples of full scale sector models that do not confine themselves to

single markets or a closely related set of markets. In methodological terms EUFASOM (Schneider et al.

2008) and GLOBIOM (Havlík et al. 2010) go back to the US model ASM (recently: Schneider, McCarl,

Schmid, 2007). In contrast to the examples above, these are large scale LP models that are designed to

cover technology choices in detail while the Takayama-Judge approach in trade representation is so far

only used in its standard form (only specific tariffs, no TRQs).

4.2. Non-spatial partial equilibrium models for homogeneous goods

Non spatial models have a so-called “world market price” that is assumed to clear global markets. This

is sometimes also called the “middle Atlantic Ocean price” to show its synthetic nature. However, in

several models such as FAPRI, AGLINK or AGMEMOD, these world market prices are “key prices”

referring to a specific price notation defined by location, product quality and other contract details for

which time series exist, thus resolving the ambiguities on the definition of the world price. Amington

style models do not have such a key price. However, from the data base and scenario results weighted

international averages of different prices (cif, fob, producer etc.) can be calculated and used to report

“world prices” and their changes.

The parameters in price transmission equations can be either estimated from time series / cross

sectional analysis or derived from transport costs and policy parameters such as tariffs or OECD

PSE/CSE calculations, or based on a combination of the two.

The history of MCMs starts with SWOPSIM (Roningen 1986; Roningen, Dixit 1991) in the eighties,

and some SWOPSIM design features are still found in established modelling systems such as

behavioural equations in double log form. SWOPSIM also used iso-elastic functions to link the world

market to domestic prices. The tables with these price-transmission elasticities are documented

(Sullivan 1990), and had been subsequently used also by other studies. The price transmission elasticity

captures in a single parameter the combined impact of transport and transaction costs, policy

interventions (tariffs, export subsidies, domestic measures) and their responsiveness to world market

prices as well as of product heterogeneity. Transport and transaction costs refer to both international (to

border/from border) and domestic transports and transaction (from border to consumer or supplier to

border).

The World Food Model of FAO in an early version comprised double-log price transmission functions

between the world market and domestic prices. A later version used linear ones which included tariffs

and transport costs against the uniform world market price in the model. The transport costs were

added for net importers and subtracted for exporters (Cluff 2003).

19

AGLINK/COSIMO, a combined OECD/FAO effort, is a recursive-dynamic net trade model solved in

yearly steps where in most cases linear price transmission equations are used to link key market to

domestic prices (OECD 2007). The key market prices act as world market prices in the system. The

price transmission equations typically comprise tariffs but also margins. These margins, the so-called

add factors, are time and market specific and set such that domestic prices from country specific

outlooks provided by the different teams line up to the key market prices. However, AGLINK, as a

weak template model, leaves the teams being responsible for the individual country module sizeable

freedom to choose whatever they just appropriate to link quantities and prices from their country

module to the rest of the modelling system. In some cases, instead of using a price transmission

equation, there is domestic market price acting as a clearing variable in the domestic market which is

linked via behavioural equations for imports or exports to the world market. Equally, some world

markets such as for beef are split into a Pacific and Atlantic one.

The FAPRI modelling system consists of individual commodity models or group of commodity

models linked together via cross-price effects. These models can also be used independently by fixing

the cross-prices, and have been estimated independently, typically as single equation regression models,

or specified based on expert knowledge. The documentation for the oilseeds module (FAPRI 2010)

states: “Using price transmission equations driven by estimated or consensus price transmission

elasticities, we link the world price in domestic currency and the domestic price for all products. The

price transmission equations assume that agents in each country are price-takers in the world market.

Countries are either natural importers or exporters if their autarkic price falls above or below the world

price. Abstracting from any spatial consideration and assuming an "ad valorem tariff only" regime, the

domestic price can be expressed as Pd = + · Pw · r · (1+d), where Pd is the domestic price, Pw is

the world price of the commodity including international transportation cost if the country is an

importer (FOB price for exporters), r is the exchange rate, and d summarizes policy interventions

between the world and domestic markets and is expressed in ad valorem form. Parameter captures

the divergence of the domestic and border price that does not depend on the price level but rather

reflects transaction costs arising between the farm gate and the market place, and/or marketing mark-

ups. It is unclear how a regime switch from net importer or exporter is treated as is fixed. The

description is found in similar form also for other modules of FAPRI, but it cannot be excluded that

solutions differing from the standard discussed above are also present for specific country and

commodity combinations. Reviewing FAPRI, Cluff (2003) reports that elasticity numbers in the price

transmission model are a combination of estimated elasticities and elasticities from the literature or

20

from expert opinion. Anchor prices used by the FAPRI are for cereals mostly US Gulf notation, for oils

and cakes mostly notations in European ports, and for dairy northern European prices and livestock

domestic US prices.

AGMEMOD (Bartova, M’Barek 2008) is a Multi-Commodity model for EU agriculture based on

single-regression behavioural equations and structured in country modules. It is linked institutionally to

FAPRI and has adopted many aspects of the FAPRI methodology. Similar to FAPRI’s concept of

international anchor prices, for each European commodity market one specific country’s price is

treated as the key price to which the prices of other countries are linked. The price linkage equations

are usually derived from regression analysis and include self-sufficiency rations in the key and country

market in addition to the prices concerned (Bartova, M’Barek 2008, p. 17). For the key price, the price

transmission equations link to a world market price (from FAPRI) and might comprise besides

exchange rates policy variables such as intervention prices, tariff rate quota levels and subsidised

export limits. Due to the case specific implementation, the variables driving the equations might

however differ between markets.

ESIM is a net trade model where commodities are treated as homogenous and price differences are

hence linked to transport / transaction costs and policy interventions such as border protection

measures. In order to capture the effect of a regime switch from net importer to net exporter, the model

embeds a logistic price transmission function (Banse, Grethe 2006) similar to Lampe (1999) that is

responsive to net trade. Both approaches can be understood as a smooth approximation of the spatial

arbitrage condition. Specifically, the domestic market price smoothly declines from an upper asymptote

reflecting c.i.f. prices plus tariffs to a lower asymptote corresponding to the f.o.b. price when the

country turns from a large net importer to a large net exporter, but with the turning point usually

located at a zero net trade volume.

WEMAC (e.g. Benjamin, Guéguen, Houée 2003, Houée-Bigot 2006) is a partial equilibrium model

that differs from FAPRI and AGMEMOD in its stronger reliance on microeconomic theory and more

rigorous use of econometric techniques (including stationarity tests and use of system methods rather

than OLS). However, in terms of the price linkage it also applies linear price linkage equations for the

intra EU price transmission from the dominant key market to the other Member States represented.

CAPSIM is a partial equilibrium model relying on the same database as CAPRI but on a higher level

of aggregation. It also shares the reliance on calibration techniques, exploiting microeconomic

regularity conditions. The key differences are the simpler specification of the EU supply side

(behavioural functions on the MS level rather than regionalised programming models) as well as

simple gross trade functions for the rest of the world (see section 3.5) rather than a full scale global

21

trade model. However, the last version included an interesting specification of intra EU price

transmission where national producer prices are proportionally linked to EU prices with the scaling

factor being a function of net trade of the MS (Witzke, Tonini 2008, p. 230). This mechanism was

shown to provide a smooth approximation to a switching regime (Witzke, Zintl, Tonini 2009, p. 48-49)

albeit with a quite weak empirical basis.

Trying to summarise the solutions in various modelling systems has to face the problem that many

models use market and region specific specifications, depending on the data. Accordingly, the

empirical content and detail of these individual equations is often impossible to deduct from the general

model description. Bearing this caveat in mind, the following conclusions can be drawn. Overall it

appears that different variants of linear price transmission equations are most frequent. Thus the link

between domestic and world markets is based on some fixed relative and/or additive margin, apart

from trade policy instruments and exchange rates. These margins are either estimated from time series,

calibrated to a base year or chosen to reflect some expert knowledge. They may express transport and

transaction costs under the assumption that the basic trade pattern does not change, but equally they

will capture quality differences between the key price and the domestic one.

4.3. Armington style models for heterogeneous products

As most Computable General Equilibrium models, GTAP treats imported and domestically produced

goods as non-perfect substitutes based on the Armington assumption. Additionally, fob and cif prices

are linked via freight margins, and selling prices of imported goods comprise the effect of tariffs and

taxation. The related equations are linear and based on wedges, and effect of the underlying data base

in values, so that prices are all scaled to unity. Usually price transmission is expressed in terms of the

Armington elasticities that have received particular attention therefore (Section 5.2.1). However, in an

attempt to validate GTAP in terms of the price volatility predicted from the model in stochastic

simulation experiments, Valenzuela et al. (2007) found that a standard short run price transmission

elasticity may also be incorporated on top of the Armington assumption to improve the fit of historical

price volatility in GTAP.

In addition to the Armington assumption on the demand side, each GTAP sector produces outputs

tailored to the domestic market and for exports according to a Constant Elasticity of Transformation

function. In contrast to the MCMs discussed above, no world market or anchor price is present in the

system and all prices for one commodity are indirectly linked by the substitution between import and

domestic sales on the demand side and between domestic sales and exports on the supply side.

22

The market model of CAPRI (Britz & Witzke 2008) differs from all MCMs above as it based on the

Armington assumption. In contrast to GTAP and most CGEs, it does not use a CET function on the

supply side. All prices are expressed in EURO. CIF prices are linked to FOB prices of exporters

(regional market prices net of any export subsidies) with fixed per unit transport costs. Adding ad-

valorem and specific tariffs to CIF prices gives import prices considered by consumers for their

consumption decision making. Ad valorem and specific tariffs can be endogenous variables depending

on TRQs or in case of the EU represent flexible levies ensuring minimal import prices as long as the

bound rate is not reached.

The per unit transport costs in CAPRI had been estimated from time series of per unit export and

import values, and regressed on distances and dummies referring to the exporter and importer country

which can be understood as proxy for port handling costs and similar fixed per unit costs linked to the

origin and destination independent of the transport distance. The raw data are subject to considerable

statistical noise. Trade matrices are available e.g. from FAO which report for each transport flow

importer and exporter notification of values and quantities. Ideally, these notifications should show

identical quantities, so that the derived import and export unit values can be used to estimate average

transport and transaction costs in a given year. However, for a range of reasons such as classification

errors, differences in reporting period and general reporting errors, the exporter and importer

notifications often differ considerably.

In contrast to CGEs, a CAPRI “trade block” featuring the price transmission mechanism described

above can be broken down to several countries or group of countries with their own behavioural

equations. The producer prices of these countries are currently linked with a fixed percentage margin to

the market price of the trade block (for example EU15); a simple specification that will be reconsidered

for CAPRI-RD Deliverable 3.3.2. The percentage margins are determined from the base year producer

prices derived from the Economic Accounts of Agriculture for EU countries. Conceptually, they are

hence unit values, derived from dividing total revenues by production quantities, and do not refer to

clearly defined price notation for a specific quality.

4.3.1. Econometric research and results on Armington parameters

The typical equation to estimate in an Armington model results from the optimality condition of the

consumer to find the optimal mix of imported and domestically produced goods:

r,i

imp,r,i

dom,r,i

dom,r,i

imp,r,i

dom,r,i

imp,r,i

P

P

X

δδ

=

23

In log form, this is a linear equation linking the ratio of imported to domestic quantities of good i in

region r to the reciprocal price ratio with the substitution elasticity as a parameter to be estimated

(example: Gallaway, McDaniel, Rivera 2003, surveys: McDaniel, Balistreri 2003; Sarker, Surry 2006).

Due to the key importance of the Armington elasticities for welfare and other results, such estimates

have been undertaken frequently for particular regions and commodities. Short run Armington

elasticities of Gallaway, McDaniel, Rivera (2003) were usually between 0.5 and 2 for food products

with long run values typically between 1 and 3.

Another approach to estimate the Armington elasticity has been introduced by Warr (2008). In

equilibrium, changes in quantities produced for domestic consumption must be the same on the supply

and demand side (if exports are irrelevant) such that the following equilibrium condition holds for the

percentage price changes (small letters, region index dropped):

( )( ) ( )

( )( ) oo,iimp,iimp,io

i,i

o,iimp,i

dom,ii,iimp,iii,i

ii,iimp,idom,i

dom,iimp,iioo,idom,idom,iimp,iimp,ii,i

dom,iimp,iioo,iii,idom,ii,i

ppppshsh

shp

ppppshpsh

ppppp

φφεη

ησεση

σηη

σηηε

+=+−+

+=

⇔−+++=

−++=

where

pi,dom = domestic price of good i

pi,imp = import price of good i

pi = aggregate price of good i

po = price of other goods o

ηi,j = demand elasticity of aggregate consumption of good i with respect to price j

εi,i = supply elasticity of good i with respect to the own price i

σi = substitution elasticity between domestic and imported quantities of good i

shi,imp = value share of imports in total consumption of good i (shi,dom = 1- shi,imp)

φi,imp = price transmission elasticity from imported to domestic prices

The last expression shows the linkage of the price transmission elasticity to the Armington elasticity in

this simple market model. As expected, the transmission elasticity would approach one as σi grows to

infinity. Warr estimated the price transmission elasticity for rice in Indonesia to be about 0.3-0.4 and

inferred that the Armington elasticity would be around 3, using assumed values for the other elasticities

and shares. Even more direct, Bakhshoodeh (2010) applied the equilibrium condition to data from two

24

household surveys to calculate an Armington elasticity around 4 for rice in Iran. Of course, this

approach suffers from several simplifications such as the absence of any policy measures but the

explicit linkage to the price transmission elasticity is illuminating.

More ambitious attempts to quantify Armington elasticities have been undertaken in the GTAP

network. The first is generalisation of the standard practice to calibrate the model against a set of base

year data by Liu, Arndt, Hertel (2004). They used the Armington parameters to fit the past years 1986,

1989, and 1992, starting from a base year 1995 (GTAP 4 database), in a cross entropy setting and a 10

regions x 10 product setting. The Armington elasticity for agriculture was estimated to be 1.05 which

was at the lower bound of the CE approach.

A study of greater relevance to CAPRI is Hertel et al. (2004). This also relied on econometric

estimation of CES demand functions for imports of particular origins like Gallaway, McDaniel, Rivera

(2003). However, due to the availability of a unique, very disaggregated cross section data set on

transport costs and bilateral tariffs (acknowledging preferential tariffs) this study could circumvent a

typical problem of econometric research. Import demand estimation based on import unit values tends

to give downward biased results due to the neglect of quality variations: Demand and unit values will

be high for high qualities such that the negative impact of price on demand will be underestimated.

Armington elasticities for substitution between imports of different origins (i.e. referring to stage 2 in

the CAPRI market model, see Britz, Witzke, p….) were usually between 3 and 10 for food and

agricultural products. Depending on the product, this is sometimes higher or lower than current values

in CAPRI. A detailed comparison seems worthwhile but not in the context of this survey.

Finally, it should be mentioned that accepting product heterogeneity does not imply to accept the

Armington assumption. Indeed, most empirical analyses testing the Armington assumption in a more

general demand specification distinguishing goods by their origin have rejected its separability

assumptions (e.g. Surry, Herrard, Leroux 2002, Hanrahan, Westhof, Young 2001).

5. Conclusions for CAPRI

While it is clear that the spatial arbitrage model provides the key theoretical foundation to price linkage

modelling, its direct applicability is limited as the product list in CAPRI is more aggregate including

processed quantities of agricultural raw products according to the market balances of Eurostat and FAO.

Hence, it appears that Armington type models have greater relevance for CAPRI including intra EU

trade relationships. However, the computational problems would appear to be insurmountable if the

current set of market regions (28) were simply extended by all individual EU (and potentially Western

25

Balkan) Member States. Therefore this review also covered MCMs base on the assumption of

homogeneous good and related empirical research.

Econometric research on spatial price transmission has become quite sophisticated in terms of

methodology but the findings are quite heterogeneous. Depending on the particular database, items,

regions, and periods selected researchers have found examples for almost any relationship between two

regional prices from close short run and long run integration with a price transmission elasticity or

coefficient approaching one, to complete absence of any relationship or even “wrong” signs. It may be

expected that own estimations will have to face a similar heterogeneity that needs some filtering before

being usable in the model. Furthermore, given the inconclusive and diverse literature on market power,

it is suggested to neglect these complications for the time being.

A review of current simulation systems for agricultural markets showed that most MCMs rely on a

simple price linkage based on a constant or proportional margin, like the current CAPRI model in the

case of intra trade block price transmission. Other and therefore more interesting solutions have been

chosen in the AGMEMOD and CAPSIM models that may also be stimulating for future solutions in

CAPRI.

Directly adopting quantitative parameters for price transmission from other models (or existing

econometric studies) is usually inappropriate for many reasons. A first aspect is the temporal scale of

models. AGLINK/COSIMO, FAPRI, AGMEMOD, WEMAC work in yearly steps and comprise

recursive-dynamic features (ESIM as an option) whereas GTAP and CAPRI are comparative static

models giving results after a longer adjustment period. It can e.g. be assumed that on the short run, per

unit transport and transaction costs can be very high if unusual large amounts are needed to be shipped

and market infrastructure is not yet adapted (see the discussion of Hungary in Commission 2006, p. 18).

Accordingly, the comparative static models should show a somewhat higher price transmission, ideally

increasing with the length or run. Similarly, Liu, Arndt, Hertel (2004) have increased their Armington

elasticities depending on the time horizon of their simulation.

Furthermore, there are important differences between models according to acceptance or rejection of

the Armington assumptions. In the latter, price transmission into domestic market is dampened by the

fact that import shares react to changes in import relative to domestic producer prices and that market

prices are a weighted average of the domestic sales and imports. Where imports shares are small, price

transmission can be extremely low. The implied price transmission is hence rather sensible to the

import shares in the calibration point, and, clearly to the substitution elasticities used. Also, the product

aggregation level must be taken into account – which is however comparable at least between most of

the MCMs mentioned above.

26

A further point refers to the details in capturing domestic and border policies. Price transmission

elasticities or the substitution elasticities used in the CES equations can also be used to capture policy

effects e.g. relating to TRQs, specific tariffs, the use of applied tariffs or domestic policy instruments

stabilizing prices. To the extent that these policies are captured explicitly in the model, such as in

CAPRI, parameters referring to price transmission such as the substitution elasticities should be higher.

A further complication relates to the distinction of unit values and true prices. CAPRI uses unit values

to represent FOB and CIF prices. Unit values define also producer and consumer prices for EU

countries covered by the economic accounts of Eurostat and further national data sets. The movement

of prices is clouded in unit values due to changes in their regional, product and quality composition,

creating statistical problems in empirical analysis but also impeding comparisons with models like

AGLINK, FAPRI, or AGMEMOD which often use price notations at specific locations and for specific

qualities.

Solutions obtained elsewhere may thus provide valuable stimulus in terms of methodology, but

reusability of parameters is mostly limited by numerous differences that often become visibly only

after closer scrutiny.

6. Summary

This deliverable has reviewed the theoretical background, specific econometric research and

specifications for price transmission in other modelling systems with a focus on agriculture to draw

conclusions for future developments of CAPRI. While it is clear that the spatial arbitrage model

provides the key theoretical foundation to price linkage modelling, its direct applicability is limited as

the product list in CAPRI is more aggregate. Hence, it appears that Armington type models have

greater relevance for CAPRI, including intra EU trade relationships. However, the computational

problems would appear to be insurmountable if the current set of market regions (28) were simply

extended by all individual EU (and potentially Western Balkan) Member States. Therefore, this review

covered MCMs based on the assumption of homogeneous good as well as the GTAP model that also

relies on the Armington assumption.

The model comparison and the review of econometric research have yielded a wide variety of

approaches and findings. These results may thus provide valuable stimulus in terms of methodology

but reusability of parameters is mostly limited by numerous differences to CAPRI. These may relate to

the level of temporal aggregation, the product definition, treatment of product heterogeneity, policy

coverage or technical issues like the distinction of unit values and true prices. It is necessary therefore

to proceed to an empirical analysis tailored to the definitions and database of CAPRI.

27

7. References

Abullai, A. (2000) Spatial Price Transmission and Asymmetry in the Ghanaian Maize Market. Journal

of Development Economics, 63 (2): 327-349.

Alexander, C.O., Wyeth, J. (1994) Cointegration and Market Integration: an Application to the

Indonesian Rice Market. Journal of Development Studies, 30 (2): 303-308.

Anania, G. (2010) EU Economic Partnership Agreements and WTO Negotiations. A Quantitative

Assessment of Trade Preference Granting and Erosion in the Banana Market. Food Policy,

35 (2): 140-153 (doi:10.1016/j.foodpol.2009.11.001).

Anania, G., Drogué, S., Paris, Q. (2009) Calibrating Mathematical Programming Spatial Models.

AgFoodTrade Working Paper (http://www. agfoodtrade.eu/).

Ardeni, P.G. (1989) Does the Law of One Price really hold for Commodity Prices? American Journal

of Agricultural Economics, 71 (3): 661-669.

Armington, P. (1969) A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production.

International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, XVI: 159-78..

Banse, M., Grethe, H. (2006) Using the Logistic Functional Form for Modelling International Price

Transmission in Net Trade Simulation Models. Paper presented on the 2006 IAAE Annual Meeting,

August 12-18, Queensland, Australia.

Baffes, J. (1991) Some further Evidence on the Law of One Price: The Law of One Price still holds.

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 73 (4): 1264-1273.

Bakhshoodeh, M. (2010) Impacts of World Prices Transmission to domestic Rice Markets in rural Iran.

Food Policy, 35 (1): 12-19.

Barrett, C. B. (1996) Market analysis: Are our Enriched Toolkits Well Suited to Enlivened Markets?

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 78 (3): 825-829.

Barrett, C. B., Li, J. R. (2002) Distinguishing between Equilibrium and Integration in Spatial Price

Analysis. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 84 (2): 292-307.

28

Bartova, L., M’Barek, R. (eds) (2008) Impact Analysis of CAP Reform on the Main Agricultural

Commodities, Report III, AGMEMOD model description. JRC-IPTS Seville, EUR 22940 EN/3 - 2008.

Baulch, B. (1997) Transfer Costs, spatial Arbitrage, and testing for Food Market Integration.

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 79 (2): 477-487.

Benjamin, C., Guéguen, C., Houée, M. (2003) World Cereals Markets under Alternative Common

Agricultural Policy Reforms. Proceedings of the IAAE International Conference, Durban, South Africa.

Bouamra-Mechemache Z., Chavas, J.P., Cox, T., Réquillart, V. (2002) EU dairy Policy Reform and

future WTO Negotiations: a spatial Equilibrium Analysis. Journal of Agricultural Economics. 53(2): 4-

29.

Bouamra-Mechemache, Z., Requillart, V. (2005) Report on Dairy Policy Simulations, EDIM

Deliverable, D08.05, 31/12/05 (http://edim.vitamib.com/).

Bouamra-Mechemache, Z., Jongeneel, R., Requillart, V. (2008). Impact of a gradual Increase in Milk

Quotas on the EU dairy Sector. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 35 (4): 461–491.

Schmidhuber, J., Britz, W. (2001) The AT2030 model: An Overview. Presentation at the World Outlook

Conference, Stresa, Italy (http://www.agp.uni-bonn.de/agpo/rsrch/at2030/@2030.ppt).

Britz, W., Witzke, P. (eds) (2008) CAPRI Model Documentation 2008: Version 2 (http://www.capri-

model.org/docs/capri_documentation.pdf)..

Brooks, J., Melyukhina, O. (2005) Estimating the Pass-Through of Agricultural Policy Reforms: an

Application to Brazilian Commodity Markets OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Working Papers,

No. 2, OECD Publishing (doi:10.1787/827275354437)..

Cluff, M. (2003) A Review of Spatial Price Transmission in major World Multi-Commodity Models.

Paper for the World Outlook Conference 2003 in Paris, France.

Commission of the European Communities (2006) Prospects for Agricultural Markets and Income

2006 – 2013. Directorate of Agriculture, Brussels, Belgium.

Conforti, P. (2004) Price transmission in selected agricultural Markets. FAO Commodity and Trade

Policy Research Working Paper No. 7 (ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/007/j2730e/j2730e00.pdf)..

29

Cramon-Taubadel, S. v., Loy, J.-P., Musfeldt, E. (1995) Empirische Methoden zur Analyse der

Marktintegration am Beispiel des EU-Schweinefleischmarktes. Schriften der Gesellschaft für

Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften des Landbaus, 31: 119-137.

Dahlgran, R.A., Blank, S.C. (1992) Evaluating the Integration of contiguous discontinuous Markets.

American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74 (2): 469-479.

Fackler, P.L, Goodwin, B.K. (2001) Spatial Price Transmission. In Gardner B. and Rausser, G. (eds)

Handbook of Agricultural Economics, 1: 971-1024. Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, Netherlands.

Fackler, P.L., Tastan, H. (2008) Estimating the Degree of Market Integration. American Journal

Agricultural Ecoomics, 90 (1): 69-85.

Faminow, M., Benson, B. L. (1990) Integration of spatial Markets. American Journal of Agricultural

Economics, 72 (1): 49-62.

FAPRI (2010) International Oilseeds Model, On-line documentation

(http://www.fapri.iastate.edu/models/oilseeds.aspx, 14.12.2010).

Fischer, G., Frohberg, K., Keyzer, M., Parikh, K.S. (1988) Linked National Models: A Tool for

International Food Policy Analysis. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht-Boston-London .

Fousekis, P. (2007) Multiple Markets within the EU? Empirical Evidence from Pork and Poultry

Prices in 14 EU Member Countries. Economics Bulletin, 3 (65): 1-12.

Gallaway, M.P., McDaniel, C.A., Rivera, S.A. (2003) Short-run and long-run industry-level Estimates

of U.S. Armington Elasticities. North American Journal of Economics and Finance 14 (1): 49-68.

Goletti, F., Babu, S. (1994) Market Liberalization and Integration of Maize Markets in Malawi.

Agricultural Economics, 11 (2-3): 311-324.

Goodwin B. K., Grennes T.J., Wohlgenant M.K. (1990) A revised Test of the Law of One Price using

Rational Price Expectations. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 72 (3): 682-693.

Gordon, D.V., Hobbs, J.E., Kerr, W.A. (1993) A Test for Price Integration in the EC Lamb Market.

Journal of Agricultural Economics, 44 (1): 126-134.

Granger, C.W.J. (1969) Investigating causal Relations by econometric Models and cross-spectral

Methods. Econometrica, 37 (3): 424-438.

30

Gupta, S., Mueller, R.A.E. (1982) Analyzing the pricing Efficiency in spatial Markets: Concept and

Application. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 9 (3): 301-312.

Hanrahan, K.F., Westhof, P., Young, R.E. (2001) Trade Allocation Modeling: comparing the Results

from Armington and Locally Regular AI Demand System Specifications of a UK Beef Import Demand

Allocation Model. Paper presented at the AAEA-CAES Annual Meeting, Chicago, Illinois.

Havlík, P., Schneider, U.A., Schmid, E., Böttcher, H., Fritz, S., Skalský, R., Aoki, K., De Cara, S.,

Kindermann, G., Kraxner, F., Leduc, S., McCallum, I., Mosnier, A., Sauer, T., Obersteiner, M. (2010)

Global land-use Implications of first and second Generation biofuel Targets. Energy Policy, article in

press (doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.03.030).

Hertel, T., Hummels, D., Ivanic, M., Keeney, R. (2004) How Confident Can We Be in CGE-Based

Assessments of Free Trade Agreements?, GTAP Working Paper No. 26, Revised Version March 2004,

Purdue..

Houée-Bigot, M. (2006) Modellisation Econometrique des Effets des Instruments de Soutien sur les

Marches Mondiaux des Grandes Cultures. Doctoral Thesis, University of Paris, France.

Hockmann, H., Vönecki, É. (2009) Market Integration and Market Power in the Internal EU Market

for Butter. In: Vaz, T.d.N., Nijkamp, P., Rastoin, J.-L. (eds) Traditional Food Production and Rural

Sustainable Development – A European Challenge: 135-150. Ashgate, Farnham, England.

Koontz, S.R., Garcia, P., Hudson, M.A. (1993) Meatpacker Conduct in Fed Cattle Pricing: An

Investigation of Oligopsony Power. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 75 (3): 537-548.

Koontz, S.R., Garcia, P. (1997) Meat-Packer Conduct in Fed Cattle pricing: Multiple-Market

Oligopsony Power. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 22 (1): 87-103.

Lampe, M.v. (1999) A Modelling Concept for the Long-Term Projection and Simulation of

Agricultural World Market Development – World Agricultural Trade Simulation Model WATSIM.

Doctoral Thesis, Shaker Verlag, Bonn/Aachen, Germany.

Listorti, G., Esposti, R. (2008) Making the World Market Price endogenous within the AGMEMOD

Modelling Framework: an Econometric Solution. Paper at the EAAE Seminar, Sevilla, Spain.

Listorti, G. (2009) Testing international Price Transmission under Policy Intervention. An Application

to the Soft Wheat Market. Universita’ Poitecnica Delle Marche, Italy.

31

Liu, X. (2008) Testing for Signals on oligopolistic Behaviour – Case of Finnish and German Pork

Meat Price. Paper presented at the EAAE Congress, Ghent, Belgium.

Liu, J., Arndt, T.C., Hertel, T.W. (2004) Parameter Estimation and Measures of Goodness of Fit in a

Global General Equilibrium Model. Journal of Economic Integration 19 (3): 626–649.

McCarl, B.A., Spreen, T.H. (1980) Price endogenous mathematical programming as a tool for sector

analysis. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62 (1): 87–102 .

McCorriston, S. (2002) Why should imperfect Competition matter to agricultural Economists?

European Review of Agricultural Economics 29 (3): 349-371.

McDaniel, C. A., Balistreri, E. (2003) A Review of Armington Trade Substitution Elasticities.

Economie Internationale (94-95): 301-314.

Meyer, J., Cramon-Taubadel, S.v. (2004) Asymmetric Price Transmission: a Survey. Journal of

Agricultural Economics, 55 (3): 581-611.

Mundlak, Y., Larson, D.F. (1992) On the Transmission of World Agricultural Prices. World Bank

Economic Review, 6 (3): 399-422.

Nolte, S., Grethe, H., Buysse, J. Van der Straeten, B., Claeys, D., Lauwers, L., Van Huylenbroeck, G.,

(2010) Modelling preferential SugarIimports of the EU: a spatial Price Equilibrium Analysis.

European Review of Agricultural Economics, 37 (2): 165-186.

OECD (2007) Documentation of the AGLINK-COSIMO model. Working Party on Agricultural Policies

and Markets, Directorate for Food, Agriculture and Fisheries, Committee for Agriculture, Organization

for Economic Cooperation and Development, AGR/CA/APM(2006)16/FINAL, 14.5.2007, Paris,

France

(http://www.olis.oecd.org/olis/2006doc.nsf/ENGREFCORPLOOK/NT00009066/$FILE/JT03223642.P

DF).

Peltzman, S. (2000) Prices Rise faster than they fall. Journal of Political Economy, 108 (3): 466-502.

Rapsomanikis, G., Hallam, D., Conforti, P. (2003) Market Integration and Price Transmission in

selected Food and Cash Crop Markets of Developing Countries: Review and Applications. In:

Commodity Market Review 2003 - 2004. FAO, Rome, Italy.

32

Ravaillon, M. (1986) Testing Market Integration. American Journal of Agricultural

Economics, 68 (1): 102-109.

Roningen, V. (1986) A Static World Policy Simulation (SWOPSIM) Modeling Framework. Staff Report

No AGES 860625. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture.

Roningen, V.O., Dixit, P.M. (1991) Documentation of the Static World Policy Simulation, (SWOPSIM)

Modeling Framework. Staff Report No. AGES 9151. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture.

Rutherford, T. F. (1995) Extensions of GAMS for Complementarity Problems arising in Applied

Economic Analysis. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 19 (8): 1299–1324.

Sanjuán, A.I., Gil, J.M. (2001) Price Transmission Analysis: a flexible methodological Approach

applied to European Pork and Lamb Markets. Applied Economics, 33 (1): 123-131.

Sarker, R., Surry, Y. (2006) Product Differentiation and Trade in Agri-Food Products: Taking Stock

and Looking Forward. Invited Paper Presented at the International Agricultural Trade Research

Consortium Annual Meeting, San Diego, California.

Schneider, U., Balkovic, J., De Cara, S., Franklin, O., Fritz, S., Havlík, P., Huck, I., Jantke, K., Kallio,

M, Kraxner, F., Moiseyev, A., Obersteiner, M., Ramos, C.I., Schleupner, C., Schmid, E., Schwab, D.,

Skalsky, R. (2008) The European Forest and Agricultural Sector Optimization Model – EUFASOM,

Paper presented at the EARE Annual Conference, Gothenburg, Sweden.

Schneider, U.A., McCarl, B.A., Schmid, E. (2007) Agricultural Sector Analysis on Greenhouse Gas

Mitigation in US Agriculture and Forestry. Agricultural Systems 94 (2): 128–140..

Serra, T., Gil, J.M. (2006) Local polynomial fitting and spatial Price Relationships: Price

Transmission in EU Pork Markets. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 33 (3): 415-436.

Sexton, R.J., Kling, C.L., Carman, H.F. (1991) Market Integration, Efficiency of Arbitrage, and

imperfect Competition: Methodology and Application to U.S. Celery. American Journal of Agricultural

Economics, 73 (3): 568-580 .

Sharma, R. (2002) The Transmission of World Price Signals: the Concept, Issues and some Evidence

from Asian Cereal Markets. In: Agricultural Trade and Poverty – Making policy Analysis count.

OECD, Paris, France.

33

Sullivan, J. (1990) Price Transmission Elasticities in the Trade Liberalization (TLIB) Database. Staff

Report No AGES-9034. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Agriculture.

Surry, Y., Herrard, N., Leroux, Y. (2002) Modelling Trade in Processed Food Products: An

Econometric Investigation. European Review of Agricultural Economics. 29(1): 1-29.

Takayama, T., Judge, G.G. (1971) Spatial and temporal Price and Allocation Models. NorthHolland,

Amsterdam, Netherlands.

Tyers, R., Anderson, K. (1992) Disarray in World Food Markets: a quantitative Assessment.

Cambridge University Press, England.

Valenzuela, E., Hertel, T., Keeney, R., Reimer, J. (2007) Assessing Global Computable General

Equilibrium Model Validity using Agricultural Price Volatility. The American Journal of Agricultural

Economics, 89 (2): 383 – 397.

Viju, C., Nolan, J., Kerr, W.A. (2006) Common Markets measuring Price Integration in European

agricultural Markets. Review of European and Russian Affairs, 2 (1): 33-56 .

Wang, D., Tomek, W.J. (2007) Commodity Prices and Unit Root Tests. American Journal of

Agricultural Economics, 89 (4): 873-889.

Warr, P. (2008) The Transmission of Import Prices to domestic Prices: an Application to Indonesia.

Applied Economics Letters, 15: 499-503.

Witzke, H.P, Tonini, A. (2008) Milk Quota Expiry Impacts and Sensitivity Analyses using the CAPSIM

model. Agrarwirtschaft, 58: 228-237.

Witzke, H.P., Zintl, A., Tonini, A. (2009) The common agricultural Policy Simulation (CAPSIM)

Model: dairy Reform and Western Balkan Countries Accession Scenarios. JRC Scientific and

Technical Report series: 1-106. Seville, Spain

(http://ipts.jrc.ec.europa.eu/publications/pub.cfm?id=1579).

Wright, B. (2001) Storage and Price Stabilization. In: Gardner, B.L., Rausser, G.C. (eds) Handbook of

Agricultural Economics, 1: 817-861. Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, Netherlands.

Zanias, G.P. (1993) Testing for Integration in European Community agricultural Product Markets.

Journal of Agricultural Economics, 44 (3): 418-427.

34


Recommended