+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Do Partisan Ties Still Bind? The Impact of the European Union on Domestic Spending Agendas,...

Do Partisan Ties Still Bind? The Impact of the European Union on Domestic Spending Agendas,...

Date post: 14-May-2023
Category:
Upload: canterbury-nz
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
21
Do Partisan Ties Still Bind? The Impact of the European Union on Domestic Spending Agendas, 1980-1995 * Robert E. Bohrer II Department of Political Science Gettysburg College Gettysburg, PA 17325-1486 [email protected] Alexander C. Tan Department of Political Science University of North Texas Denton, TX 76203 [email protected] * Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Southwestern Social Science Association, Galveston, March 16-18, 2000.
Transcript

Do Partisan Ties Still Bind? The Impact of the European Union on Domestic Spending Agendas, 1980-1995*

Robert E. Bohrer II Department of Political Science

Gettysburg College Gettysburg, PA 17325-1486

[email protected]

Alexander C. Tan Department of Political Science

University of North Texas Denton, TX 76203

[email protected]

* Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Southwestern Social Science Association, Galveston, March 16-18, 2000.

2

Introduction

With the ratification of the Maastricht Treaty in 1992, the member-states of the

European Union (EU) embarked on an ambitious project focusing on a common currency

through the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). Under the conditions set forth in

Maastricht, countries seeking to join in the first wave of the EMU are required (beginning

in 1997) to demonstrate fiscal discipline by keeping annual deficits under 3% of GDP

while debt should be less than 60% of GDP (or, at a minimum, moving in that direction),

in addition to controlling inflation and minimizing currency fluctuations. As a result of

these criteria, governments across Europe imposed austerity measures to meet the entry

requirements. While such belt-tightening efforts were successful for 14 of the 15

member-states, the political impact of these efforts has been profound. Most noticeably,

parties of the left benefited and swept into government in 13 of 15 member states, and for

the first time in history the left simultaneously controlled the governments of the “big

four” – Italy, France, Germany and the United Kingdom (Bohrer and Tan, Forthcoming).1

Presumably, the gains of parties of the left can be attributed to voters reacting

negatively to austerity measures. Hence, parties of the left are viewed as defenders of the

welfare state and the most likely to roll back cuts made to meet the Maastricht criteria for

entry into the EMU. This view is in line with Huber and Inglehart’s (1995) findings that

today’s parties of the left are primarily reactive parties that seek to limit retrenchments of

the welfare state. The irony of the post-Maastricht period may be that electorates have

1 The eleven countries gaining membership in the EMU were: Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Portugal and Spain. The UK, Denmark, and Sweden met the Maastricht criteria but did not elect to join while Greece sought membership but did not meet the criteria.

3

shifted support to the left in order to keep the status quo, but governments of the left are

discovering that continued compliance with the entry criteria make such restorations

difficult, if not impossible, to put in place. Upon taking office, both Lionel Jospin in

France and Gerhard Schroeder of Germany have had to significantly modify campaign

promises on restoring social justice. External constraints – in the broad sense

globalization and specifically, those formally contained in the EMU entry criteria – have

limited domestic policy agendas.

In addition, the left restoration of the 1990s may result in dramatically different

policy agendas than the leftist governments of the past. While in the past the left was

grounded in Keynesian principles of heavy government involvement in economic

management, the modern European left is more in line with the so-called "Third Way".

This new path - most clearly illustrated by Tony Blair's remaking of the Labour Party in

the UK, but also influential in the German Social Democratic Party, the French Socialists

and the Italian Olive Tree - is much more moderate and less dedicated to principles of

government involvement in the economy.

We examine fluctuations in domestic social spending in the member states of the

European Union during the period 1980 to 1995. Using a pooled cross-sectional time-

series, we find that non-leftist governments, consensus institutions, unemployment and

the proportion of the population age 65 and older all lead to increased social expenditures

as a percentage of Gross Domestic Product. For social spending as a percentage of total

expenditures, leftist governments and unemployment both lead to increased expenditures

but the squeeze on budgets following the Maastricht Treaty has a negative impact on

social spending. Taken together, these results show that partisan ties do indeed still seem

4

to bind, but how they bind differs across measures of expenditures. Most strikingly, the

priorities of the left seem to have shifted away from social spending as a priority in times

of economic growth. In addition, the constraints imposed by the Maastricht Treaty have

limited the relative impact of social spending in EU member-states.

Determinants of Domestic Spending

The existing literature identifies several factors that influence the level of

domestic spending. Specifically, economic factors, institutional design, the ideological

orientation of governments and demographic issues have all been pointed to as influential

determinants of social spending. Below we examine each of these factors as well as the

influence of the post-Maastricht era on social spending patterns.

Economic Factors

Economic forces have been found to influence domestic spending patterns in the

relatively well-developed welfare states of Western Europe. In particular, increases in

unemployment have been found to be positively related to social expenditures (Cameron

1978; Rotte 1998). The rationale is fairly straightforward: welfare state benefits for the

unemployed lead to greater expenditures as transfers to the unemployed must be made.

Hence, we expect, all else equal, increases in unemployment will lead to increased

domestic expenditures.

In addition to the influence of unemployment, in eras of economic growth

government expenditures are likely to grow. For example, during the heyday of the

welfare state in the 1960s, the Dutch government dramatically increased social

5

expenditures as the economic situation of the country improved markedly from petroleum

profits. By contrast the dual oil shocks of the 1970s and the recession of the late 1980s

and early 1990s have meant increased scarcity across Europe. This development puts a

squeeze on domestic budgets, particularly in light of the Maastricht criteria for entry into

the EMU.

Taken together, increases in unemployment have been shown to cause increased

domestic expenditure levels, and the recent era has been one of slow growth for the

economies of the region. Considering the extremely high levels of unemployment across

the region of late, based on past behavior we would expect increased social expenditures

to offset the impact of joblessness.

Institutional Design

The debates over the effects of democratic institutional design have also revealed

differences in expenditure patterns. Essentially, this debate centers around majoritarian

and consensus-based institutional design questions. Majoritarian democracies tend to

have single-party government, an executive that dominates the legislative branch, lower

numbers of political parties and issue dimensions, greater electoral disproportionality, are

more likely to be unicameral or asymmetrically bicameral and centralized (Lijphart

1984: 212-22). In contrast, consensus systems are characterized by power sharing

accomplished through coalition governments, a multiparty system with several issue

dimensions, roughly equal executive-legislative relations, proportional representation,

balanced bicameralism and federalism. In a later analysis, Lijphart and Crepaz (1991)

added the level of corporatism to the characteristics of consensus systems.

6

Lijphart (1994) and Crepaz (1996a; 1996b) have found that consensus-based

democracies have a host of positive attributes, including lower levels of inequality, higher

voter turnout, and greater support for family programs than their majoritarian

counterparts. Moreover, Bohrer (1997) finds that these differences hold in terms of

greater overall social expenditures and, consequently, higher taxation levels to fund these

expenditures also characterize consensus systems.

Similarly, Robertson and Cutcomb (1987) find that majoritarian systems display

greater policy energy while consensus systems are characterized by policy ballast. This

relationship meshes with Popper’s (1988) critique of proportional representation (PR)

systems. In consensus systems (with PR as a key component), the continuity of parties

and the nature of coalition government make large shifts in policy difficult. Conversely,

in a majoritarian system, the institutional concentration of power facilitates policy

changes when a new party takes power.

While Lijpart and Crepaz see consensus systems in a positive light, other scholars

have found less positive outcomes associated with systems where power is dispersed

widely. Roubini and Sachs (1989) find that in systems where political control is dispersed

across parties (as in coalitions) and/or institutions (such as separate parties in control of

the executive and legislative branches), inefficient budgetary policy is likely (Roubini

and Sachs 1989). Specifically, the stronger the government, the lower the deficit, and the

weaker the government, the greater the deficit. Moreover, they find that in times of fiscal

crises such as the oil crises of the 1970s, ‘strong’ governments were much more likely to

control deficits than their ‘weaker’ counterparts. Hahm (1994) finds a similar relationship

in Japan.

7

Borrelli and Royed (1995) also offer a follow-up study to Roubini and Sachs.

Using a more sophisticated measure of government “strength”, they find no direct effect

of government strength on deficits, but they do find a significant effect for government

strength when the index numbers are interacted with a dummy variable representing poor

economic conditions. The upshot of these findings is that when economic times are good,

weaker governments manage deficits as well as stronger governments. In poor economic

periods, however, stronger governments are more effective at managing deficits (Borrelli

and Royed 1995: 246). Despite variations in measurement, the underlying issue remains

the dispersion of political power. On this issue all three works are in agreement – when

political power is dispersed broadly, fiscal discipline weakens. Based on these studies, we

would expect to find that consensus democracies have higher expenditures than

majoritarian systems, and this difference should be most acute in times of economic

scarcity.

Party Ideology

The ideological complexion government is another important factor affecting

spending levels. As Budge and Keman (1990) have shown, once in office European

political parties generally take the promises made in their manifestoes quite seriously.

Moreover, studies done by Castles and Mair (1984) and Huber and Inglehart (1994) have

shown that the ideological nature of political parties in Europe is more profound than

differences in the United States. In other words, there is a great deal of variation in left-

right terms within European countries. Given that these differences exist, it would seem

8

to follow that government spending patterns would be influenced by the ideological

composition of government.

Indeed, left-leaning governments have been found to have higher levels of

government spending than governments of the center or right (Cameron 1978; Lewis-

Beck and Rice 1985; Blais, Blake and Dion 1993). It is reasonable to assume that higher

levels of spending will lead to higher total outlays to finance more extensive social

programs and possibly to service debt incurred as a result of such programs (Cusack

1996). Based on this evidence, we would expect left-leaning governments to have higher

social expenditures than right, centrist, or mixed governments.

However, given the nature of the "Third Way" adopted by several major parties of

the left, there is strong reason to believe that the patterns of the past will not necessarily

be followed. Particularly in terms of the priority given to social expenditures, the

moderate, almost liberal stance of parties such as the UK Labour Party may mean a lower

priority for social spending than in the past. Though much has been made of the "Third

Way" in the journalistic world, little scholarly attention has been paid to the outcomes

produced by these new governments of the left. Hence, based on past behavior we would

expect leftist governments to have higher levels of social spending. However, the shift in

leftist ideology may temper this pattern.

Demographic Forces

Another factor influencing the level of spending in a country is the demographic

composition of society. Specifically, the aging of the population places additional

demands for expenditures, as older groups require higher expenditures than the young

9

(Oxley and Martin 1991, 176). Two recent examples of such pressures are the debate

over the future of social security in the United States and the bankruptcy of the Italian

pension system. Both of these programs face deep fiscal problems as the populations of

both countries age and the aged comprise a higher percentage of the population.

Moreover, across Europe, aging populations and declining birth rates have increased

dependency ratios (the proportion of those receiving passive welfare benefits to those of

working age population: 15-64), placing pressure on domestic spending agendas (Rhodes

1997). Thus, we would expect aging populations to result in higher social expenditure

levels.

The Maastricht Effect

In addition to the factors discussed above, the external constraints contained in the

Maastricht Treaty have limited spending agendas as well. These constraints may have

changed the nature of the European political-economic landscape as governments are

now bound to meet and maintain the EMU criteria. Hence, the wake of the Maastricht

Treaty has changed the fundamental nature of the determinants of domestic spending.

Rotte (1998) finds that prior to Maastricht increases in unemployment were related to

increased deficit levels, but after the passage of the Maastricht Treaty this relationship no

longer holds. It would appear that the constraints put into place for EMU have limited the

amount of intervention that domestic governments can undertake.

Similarly, Bohrer and Tan (Forthcoming) find a significant relationship between

the post-Maastricht budgetary squeeze and votes for the left, indicating a shift to the left

in response to austerity measures. This follows with the literature reviewed above that

party positions make a difference as it seems that voters are indicating a desire for greater

10

social spending rather than austerity measures. However, given the constraints placed on

domestic budgets following the passage of Maastricht, parties may no longer be able to

significantly alter spending patterns. According to this explanation, following the passage

of the Maastricht Treaty the nation-states of Europe find themselves faced with a

situation similar to other, economically weaker states that find their agendas constrained

by external forces such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) or currency markets. 2

Moreover, these constraints have had an effect prior to the implementation of the EMU

as governments anticipate the difficulties of meeting the entry criteria by 1997. Hence, if

this line of reasoning is correct, we would expect the factors traditionally viewed as

responsible for variations in spending patterns to exhibit less influence following the

ratification of the Maastricht Treaty in 1992.

Data & Methods

Given the above review, we expect unemployment, the institutional framework,

the ideological composition of government, and the percentage of the population age 65

and over to determine social spending in the member-states of the EU. In addition, the

external constraints of budgets included in the Maastricht criteria indicate that these

factors will be mitigated after 1992 as domestic agendas must respond to the entry

criteria. Our hypothesis is thus:

Social Spending = a+b1Unemployment+b2Govt. Ideology+b3Consensus + b4Aged Population+ b5Squeeze

2 The difference of course is that the EMU is at a certain level a voluntary commitment, though individuals do not have the right to opt out.

11

Dependent Variables

“Social Spending” is operationalized in two ways, resulting in two models. First

we examine social spending as a percentage of GDP terms using data taken from the

OECD (1999). For the second model we look at social spending as percentage of total

expenditures, also from the OECD (1999). The rationale behind testing the model on two

dependent variables is grounded in the nature of these indicators. While social

expenditures as a percentage of public expenditures tells us about the impact of social

spending relative to other types of public spending, it does not tap into the priority given

to social spending relative to the size of the economy.

Put somewhat differently public expenditures can be relatively “locked in”

relative to one another. Matters like pensions and unemployment compensation compete

over the total public expenditure pool of funds with matters such as infrastructure

improvements (e.g., roads, railways). While social expenditures may command a larger

share of public expenditures from one year to the next, it does not tell us the priority of

social or public expenditures relative to the whole economy. To tap into this dimension,

the percentage of social expenditures relative to GDP is more appropriate as it allows us

to measure the priority governments place on social spending. Using two measures of

social expenditures allows for a more refined analysis of governmental priorities.

Independent Variables

The variable “Unemployment” is simply the annual rate of unemployment in a

country and data were collected from various issues of the OECD Main Economic Indicators

and OECD Economic Outlook. To measure the ideological composition of a government,

12

data are taken from Woldendorp, Keman and Budge (1993). This measure consists of a

five-point scale coded “1” for right-wing dominance (66.6 percent of cabinet ministries

and supporting seats in government controlled by parties of the right, “2” if right-wing

and center parties control between 33.3 and 66.6 percent, “3” if center parties control

over 50 percent of parliamentary and cabinet seats or if right-wing and left-wing parties

for a government together and neither dominates, “4” if the share of cabinet and

supporting parliamentary seats controlled by the left and center is between 33.3 and 66.6

percent, and “5” if left-wing parties control over two-thirds of all ministries and

supporting parliamentary seats. When governments change within a year, ideological

scores are weighted by the time in office.

The variable “Consensus” is a dummy variable indicating if a system is consensus

or majoritarian in nature. Coding is based on Lijphart and Crepaz’s (1991) measures

which, unfortunately are static and do not include measures for Spain, Greece and

Portugal. All three of these systems are coded as majoritarian, as Greece is clearly

majoritarian and Portugal is similar to the majoritarian French system. While Spain has

some consensus elements – proportional representation and federalism – it is also

characterized by highly disproportional PR and minimum-winning or single party

governments. “Aged Population” is a variable representing the proportion of the

population aged 65 or older, and data are taken from the United Nations (1996).

To measure the impact of the scarcity of the post-Maastricht era, the variable

“Squeeze” is operationalized as the government budget balance (i.e., surplus or deficit) as

a percentage of GDP and the time period indicator for when the Maastricht Treaty was

signed (to distinguish pre- and post-Maastricht deficits and surpluses). Hence, this

13

variable measures the deficit level relative to the 3% of GDP maximum mandated by the

Maastricht Treaty. As the entry criteria for the EMU specify a 3% maximum for deficits,

countries with higher deficits require austerity measures to meet this criterion and thus

experience more of a squeeze on domestic budgets and policy agendas.3

Based on our review of the literature, we expect more leftist governments, higher

levels of unemployment, consensus democracy, and a higher proportion of citizens age

65 or older to be associated with higher levels of social expenditures. Conversely, the

increased budgetary squeeze associated with the passage of the Maastricht Treaty is

expected to be negatively related to social expenditure levels.

Results

The results of our first empirical test – the determinants of social spending as a

percentage of GDP – our contained in Table 1 below.4 This analysis shows that

consensus democracy, unemployment, and the percentage of the population age 65 and

over all are associated with higher levels of social expenditures. These results are

consistent with our expectations based on the literature review above.

An interesting finding is shown for the role of government ideology. Our analysis

shows that more leftist governments are associated with lower levels of social spending

as a proportion of GDP. Based on this finding, it would appear that the priority that leftist

3 In order to ease interpretation of the empirical results, we multiplied the budget deficit figures with –1 so that higher positive numbers means a greater squeezing effect due to higher budget deficits. 4 Diagnostic tests revealed the presence of autocorrelation in our data, so the Cochrane-Orcutt method was used to correct this problem. In the tables shown below, corrected models are reported. Due to problems in obtaining complete data, Luxembourg was excluded from our empirical analysis.

14

governments place on social spending relative to the economy as a whole is actually

lower than that of governments of the center or the right. Thus, in the present era of the

“New Left” the spending priorities of leftist governments are even less generous than

their ideological competitors.

While not statistically significant, the “Squeeze” variable is in the expected

negative direction. Though we do not want to put much stock in an insignificant finding,

it is interesting to the note the negative impact of the post-Maastricht squeeze on social

spending. The direction of this coefficient does provide some evidence of a negative

impact on social expenditures resulting from the budget squeeze to meet entry criteria.

Turning to our second model, we see some interesting differences from Model 1.

Table 2 indicates that government ideology and unemployment are significantly and

positively related to social expenditures as a percentage of total expenditures. While in

Model 1 leftist governments were associated with lower expenditure levels, in this model

our results indicate that governments of the left tend to dedicate a greater share of total

expenditures to social spending than rightist or centrist governments.

The post-Maastricht “Squeeze” also exerts a significant influence on social

expenditures, and in the expected, negative direction. This result indicates that in the

post-Maastricht era of scarcity and external constraints, deficit pressures lead to a lower

proportion of total expenditures dedicated to social spending than the era prior to the

passage of the Maastricht Treaty.

Model 2 also reveals two somewhat surprising results as neither consensus

democracy nor the percentage of the population age 65 and over exerts a significant

impact on social expenditures as a percentage of total expenditures. Hence, in terms of

15

the priority given to social expenditures relative to expenditures in general, neither of

these variables influences outcomes. With regard to consensus democracies, the

variations between Model 1 and Model 2 may be attributable to the size of the economies

of these countries. Consensus systems tend to dominate the smaller nation-states of

Europe. As these countries tend to have smaller GDPs, the results in Model 1 may be

driven by differences in the size of the economies between consensus systems such as

Austria and Belgium and the larger majoritarian economies of the United Kingdom and

France.

The most interesting contrast between the two models concerns the role of

ideology on the two operationalizations of the dependent variable. While governments of

the left are associated with greater social expenditure levels as a percent of total social

expenditures, these same governments have lower levels of social expenditures relative to

GDP than governments of the center or right. What explains this apparent contrast?

Leftist governments seem to prioritize social spending at a higher level than other

types of public expenditures while assigning a lower priority to social spending as a

proportion of GDP. Strategically, social expenditures as a percentage of GDP may be an

issue more of interest to Brussels – showing a commitment to scaling back – while

domestically, dedicating a higher proportion of total spending to social spending may be

used as a way to placate concerns about welfare state cutbacks.

In addition, there is less transparency domestically in terms of GDP as???

Overall then, we see that only unemployment is statistically significant in a

consistent positive direction across both models. Given the high levels of unemployment

across the region and the constraints of EMU, governments of EU member-states are

16

faced with more rigidity than in the past. The commitment of resources to unemployment

compensation combined with the convergence criteria means that there is little room for

flexibility in other areas of social spending. Hence, constraints of budget priorities, both

domestic and external, have limited the spending agendas of governments.

Conclusions

Based on our findings, we can conclude that partisan ties do indeed still seem to

bind in the member-states of the European Union. However, the nature of these ties

varies according to the dependent variable under examination. In terms of social spending

as a percentage of GDP, leftist governments are negatively associated with social

spending. With regard to social spending as a proportion of total expenditures, though,

governments of the left appear to place a higher priority to social spending than

governments of the center and the right.

The implications of this finding for the citizens of Europe are still unclear. The

combination of left-leaning governments currently dominating member-states of the EU

would seem to indicate that social spending would maintain a high priority. However, the

influence of the post-Maastricht “Squeeze” variable mitigates this expectation somewhat

as the deficit squeeze following the Maastricht Treaty is negatively associated with social

spending in terms of total expenditures. Hence, these two factors appear to be moving in

opposite directions. Given the strict nature of the Maastricht criteria, it would seem likely

that flexibility will have to come at the expense of social expenditures.

Finally, it is important to note that these results are based on data from the period

leading up to the EMU and do not account for the most severe constraints. These

17

constraints became more profound in 1997 when entry criteria officially went into effect.

Hence, while our findings indicate a role for partisan ties, it would appear likely that the

external constraints found to be influential in Model 2 will become stronger in the future.

As a result, partisan ties may soon weaken. If this occurs, the increases in voter volatility

displayed in the 1990s (Bohrer and Tan 1999) can be expected to increase as parties are

unable to deliver on their electoral promises. As the present dilemma in Austria

illustrates, extremist political parties stand to benefit from such dissatisfaction.

18

Table 1: Determinants of Social Spending per GDP

_______________________________________________________________ _ Variable Estimated Coefficients ________________________________________________________________ _ Gov’t Ideology -0.28 ** (0.14) Consensus 6.60*** (0.81) Squeeze -0.027 (0.065) Unemployment 0.244*** (0.071) Aged population 0.76*** (0.19) Constant 8.01*** (2.89) R-squared 0.898 Adjusted R-squared 0.895 Durbin H-stat 1.35 N=187 ______________________________________________________________________ ***p<0.01; **p<0.05; * p<0.10 (one-tailed)

19

Table 2: Determinants of Social Spending as Percentage of Total Spending

____________________________________________________________________ Variable Estimated Coefficient ____________________________________________________________________ Gov’t Ideology 0.688*** (0.19) Consensus 0.074 (1.05) Squeeze -0.28*** (0.085) Unemployment 0.14** (0.083) Aged population 0.039 (0.26) Constant 44.75*** (3.98) R-squared 0.7849 Adjusted R-squared 0.778 Durbin H-stat 0.39 N=171 _____________________________________________________________________ ***p<0.01; **p<0.05; * p<0.10 (one-tailed)

20

References

Blais, Andre, Donald Blake and Stephane Dion. 1993. “Do Parties Make a Difference? Parties and the Size of Government in Liberal Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 37: 40-62. Bohrer, Robert E. II. Forthcoming. Decision Costs and Democracy: Trade-Offs in Institutional Design. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate Press Ltd. Bohrer, Robert E. II and Alexander C. Tan. 2000. “Left Turn in Europe? Reactions to Austerity and the EMU.” Political Research Quarterly 53: 575-595. Bohrer, Robert E. II and Alexander C. Tan. 1999. “The Impact of Scarcity in Europe: Shifting Allegiances and Volatile Electorates.” Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, April 15-18 (with Alexander Tan). Borrelli, Stephen A. and Terry J. Royed. 1995. “Government ‘Strength’ and Budget Deficits in Advanced Democracies.” European Journal of Political Research 28: 225-260. Budge, Ian and Hans Keman. 1990. Parties and Democracy: Coalition Formation and Functioning in Twenty States. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Cameron, David. 1978. “The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Perspective.” American Political Science Review 72: 1243-1261. Castles, Francis G. and Peter Mair 1984. “Left-Right Political Scales: Some ‘Expert’ Judgments.” European Journal of Political Research 12: 73-88. Crepaz, Markus M.L. 1996a. “Constitutional Structures and Regime Performance in 18 Industrialized Democracies: A Test of Olson’s Hypothesis.” European Journal of Political Research 29: 87-104. Crepaz, Markus M.L. 1996b. “Consensus versus Majoritarian Democracy: Political Institutions and Their Impact on Macroeconomic Performance and Industrial Disputes.” Comparative Political Studies 29: 4-26. Cusack, Thomas R. 1996. “Partisan Politics and Public Finance: Changes in Public Spending in the Industrial Democracies, 1955-1989.” Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco. Hahm, Sung Deuk. 1994. “Political Institutions and Fiscal Policy Outcomes in Japan,” Pacific Focus 9: 47-63. Huber, John and Ronald Inglehart. 1995. “Expert Interpretations of Party Space and Party Locations in 42 Societies.” Party Politics 1: 73-111.

21

Lewis-Beck, Michael and Rice, T. 1985. “Government Growth in the United States.” Journal of Politics 47: 2-30. Lijphart, Arend. 1984. Democracies: Patterns of Majoritarian and Consensus Government in Twenty-One Countries. New Haven: Yale University Press. Lijphart, Arend and Markus M.L. Crepaz. 1991. “Corporatism and Consensus Democracy in Eighteen Countries: Conceptual and Empirical Linkages.” British Journal of Political Science 21: 235-256. Lijphart, Arend. 1994. ”Democracies: Forms, Performance and Constitutional Engineering.” European Journal of Political Research 25: 1-17. OECD. 1999. Social Expenditure Database. Paris: OECD. OECD. Various years. Main Economic Indicators. OECD: Paris. Oxley, Howard and John P. Martin. 1991. “Controlling Government Spending and Deficits: Trends in the 1980s and Prospects for the 1990s.” OECD Economic Studies 17: 145-189. Popper, Karl R. 1988. “Popper on Democracy: The Open Society and its Enemies Revisited.” Economist, April 23. Rhodes, Martin. 1997. “The Welfare State: Internal Challenges, External Constraints.” In Developments in West European Politics, ed. Martin Rhodes, Paul Heywood and Vincent Wright. New York: St. Martin’s Press. Robertson, John D. and Sue W. Cutcomb. 1987. “Parliamentary Executive-Legislative Relations and the Implications of Cabinet Stability: ‘Ballast’ and ‘Energy’ in Macroeconomic Policy.” Western Political Quarterly 40: 7-27. Rotte, Ralph. 1998. “International Commitment and Domestic Politics: A Note on the Maastricht Case.” European Journal of International Relations 4: 131-142. Roubini, Nouriel and Jeffrey D. Sachs. 1989. “Political and Economic Determinants of Budget Deficits in the Industrial Democracies.” European Economic Review 33: 903-938. Stimson, James A. 1985. “Regression in Space and Time: A Statistical Essay.” American Journal of Political Science 29: 914-947. Woldendorp, Jaap, Hans Keman, and Ian Budge. 1993. “Political Data 1945-1990.” European Journal of Political Research 24: 1-120.


Recommended