+ All Categories
Home > Documents > WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

Date post: 26-Mar-2022
Category:
Upload: others
View: 3 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
22
CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series Paper No.68 Industry R&D Location 1 – the role of accessibility to university R&D and institutions of higher education Martin Andersson, Urban Gråsjö & Charlie Karlsson May 2006 1 [email protected] , [email protected] , [email protected]
Transcript
Page 1: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series

Paper No.68

Industry R&D Location1 – the role of accessibility to university R&D and

institutions of higher education

Martin Andersson, Urban Gråsjö & Charlie Karlsson

May 2006

1 [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]

Page 2: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

1

INDUSTRY R&D LOCATION

– the role of accessibility to university R&D and institutions of higher education

By

Martin Andersson, Urban Gråsjö & Charlie Karlsson

[email protected], [email protected], [email protected]

Abstract The rapid globalization in recent years has created a radically new competitive situation for the rich industrialized countries. Newly industrialized countries and not least China have be-come more and more successful in penetrating the markets in the rich industrialized countries with increasingly more advanced export products. This has generated a discussion in the rich industrialized countries on how to meet this increased international competition. In some countries demands for various protective measures have been raised while in others the dis-cussion has mainly focused on how to develop a competitive strategy mainly concentrating on making the own products more sophisticated by increasing their knowledge content. This is by no means since the direct product development is controlled to a high extent by multina-tional firms, which to an increasing degree are foreign owned. Governments mainly have to rely on indirect measures, such as increasing the volume of higher education and public, mainly university R&D. This raises the question: how responsive is private industry to these kinds of indirect measures. Against this background, the purpose of this paper is to analyze to what extent that the location and the extent of higher education and university R&D, respec-tively, influence the location and the extent of industry R&D in Sweden using an accessibility approach. After an extensive literature survey, we develop a simple theoretical model for the location of R&D from the perspective of a multinational enterprise. From this theoretical model, we then deduce our empirical model, which we then estimate in the form of a Tobit model using data from Swedish labour market regions and municipalities. We show that the location of industry R&D in Sweden can be partly explained by the intra-municipal accessi-bility to students in higher education, while the accessibility to university R&D turned out to be insignificant. Key-words: industry R&D, university R&D, higher education, region, municipality, location, accessibility, Tobit model, Sweden JEL-Codes: O300, O380, O520, R110, R120, R320

Page 3: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

2

1. Introduction The rapid globalization in recent years has created a radically new competitive situa-tion for the rich industrialized countries. Not least due to the rapid industrial growth in China, they have experienced increased penetration of their domestic markets by products produced in China and other newly industrialized countries2. This increased penetration of imported goods has not been limited to “simple” products such as tex-tile, cloths and shoes. To an increasing degree, the rich industrialized countries have been able to observe an increasing penetration also of more advanced industry prod-ucts such as computers, cars and mobile phones.

The increased import penetration has generated different reactions in different countries. In some countries such as the US, voices have been raised for introducing various protectionist measures. The same has been true within the European Union (EU), which has introduced quotas for China’s export of cloths to EU. Another reac-tion heard, for example, in Sweden is that the rich industrialized countries must in-crease the knowledge content and the degree of sophistication of their products to re-tain their comparative advantages in their export markets and to find new export mar-kets.

How this shall be achieved in practical terms is much more of an open question. Of course, there has been a strong argument for increasing the share of young people going to university as well as for increasing the public R&D investments. However, higher education by itself does not make old products more knowledge intensive or generate new products or processes, nor does public R&D investments to any major extent. Public R&D investments are mainly directed towards basic research.

The upgrading of old products, the generation of new products and the develop-ment and upgrading of processes is the object of industry research mainly controlled by private industry. The possibilities for governments to directly control private R&D is limited in market economies and the options to subsidize private R&D are also lim-ited within e.g. the EU, since such subsidies distort competition. There are, however, indirect measures, such as investments in higher education and public R&D, to influ-ence industry R&D. The question is: how responsive is private industry to these kinds of indirect measures?

The answer to that question is by no means simple. To take Sweden as an exam-ple, we can observe that about 90 percent of all private R&D is controlled by multi-national enterprises (MNEs) and about 40 percent of that is performed by foreign-owned MNEs. Swedish MNEs on the other hand perform almost half of their R&D abroad (Lööf, 2005). Given that a very limited number of MNEs, of which a high share is foreign-owned, control so much of the industry R&D it is an open question to what extent national and regional policies can influence industry R&D in a country or region. MNEs, for instance, optimize their operations at a global scale.

Nevertheless, a possible way in which national and regional policies can affect in-dustry R&D is to make regions attractive as locations for R&D by private firms. In an earlier paper, two of the authors (Karlsson & Andersson, 2005) of this paper studied among other things how the location of industry R&D is influenced by the location of public, i.e. university, R&D. The empirical results pointed in the direction of a posi-

2 China’s share of the EU-market (imports from China as a share of total imports) has, for instance, grown from about 2 % 1990 to 9 % 2003. During the same time period, Chinas share of the US market (defined analogously) grown from 3.2 % to 12.5 %, (see Prasad (ed), 2004, IMF).

Page 4: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

3

tive influence. However, that paper did not consider the possible influence of higher education in terms of students and graduates. A recent study by Faggian & McCann (2006), for instance, shows that migration effects of embodied human capital in stu-dents and graduates is of greater importance than (informal) university-industry spill-overs. This suggests that the effect of students and graduates at institutions of higher education on the location of industry R&D needs to be considered. In view of this, the purpose of this paper is to analyze to what extent that the location and extent of public R&D and higher education, in terms of potential recruitment of graduates, influence the location and the extent of industry R&D in Sweden.

The paper is organized as follows: In Section 2 we discuss some general charac-teristics of innovation processes and their dependence upon knowledge flows, and give an overview of the general spatial conditions for innovation processes, which is followed by an elaboration over the factors determining the location of company R&D in general and its dependence on closeness to university R&D and higher edu-cation, in particular. The data, the models and the econometric techniques used in the empirical analysis is presented in Section 3. Our empirical analysis can be found in Section 4 and our conclusions in Section 5.

2. Innovation Processes, Agglomeration and the Lo-cation of Industry R&D

2.1 Innovation Processes and Knowledge Flows Knowledge and information are critical inputs in innovation processes. However, there is an important distinction. Knowledge is a critical input in innovation proc-esses, which is used to generate new or improved products and/or new production techniques. This knowledge input may come from different sources: (i) scientific knowledge in the form of basic scientific principles, (ii) technological knowledge in the form of technical solution and blueprints, and/or (iii) entrepreneurial knowledge, i.e. knowledge about customer preferences and willingness to pay, market conditions, business concepts and business methods, etc (Karlsson & Johansson, 2006). These types of knowledge can be developed in R&D processes over time and can be ac-cessed through various types of knowledge networks. This explains why firms are ac-tive in many different knowledge networks with many economic actors possessing different types of knowledge (Batten, Kobayashi & Andersson, 1989).

Except for knowledge networks internal to firms, they derive information and knowledge from their participation in external knowledge networks, which in the lit-erature are described as innovation networks or innovation systems. Each firm will normally simultaneously participate in a range of such networks involving customers, suppliers, other firms in the industry, universities, R&D institutes, etc. Sometimes a distinction is made between horizontal and vertical networks (Cox, Mowatt & Prevezer, 2003). Firms can be embedded in horizontal knowledge networks with similar firms and in vertical knowledge networks with supplier and customer firms.

For innovative firms, interaction with the scientific community via specialized knowledge networks is generally considered as crucial. Innovative firms are in par-ticular assumed to be highly dependent upon knowledge generated in nearby research universities. In this paper we are in particular interested in studying the involvement

Page 5: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

4

of innovative firms in knowledge networks involving research universities and insti-tutions of higher education.

2.2 The Spatial Conditions for Innovation Processes It is a common observation that innovations tend to be agglomerated, i.e. to be clus-tered and in particular to clusters in large urban regions. Large urban regions offer proximity advantages, which facilitate information and knowledge flows (Artle, 1959; Vernon, 1962; Glaeser, 1999; Feldman & Audretsch, 1999) and create a proximity-based communication externality (Fujita & Thisse, 2002).

Why do innovations tend to be clustered in large urban regions? What are the proximity and accessibility benefits these regions offer? Already Marshall (1920) identified the exchange of information as an externality leading to the agglomeration of economic actors. In more recent years, Henderson (1974) has used information ex-change in the form of technology spillovers as an explanation for the agglomeration of economic agents across space. Proximity is seen as critical for all the different types and forms of knowledge flows essential in innovation processes (Karlsson & Johans-son, 2006).

Within large functional urban regions3, firms have normally high accessibility to pertinent actors, such as customers, suppliers, research universities and other institu-tions of higher education, R&D institutes, etc. These actors are all important sources for intellectual capital and innovation-relevant information and knowledge. Large functional urban regions also offer greater opportunities for labor mobility, which is an important channel for knowledge transfers and for the maintenance and growth of knowledge capital.4

There has been a steady progression of theoretical frameworks and methods to in-vestigate the influence of spatial factors on innovation processes. These range from general knowledge production functions that embody broad forms of distance-sensi-tive knowledge flows, including tacit as well as formal knowledge inputs, to more precisely specified models of knowledge flows and spillovers including so called lo-calized knowledge spillovers through patents, patent citations and product innovations (Varga, 2002). Studies of localized knowledge spillovers occasionally, although not always, distinguish clearly between pecuniary and technological spillovers, their pub-lic and club good features, and various forms of private intellectual property.

The size of a functional region is critical also to its ability to attract, support and maintain innovative firms. Large functional urban regions offer special advantages to firms by offer many clusters of specific industries as well as a broad range of indus-tries. They combine the specialization advantages of the Marshall-Arrow-Romer type with the diversity advantages advocated by Jacobs (1969). Hence, large functional urban regions offer innovative firms advantages in the form of both network and ag-glomeration externalities, which stimulate knowledge transfers.

Large functional urban regions are also important since they represent an arena at which different geographical scales meet. They represent a nexus between local, re-gional, national and international networks of different kinds including knowledge networks (Lagendijk, 2001).

3 Functional urban regions are delimited by labor and housing market perimeters. 4 One hour’s travel time by car from a given location seems to set the limit for the positive proximity externalities associated with agglomerations (Johansson, Klaesson & Olsson, 2002).

Page 6: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

5

2.3 The Location of Industry R&D There are plenty of evidences in the literature that industry R&D is substantially more concentrated spatially than industry production.5 For example, Kelly & Hageman (1999) show that innovation exhibits strong geographical clustering, independently of the distribution of employment. Sectors locate their R&D not where they are produc-ing but near to where other sectors do their R&D. However, Audretsch & Feldman (1996) found that there are substantial differences across sectors in spatial clustering with some industries, like computers and pharmaceuticals, displaying a higher degree of concentration compared to all manufacturing. Similar conclusions were drawn by Breschi (1999) after an examination of patent data for the period 1978-1991 from the European Patent Office (EPO).

Theoretical arguments concerning localized knowledge flows suggests that knowledge production and innovative activities within a company will tend to be more efficient in agglomerations containing research universities and other R&D per-forming companies, since the access to knowledge flows and potential knowledge externalities is greater. The knowledge production and the innovative activities will be more productive in such agglomerations because there is a high probability that com-panies can access potentially useful external knowledge at a cost that is lower than producing this knowledge internally or of trying to acquire it externally from a geo-graphic distance (Harhoff, 2000). The cost of transferring such knowledge is a func-tion of geographic time distance. This is one of the arguments why R&D agglomera-tions are likely to give rise to localized knowledge externalities (Siegel, Westhead & Wright, 2003). Thus, given the character of knowledge flows, it seems natural to as-sume that the spatial dimension is a key factor explaining the location of R&D activi-ties of companies. The location of R&D activities of companies is influenced by the potential knowledge externalities from knowledge flows from university R&D and R&D in other companies.

There is a rich literature regarding various aspects of the relationship between university R&D and industry R&D and innovation and to a certain extent also about the relationship between higher education and industry R&D and innovation. Some studies focus on the ability of companies to utilize knowledge flows from universities (Cohen & Levinthal, 1989 & 1990; Cockburn & Henderson,1998; Ziedonis, 1999; Lim, 2000). Another strand of literature studies the characteristics of universities that generate knowledge flows of interest for industry R&D and innovation (Henderson, Jaffe & Trajtenberg, 1998; Thursby & Thursby, 2002; Feldman, et al., 2002; Jensen & Thursby, 1998; Di Gregorio & Shane, 2000). A third set of studies analyze the chan-nels through which knowledge flow from universities to industry (Cohen, et al., 1998; Cohen, Nelson & Walsh, 2002; Agrawal & Henderson, 2002; Colyvas, et al., 2002; Shane, 2002). These channels include:

• Personal networks of academic and industry researchers (Liebeskind, et al., 1996; MacPherson, 1998)

5 However, there are authors that claim that R&D-intensive and high-tech industries do not necessarily agglomerate (Devereux, Griffith & Simpson, 1999; Shaver & Flyer (2000), Kalnins & Chung, 2001, Barrios, et al., 2003; Alecke, et al., 2003). In her study of Japanese investments in Europe Mariani (2002) found that R&D tends to locate close to production activities.

Page 7: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

6

• University researchers consulting to industry or serving on company boards • University researchers leaving university to work for industry • Technological spillovers of newly created knowledge from universities to

industry. • Purchases by industry of newly created university knowledge or intellectual

property • Spin-offs of new firms from universities, i.e. academic entrepreneurship

(Slaughter & Lesley, 1997; Stuart & Shane, 2002) • Universities creating incubators, enterprise centers and science parks to im-

prove interaction with industry, and to facilitate university knowledge trans-fers.

• Participation in conferences, seminars and presentations • Flows of fresh graduates at the master and PhD level to industry (Varga,

2000). However, there seems to be fewer studies that explicitly study the influences of uni-versity R&D on companies in general and on company R&D, in particular. The spe-cific and relative role played by each of these different links for the development of industry is not well understood (Karlsson & Manduchi, 2001). Moreover, the actual links between universities and industry in many cases have proved difficult to detect. However, recent studies have shown strong evidence of knowledge transfers and spillover flows, as demonstrated by the joint distributions of university capacity and high technology sectors (Varga, 1997 & 2002).

At a general level research universities have been identified as a location factor of growing importance (Henderson, Jaffe & Trajtenberg, 1995; Zucker & Darby, 1998; Adams, 2002; Hall, Link & Scott, 2003; Zucker & Darby, 2005). It has been sug-gested that regions with strong research universities have better opportunities to at-tract and support innovative firms than regions without such universities. Regionally based science parks can be seen as an institutional set-up to integrate the resources of research universities and innovative firms (Luger & Goldstein, 1991). Also, network type interactions among innovative firms and private and public research institutions seem to be of growing importance (Lundvall, 1992, Ed., Nelson, 1993, Ed., Etzkowitz & Leyersdorff, 2000; Charles, 2003).

Zucker, Darby and Brewer (1998) examine the location decisions of companies relative too the location of star university scientists. Mariani (2002) in a study of Japanese investments in Europe showed that geographical proximity to the local sci-ence base is an important factor for locating only R&D laboratories compared to R&D and production and production only. Agrawal & Cockburn (2002) use data on scien-tific publications and patents as indicators of university R&D and industry R&D and find strong evidences of geographic concentration in both activities at the level of metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) in the US. They also find strong evidences of co-location of upstream and downstream R&D activities. Agrawal & Cockburn (2003) report that high levels of university publishing in metropolitan areas in the United States and Canada tend to be matched by high levels of company patenting in the same technology field and metropolitan area, suggesting co-location of research activities. Other empirical studies suggest a strong correlation between the specializa-tion of the regional R&D infrastructure and the innovative activities conducted by in-dustry (Feldman, 1994 a; Felder, Fier & Nerlingar 1997 a & b; Harhoff, 1997; Nerlin-ger, 1998). These results can be interpreted as indicating that knowledge externalities from the R&D infrastructure can be best used in innovation activities in companies in

Page 8: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

7

the same or closely related scientific and technological field(s). The correlation tends to increase with the complexity of the R&D and innovation activities and the more specific the demand for technological know-how (Feldman, 1994 a; Feldman & Flor-ida, 1994). Results presented by Bade & Nerlinger (2000) indicate strong correlations between the occurrence of new technology-based firms and the proximity to R&D-facilities comprising universities, technical colleges and non-university R&D-insti-tutes as well as private R&D.

Griliches’ ‘knowledge production function approach’ (Griliches, 1979) did not ac-knowledge that knowledgeable persons and knowledge production activities are spread out in geography and at the same time to a high degree concentrated to ag-glomerations. However, the original ‘knowledge production function approach’ has later been modified to also accommodate the spatial dimension (Jaffe, 1989; Audretsch & Feldman, 1994 & 1996; Feldman, 1994a & 1994b). The inputs and out-puts considered in these studies vary from study to study and so does the geographic unit of analysis. With a few exceptions (Henderson, Jaffe & Trajtenberg, 1994; Beise & Stahl, 1999), empirical research suggests that knowledge flows from public science to companies decline with geographical distance.

The input ‘federal research funding’ is related to the output ‘new patents issued’ at the state level in the US study by Jaffe (1989). Acs, Audretsch & Feldman (1992) cor-relate the input ‘university research spending’ with the output ‘new product an-nouncements’. Jaffe, Trajtenberg & Henderson (1993) use the input ‘original patents’ to explain the output ‘patents that cite the original patents’ at the city level in the US. They as well as several other studies (Narin, Hamilton & Olivastro, 1997; Verspagen, 1999; Malo & Geuna, 2000) find that academic papers and university patents are more frequently cited than their equivalents from private companies suggesting that public science outputs are an important knowledge source for inventions in compa-nies. However, this method is not entirely accurate because the cited papers and pat-ents may not have contributed to the invention, since the citation may be included only to build the patent claim. This method also underestimates the value of public R&D since many inventions are not patented (Arundel & Kabla, 1998). Audretsch & Feldman (1996) connect the input ‘local university research funding’ in the US to the output ‘local industry value-added’ at the state level. The input ‘number of local re-search stars’ is associated to the output ‘number of new local biotech firms’ at the level of the economic region in the US by Zucker, Darby & Armstrong (1998). Bran-stetter (2000) links the input ‘scientific publications from the University of California’ to the output ‘patents that cite those papers’ at the state level. The input ‘hours of in-teraction with the MIT professor associated with a particular patented invention’ is used by Agrawal (2002) to estimate the effect on the ‘likelihood or degree of success of commercializing that invention’ and he also evaluates the impact of distance on this effect. Mowery & Ziedonis (2001) find knowledge flows from universities through market transactions to be more geographically localized than those operating through non-market “spillovers”. This indicates that high contact intensity is especially im-portant when knowledge must be specified as a commodity for which property rights are clearly defined. Irrespectively of whether these studies use the production function approach or patent citations they find that knowledge flows from academic research to private companies are highly localized at the regional or state level in the US.

In summary, the abovementioned theoretical arguments and empirical results point in the direction that the location of industry R&D is attracted to locations with high accessibility to universities R&D and students and graduates at institutions of higher education.

Page 9: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

8

2.4 Accessibility and Industry R&D Location across Re-gions

The preceding sections suggest that investments in industry R&D are attracted to lo-cations with high accessibility to university R&D and students and graduates at insti-tutions of higher education. This section illustrates how this kind of accessibility po-tentially affects firms’ evaluation of alternative locations for their R&D investments. Given the discussion in the introduction about the dominating role of multinational national enterprises (MNEs) in industry R&D, it seems natural to take a MNE as an example.

Consider a MNE that is about to choose a location for their R&D investments. Since such a firm operates at a global level, we may conjecture that the MNE’s first decision is which part of the world it should choose. This can be choice among, e.g. Western Europe, Asia or North America, and is likely to depend on which part of the world constitutes the main (or home) market for the MNE. Given the choice of conti-nent, the question is then which country to choose6. Conditional on the choice of Europe, for instance, this involves a choice between Germany, France, Sweden or U.K, etc. Once a country has been chosen, the question is which region to locate in. An MNE certainly evaluates the alternative regions in an economic territory (such as a country) based on a set of pertinent attributes of the regions. A main conjecture here is that accessibility to university R&D and institutions of higher education are two such pertinent attributes of regions.

Against the background above we now consider a MNE that has decided to locate its R&D investments in a country which hosts N ={1,…,n} regions. How is a region’s accessibility to university R&D and institutions of higher education related to the at-tractiveness of the region as regards location of an R&D unit? Here, we employ the basic set-up in Johansson, Klaesson & Olsson (2002) and relate accessibility to the preference structure in random choice theory, which starts from a stochastic specifi-cation of the preference value associated with different alternatives. We start with in-stitutions of higher education in terms of student and graduates.

A R&D unit r located in region Ni ∈ by an MNE faces the set of N alternatives as regards recruitment of graduates from institutions of higher education. The set N denotes the set of regions in the national economy considered. Thus, each alternative pertains to student and graduates at institutions of higher education in a specific re-gion. We might now ask: what determines the preference value of R&D unit r as re-gards potential recruitment of (and collaboration with) graduates in region Nj ∈ ? This preference value, denoted by rijU , is specified as consisting of two parts:

ijrijrij uU ε+= ,, (2.1)

where riju , denotes the deterministically known part and ijε denotes random influence from non-observed factors. riju , is in turn assumed to be a function of (i) the size of the institution of higher education (in terms of graduates), Hj, (ii) the quality differen-tial of the graduates between region i and j, qj, (iii) the wage differential of graduates

6 It should here be recognized that ample evidence suggests that MNE particularly likely to locate their R&D activities to their home country compared to other activities, (Patel & Pavitt, 1995).

Page 10: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

9

(cost differential) in region j and i, (pj – pi), (iv) interaction costs between i and j, cij, and (v) travel time between region i and j, tij. riju , is specified in Equation (2.2):

ijijijijjrij tcppqqHu γβαδ −−−−−+= )()(ln, (2.2) where δ, α, β and γ are parameters. In Equation (2.2) the size of the institution of higher education in region j can be interpreted as the attraction factor in region j.

Assuming that the ijε are i.i.d. and extreme value distributed, the probability that a R&D unit r will hire (or collaborate with) graduates in region j, given that the R&D unit is located in region i, rijP , , is given by7:

{ }

{ }∑ ∈

=Nj

u

u

rijrij

rij

e

eP,

,

, (2.3)

Equation (2.3) is the general expression for the choice probabilities in the multinomial logit (MNL) model, (see e.g. Anderson, de Palma & Thisse, 1992). In Equation (2.3), the numerator is the preference value for graduates from institutions of higher educa-tion in municipality j whereas the denominator is the sum of such preference values.

Now consider the denominator in (2.3) and assume that (i) the quality of the graduates and the wages are equal in all regions and (ii) the monetary travel costs are proportional to the time distance such that ijij tc γ= . Using these assumptions, the de-nominator in (2.3) can be expressed as: { }∑ ∈

−=Nj

tj

Hi

ijeHT λ (2.4)

where )( γβγλ += . The expression in (2.4) gives the sum of the preference values, conditional on a location in region i. Observe that the set of N alternatives is the same in any region in the set N ={1,…,n}. Thus, an R&D unit located in region Ns ∈ faces the same set of alternatives, i.e. alternative regions, as a R&D unit located in Ni ∈ , but the sum of the preference values from that location is different8. Hence, locations where the sum of such preference values is high can thus be interpreted as location with high attractiveness9. H

iT in Equation (2.3) is also a standard measure of accessibility with exponential distance decay. This type of accessibility measure be-longs to the family of accessibility measures that satisfies criteria of consistency and meaningfulness, as has been shown in Weibull (1976). Both the size of the attractor and time distances in (2.4) are arguments in the preference function in (2.2).

An analogous reasoning can be applied to university R&D. Region i’s accessibil-ity to university R&D is thus be expressed as:

{ }∑ ∈

−=Mj

tDRj

Ui

ijeUT λ& (2.5)

7 This condition is derived in several texts, see inter alia Train (1993), Anderson, de Palma & Thisse (1992). 8 i.e. tsj ≠ tij. 9 Compare Ben-Akiva & Lerman (1979).

Page 11: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

10

where DRjU & denotes the size of the investments in university R&D in region j.

A national economy can be divided into functional regions that consist of one or several localities. Such localities are here labeled municipalities. Functional regions are connected to other functional regions by means of economic, knowledge and in-frastructure networks. The same prevails for the different municipalities within a functional region. Moreover, each municipality can also be looked upon as a number of nodes connected by the same type of networks. With reference to such a structure, it is possible to separate between (i) intra-municipal accessibility, (ii) intra-regional accessibility10. Letting R denote the set of municipalities belonging to functional re-gion R, such that NR ⊂ , the different accessibilities can be expressed as (accessibility to H is here taken as an example):

• Intra-municipal => { }iiti

HiM eHT λ−=

• Intra-regional => { }∑ ≠∈

−=jiRj

tj

HiR

ijeHT,

λ

The advantage of this separation is that the effect of each type of accessibility can be estimated directly. The subsequent sections of the paper analyses the relationship between the location of industry R&D and accessibility to university R&D and acces-sibility to students and graduates at institutions of higher education using data at the municipality-level in Sweden.

3. Empirical Model, Variables and Data The empirical model used to assess the relationship between the location of industry R&D and accessibility to university R&D and student enrolment at institutions of higher education, respectively, is presented in Equation (3.1) below, where t refers to 2001 and τ−t to 1995.

...,4,3,2

&,1

&, +++++= −

HtiR

HtiMti

DRti

DRti TTMPII ββββα τ

(3.1) ti

airti

UtiR

UtiM DTT ,,7,6,5... εβββ ++++

The variables in the model are explained in Table 3.1. Industry R&D in municipality i in 2001 is thus explained by: (i) industry R&D in 1995, (ii) market potential of mu-nicipality i in 2001, (iii) intra-municipal and intra-regional accessibility to students enrolled at institutions of higher education in 2001, (iv) intra-municipal and intra-re-gional accessibility to university R&D 2001 and (v) a dummy which takes the value 1 if municipality i belongs to a functional region hosting an international airport. The industry R&D in previous periods is a natural control variable to include. Moreover, the market potential of a municipality can be seen as a ‘catch-all’ variable and is in-deed related to the theoretical discussion in previous sections on the advantages of 10 It is possible to also define a third type of accessibility extra-regional accessibility, (see e.g. Johans-son, Klaesson & Olsson, 2002). However, this accessibility is not considered in the present paper. There is now a set of papers using municipalities as the observational unit, which have used all three types of accessibility. These papers have shown that extra-regional accessibility is insignificant in a large number of alternative settings, (see e.g. Gråsjö, 2005 a & b; Karlsson & Andersson, 2006; Andersson & Gråsjö, 2005)

Page 12: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

11

large regions as locations for R&D. Researchers are in general mobile and are ex-pected, but also required, to participate in various conferences around the world. Be-cause of this, we include a dummy for international airports as an additional control variable. Table 3.1. Description of variables in Equation (3.1).

Variable Description Source

DRtiI &

, Industry R&D in terms of man-years in municipality i 2001. Statistics Sweden (SCB)

DRtiI &

, τ− Industry R&D in terms of man-years in municipality i 1995. Statistics Sweden (SCB)

MPi t

Market potential of municipality i in 2001. Measured as the municipality’s accessibility to population.

Statistics Sweden (SCB)

H Student enrolment at institutions of higher education in 2001. Statistics Sweden (SCB)

U University R&D in terms of man-years in 2001. Statistics Sweden (SCB)

XtiMT ,

Intra-municipal accessibility to variable X in municipality i 2001, based on travel time distances by car*.

Statistics Sweden (SCB) and the Swedish Road Administration (SRA)

XtiRT ,

Intra-regional accessibility to variable X in municipality i 2001, based on travel time distances by car*.

Statistics Sweden (SCB) and the Swedish Road Administration (SRA)

airtiD ,

A dummy which is 1 of municipality i belongs to a functional region hosting an international airport, 0 otherwise.

Statistics Sweden (SCB)

*) X indicates the variable to which accessibility is calculated and is either H or U. The data used in the paper are constructed based on secondary material from Statistics Sweden (SCB). The R&D data originates from SCB and are collected by SCB via questionnaires that are sent out to firms and universities. The R&D data is measured in man-years. One man-year is the amount of work a full-time employee performs during a year. This means that a full-time employee who only spends 50 % of her work on R&D counts as 0.5 man-years. The data on students and graduates at institu-tions of higher education also comes from SCB. These data report the number of stu-dents enrolled at institutions of higher education (i.e. university students and gradu-ates) in different regions in different municipalities in Sweden.

Accessibility is calculated for university R&D and student enrolment at institu-tions of higher education. These calculations are based on a Swedish travel time-dis-tance matrix, which reports the minimum travel time by car: (i) between zones within municipalities and (ii) between municipalities. This matrix is provided by the Swedish Road Administration (SRA). The time distance sensitivity parameter was set to 0.017 in these calculations. This is the sensitivity parameter found by Hugosson & Johans-son (2001) in a study of the spatial extent of business trips across Swedish regions.

In order to provide the reader with a feel for the data of main interest in the paper, descriptive statistics for industry and university R&D and student enrolment at insti-tutions of higher education are presented in Table 3.2. As can be seen from the differ-ence between the mean and median, the data are highly skewed to the right.

Page 13: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

12

Table 3.2. Descriptive statistics for industry and university R&D and student enrolment at institutions of higher education across Swedish municipalities in 2001.

Industry R&D University R&D Student enrolment*

Min 0 0 0

Max 11 912.35 3 452.03 44 578

Mean 171.87 68.94 1 006.89

Median 7.92 0 6

Std. deviation 894.58 380.57 4 135.90

Skewness** 10.45 (0.14)

7.08 (0.14)

7.04 (0.14)

Kurtosis** 123.27 (0.29)

52.31 (0.29)

59.56 (0.28)

No. obs. 286 286 286

Data source: Statistics Sweden (SCB) *) Refers to student enrolment at institutions of higher education.

**) Standard errors presented within brackets.

Figure 3.1 compares the spatial concentration of industry and university R&D and student enrolment at institutions of higher education with population in 2001. Munici-palities where ranked in ascending order according to their share of the total popula-tion. Then, the cumulative percentage of population, industry R&D and university R&D where calculated. As is evident from the figure, industry and university R&D as well as student enrol-ment at institutions of higher education are more concentrated than population. More-over, university R&D and student enrolment show a similar concentration pattern whereas industry R&D is relatively less concentrated in space.

4. The Location of Industry R&D – An Empirical Analysis

Parameter estimated of the variables in Equation (3.1) are presented in Table 3.3. Three models are tested; one including accessibility to both university R&D and stu-dents and graduates and two with each accessibility variable separately. This is so be-cause H

tiMT , and UtiMT , as well as H

tiRT , and UtiRT , are correlated. Such a correlation might

distort the parameter estimates. The standard errors reported in the Table 3.1 are boot-strapped using 1000 replications, which reduces biases from potential heteroscedas-ticity.

Page 14: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

13

0102030405060708090

100

0 50 100 150 200 250

Population University R&DIndustry R&D Student enrolment

Figure 3.1. The spatial concentration of industry and university R&D and student enrolment at institu-

tions of higher education relative to population.

Since the dependent variable is bottom-censored, i.e. cannot be below zero, and several municipalities have zero R&D man-years in the industry, the parameters are estimated using a Tobit model after Tobin (1958). The Tobit model assumes a latent dependent variable, Yi*, that is not directly observed. Yi is however observed and is defined as:

*ii YY = iff cYi >*

(3.1) cYi = iff cYi ≤*

where c denotes the lower bound below which Yi* is censored. Yi* is assumed to be generated by the canonical linear regression model such that:

iii XY εβ += '* (3.2) where denotes Xi a vector of regressors and β a corresponding vector of parameters. The error terms are assumed to be i.i.d, εi ∼N(0,σ2). In our case, the lower bound is zero, c = 0. Neglecting such a lower bound can lead to biased and inconsistent pa-rameter estimates. The estimates reported in the table shows that industry R&D in previous time periods is a good predictor of the R&D in present time periods. The parameter estimate is sig-nificant and positive in all specifications. Likewise, the parameter estimate of the market potential variable comes out as significant and positive. Thus, consistent with previous literature and theory industry R&D seems to be attracted to larger regions. Interestingly, the intra-municipal accessibility to students and graduates at institutes of higher education comes out as positive and significant in the specifications were it is

Cumulative share (%)

Municipalities ranked in ascendingorder according topopulation share

Page 15: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

14

included. Intra-regional accessibility is insignificant. None of the parameter estimates for accessibility to university R&D is significant. This indicates that the main attractor for industry R&D on average is not the university R&D as such, but rather the human capital embodied in students and graduates at institutions of higher education. This cannot, however, be interpreted as that university R&D is unimportant. The supply of students and graduates are certainly large in regions where University R&D is large. Rather, as aforementioned, the results suggest that the main attractor is the supply of students and graduates. Thus, consistent with other recent studies (c.f. Faggian & McCann, 2006), the results indicate that university R&D is mainly accessed indirectly via labor-market transactions. Table 3.3. Tobit estimates of the parameters in Equation (3.1), bootstrapped standard errors (1000 rep-

lications).

Variable Estimates (Tobit model)

Estimates (Tobit model)

Estimates (To-bit model)

Intercept -86.39 (-4.77)

-91.24 (-5.21)

-84.92 (-4.59)

DRtiI &

, τ− 1.06 (0.06)

1.06 (0.05)

1.10 (0.06)

MPi t 0.0001 (0.00)

0.0001 (0.00)

0.0001 (0.00)

HtiMT , 0.02

(0.01) 0.03

(0.01) -

HtiRT , n.s. n.s. -

UtiMT , n.s. - n.s.

UtiRT , n.s. - n.s.

airtiD , n.s. n.s. n.s.

Pseudo R2 0.27 0.27 0.26

# censored obs. 106 106 106

# obs. 286 286 286 *) only parameter estimates significant at the 0.05 level are shown in the table, (n.s denotes insignifi-

cance at the 0-05 level). **) bootstrapped standard errors presented within brackets.

5. Conclusions The endeavor in this paper has been to analyze how the location of industry R&D is related to accessibility to students and graduates at institutions of higher education and university R&D. Two types of accessibilities were considered in the paper: (i) intra-municipal accessibility and intra-regional accessibility.

By relating the location of industry R&D across Swedish municipalities to a set of municipal characteristics, including intra-municipal and intra-regional accessibility to

Page 16: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

15

university R&D and students and graduates at institutions of higher education, it is shown that the location of industry R&D can be related to accessibility to students and graduates at institutions of higher education. However, we find no significance as re-gards accessibility to university R&D. This indicates that the main attractor for indus-try R&D on average is not the university R&D as such, but rather the human capital embodied in students and graduates at institutions of higher education. However, this is not interpreted as that university R&D is unimportant. The supply of students and graduates are certainly large in regions where University R&D is large. Rather, as aforementioned, the results suggest that the main attractor is the supply of students and graduates. Thus, consistent with other recent studies (c.f. Faggian & McCann, 2006), the results indicate that university R&D is mainly accessed indirectly via labor-market transactions.

The methodology applied in the paper, however, does admittedly not allow for causative interpretations. An avenue for further research is therefore to use method-ologies that allow for causative interpretations. Moreover, the paper has used aggre-gate R&D data across industries. Controlling for heterogeneity across industries re-quires disaggregate R&D data and is a further topic for additional research.

Page 17: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

16

References Acs, Z.J., D.B. Audretsch & M.P. Feldman (1992), Real Effects of Academic Re-

search, American Economic Review 82, 363-367 Adams, J.D. (2002), Comparative Localization of Academic and Industrial Spillovers,

Journal of Economic Geography 2, 253-278 Agrawal, A. (2002), Technology Acquisition Strategy for Early-Stage Innovations:

Measuring the Importance of Engaging the Inventor, Queen’s University (mimeo)

Agrawal, A & I.M. Cockburn (2002), University Research, Industrial R&D and the Anchor Tenant Hypothesis, NBER Working paper 9212, Cambridge, MA

Agrawal, A & I.M. Cockburn (2003), The Anchor Tenant Hypothesis: Exploring the Role of Large, Local, R&D Intensive Firms in Regional Innovation Systems, International Journal of Industrial Organisation 21, 1227-1253

Agrawal, A & R. Henderson (2002), Putting Patents in Context: Exploring Knowl-edge Transfer from MIT, Management Science 48, 44-60

Alecke, B., et al. (2003), New Empirical Evidence on the Geographic Concentration of German Industries: Do High-Tech Clusters Really Matter?, The Annals of Regional Science (forthcoming)

Anderson, S.P, A. de Palma & J-F. Thisse (1992), Discrete Choice Theory of Product Differentiation, The MIT Press, Cambridge

Andersson, M. & U. Gråsjö (2005), On the Specification of Regression Models with Spatial Dependence – An Application of the Accessibility Concept, CESIS Working Paper 51, Centre for Science and Innovation Studies, KTH/JIBS, Stockholm/Jönköping

Andersson, M. & C. Karlsson (2004), The Role of Accessibility for Regional Innova-tion Systems, in Karlsson, Flensburg & Hörte (2004) (Eds.), 283-310

Andersson, Å.E., D.F. Batten and C. Karlsson (1989) (Eds.), Knowledge and Indus-trial Organisation, Berlin; Springer-Verlag

Archibugi, D. & B.-Å. Lundvall (2001) (Eds.), The Globalising Learning Economy, Oxford; Oxford University Press

Artle, R. (1959), The Structure of the Stockholm Economy – Toward a Framework for Projecting Metropolitan Community Development, Stockholm; Stockholm School of Economics

Arundel. A. & I. Kabla (1998), What Percentage of Innovations are Patented? Empiri-cal Estimates for European Firms, Research Policy 27, 127-141

Audretsch, D.B, & M. Feldman (1994), Knowledge Spillovers and the Geography of Innovation and Production, Discussion Paper 953, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London

Audretsch, D.B, & M. Feldman (1996), R&D Spillovers and the Geography of Inno-vation and Production, The American Economic Review 86, 630-640

Bade, F.-J. & E.A. Nerlinger (2000), The Spatial Distribution of New Technology-Based Firms: Empirical Results for West-Germany, Papers of Regional Science 79, 155-176

Barrios, S., et al. (2003), Agglomeration Economies and the Location of Industries: A Comparison of Three Small European Countries, CORE Discussion paper, 2003-67

Page 18: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

17

Batten, D.F., J. Casti & R. Thord (1995) (Eds.), Networks in Action. Communication, Economics and Human Knowledge, Berlin; Springer-Verlag

Batten, D.F., K. Kobayashi & Å.E. Andersson (1989), Knowledge, Nodes and Net-works: An Analytical Perspective, in Andersson, Batten & Karlsson (1989) (Eds.), 31-46

Beise, M. & H. Stahl (1999), Public Research and Industrial Innovation in Germany, Research Policy 28, 397-422

Ben-Akiva, M & S. Lerman (1979), “Disaggregate Travel and Mobility Choice Mod-els and Measures of Accessibility”, in Henscher, D.A & P.R Stopher (Eds.), Be-havioral Travel Modelling, Croon Helm, London: pp. 654-679

Bingham, R. & R. Mier (1997) (Eds.), Dilemmas of Urban Economic Development. Issues in Theory and Practice, Sage Publications, London

Branstetter, L. (2000), Measuring the Link Between Academic Science and industrial Innovation: The Case of California’s Research Universities, Paper presented at the NBER Summer Institute

Breschi, S. (1999), Spatial Patterns of Innovation: Evidence from Patent Data, in Gambardella & Malerba (1999) (Eds.), 71-102

Chandler, A., P. Hagström & Ö. Sölvell (1998) (Eds.), The Dynamic Firm, New York, Oxford University Press

Charles, D. (2003), Universities and Territorial Development: Reshaping the Regional Role of UK Universities, Local Economy 18, 7-20

Cockburn, I. & R. Henderson (1998), Absorptive Capacity, Coauthoring Behaviour and the Organisation of Research in Drug Discovery, Journal of Industrial Eco-nomics XLVI, 157-182

Cohen, D.W., et al. (1998), Industry and the Academy: Uneasy Partners in the Cause of Technological Advance, in Noll R.G., (1998) (Eds.) Challenges to Research Universities, Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution Press: pp.171-199

Cohen, D.W. & D.A. Levinthal (1989), Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of R&D, The Economic Journal 99, 569-596

Cohen, D.W. & D.A. Levinthal (1990), Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and Innovation, Administrative Science Quarterly 35, 128-152

Cohen, D.W., R.R. Nelson & J. Walsh (2002), Links and Impacts: The Influence of Public Research on Industrial R&D, Management Science 48, 1-23

Colyvas, J., e al., (2002), How Do University Inventions Go Into Practice?, Manage-ment Science 48, 61-72

Cox, H., S. Mowatt & M. Prevezar (2003), New Product Development and Product Supply within a Network Setting: The Chilled Ready-Meal Industry in the UK, Industry and Innovation 10, 197-217

Devereux, M.P., R. Griffith & H. Simpson (1999), The Geographic Distribution of Production Activity in the UK, IFS Working Paper W99/26, Institute for Fiscal Studies

Di Gregorio & S. Shane (2000), Why Do Some Universities Generate More Spill-overs than Others?. University of Maryland (mimeo)

Etzkowitz, H. & L. Leyersdorff (2000), The Dynamics of Innovation: From National Systems and “Mode 2” to a Triple Helix of University-industry-government Relations, Research Policy 29, 109-123

Faggian, A & McCann P. (2006) Human Capital and Regional Knowledge Assets: a Simultaneous Equation Model, Oxford Economic Papers (forthcoming)

Page 19: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

18

Felder, J., A. Fier & E. Nerlinger (1997 a), High Tech in den neuen Ländern: Unter-nehmensgründungen und Standorte, Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsgeographie 41, 1-17

Felder, J., A. Fier & E. Nerlinger (1997 b), Im Osten nichts Neues? Unternehmens-gründungen in High-Tech Industrien, in Harhoff, (1997) (Hrsg) 73-100

Feldman, M. (1994a), The Geography of Innovation, Kluwer, Dordrecht Feldman, M. (1994b), Knowledge Complementarity and Innovation, Small Business

Economics 6, 363-372 Feldman, M., et al. (2002), Equity and the Technology Transfer Strategies of Ameri-

can Research Universities, Management Science 48, 105-121 Feldman, M. & D. Audretsch (1999), Innovation in Cities: Science-Based Diversity,

Specialisation and Localised Competition, European Economic Review 43, 409-429

Feldman, M.P. & R. Florida (1994), The Geographic Sources of Innovation: Techno-logical Infrastructure and Product Innovation in the United States, Annals of the Association of American Geographers 84, 210-229

Fischer, M.M. & J. Fröhlich (2001) (Eds.), Knowledge, Complexity and Innovation Systems, Berlin; Springer-Verlag

Fujita, M. & J.-F., Thisse (2002), Economics of Agglomeration – Cities, Industrial Location and Regional Growth, Cambridge; Cambridge University Press

Gambardella, A. & F. Malerba (1999) (Eds.), The Organisation of Innovative Activity in Europe, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press

Glaeser, E. (1999), Learning in Cities, Journal of Urban Economics 46, 254-277 Gordon, I.R. & P. McCann (2000), Industrial Clusters: Complexes, Agglomeration

and/or Social Networks, Urban Studies 37, 513-532 Griliches, Z. (1979), Issues in Assessing the Contribution of Research and Develop-

ment to Productivity Growth, Bell Journal of Economics 10, 92-116 Gråsjö, U. (2005a),Accessibility to R&D and Patent Production, An Application of

the Accessibility Concept, CESIS Working Paper 37, Centre for Science and In-novation Studies, KTH/JIBS, Stockholm/Jönköping

Gråsjö, U. (2005b), Human Capital, R&D, and Regional Export Performance, An Ap-plication of the Accessibility Concept, CESIS Working Paper 50, Centre for Science and Innovation Studies, KTH/JIBS, Stockholm/Jönköping

Hall, B.H., A.N., Link & J.T. Scott (2000), Universities as Research Partners, NBER Working Paper 7643

Harhoff, D. (1997), Innovation in German Manufacturing Enterprises: Empirical Studies on Productivity, Externalities, Corporate Finance, and Tax Policy, Ha-bilitationsschrift, Universität Mannheim

Harhoff, D. (1997) (Hrsg), Unternehmensgründungen – Empirische Analysen für die alten and neuen Bundesländer, Vol. 7, Baden-Baden

Harhoff, D. (2000), R&D Spillovers, Technological Proximity, and Productivity Growth – Evidence from German Panel Data, Schmalenbach Business Review 52, 238-260

Henderson, J.V. (1974), The Size and Type of Cities, American Economic Review 89, 650-656

Henderson, R.M., A. Jaffe & M. Trajtenberg (1994), Numbers Up, Quality Down? Trends in University Patenting 1965-1992, Presentation to CEPR/AAAS Con-ference University Goals, Institutional Mechanisms and the Industrial Transfer-ability of Research, Stanford University, March 18-20

Page 20: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

19

Henderson, R.M., A. Jaffe & M. Trajtenberg (1995), Universities as a Source of Commercial Technology: A Detailed Analysis of Univeristy Patenting 1965-1988, NBER WP 5068

Henderson, R.M., A. Jaffe & M. Trajtenberg (1998), Universities as a Source of Commercial Technology: A Detailed Analysis of University Patenting, 1965-1988, Review of Economic sand Statistics 80, 119-127

Hugosson, P. (2001) Interregional business travel and the economics of business in-teraction, JIBS Dissertation Series No. 009, Jönköping

Hugosson, P. & B. Johansson (2001), “Business trips between functional regions”, in Hugosson, P. (2001)

Jacobs, J. (1969), The Economy of Cities, New York; Vintage Jaffe, A.B. (1989), Real Effects of Academic Research, American Economic Review

79, 957-970 Jaffe, A.B., M. Trajtenberg & R. Henderson (1993), Geographic Localisation of

Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations, Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 577-598

Jensen, R. & M. Thursby (1998), Proofs and Prototypes for Sale: The Tale of Univer-sity Licensing, NBER Working Paper No. 6698, Cambridge, MA

Johansson, B., C. Karlsson & L. Westin (1994) (Eds.), Patterns of a Network Econ-omy, Berlin; Springer-Verlag

Johansson, B., J. Klaesson & M. Olsson (2002), Time Distances and Labor Market Integration, Papers in Regional Science 81, 305-327

Kalnins, A. & W. Chung (2001), Firm Heterogeneity, Market Heterogeneity and Ag-glomeration, Strategic Management Journal (forthcoming)

Karlsson, C. & Andersson, M. (2005, The Location of University R&D and the Loca-tion of Company R&D – How Are They Related? CESIS Working Paper 38, Centre for Science and Innovation Studies, KTH/JIBS, Stockholm/Jönköping

Karlsson, C., P. Flensburg & S.-Å. Hörte (2004) (Eds.), Knowledge Spillovers and Knowledge Management, Cheltenham; Edward Elgar

Karlsson, C. & B. Johansson (2006) Towards a Dynamic Theory for the Spatial Knowledge Economy, in Johansson, B., C. Karlsson & R.R. Stough (2006) (Eds.), Entrepreneurship and Dynamics in the Knowledge Economy, Routledge, London & New York (Forthcoming)

Karlsson, C. & A. Manduchi (2001), Knowledge Spillovers in a Spatial Context – A Critical Review and Assessment, in Fischer & Fröhlich (2001) (Eds.), 101-123

Kelly, M. & A. Hageman (1999), Marshallian Externalities in Innovation, Journal of Economic Growth 4, 39-54

Lagendijk, A. (2001), Scaling Knowledge Production: How Significant is the Re-gion?, in Fischer & Frölich (2001) (Eds.), 79-100

Landau, R. (1986) (Ed.), The Positive Sum Strategy, Washington, D.C., National Academic Press

Liebeskind, J., et al. (1996), Social Networks, Learning and Flexibility: Sourcing Sci-entific Knowledge in new Biotechnology Firms, Organizational Science 7, 428-443

Lim, K. (2000), The Many Faces of Absorptive Capacity: Spillovers of Copper Inter-connect Technology for Semiconductor Chips, MIT (mimeo)

Luger, M. & H. Goldstein (1991), Technology in the Garden: Research Parks and Regional Development, Chapel Hill; University of North Carolina Press

Luger, M. & H. Goldstein (1997), What is the Role of Public Universities in Regional Economic Development? In Bingham & Mier (1997) (Eds.),104-134

Page 21: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

20

Lundvall, B.-Å. (1992) (Ed.), National Systems of Innovation, London, Pinter Lööf, H. (2005), Den växande utlandskontrollen av ekonomierna i Norden. Effekter

på FoU, innovation och produktivitet, ITPS A 2005:005 MacPherson, A.D. (1998), Academic-industry Linkages and Small Firm Innovation:

Evidence from the Scientific Instruments Sector, Entrepreneurship and Re-gional Development 10, 261-276

Malo, S. & A. Geuna (2000), Science-Technology Linkages in an Emerging Research Plattform: The Case of Combinatorial Chemistry and Biology, Scientometrics 47, 303-321

Mariani, M. (2002), Next to Production or to Technological Clusters? The Economics and Management of R&D Location, Journal of Management and Governance 6, 131-152

Marshall, A. (1920), Principles of Economics, 8th edition, London; Macmillan Mowery, D.C. & A.A. Ziedonis (2001), The Geographic Reach of Market and Non-

Market Channels of Technology Transfer: Comparing Citations and Licences of University Patents, NBER Working Paper No. 8568

Narin, F., K.S. Hamilton & D. Olivastro (1997), The Increasing Linkage between U.S. Technology and Public Science, Research Policy 26, 317-320

Nelson, R.R. (1986), Institutions Supporting Technical Advance in Industry, Ameri-can Economic Review 76, 186-189

Nelson, R.R. (1993) (Ed.), National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Study, New York, Oxford University Press

Nelson R.R. & Winter S.G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge Mass., Harvard University Press

Nerlinger, E. (1998), Standorte und Entwicklung junger innovativer Unternehmen: Empirische Ergebnisse für West-Deutschland, ZEW-Schriftenreihe 27, Baden-Baden

Noll, R. (1998), Challenges to the Research University, Brookings Institution, Wash-ington, D.C.

Patel, P. & Pavitt, K. (1995), “Patterns of Technological Activity: Their Measurement and Interpretation,” in Paul Stoneman (ed), Handbook of the Economics of Inno-vation and Technological Change, Oxford: Blackwell.

Prasad, E. (ed) (2004), China’s growth and integration into the world economy: pros-pects and challenges, IMF Occasional Paper No 232, Washington DC

Shane, S. (2002), Selling University Technology: Patterns from MIT, Management Science 48, 122-137

Shaver, J.M. & F. Flyer (2000), Agglomeration Economies, Firm Heterogeneity, and Foreign Direct Investments in the United States, Strategic Management Journal 21, 1175-1193

Siegel, D.S., P. Westhead & M. Wright (2003), Assessing the Impact of University Science Parks on Research Productivity: Exploratory Firm-Level Evidence from the United Kingdom, International Journal of Industrial Organisation 21, 1357-1369

Slaughter & Leslie (1997) Stuart, T.E. & S. Shane (2002), Organisational Endowments and the Performance of

University Start-ups, Management Science 48, 151-170 Sörensen, C. (1997) (Ed.), Empirical Evidence of Regional Growth: The Centre-Pe-

riphery Discussion, The Expert Committee of the Danish Ministry of the Inte-rior, Copenhagen

Page 22: WP68 Andersson, Gråsjö, Karlsson

21

Thursby, J. & M. Thursby (2002), Who Is Selling the Ivory Tower? Sources of Growth in University Licensing, Management Science 48, 90-104

Tobin, J. (1958), “Estimations of Relationships for Limited Dependent Variables”, Econometrica, 26, 24-36

Train, K. (1993), Qualitative Choice Analysis – theory, econometrics and an applica-tion to automobile demand, MIT Press, Massachusetts

Varga, A. (1997), University Research and Regional Innovation: A Spatial Economet-ric Analysis of Technology Transfers, Boston; Kluwer Academic Publishers

Varga, A. (2000), Local Academic Knowledge Transfers and the Concentration of Economic Activity, Journal of Regional Science 40, 289-309

Varga, A. (2002), Knowledge Transfers from Universities and the Regional Economy: A Review of the Literature, in Varga & Szerb (2002) (eds.), 147-171

Varga, A. & Szerb (2002) (eds.), Vernon, R. (1962), Metropolis 1985, Cambridge, MA; Harvard University Press Verspagen, B. (1999), Large Firms and Knowledge Flows in the Dutch R&D System:

A Case Study of Philips Electronics, Technology Analysis & Strategic Manage-ment 11, 211-233

Weibull, J. (1976), An Axiomatic Approach to the Measurement of Accessibility, Re-gional Science and Urban Economics 6, 357-379

Ziedonis, A. (1999), Inward Technology Transfer by Firms: The Case of University Technology Licences, University of California, Berkeley (mimeo)

Zucker, L.G. & M.R. Darby (1998), Capturing Technological Opportunity via Japan’s Star Scientists: Evidence from Japanese Firm’s Biotech Patents and Products, NBER Working Paper 6360

Zucker, L.G. & M.R. Darby (2005), Socio-eonomic Impact of Nanoscale Science: Initial Results and NanoBank, NBER Working Paper 11181

Zucker, L., M. Darby & J. Armstrong (1998), Intellectual Capital and the Birth of U.S. Biotechnology Enterprises, American Economic Review 88, 290-306


Recommended