+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a...

Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a...

Date post: 29-Jun-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
12
379 Advances in Production Engineering & Management ISSN 1854‐6250 Volume 14 | Number 3 | September 2019 | pp 379–390 Journal home: apem‐journal.org https://doi.org/10.14743/apem2019.3.335 Original scientific paper Optimal timing of price change with strategic customers under demand uncertainty: A real option approach Lee, Y. a , Lee, J.P. b , Kim, S. b,* a Department of Mechanical Engineering, University of Texas at San Antonio, San Antonio, United States of America (USA) b College of Business Administration, Hongik University, Seoul, South Korea ABSTRACT ARTICLE INFO This paper proposes a model to determine the optimal markdown timing for a company with strategic customer purchasing behaviour. Since strategic cus‐ tomers are aware of potential markdown under the posted pricing scheme, they may choose to wait longer to maximise their utilisation instead of buying a product and fulfilling an instant surplus. On the other hand, the seller can delay the markdown decision until it is proved to be profitable and hence has an option to determine the timing. In estimating the value of the markdown decision, the seller’s option needs to be estimated. However, the value of the option is hard to be captured by the conventional net present value analysis. Under market uncertainty where potential customer demand evolves over time, the seller’s revenue function is in the form of a stochastic dynamic pro‐ gramming model. Applying a real option approach, we investigate the optimal price path and propose the optimal markdown threshold. Given the mark‐ down costs incurred, we find that the optimal discount timing for the firm is determined by a threshold policy. Furthermore, our results show that if future market becomes more uncertain, the seller needs to wait longer or delay the markdown decision. In addition, the optimal threshold of the markdown decreases exponentially in a declining market, which explains the early mark‐ down policy of some consumer product companies. Β© 2019 CPE, University of Maribor. All rights reserved. Keywords: Strategic customers; Price change; Posted pricing; Markdown; Demand uncertainty; Real option *Corresponding author: [email protected] (Kim, S.) Article history: Received 28 February 2019 Revised 10 September 2019 Accepted 12 September 2019 1. Introduction Demand management becomes the basis for the decision making of the firms; from production planning to inventory management [1, 20]. Pricing policies are frequently used tools when firms manage their demand [20]. The pricing policies of a firm are often complex and diverse depend‐ ing on the business environment in which the company lies [1, 5, 6, 14, 20]. In the fashion indus‐ try, for instance, simple markdown pricing is widely used to sell out remaining stock after the regular sales season [21]. Some customers may choose to wait and purchase the product later at the markdown price rather than buying it right away. On the other hand, airline companies con‐ tinuously mark up the prices of tickets upon departure. When looking for an airline ticket, cus‐ tomers can expect an increase in prices if they delay their purchase. Therefore, understanding customer purchasing behaviour is critical for the firm to make pricing decisions. Strategic customers in the operations management literature are defined as those who are aware of the firm's dynamic pricing policies and make inter‐temporal purchasing decisions [20]. Since such customers are conscious of potential changes in prices at a later point in time, they are being strategic rather than myopic. Instead of buying a product and fulfilling an instant sur‐
Transcript
Page 1: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

 

 

 

   

379 

AdvancesinProductionEngineering&Management ISSN1854‐6250

Volume14|Number3|September2019|pp379–390 Journalhome:apem‐journal.org

https://doi.org/10.14743/apem2019.3.335 Originalscientificpaper

  

Optimal timing of price change with strategic customers under demand uncertainty: A real option approach

Lee, Y.a, Lee, J.P.b, Kim, S.b,*  aDepartment of Mechanical Engineering, University of Texas at San Antonio, San Antonio, United States of America (USA) bCollege of Business Administration, Hongik University, Seoul, South Korea   

A B S T R A C T   A R T I C L E   I N F O

Thispaperproposesamodeltodeterminetheoptimalmarkdowntimingforacompanywithstrategiccustomerpurchasingbehaviour. Since strategic cus‐tomers are aware of potentialmarkdownunder the posted pricing scheme,theymaychoosetowaitlongertomaximisetheirutilisationinsteadofbuyingaproductand fulfillingan instant surplus.On theotherhand, thesellercandelaythemarkdowndecisionuntilitisprovedtobeprofitableandhencehasanoptiontodeterminethetiming. Inestimatingthevalueof themarkdowndecision,theseller’soptionneedstobeestimated.However,thevalueoftheoptionishardtobecapturedbytheconventionalnetpresentvalueanalysis.Under market uncertainty where potential customer demand evolves overtime,theseller’srevenuefunctionisintheformofastochasticdynamicpro‐grammingmodel.Applyingarealoptionapproach,weinvestigatetheoptimalprice path and propose the optimal markdown threshold. Given the mark‐downcostsincurred,wefindthattheoptimaldiscounttimingforthefirmisdeterminedbyathresholdpolicy.Furthermore,ourresultsshowthatiffuturemarketbecomesmoreuncertain,thesellerneedstowaitlongerordelaythemarkdown decision. In addition, the optimal threshold of the markdowndecreasesexponentiallyinadecliningmarket,whichexplainstheearlymark‐downpolicyofsomeconsumerproductcompanies.

Β©2019CPE,UniversityofMaribor.Allrightsreserved.

  Keywords:Strategiccustomers;Pricechange;Postedpricing;Markdown;Demanduncertainty;Realoption

*Correspondingauthor:[email protected](Kim,S.)

Articlehistory:Received28February2019Revised10September2019Accepted12September2019

  

1. Introduction 

Demandmanagementbecomesthebasisforthedecisionmakingofthefirms;fromproductionplanningtoinventorymanagement[1,20].Pricingpoliciesarefrequentlyusedtoolswhenfirmsmanagetheirdemand[20].Thepricingpoliciesofafirmareoftencomplexanddiversedepend‐ingonthebusinessenvironmentinwhichthecompanylies[1,5,6,14,20].Inthefashionindus‐try, for instance,simplemarkdownpricing iswidelyusedtoselloutremainingstockaftertheregularsalesseason[21].Somecustomersmaychoosetowaitandpurchasetheproductlateratthemarkdownpriceratherthanbuyingitrightaway.Ontheotherhand,airlinecompaniescon‐tinuouslymarkupthepricesofticketsupondeparture.Whenlookingforanairlineticket,cus‐tomerscanexpectan increase inprices if theydelaytheirpurchase.Therefore,understandingcustomerpurchasingbehaviouriscriticalforthefirmtomakepricingdecisions.

Strategic customers in theoperationsmanagement literature aredefined as thosewhoareawareofthefirm'sdynamicpricingpoliciesandmakeinter‐temporalpurchasingdecisions[20].Sincesuchcustomersareconsciousofpotentialchangesinpricesatalaterpointintime,theyarebeingstrategicratherthanmyopic.Insteadofbuyingaproductandfulfillinganinstantsur‐

Page 2: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Lee, Lee, Kim  

380  Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019

plus, they strategicallywait for a future pricemarkdown and thereby seek tomaximise theirutilisation[5,6,18].Assuch,strategiccustomershavebecomeasubstituteformyopiccustom‐erswhosimplymakeabuyingdecisionifthepriceislowerthantheirvaluation[5,6,20].There‐fore, firmsmustcomprehendthestrategicbehaviourofcustomersandfindanoptimalpricingschemebasedonittomaximiserevenue.

Inresponsetothestrategicbehaviourofcustomers, the firm'sdecisionsaregenerallytwo‐fold:thetimingofpricechangesandtheavailabilityoftheproduct[3,20].Thefirmsellsaprod‐uctforadurationoftime,afterwhichitmaydecidetochangethepriceatacertainpointintime.Limited supply could also be used as a marketing strategy to increase the sense of urgencyamongcustomers.Therefore,customersinthemarketchooseeithertopurchaseaproductatitscurrentpriceor to revisit it after theprice goesdown, consideringnotonly the timingof themarkdownbutalsothepossibilityofsellouts.

Inthispaper,weinvestigatethemarkdowndecisionofamonopolistwhowishestomaximiseexpectedrevenuesinthepresenceofstrategiccustomers.Ourmodelcapturesseveralimportantpropertiesofthemarketenvironmentforconsumerproducts.First,thesellercommitstoafixedpath of two prices: itmay sell a product for a duration of time, afterwhich itmay decide tochangetheprice.Themarkdowndecisioncanbemadenomorethanonceoverthesaleshorizonand is hence irreversible. Second, customers show strategic purchasing behaviour towardsfirms:evenifthevaluationoftheproductexceedsthepriceoftheproductduringthefirstpartofthesaleshorizon,customersmaynotsimplypurchaseit.Instead,theirdecisiontopurchaseisbasedonthevaluationthatexceedsacertainlevel,thusfollowingathresholdpolicy.Third,po‐tentialcustomerdemandisstochastic.Inparticular,themarketsizefollowsageometricBrown‐ianmotionthatevolvesdynamicallyovertime.

Weconsideraseller'sproblemondecidingtheoptimalpricepathandthetimingofamark‐down under demand uncertainty. Specifically,we present a stochastic dynamic programmingmodelwherethesellerhasasingleopportunity todiscountthepriceof theproductatasunkcost.Customersinthemarketareawareofapotentialmarkdownandthelikelihoodofasellout.Basedoncustomers'valuationinregardtothetwoprices,thevalueofthefirmisexpressedasastreamofexpectedrevenues.Solvingtheproblemusingarealoptionapproach,weshowthattheseller'soptimalmarkdowntimingdecision isbasedonthethresholdpolicy.Tothebestofourknowledge,thisisoneofthefirststudiesthatconsidersapostedpricingschemeundermar‐ketuncertainty.

Theremainderofthepaperisorganisedasfollows.Section2outlinespreviousrelatedworkstosummariseextantresearch.Section3proposesarevenuemaximisationmodel,andSection4continueswiththetopicbyanalysingthesolutionofthemodel.Finally,wediscussbroaderfind‐ings,conclusions,andpotentialfutureresearchopportunitiesinSection5.

2. Literature review 

Strategiccustomersandfirms'pricingpolicyproblemshavebecomeanincreasinglyproductiveresearch area.Amongothers, studies regarding customerpurchasingbehavior are thoroughlyreviewedbyShenandSu[20].Mostofthepapersintheliteratureconsidertwoimportantele‐ments inmodellingstrategiccustomerbehaviour.Thefirst isthearrivalprocessofcustomers.Whethercustomerspreexistedinthemarket[7,13,18]orsequentiallyarrivedinthemarket[3,14,21,23]isaquestionbasedonthispremise.Thesecondisthedecisionmakingofthecustom‐ersandhowthedecisionmakingultimatelyformsanequilibrium.Regardlessofthemarketsize,thedecisionmakingofanindividualcustomermakesanimpactonthedynamicsofthemarketto some extent. For instance, when many customers purchase goods in the early stages, theproductmayrunoutofstockforsomeofthosewhoinitiallydecidedtodelaythepurchase[13].Sometimescustomersmayhavetopurchasethegoodsatanevenhigherpriceifthefirmorsell‐erchoosestoadoptamarkuppricingpolicy[24].Astrategiccustomertriestomakeanoptimaldecision,foreseeingthesesituations,andthisprocessmay, inturn,compriseanequilibriumindecisionmaking.Theseller,ontheotherhand,setshisorherpricingpolicybasedonthisequi‐libriuminanefforttomaximiseprofit.Therefore,thisgame‐theoreticrelationshipwithconflict‐

Page 3: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Optimal timing of price change with strategic customers under demand uncertainty: A real option approach 

Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019  381

ing interestsbetweenthesellerandthestrategicbuyersnecessarily leadstoahighlycomplexmodelinmanystudies.

Thereare twotypesofsimplifications todealwith thecomplexity in themodelling.Firstly,thetimeofthepricechangeisoftenfixed.Aspecificnumberofperiodsarepresumed,andstaticpricingismaintainedforthedurationoftheperiods.Inotherwords,theanalysisofoptimalpric‐ingisbasedonthedefinitenumberofperiodsinwhichafixedpriceisoffered,ratherthanfind‐ingthepricechangingperiodonebyone[5‐7,13].Thesecondcaseisthesizeofthemarket:inapplyingagametheoryapproach,asmallmarketsizeisassumed.Inthissituation,acustomerpredicts the decisionmaking of other consumers tomake his or her optimal decision and anequilibriumofstrategicpurchases isachieved.AvivandPazgal[3] foundthata firm'sbenefitsfrompricedifferentiationmaydecreaseascustomersbecomemorestrategic,andhenceoptimalpricingpoliciesmayresultinpotentialrevenuelossesinthepresenceofstrategiccustomers.

Customers'purchasingdecisionsdependontheinteractionamongthepricingpolicy,availa‐bility,customervaluations,remainingtime,andsoforth.Underthepostedpricing,forinstance,wherethesellerannouncesitspricepathinadvance,theavailabilityoftheproductorthepossi‐bilitytopurchaseitlaterintimewillbethemajorconcernforthecustomer[2,7,13].AsDasuandTong[7]specificallypointedout,theseller'sdynamicpricingdecisionismeaningfulonlyifcustomersareawareofthestock‐outpossibility,whiletheimpactoftheperceptiononstrategiccustomerbehaviourisdifferent inheterogeneouscustomervaluations[23]. Inmanystudies,atwo‐periodpostedpricingschemehasbeenusedduetoitssimplicityandapplicability,althoughthesellercanstillmakeapricechangeatanytime[4,7,13,15].DasuandTong[7],inparticular,foundthat theapproximationclose to themaximumrevenuecanbeachievedbytwoor threepricingchanges.Inthisstudy,ourmodelwillalsobebasedonthetwo‐periodpostedpricingincontinuoustimeperiodstofindtheoptimaltimingofpricechange,whiletheavailabilityoftheitemislimitedafterthemarkdown.

Asforthefirm'spointofview,ontheotherhand,marketsizeisthemainsourceofuncertain‐ty.Giventhepriceandthetimingofthepricechange,thefirm'srevenuemustbesignificantlydifferentdependingonchangesindemandatthemoment.Undermarketuncertainty,thesellercaneithermakean immediateprice changeor intentionallydelay thedecision toobserve theactualdemandmovement.Thissituationisverycommoninmanyoperationalpractices:compa‐nieshaveanopportunitytoinvestbuttheycanstillwaitfornewinformation.Inotherwords,afirmwith theability topostponeadecisionhas theoption,not theobligation, toexercise it –making it analogous to holding a financial call option. Since first proposed by Pindyck [19],McDonaldandSiegel[17],DixitandPindyck[8]andothers,thisrealoptionapproachhasbeenwidelyborrowedintheareasofmarketingandoperationsmanagementbecauseithelpsustobetterunderstandthetruevalueoftheinvestmentopportunity.

Adoptingtherealoptionconceptisnotcompletelynewinrevenuemanagementliterature.Innumerouspapers,thedynamicpricingdecisionisdeterminedbyconsideringtheoptionvalueofunsoldproducts[11,16].Sincethisoptionvaluedecreasestowardstheendofthetimehorizon,theoptimalpricepathalsodecreasesovertime.Inanotherpaper,GallegoandSahin[10]usedthe real option approach tomodel uncertain customer valuations. In this paper, however,weassumethatpotentialcustomerdemandevolvesovertimeandfollowsthegeometricBrownianmotion(GBM).Assumingtheknowndistributiononcustomervaluationsandthelevelofavaila‐bility,weexploretheoptimalmarkdowntimingproblembasedonthenetpresentvalueoftheseller'sexpectedrevenue.Tothebestofourknowledge,intheliteratureonstrategiccustomers,there areonly ahandful of studies thatdealwith theoptimal timingof price change, andyetfewerstillthatatthesametimeaddressoptimalpricingwithstrategiccustomersundermarketuncertainty.

3. Model description 

Inthispaper,weconsideramonopolisticfirmthatsellsasingleitemtopotentialcustomersovertwoperiods.Thefirmwantstomaximiseitsnetpresentvalueofexpectedrevenue.Below,weexplainfurtherassumptionsbeforebuildingourmodel.

Page 4: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Lee, Lee, Kim  

382  Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019

Assumption1.Themonopolistic firm followsatwo‐periodmarkdownpricingschemeandcom‐mitstothepricepathinbothphases.

Assumption2.Theoriginal( )andmarkdownprices( )arepre‐announcedandthe in‐stockprobability(Ο€)inthesecondperiodisalsogiveninformation.

Assumption 3. Customersare strategic rather thanmyopicandareawareofmarkdownsandpossibilitiesofstock‐outs.

Assumption4.Thedistributionofcustomervaluations( β‹… )isknown.

3.1 Valuation of a strategic customer 

Supposethatthereisamonopolistwhohasasufficientlylargenumberofanitem.Untiltime ,theitemisinitiallysoldatprice ,andafter theitemissoldatthemarkdownprice .Thetwoprices, and ,arepre‐announced.CustomerdemandfollowsageometricBrownianmotion(GBM),andeachcustomerissupposedtopurchaseonlyoneunitoftheitem.Whentheselleroffersamarkdownprice,weassumethatthesellercancontrolthelevelofproductavaila‐bility, ,toinducescarcity.Inotherwords,inthesecondperiod,thein‐stockprobabilitydecidedbythesellerwillbesetto 1.Controllingtheavailabilityofservicesoritemsofdifferentclas‐sesisprevalentinrevenuemanagement[24]andinducingalevelofscarcityisalsooneofthemostcommonstrategiesinmarketing[9,22].

Let denotethecustomer'ssurplus.Thentheutilisationofthecustomerwhopurchasestheitemrightnowisasfollows:

(1)

where isthesurplusofthecustomerand isthecurrentpriceoftheproduct.Similarly,theutilisationofthecustomerwhodecidestowaitforthediscountisasfollows:

(2)

where is the customer'svaluationof theproduct, is the currentpriceof theproduct, isthe future price of the product, and is the service level of the product at the lowerprice .Thus, the stock‐out probability is1 . stands for the customer's preference for risk; 0indicates risk‐averse, 0risk‐taking, and 0risk‐neutral attitude. Furthermore, we as‐sumethatthecustomersareeitherrisk‐averseorrisk‐neutral,whichisaprevalentassumptionmadebymanyresearchers[13,15].

Inthissetting,thestrategiccustomersdecidetopurchaseinthefirstperiodiftheirvaluationisgreaterthanorequaltothethresholdvalue.Thepurchasingdecisionofthestrategiccustomerisdeterminedbythefollowinglemma.

Lemma1.Thethresholdofastrategiccustomer'svaluationisgivenby:

1 (3)

Proof.Thetwochoices,purchasingrightnoworwaitingforadiscount,generatethesamesur‐pluswhen .Solvingtheequation,astrategiccustomerwillhavethefollowingthreshold.Thatis,

. (4)Thiswouldfinishtheproof.

If 1,nocustomerswouldbuyinthefirstperiod.Furthermore,weassumethatcustomersdonotpurchaseiftheutilisationislessthanzerowithoutlossofgenerality.Thatmeans, isnotlessthan .Therefore,itissufficienttoconsideronlythecasewherethethresholdisbetweenthefirstperiod'spricingandone.Thatis,

1 (5)

Thisalsodecidestheupperandthelowerboundsof accordingly.Followingtheliterature,potentialcustomerdemandisassumedtobeamultiplicationofthe

customervaluefunctionandthetime‐varyingpotentialdemand.Thatis,thedemandfunctionisgivenby

Page 5: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Optimal timing of price change with strategic customers under demand uncertainty: A real option approach 

Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019  383

1 (6)

where is a knowndistribution function of the product at customer valuation , and isthemultiplicativedemandshockprocess.Thismaybethoughtasdemandinwhichtheproducthasaunitprice.

In the firstperiod,a strategiccustomerwouldpurchase theproduct, if and 0.Therefore,fromtheconditions,

 and  (7)

wehave

. (8)

Since forthecustomerspurchasinginthefirstperiod,thecurrentdemandfunctionis

1 11

. (9)

Ontheotherhand,aproportionofcustomerswouldwaitandpurchaselateratalowerprice,if and 0.Thevaluationofsuchcustomersisasfollows:

. (10)

Hence,thedemandfunctionofthecustomerswhocomebacklaterinthesecondperiodtopur‐chasewillbe:

1. (11)

Finally,whentheproductstartsbeingsoldatamarkdownprice ,anycustomerwhoseval‐uationisatleastgreaterthanthepricewouldpurchaseit.Namely,thedemandfunctionwillbe:

1 . (12)

Without loss of generality, let the valuation of customers, , be uniformly distributed over[0,1].Thenthedemandforeachcaseisgivenasfollows:

1 11

1 (13)

1 1 1 (14)

1 . (15)

3.2 Customer demand 

Inthispaper,weuseageometricBrownianmotion(GBM)toformulatethemulti‐plicativede‐mandshock attime .Thatmeanstherelativechangeindemand, / , withinashorttimeinterval, , ,canvarywithtime .Thedynamicsofdemandarerepresentedbythefollow‐ingformula:

, (16)

where isthegrowthrateordriftrateindemand, isthevolatilityoftheprocess,and isastandardWienerprocess. If 0,market size is increasingover time. If 0,market size isdecreasing.

Thiscontinuousrandomvariable issaidtohavelognormaldistributionbecausetheinte‐gralofEq.16givesthefollowingdemandfunction(seeAppendixAforthederivation):

⁄ , (17)

where istheinitialdemand.Whilethebell‐shapedpatternofdemandisexpectedbyEq.17,therealisationofdemandwillsubstantiallydeviatefromit,dependingonthemarketvolatility,asshowninFig.1.

Page 6: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Lee, Lee, Kim  

384  Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019

Fig.1 SamplepathofpotentialdemandfromthegeometricBrownianmotioninadecreasingmarket.

Note that the threesamplepaths inFig.1aredrawn fromEq.16withameandrift rateof

0.1and three standard deviations of 0.05, 0.1, and 0.2. As shown in the figure, thesamplepathwithalargerstandarddeviationtendstofluctuatesignificantly,whileallthreetra‐jectorieshaveadecreasingtrendincommonduetothenegativemeandriftrate.

3.3 Optimal timing of price discount 

Next,weconsidertheoptimaltimingproblemconditionedonthecustomer'spurchasingstrat‐egy.Wedevelopamodelforanoptimaldiscounttimingdecisionusingarealoptionmodel.Inpractice,thecompanyhasan"option"todelaythediscountandhenceneedstodeterminewhenthepriceshouldbediscounted.Aftermarkdown,thecompanywouldmakerevenue ,withanirreversiblesunkcost beingincurredfromsalespromotion,inventorymanagement,andsoforth.

Hereinweformulatethevaluefunctionofthefirmwithanopportunityofthediscounttiming.Whentheproductissoldattheoriginalprice ,aproportionofcustomers, ,whosevalua‐tionisfarhigherthan ,orgreaterthan ,willdecidetopurchasetheitem.Agroupofstrategiccustomers, , whose valuation is between and would like to wait and see if the price ismarkeddown.Once the firmdecides todiscount theoriginalprice to themarkdownprice, ,theycomebacktopurchasetheproductbutonly ofthemwillbeabletogetone.Weassumethat suchdemand is instantaneous,meaning that customerdemandaccumulatedup to time willberealisedattime [3].Fromtime ,anycustomerswhosevaluationisatleasthigherthanwouldliketopurchasetheproductbut,again,only ofthemwouldgetone.Webeginwith thevalue functionof the firm for theoptimaldiscount timingproblem.The

valueofthefirm, ,isthestreamofrevenue,whichconsistsofthreecasesstatedearlier.Weusedynamicprogramming,stipulatinganexogenousdiscountrate .Then istheexpectedpresentvalue

max 1 (18)

where

1 . (19)

Sincethedemandofstrategiccustomerswillberealisedattime ,werearrangetheformulasothattherevenueisincludedintheterminalpayoff .Then

Page 7: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Optimal timing of price change with strategic customers under demand uncertainty: A real option approach 

Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019  385

max 1 (20)

where

1 (21)

1 (22)

1 (23)

Since 1 / (See Appendix A) and ⁄ , we

finallyhave:

1 1 (24)

Substituting inEq.3intotheformula,thevaluefunctionofthefirmissummarisedasfollows.

Proposition1.Thevaluefunctionofthefirmforoptimaldiscounttiming isgivenby:

max1

1 (25)

where

11 1 (26)

Bysolvingthisstochasticdynamicprogrammingproblem,wecanobtaintheoptimaltimingforamarkdown.Theoption‐likeapproachshownin[17]and[19]isusedtosolvethedynamicstochasticproblem.Asthepotentialdemand evolvesstochastically,theoptimalstrategyistoexercise(markdown)sothatthevalueisatleastgreaterthanthecriticalvalue βˆ—.Afirm’sop‐timalmarkdowntimingsolutionisrepresentedinthefollowingproposition.Proposition2.Acompanyconsideringmarkdownoftheretailpricewillhaveavaluefunctionasfollows:

1 βˆ—

1 1 βˆ— (27)

whereβˆ—

1β‹…

1 11 (28)

1 1β‹…

βˆ—

(29)

and12

12

2 (30)

Proof.Let denotethetimingatwhichthefirmdiscountstheoriginalpriceoftheitem.Asde‐scribedearlier,thefirmmakesrevenueflowsof 1 beforethemarkdown.Attime ,thefirmwouldmakerevenueflow withtheirreversiblesunkcost .Therefore,asshownin[8],theBellmanequationinthecontinuationregion,wherevaluesof arenotoptimaltomark‐down,isgivenby:

1 , (31)

whichimpliesthatoveratimeinterval ,thetotalexpectedreturnonthemarkdownopportu‐nityisequaltoitsexpectedrateofcapitalappreciation.

Page 8: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Lee, Lee, Kim  

386  Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019

ApplyingIto'slemma,wehave

12

, (32)

where ⁄ and ⁄ .SubstitutingEq.16anddividingthroughby ,wehavethefollowingBellmanequation(see

AppendixBforproof):

12

1 0(33)

Toensuretheexistenceoftheoptimalsolution,weassumethat .Thedifferentialequa‐tion mustsatisfythefollowingthreeboundaryconditions:

0 0 (34)

βˆ— 1 1βˆ—

(35)

βˆ— 1 (36)

Eq.34holdsbasedon theobservation that itwill stayzero if thestochasticprocess goes tozero.Theothertwoequationsaretoimposecontinuityandsmoothnessatthecriticalpoint βˆ—,thepotentialdemandatwhichitisoptimaltodiscount.Eq.35isthevalue‐matchingcondition,indicatingtherevenuethefirmmakesuponmarkdown.Eq.36isthesmooth‐pastingconditionatthepoint.

Therefore,thesolutionofthedifferentialEq.33musttaketheform

1, (37)

where isaconstanttobedeterminedand isoneofthesolutionsofthefollowingquadratureequation:

12

1 0. (38)

Solvingtheequationandtake

12

12

21 (39)

toensuretheboundarycondition.Fromthesmoothpastingandthevalue‐matchingconditions,wehave

βˆ— βˆ— 1 βˆ— 1 1βˆ—

(40)

and

βˆ— βˆ— 1 1. (41)

Solvingtheseequationsresultsin:

βˆ—1

β‹…1 1

1 (42)

1 1β‹…

βˆ—

(43)

and12

12

2. (44)

Herein, only if 1 / and 1 1 ,we have a positive

Page 9: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Optimal timing of price change with strategic customers under demand uncertainty: A real option approach 

Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019  387

threshold βˆ— 0.ThisresultleadstoProposition3.Again,thethreshold βˆ—determinestheoptimalmarkdowntimingforafirm.Whentheactual

customerdemandofthefirmattime islowerthanthethreshold βˆ—,itisbeneficialtoselltheproductattheoriginalretailprice ,makingtherevenuestreamof 1 / aswellasgiving the flexibility that the firmcanhold for thepricemarkdown,measuredbyΞ±X .On theotherhand,whentheactualdemandisgreaterthanthethresholdXβˆ—,thefirmwilldecidetodis‐

countthepriceandtakethebenefitofmarkdown 1 byspend‐

inginvestmentcost .

4. Analysis and discussion 

Thissectionexplainssomeof the importantcharacteristics foroptimalmarkdownapproachessuggestedearlier.First,thefollowingpropositionillustratesthatthereexistsapositivethresh‐oldforthefirmatanygiventime underspecificconditionsfor and .

Proposition3. Let βˆ—denotetheoptimaltimingofmarkdowntomaximisethe firmvalue.Thentheoptimalmarkdowntimeisfinite βˆ— ∞[12],andthefirstepochthatdemandexceedsthethre‐sholdisestimatedatthefollowingtime:

βˆ— inf 0 | βˆ— , (45)

where there exists a positive threshold βˆ— β‹… 1

attime if 1 / and 1 1 / .Proof.ByProposition2.

Notethatweassumeadecreasingmarketsize( 0).Astime increases,therefore,wecanobserve that the threshold βˆ—decreases exponentially,while theminimumvalue for the fixedcost thatisrequiredforthisapproachtobefeasibleincreasesexponentiallybeforehittingthelowerbound asshowninthefollowingproposition.

Proposition 4. As β†’ ∞, we have a threshold βˆ— β†’ 0and the lower bound of the fixed costβ†’ / .Again,as the threshold βˆ—for themarkdowndecreasesexponentially,a firmis likely tode‐

cideonapricediscountintherelativelyearlystages.Italsoindicatesthatnosignificantrevenueis expected after a certain amountof timebecauseof the reduction in customerdemand, andhencethefirmnolongerneedstoinvestmoreinlaterstagesunderthisapproach.

Astheoptimaltiming βˆ—isrepresentedbysomeexogenousfactors,weexploittheimpactoftheparametersonthethreshold.

Proposition5.Theoptimaltimingthresholdincreaseswithrespecttodemandvolatility.Thatis,

βˆ—

0 (46)

Proof.Notingthefractionalvalue 0,wetakethederivativeof fromEq.16withrespecttothedemandvolatility, .Weknow 11isoneofthesolutionstothefollowingquadraticfunction

0(theothersolutionis 0),where12

1 .(47)

Takingaderivativeoftheequation,wehave

0. (48)

Since ⁄ 0and ⁄ 0,wehave

0. (49)

Furthermore,

Page 10: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Lee, Lee, Kim  

388  Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019

111

0. (50)

Finally,thederivativeoftheoptimalthreshold βˆ—withrespecttoΟƒis,βˆ—

1 1 11 0 (51)

Thispropositionindicatesthattheoptimalmarkdownthresholdincreasesasthevariationindemandincreases.Simplyput,itismorebeneficialforthefirmtowaitanddelaythemarkdown,therebyavoidingtheriskofmakingtheinstantaneousdecisionwhenthemarketishighlyuncer‐tain. The firm iswilling tomake themarkdown decision, onlywhen excessive revenue is ex‐pectedwheretheamountofuncertaintyregardingfuturedemandislarger.

5. Conclusion 

Inthispaper,theoptimalpricingpolicyofamonopolisticfirmisinvestigatedwithstrategiccus‐tomerbehaviour.Whencustomersstrategicallywait foradiscount, themonopolisthasanop‐tiontoofferamarkdowntomaximiseitsrevenue.Assumingthattheunderlyingcustomerde‐mandisstochastic,evolvingdynamicallyovertime,wedevelopavaluefunctionforthefirmtofindtheoptimaltimeforthediscount.Usingarealoptionapproach,thestochasticdynamicpro‐grammingmodelissolved.Giventhefixedcostofthemarkdown,servicelevel,andaknowndis‐countedprice,theoptimalpolicyforthefirmistofollowthethresholdpolicy.Thesellermax‐imisesitsrevenuebydiscountingthepriceoftheproductwhenthepotentialcustomerdemandisgreaterthanthethresholdvalue.

Thecontributionofthispaperisasfollows:Consideringtheoptimalmarkdowndecisionforamonopolistic sellerwith strategic customers,we address the gap in other literature on thesecustomerswithproblemsundermarketuncertainty.Astochasticdynamicoptimisationmodelisproposedtofindtheoptimalmarkdownstrategyoftheseller.Arealoptionapproachisappliedtoobtainaclosed‐formsolutionofthefirm’sdemandthreshold.Theanalysisoftheoptimaltim‐ingrevealstherelationshipbetweenthedegreeofmarketuncertaintyandthemarkdowndeci‐sion‐making.

Althoughtheoptimalthresholdpolicyisfound,carefulinterpretationsoftheresultareneed‐ed.First,customersareawareofpotentialmarkdownswhilethediscountedpriceisknown.Theseller may not exercise the option to markdown if the potential demand never exceeds thethreshold. Second,we found that there is an exponential decrease in the threshold value in adecliningmarket,whichjustifiestheearlymarkdowninsomeindustries.Ontheotherhand,theoptimalmarkdownthresholdincreasesasthevariationindemandincreases.Thisindicatesthata firmneeds to avoid the riskof committingmarkdownpricing too earlywhen themarket ishighlyuncertain.Thecompany’smanufacturingandproductionplanningmustbealignedwiththisstrategicdecisiononthemarkdowntiming.

There aremany challenges involved in the proposed study for future research. Discussionoverpotentialdemandisrecommended.Furtherinvestigationonthepostedpricingschemeofdemanddiffusioncanbedevelopedwherethenewproductgetsadoptedinthepopulationovertime.Anotherpotentialareaofresearchwouldbethepredictionofstrategiccustomerdemandbyapplyingdata‐drivenapproaches,suchasmeta‐heuristicsandmachinelearningalgorithms.Finally,aninterestingextensionwouldbetoimplementtheproposedframeworkonreal‐worldproblemstodemonstratethepracticalimplicationsofourmodel.

Conflict of interests 

Theauthors thank theeditorand tworeviewers for their constructivecomments,whichhelpedus to improve thispaper.Theauthorsdeclarethatthereisnoconflictofinterestsregardingthepublicationofthispaper.

   

Page 11: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Optimal timing of price change with strategic customers under demand uncertainty: A real option approach

Acknowledgement This work was supported by the Ministry of Education of the Republic of Korea and the National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF-2016S1A5A8019542).

References [1] Albey, E., Norouzi, A., Kempf, K.G., Uzsoy, R. (2015). Demand modeling with forecast evolution: An application to

production planning, IEEE Transactions on Semiconductor Manufacturing, Vol. 28, No. 3, 374-384, doi: 10.1109/ TSM.2015.2453792.

[2] Arnold, M.A., Lippman, S.A. (2001). Analytics of search with posted prices, Economic Theory, Vol. 17, No. 2, 447-466, doi: 10.1007/pl00004113.

[3] Aviv, Y., Pazgal, A. (2008). Optimal pricing of seasonal products in the presence of forward-looking consumers, Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, Vol. 10, No. 3, 339-359, doi: 10.1287/msom.1070.0183.

[4] Cachon, G.P., Swinney, R. (2009). Purchasing, pricing, and quick response in the presence of strategic consumers, Management Science, Vol. 55, No. 3, 497-511, doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1080.0948.

[5] Chen, Y., Farias, V.F. (2018). Robust dynamic pricing with strategic customers, Mathematics of Operations Re-search, Vol. 43, No. 4, 1119-1142, doi: 10.1287/moor.2017.0897.

[6] Chen, Y., Farias, V.F., Trichakis, N. (2019). On the efficacy of static prices for revenue management in the face of strategic customers, Management Science, doi: 10.1287/mnsc.2018.3203.

[7] Dasu, S., Tong, C. (2010). Dynamic pricing when consumers are strategic: Analysis of posted and contingent pricing schemes, European Journal of Operational Research, Vol. 204, No. 3, 662-671, doi: 10.1016/j.ejor.2009. 11.018.

[8] Dixit, A.K., Pindyck, R.S. (1994). Investment under uncertainty, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, USA.

[9] Dye, R. (2000). The buzz on buzz, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 78, 139-146. [10] Gallego, G., Sahin, O. (2006). Inter-temporal valuations, product design and revenue management, Airline Group

of the International Federation of Operational Research Societies (AGIFORS). [11] Gallego, G., Van Ryzin, G. (1994). Optimal dynamic pricing of inventories with stochastic demand over finite

horizons, Management Science, Vol. 40, No. 8, 999-1020, doi: 10.1287/mnsc.40.8.999. [12] Harrison, J.M. (2013). Brownian models of performance and control, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,

United Kingdom, doi: 10.1017/CBO9781139087698. [13] Kim, S., Huh, W.T., Dasu, S. (2015). Pre-announced posted pricing scheme: Existence and uniqueness of equilib-

rium bidding strategy, Operations Research Letters, Vol. 43, No. 2, 151-160, doi: 10.1016/j.orl.2014.12.010. [14] Liu, M., Bi, W., Chen, X., Li, G. (2014). Dynamic pricing of fashion-like multiproducts with customers’ reference

effect and limited memory, Mathematical Problems in Engineering, Vol. 2014, Article ID 157865, 10 pages, doi: 10.1155/2014/157865.

[15] Liu, Q., Van Ryzin, G.J. (2008). Strategic capacity rationing to induce early purchases, Management Science, Vol. 54, No. 6, 1115-1131, doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1070.0832.

[16] McAfee, R.P., Te Velde, V. (2007). Dynamic pricing in the airline industry, In: Hendershott T.J. (ed.), Handbook of Economics and Information Systems, Vol. 1, Elsevier Science, New York, USA, doi: 10.1016/S1574-0145(06) 01011-7.

[17] McDonald, R., Siegel, D. (1986). The value of waiting to invest, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 101, No. 4, 707-727, doi: 10.2307/1884175.

[18] Γ–zer, Γ–., Zheng, Y. (2015). Markdown or everyday low price? The role of behavioral motives, Management Sci-ence, Vol. 62, No. 2, 326-346, doi: 10.1287/mnsc.2014.2147.

[19] Pindyck, R. (1990). Irreversibility, uncertainty, and investment, Working Paper No. 3307, National Bureau of Eco-nomic Research, Cambridge, USA, doi: 10.3386/w3307.

[20] Shen, Z.-J.M., Su, X. (2007). Customer behaviour modelling in revenue management and auctions: A review and new research opportunities, Production and Operations Management, Vol. 16, No. 6, 713-728, doi: 10.1111/ j.1937-5956.2007.tb00291.x.

[21] Smith, S.A., Agrawal, N. (2017). Optimal markdown pricing and inventory allocation for retail chains with inven-tory dependent demand, Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, Vol. 19, No. 2, 290-304, doi: 10.1287/msom.2016.0609.

[22] Stock, A., Balachander, S. (2005). The making of a β€œhot product": A signalling explanation of marketers' scarcity strategy, Management Science, Vol. 51, No. 8, 1181-1192, doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1050.0381.

[23] Su, X. (2007). Intertemporal pricing with strategic customer behaviour, Management Science, Vol. 53, No. 5, 726-741, doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1060.0667.

[24] Talluri, K.T., Van Ryzin, G.J. (2006). The theory and practice of revenue management, Springer-Verlag, New York, USA.

Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019 389

Page 12: Y. J.P.b S. - APEMapem-journal.org/Archives/2019/APEM14-3_379-390.pdfSolving the problem using a real option approach, we show that the seller's optimal markdown timing decision is

Lee, Lee, Kim

Appendix A: Proof of Proposition 1

Since 𝐸𝐸 �∫ 𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑𝑇𝑇0 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑� = ∫ 𝐸𝐸 𝑇𝑇

0 [𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑]𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 by Fubini's Theorem, we first apply Ito's lemma to 𝑑𝑑 ln𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑 , to find 𝐸𝐸[𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑]:

𝑑𝑑 ln𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑 =1𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑 βˆ’

12

1𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑2

(𝑑𝑑𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑)2 (52)

=1𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑

(πœ‡πœ‡π‘‹π‘‹π‘‘π‘‘ + πœŽπœŽπ‘‹π‘‹π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘)βˆ’12

1𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑2

(𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑2𝜎𝜎2𝑑𝑑2) (53)

= πœ‡πœ‡ 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 + 𝜎𝜎 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 βˆ’12𝜎𝜎2 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 (54)

After integrating and applying the fundamental theorem of calculus, we obtain:

ln𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑 βˆ’ ln𝑋𝑋0 = οΏ½πœ‡πœ‡ βˆ’12𝜎𝜎2οΏ½ 𝑑𝑑 + πœŽπœŽπ‘Šπ‘Šπ‘‘π‘‘ (55)

𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑 = 𝑋𝑋0π‘’π‘’οΏ½πœ‡πœ‡βˆ’12𝜎𝜎

2�𝑑𝑑+πœŽπœŽπ‘Šπ‘Šπ‘‘π‘‘ (56)

The general form of expectation for Gaussian random variable is 𝐸𝐸[𝑒𝑒𝑋𝑋] = 𝐸𝐸 οΏ½π‘’π‘’πœ‡πœ‡+12𝜎𝜎

2οΏ½, where 𝑋𝑋

has the law of a normal random variable with mean πœ‡πœ‡ and variance 𝜎𝜎2. Since we know the stand-ard Brownian motion π‘Šπ‘Šπ‘‘π‘‘~𝑁𝑁(0, 𝑑𝑑), taking expectation on both sides yields the following [9]:

𝐸𝐸[𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑] = 𝑋𝑋0π‘’π‘’οΏ½πœ‡πœ‡βˆ’12𝜎𝜎

2�𝑑𝑑𝐸𝐸[π‘’π‘’πœŽπœŽπ‘Šπ‘Šπ‘‘π‘‘] (57)

= 𝑋𝑋0π‘’π‘’οΏ½πœ‡πœ‡βˆ’12𝜎𝜎

2�𝑑𝑑𝑒𝑒0+12𝜎𝜎

2𝑑𝑑 (58)

= 𝑋𝑋0π‘’π‘’πœ‡πœ‡π‘‘π‘‘ (59) Finally taking integral produces the following results:

οΏ½ 𝐸𝐸 𝑇𝑇

0[𝑋𝑋𝑑𝑑]𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 = οΏ½ 𝑋𝑋0π‘’π‘’πœ‡πœ‡π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘

𝑇𝑇

0=𝑋𝑋0πœ‡πœ‡

(π‘’π‘’πœ‡πœ‡π‘‡π‘‡ βˆ’ 1) (60)

Appendix B: Proof of Theorem 1 Substituting Eq. 16 into Eq. 32, we have the following equation:

𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 = 𝑑𝑑′(πœ‡πœ‡π‘‹π‘‹ 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 + πœŽπœŽπ‘‹π‘‹ 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑) +12𝑑𝑑′′(πœ‡πœ‡π‘‹π‘‹π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘ + πœŽπœŽπ‘‹π‘‹ π‘‘π‘‘π‘Šπ‘Š)2 (61)

= πœ‡πœ‡π‘‹π‘‹π‘‘π‘‘β€²π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘π‘‘ + πœŽπœŽπ‘‹π‘‹ π‘‘π‘‘β€²π‘‘π‘‘π‘Šπ‘Š +12πœ‡πœ‡2𝑋𝑋2𝑑𝑑′′(𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑)2 + πœ‡πœ‡πœŽπœŽπ‘‹π‘‹2𝑑𝑑′′(𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑)(π‘‘π‘‘π‘Šπ‘Š) +

12𝜎𝜎2𝑋𝑋2𝑑𝑑′′(π‘‘π‘‘π‘Šπ‘Š)2 (62)

Taking expectations on both sides to apply some properties of GBM and discarding all terms involving dt to a power higher than 1, we have

E[𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑] = οΏ½πœ‡πœ‡π‘‹π‘‹π‘‘π‘‘β€² +12π‘‘π‘‘β€²β€²πœŽπœŽ2𝑋𝑋2οΏ½dt = [π‘Ÿπ‘Ÿπ‘‘π‘‘ βˆ’ π‘π‘π‘œπ‘œ(1 βˆ’ 𝜏𝜏)]𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑. (63)

Note that the term (𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑)(π‘‘π‘‘π‘Šπ‘Š) has magnitude (𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑)3/2, 𝐸𝐸[π‘‘π‘‘π‘Šπ‘Š] = 0, 𝐸𝐸[(π‘‘π‘‘π‘Šπ‘Š)2] = 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑, and 𝐸𝐸[𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑] = 0. After dividing through by 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑, we have the Bellman Eq. 33.

390 Advances in Production Engineering & Management 14(3) 2019


Recommended