+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

Nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

Date post: 05-Mar-2023
Category:
Upload: independent
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
17
Nitrate Pollution Control Under Soil Heterogeneity Yolanda Martínez a , Ben White b and José Albiac a,* a Centro de Investigación y Tecnología Agroalimentaria. Gobierno de Aragón. P.O.Box 727. 50080 Zaragoza. Spain. b School of Agricultural and Resource Economics. University of Western Australia. Crawley WA 6009. Australia. Abstract This article presents results on measures to abate corn nitrogen pollution when soil heterogeneity is considered. A dynamic economic model is used with control variables for both nitrogen fertilizer and irrigation water, which incorporates the influence of soils on corn production and nitrate leaching dynamics. The economic model yields the profit- maximizing nutrient and water management plans for three soil types in the Flumen- Monegros irrigation area of the Ebro basin in Spain. Several policy options to control nitrate leaching pollution in the area are examined; water taxes, nitrogen taxes, a standard on nitrogen fertilizer, and a nitrogen pollution discharge tax. These measures to abate nitrogen pollution are evaluated by their cost efficiency, and results show that a quantitative limit on applied fertilizer is the preferred second best measure, after the first best nitrogen emission tax. Differentiating control measures by soil type for corn enhances welfare, although welfare gains are small. Keywords: dynamic optimization, soil heterogeneity, nitrate pollution abatement, efficiency of measures by soil type. * Corresponding author. Tel.: +34 976716351. email: [email protected]
Transcript

Nitrate Pollution Control Under Soil Heterogeneity

Yolanda Martiacuteneza Ben Whiteb and Joseacute Albiaca

a Centro de Investigacioacuten y Tecnologiacutea Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten POBox 727 50080 Zaragoza Spain

b School of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of Western Australia Crawley WA 6009 Australia

Abstract

This article presents results on measures to abate corn nitrogen pollution when soil

heterogeneity is considered A dynamic economic model is used with control variables for

both nitrogen fertilizer and irrigation water which incorporates the influence of soils on

corn production and nitrate leaching dynamics The economic model yields the profit-

maximizing nutrient and water management plans for three soil types in the Flumen-

Monegros irrigation area of the Ebro basin in Spain Several policy options to control

nitrate leaching pollution in the area are examined water taxes nitrogen taxes a standard

on nitrogen fertilizer and a nitrogen pollution discharge tax These measures to abate

nitrogen pollution are evaluated by their cost efficiency and results show that a quantitative

limit on applied fertilizer is the preferred second best measure after the first best nitrogen

emission tax Differentiating control measures by soil type for corn enhances welfare

although welfare gains are small

Keywords dynamic optimization soil heterogeneity nitrate pollution abatement efficiency of measures by soil type Corresponding author Tel +34 976716351 email maellaunizares

2

1 Introduction

The twentieth century was a period of accelerated technological change and innovation

in agricultural production with large gains in productivity and expanded use of inputs such

industrial fertilizers and pesticides In developed countries these technological advances

coupled with agricultural policies supporting domestic agriculture were responsible for an

impressive increase in production and resulted finally in a problem of excess supply for

several agricultural commodities These high yield production technologies based on

intensive use of fertilizers and pesticides created also a severe problem of soil degradation

and water resources pollution The European Environment Agency identifies fertilizers and

pesticides as the first cause of water quality deterioration in many European Union

watersheds (EEA 1999)

In Spain agricultural mechanization in the nineteen sixties and the subsequent

introduction of high yield crop varieties led to a strong increase in the use of mineral

fertilizers between 1960 and 1990 leveling off in the last decade Average use of fertilizers

per hectare is well below other European countries around half the consumption in France

or Germany or a fifth of Netherlands However excessive fertilizer application is a

problem that generates nutrient pollution in some specific watersheds One important

problem in non-point source pollution is caused by nitrate fertilization in agricultural

activities These activities have negative effects on water quality and constitute a serious

risk to fluvial ecosystem habitats and species and to human health

The new Water Framework Directive enacted by the European Union defines the

mandatory objective of reaching ldquogood condition of waterrdquo over all waters The Directive

promotes water prices at full recovery costs including environmental costs Management

of water irrigation in Spain is going to acquire a key role as a consequence of this Directive

which establishes emission restrictions and quality standards management of water based

on watersheds and user participation and user water prices close to full costs The National

Hydrologic Plan approved by the Spanish Parliament in 2001 is going to be the

fundamental norm shaping water management and water quality in Spain In the

agricultural sector the Plan introduces measures to modernize irrigation and large water

transfers to the Southeast regions in order to solve the critical problems of overuse scarcity

and degradation of water resources This expansion of water supply through inter-basin

transfers to solve water scarcity and quality degradation has been severely criticized by

water experts (Albiac et al 2002 Hanemann 2003 Howitt 2003)

3

Nitrate pollution in Spain affects specially the Southeast Mediterranean coast and the

Ebro and Guadalquivir watersheds inside the country Nitrate loads depend on different

factors such as input use type of crops and soil characteristics The studies by Feijooacute et al

(2000) and Martiacutenez (2002) indicate the importance of considering these factors in

environmental policy analysis Cost efficient abatement of leaching emissions depends

critically on the correct evaluation of different pollution control measures Several studies

have examined the cost-efficiency of alternative measures for some crops corn (Yadav

1997 Vickner et al 1998) wheat and barley (Miettinen 1998 Schmid 2001) corn wheat

barley rice sunflower and alfalfa (Martiacutenez 2002) and cotton (Khanne et al 2000)

Ranking of measures is contingent not only upon crop type but also upon soils since the

effect of soils on the cost-efficiency of measures may be significant Information on these

effects is scarce and limited to corn and alfalfa with three soil classes (Thomas and Boisvert

1994) and lettuce with two soils (Helfand and House 1995)

This study analyzes the cost-efficiency of several policy instruments to curb nitrogen

pollution and the effects of soil heterogeneity on the cost-efficiency of measures This

procedure gives information on the robustness of cost-efficiency rankings when

instruments are applied to different soil types The policy instruments examined are water

use taxes nitrate use taxes fertilization limits and taxes on nitrate emissions An important

feature of this study is the use of optimal control techniques since nitrogen pollution is an

intertemporal process The dynamics of nitrogen pollution is driven by soil nitrogen

content which affects yields and nitrogen leaching throughout the planning horizon

2 Study area

The Flumen-Monegros irrigation district includes sixteen villages with important

irrigation agricultural activities The area has an extension of 77841 ha with 60000 ha

cultivated and 45898 ha (75) under irrigation (Table 1)

Table 1 Land use in the study area (ha)

Source DGA (1999)

Dryland Irrigated acreage Total district

Cultivated land 14250 45781 60031 Pastures 1418 0 1418 Forest 4924 117 5041 Other 11351 0 11351 Total acreage 31943 45898 77841

4

Table 2 Soil classification

Soil

Unit Series Productivity

Acreage (ha)

WHCa Efficiencyb ECc

AG0 Chacilla High 2478 1800 60 25 AG1 Planteros Low 7558 730 40 25 AG2 Corraletes Intermediate 17263 2043 60 80 AG3 Valfonda Low (high salinity) 4944 2680 80 120 AG4 Planteros Low (dryland) 691 1350 - 28

a Water-holding capacity (m3ha) b Irrigation efficiency () c Salinity (Electric conductivity dSm) Source Nogueacutes (2002)

The climate is semi-arid with insufficient rain throughout the entire year and clearly

irrigation is essential for agricultural production The water resources origin is the Gaacutellego

river through the Sotonera dam with 187 hm3 of capacity and the Cinca river through the

Cinca canal system Surface irrigation is the common irrigation system although sprinkle

irrigation is being introduced in some locations A map of soils from Noguumleacutes (2002) and

Noguumleacutes et al (1999) has been used so corn yield water and fertilizer application and

percolation and leaching can be differentiated by soil type The main crops in the zone are

winter cereals (barley and wheat) corn sunflower rice and alfalfa for which statistical data

are available on crop acreage (Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999) Another source on crop spatial

distribution is Casterad and Herrero (2003) and their procedure combines remote-sensing

information with estimations from field surveys Crop costs are published by MAPA

(2000) and other information has been collected on agronomic data and crop management

operations weather information and water management practices by irrigation user

associations

The physical and socio-economic characteristics of the irrigation district are described

in Martiacutenez (2002) Five soil types are identified in the district as defined by Noguumles (2002)

with the parameters shown in table 2 Corn is planted only in soils Chacilla (AG0)

Planteros (AG1) and Corraletes (AG2) and the analysis focus on these three soils which

cover 27300 ha Valfonda (AG3) and dryland Planteros (AG4) soils are not suitable for

corn cultivation because Valfonda is the most salt affected and Planteros (AG4) is dryland

Figure 1 shows corn location by soil type 1560 ha on Corraletes soils 1180 ha on Chacilla

and 490 ha on Planteros

Although there is not specific data about nitrate concentrations in the irrigation district

the RICA network (Water Quality Integrated Network) provides water quality data on

some adjacent locations that approximates the pollution emission levels Figure 2 shows

nitrate concentration in the River Flumen at Sarintildeena located at the end of the irrigation

5

Figure 2 Map of corn by soil type in the Flumen-Monegros irrigation district

Source Casterad and Herrero (2003)

6

Figure 2 Nitrate pollution from the irrigation district (1982-2002)

Flumen at Sarintildeena

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Period

Nit

rate

con

cent

rati

on m

gl

Source CHE (2003)

district The time series include 42 observations for the 1982-2002 period with one day

nitrate concentration measurements in January and September of each year These data

show that nitrate concentration levels throughout the period move between 15 and 30 mg

NO3l with extreme values reaching 35 and 10 mgl in some periods

3 Methodology

The study analyzes the effects of several pollution control policy measures on corn

crop in a dynamic context The economic model developed includes a pollution function

that allows to assess the importance of water pollution due to agricultural activities in the

Flumen-Monegros irrigation district of the Ebro Basin in Spain

Corn yield functions and nitrate pollution functions by soil type have been estimated

using the EPIC crop growth package (Mitchell et al 1998) incorporating local information

on climate soils and tillage and operation activities The procedure consist in generating

with the package yield and leaching data series for different levels of water and nitrogen

fertilization in order to estimate the yield and pollution functions The corn yield response

function and the pollution function are then used to define the dynamic model that is

driven by the control variables water and nitrogen fertilization The EPIC simulator has

been validated in the study area after calibration using survey information from farmers

7

and corn field experimental data on yields and nitrogen leaching (Saad and Quiacutelez 1998

Saad 1999)

31 Dynamic model

The problem is stated as the maximization of welfare from corn production and

welfare is the sum of corn quasi-rent and the damage cost of nitrogen leaching In absence

of nitrogen pollution measures farmers maximize the private corn quasi-rent selecting the

amount of nitrogen fertilizer and irrigation throughout the time planning horizon (t = 1hellip

T) subject to the dynamics of nitrogen content in the soil Under discrete time the model

is the following

[ ] sum=

sdotλminus+minusminusminussdot+

T

1tttntxtyt

nx)le()sknpxpyp(

)r1(1

Maxtt

[1]

subject to

tttttt uvlengg minusminusminus+=+1 [2]

The objective function has two components the first term in parenthesis is quasi-rent

and the second term λ let is the damage cost from nitrogen leaching The sum is social

welfare through the planning horizon from corn production activities The constraint

captures the dynamics of soil nitrogen content and is defined as the balance of nitrogen

entering and leaving the soil Quasi-rent is equal to revenue minus variable and fixed costs

of corn per hectare1 and nitrogen damage is defined as a linear function of leaching

The constraint equation [2] is the motion equation for nitrogen in soil or soil nitrogen

balance Soil nitrogen in period t+1 is equal to nitrogen in period t plus fertilization minus

leaching volatilization and nitrogen uptake by corn The inclusion of the stock of nitrogen

in the soil is a key feature in order to represent the dynamic relationships among time

periods In absence of intertemporal relations the nitrogen stock in the soil yields and

nitrogen leaching would be static and constant for all periods This dynamic aspect is

crucial to adequately represent the biophysic processes leading to nitrogen pollution

Corn yield and leaching are assumed to be quadratic functions of water applied

nitrogen fertilization and the stock of nitrogen in soil The corn yield function is defined as

1 Costs include direct and indirect expenditures costs from hired labor and machinery and amortization Water and nitrogen costs are shown separately in the objective function

8

Table 3 Estimated yield and pollution functions by soil type

Yield functions Pollution functions

Variable Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Chacilla Planteros CorraletesIntercept -4091

(324) -3946 (-223)

-278 (-731)

-16619 (-499)

-12859 (-1695)

-22184 (-1042)

Water (X) 00271 (1034)

00273 (809)

00349 (3855)

-00586 (-522)

0173 (959)

0293 (466)

Nitrogen (N) 00398 (1043)

00356 (222)

00252 (1704)

00079 (057)

00702 (134)

0134 (362)

N reserve (G) 00297 (2602)

00088 (121)

00054 (135)

0177 (122)

0660 (1694)

0659 (2338)

X2 -020110-4

(-812) -019910-4

(-101) -026910-4

(-3187) 096910-4

(927) 036210-5

(363) 013510-3

(719) N2 -056110-4

(-766) -048810-4

(-433) -033610-4

(-1317) 043410-4

(166) 023010-3

(398) 062510-3

(101) G2 -051310-4

(-189) -025410-4

(-109) -059710-4

(-044)

t-statistics shown in parentheses

2

652

432

210 ttttttt gagananaxaxaay ++++++= and the leaching function is defined as

tttttt gbnbnbxbxbble 52

432

210 +++++=

The variables are yt corn yield in metric tons per hectare (Tonsha) xt irrigation water

applied (m3ha) nt nitrogen fertilization (kgha) gt nitrogen stock in soil (kgha) let

nitrogen leaching (kgha) ut nitrogen uptake by corn (kgha) and vt is nitrogen

volatilization (kgha) Nitrogen uptake and volatilization are a proportion of yield

( tt yu sdot= γ ) and fertilization ( tt nv sdot= δ ) respectively The model parameters are p corn

price in eurokg px water price in eurom3 pn active nitrogen price in eurokg s direct subsidies in

euroha k fixed costs in euroha λ pollution cost in eurokg δ volatilization rate in kgha γ

nitrogen uptake rate in kgton r discount rate and g0 is the initial value of g The estimated

yield and pollution functions are shown in table 3

The optimal control problem include the control variables irrigation water and nitrogen

fertilizer and the state variable stock of nitrogen in soil which is driven by the equation of

motion This equation is an identity linking inputs and outputs of nitrogen in the soil

4 Results

The dynamic model is used to analyze the effects of different abatement measures to

control nitrate pollution and to rank their cost-efficiency The measures examined are

higher irrigation water prices nitrogen fertilizer taxes standards limiting nitrogen

9

Table 4 Results of alternative policy measures by soil type

Welfare (euroha)

Quasi-rent (euroha)

Yield (tonsha)

Water (m3ha)

Nitrogen (kgha)

Soil nitrogen content (kgha)

Leaching (kgha)

Chacilla soil Base Scenario 1400 1456 161 6588 2772 2984 454

006 eurom3 1111 1160 158 5711 2676 3009 402 Water price 009 eurom3 950 997 154 5181 2601 3028 378 09 eurokg 1319 1373 161 6537 2757 2934 441 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 1238 1290 160 6483 2740 2880 427

Nitrogen standard 1370 1404 155 5942 2500 2248 274 Emission tax 1454 1505 160 6440 2724 2831 415

Planteros soil Base Scenario 823 993 126 6569 3225 1589 1386

006 eurom3 535 699 123 5676 3126 1779 1332 Water price 009 eurom3 375 536 119 5146 3055 1914 1312 09 eurokg 747 898 125 6513 3056 1431 1235 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 676 809 123 6457 2879 1273 1085

Nitrogen standard 851 947 119 6345 2500 955 781 Emission tax 965 1077 121 6404 2667 1089 911

Corraletes soil Base Scenario 1008 1177 141 6159 3434 2346 1374

006 eurom3 731 899 139 5417 3391 2573 1366 Water price 009 eurom3 575 743 136 4961 3360 2742 1375 09 eurokg 944 1078 139 6136 3120 2013 1095 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 887 988 137 6114 2799 1688 821

Nitrogen standard 1064 1134 133 6094 2500 1396 574 Emission tax 1126 1189 132 6096 2420 1318 510

10

fertilization and pollution emissions taxes The model is run under these alternative

scenarios generating the time paths for variables yield input use nitrogen stock in soil and

leaching

First the steady-state solution for each soil type is generated under the base scenario of

present corn production conditions in the area and then the steady-state solution for the

different alternative control measures are generated Ranking of the pollution control

measures is based on these steady-state solutions comparing welfare quasi-rent and

nitrogen leaching for each soil and for the whole irrigation district

Table 4 shows the steady-state solution under the base scenario for welfare quasi-rent

corn yield input consumption soil nitrogen content and nitrogen leaching This optimal

solution differs from actual behavior of farmers which are using excessive quantities of

nitrogen and water as noted by Oruacutes et al (2000) The reason for this excessive application

is that farmers cover the risk of underapplying inputs in parts of the field (Helfand and

House 1995) Corn producers maximize quasi-rent and are aware of the effects of

production decisions on the nitrogen stock in the soil

The base scenario approximates the actual conditions in the area related to the initial

nitrogen stock in soil corn and input prices and costs and subsidies per hectare Nitrogen

pollution levels are higher for low (Planteros) and intermediate (Corraletes) productive

soils because fertilizer consumption is higher in these soils than in the more productive

soil (Chacilla) Nitrogen leaching reaches 336 tons for the whole Flumen irrigation district

which is the sum of 54 tons from Chacilla-type soil 68 tons from Planteros and 214 tons

from Corraletes (Table 5)

The first scenario simulates an increase in water prices from 001 to 006 and 009

eurom3 This price increase reduces water and fertilizer application per hectare in the three

soil categories but nitrate emissions show a slight decrease in Chacilla and Planteros soils

and none in Corraletes soil (Table 4) The emission reduction in Chacilla and Planteros

soils is only 8 kgha when water price reaches 009 eurom3 and there is no reduction in

Corraletes because of the high level of soil nitrogen content Cost to farmers from the first

scenario is very high because quasi-rent losses are between 280 and 300 euroha for the 006

eurom3 price and between 430 and 460 euroha for the 009 eurom3 price For the whole district a

rise in water price to 006 eurom3 abates emission by only 11 tons but reduces social welfare

by 091 million euro and a 009 eurom3 water price reduces leaching by 13 tons and reduces

social welfare by 143 million euro Taxing water prices is a very inefficient instrument to curb

nitrogen emissions

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

2

1 Introduction

The twentieth century was a period of accelerated technological change and innovation

in agricultural production with large gains in productivity and expanded use of inputs such

industrial fertilizers and pesticides In developed countries these technological advances

coupled with agricultural policies supporting domestic agriculture were responsible for an

impressive increase in production and resulted finally in a problem of excess supply for

several agricultural commodities These high yield production technologies based on

intensive use of fertilizers and pesticides created also a severe problem of soil degradation

and water resources pollution The European Environment Agency identifies fertilizers and

pesticides as the first cause of water quality deterioration in many European Union

watersheds (EEA 1999)

In Spain agricultural mechanization in the nineteen sixties and the subsequent

introduction of high yield crop varieties led to a strong increase in the use of mineral

fertilizers between 1960 and 1990 leveling off in the last decade Average use of fertilizers

per hectare is well below other European countries around half the consumption in France

or Germany or a fifth of Netherlands However excessive fertilizer application is a

problem that generates nutrient pollution in some specific watersheds One important

problem in non-point source pollution is caused by nitrate fertilization in agricultural

activities These activities have negative effects on water quality and constitute a serious

risk to fluvial ecosystem habitats and species and to human health

The new Water Framework Directive enacted by the European Union defines the

mandatory objective of reaching ldquogood condition of waterrdquo over all waters The Directive

promotes water prices at full recovery costs including environmental costs Management

of water irrigation in Spain is going to acquire a key role as a consequence of this Directive

which establishes emission restrictions and quality standards management of water based

on watersheds and user participation and user water prices close to full costs The National

Hydrologic Plan approved by the Spanish Parliament in 2001 is going to be the

fundamental norm shaping water management and water quality in Spain In the

agricultural sector the Plan introduces measures to modernize irrigation and large water

transfers to the Southeast regions in order to solve the critical problems of overuse scarcity

and degradation of water resources This expansion of water supply through inter-basin

transfers to solve water scarcity and quality degradation has been severely criticized by

water experts (Albiac et al 2002 Hanemann 2003 Howitt 2003)

3

Nitrate pollution in Spain affects specially the Southeast Mediterranean coast and the

Ebro and Guadalquivir watersheds inside the country Nitrate loads depend on different

factors such as input use type of crops and soil characteristics The studies by Feijooacute et al

(2000) and Martiacutenez (2002) indicate the importance of considering these factors in

environmental policy analysis Cost efficient abatement of leaching emissions depends

critically on the correct evaluation of different pollution control measures Several studies

have examined the cost-efficiency of alternative measures for some crops corn (Yadav

1997 Vickner et al 1998) wheat and barley (Miettinen 1998 Schmid 2001) corn wheat

barley rice sunflower and alfalfa (Martiacutenez 2002) and cotton (Khanne et al 2000)

Ranking of measures is contingent not only upon crop type but also upon soils since the

effect of soils on the cost-efficiency of measures may be significant Information on these

effects is scarce and limited to corn and alfalfa with three soil classes (Thomas and Boisvert

1994) and lettuce with two soils (Helfand and House 1995)

This study analyzes the cost-efficiency of several policy instruments to curb nitrogen

pollution and the effects of soil heterogeneity on the cost-efficiency of measures This

procedure gives information on the robustness of cost-efficiency rankings when

instruments are applied to different soil types The policy instruments examined are water

use taxes nitrate use taxes fertilization limits and taxes on nitrate emissions An important

feature of this study is the use of optimal control techniques since nitrogen pollution is an

intertemporal process The dynamics of nitrogen pollution is driven by soil nitrogen

content which affects yields and nitrogen leaching throughout the planning horizon

2 Study area

The Flumen-Monegros irrigation district includes sixteen villages with important

irrigation agricultural activities The area has an extension of 77841 ha with 60000 ha

cultivated and 45898 ha (75) under irrigation (Table 1)

Table 1 Land use in the study area (ha)

Source DGA (1999)

Dryland Irrigated acreage Total district

Cultivated land 14250 45781 60031 Pastures 1418 0 1418 Forest 4924 117 5041 Other 11351 0 11351 Total acreage 31943 45898 77841

4

Table 2 Soil classification

Soil

Unit Series Productivity

Acreage (ha)

WHCa Efficiencyb ECc

AG0 Chacilla High 2478 1800 60 25 AG1 Planteros Low 7558 730 40 25 AG2 Corraletes Intermediate 17263 2043 60 80 AG3 Valfonda Low (high salinity) 4944 2680 80 120 AG4 Planteros Low (dryland) 691 1350 - 28

a Water-holding capacity (m3ha) b Irrigation efficiency () c Salinity (Electric conductivity dSm) Source Nogueacutes (2002)

The climate is semi-arid with insufficient rain throughout the entire year and clearly

irrigation is essential for agricultural production The water resources origin is the Gaacutellego

river through the Sotonera dam with 187 hm3 of capacity and the Cinca river through the

Cinca canal system Surface irrigation is the common irrigation system although sprinkle

irrigation is being introduced in some locations A map of soils from Noguumleacutes (2002) and

Noguumleacutes et al (1999) has been used so corn yield water and fertilizer application and

percolation and leaching can be differentiated by soil type The main crops in the zone are

winter cereals (barley and wheat) corn sunflower rice and alfalfa for which statistical data

are available on crop acreage (Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999) Another source on crop spatial

distribution is Casterad and Herrero (2003) and their procedure combines remote-sensing

information with estimations from field surveys Crop costs are published by MAPA

(2000) and other information has been collected on agronomic data and crop management

operations weather information and water management practices by irrigation user

associations

The physical and socio-economic characteristics of the irrigation district are described

in Martiacutenez (2002) Five soil types are identified in the district as defined by Noguumles (2002)

with the parameters shown in table 2 Corn is planted only in soils Chacilla (AG0)

Planteros (AG1) and Corraletes (AG2) and the analysis focus on these three soils which

cover 27300 ha Valfonda (AG3) and dryland Planteros (AG4) soils are not suitable for

corn cultivation because Valfonda is the most salt affected and Planteros (AG4) is dryland

Figure 1 shows corn location by soil type 1560 ha on Corraletes soils 1180 ha on Chacilla

and 490 ha on Planteros

Although there is not specific data about nitrate concentrations in the irrigation district

the RICA network (Water Quality Integrated Network) provides water quality data on

some adjacent locations that approximates the pollution emission levels Figure 2 shows

nitrate concentration in the River Flumen at Sarintildeena located at the end of the irrigation

5

Figure 2 Map of corn by soil type in the Flumen-Monegros irrigation district

Source Casterad and Herrero (2003)

6

Figure 2 Nitrate pollution from the irrigation district (1982-2002)

Flumen at Sarintildeena

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Period

Nit

rate

con

cent

rati

on m

gl

Source CHE (2003)

district The time series include 42 observations for the 1982-2002 period with one day

nitrate concentration measurements in January and September of each year These data

show that nitrate concentration levels throughout the period move between 15 and 30 mg

NO3l with extreme values reaching 35 and 10 mgl in some periods

3 Methodology

The study analyzes the effects of several pollution control policy measures on corn

crop in a dynamic context The economic model developed includes a pollution function

that allows to assess the importance of water pollution due to agricultural activities in the

Flumen-Monegros irrigation district of the Ebro Basin in Spain

Corn yield functions and nitrate pollution functions by soil type have been estimated

using the EPIC crop growth package (Mitchell et al 1998) incorporating local information

on climate soils and tillage and operation activities The procedure consist in generating

with the package yield and leaching data series for different levels of water and nitrogen

fertilization in order to estimate the yield and pollution functions The corn yield response

function and the pollution function are then used to define the dynamic model that is

driven by the control variables water and nitrogen fertilization The EPIC simulator has

been validated in the study area after calibration using survey information from farmers

7

and corn field experimental data on yields and nitrogen leaching (Saad and Quiacutelez 1998

Saad 1999)

31 Dynamic model

The problem is stated as the maximization of welfare from corn production and

welfare is the sum of corn quasi-rent and the damage cost of nitrogen leaching In absence

of nitrogen pollution measures farmers maximize the private corn quasi-rent selecting the

amount of nitrogen fertilizer and irrigation throughout the time planning horizon (t = 1hellip

T) subject to the dynamics of nitrogen content in the soil Under discrete time the model

is the following

[ ] sum=

sdotλminus+minusminusminussdot+

T

1tttntxtyt

nx)le()sknpxpyp(

)r1(1

Maxtt

[1]

subject to

tttttt uvlengg minusminusminus+=+1 [2]

The objective function has two components the first term in parenthesis is quasi-rent

and the second term λ let is the damage cost from nitrogen leaching The sum is social

welfare through the planning horizon from corn production activities The constraint

captures the dynamics of soil nitrogen content and is defined as the balance of nitrogen

entering and leaving the soil Quasi-rent is equal to revenue minus variable and fixed costs

of corn per hectare1 and nitrogen damage is defined as a linear function of leaching

The constraint equation [2] is the motion equation for nitrogen in soil or soil nitrogen

balance Soil nitrogen in period t+1 is equal to nitrogen in period t plus fertilization minus

leaching volatilization and nitrogen uptake by corn The inclusion of the stock of nitrogen

in the soil is a key feature in order to represent the dynamic relationships among time

periods In absence of intertemporal relations the nitrogen stock in the soil yields and

nitrogen leaching would be static and constant for all periods This dynamic aspect is

crucial to adequately represent the biophysic processes leading to nitrogen pollution

Corn yield and leaching are assumed to be quadratic functions of water applied

nitrogen fertilization and the stock of nitrogen in soil The corn yield function is defined as

1 Costs include direct and indirect expenditures costs from hired labor and machinery and amortization Water and nitrogen costs are shown separately in the objective function

8

Table 3 Estimated yield and pollution functions by soil type

Yield functions Pollution functions

Variable Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Chacilla Planteros CorraletesIntercept -4091

(324) -3946 (-223)

-278 (-731)

-16619 (-499)

-12859 (-1695)

-22184 (-1042)

Water (X) 00271 (1034)

00273 (809)

00349 (3855)

-00586 (-522)

0173 (959)

0293 (466)

Nitrogen (N) 00398 (1043)

00356 (222)

00252 (1704)

00079 (057)

00702 (134)

0134 (362)

N reserve (G) 00297 (2602)

00088 (121)

00054 (135)

0177 (122)

0660 (1694)

0659 (2338)

X2 -020110-4

(-812) -019910-4

(-101) -026910-4

(-3187) 096910-4

(927) 036210-5

(363) 013510-3

(719) N2 -056110-4

(-766) -048810-4

(-433) -033610-4

(-1317) 043410-4

(166) 023010-3

(398) 062510-3

(101) G2 -051310-4

(-189) -025410-4

(-109) -059710-4

(-044)

t-statistics shown in parentheses

2

652

432

210 ttttttt gagananaxaxaay ++++++= and the leaching function is defined as

tttttt gbnbnbxbxbble 52

432

210 +++++=

The variables are yt corn yield in metric tons per hectare (Tonsha) xt irrigation water

applied (m3ha) nt nitrogen fertilization (kgha) gt nitrogen stock in soil (kgha) let

nitrogen leaching (kgha) ut nitrogen uptake by corn (kgha) and vt is nitrogen

volatilization (kgha) Nitrogen uptake and volatilization are a proportion of yield

( tt yu sdot= γ ) and fertilization ( tt nv sdot= δ ) respectively The model parameters are p corn

price in eurokg px water price in eurom3 pn active nitrogen price in eurokg s direct subsidies in

euroha k fixed costs in euroha λ pollution cost in eurokg δ volatilization rate in kgha γ

nitrogen uptake rate in kgton r discount rate and g0 is the initial value of g The estimated

yield and pollution functions are shown in table 3

The optimal control problem include the control variables irrigation water and nitrogen

fertilizer and the state variable stock of nitrogen in soil which is driven by the equation of

motion This equation is an identity linking inputs and outputs of nitrogen in the soil

4 Results

The dynamic model is used to analyze the effects of different abatement measures to

control nitrate pollution and to rank their cost-efficiency The measures examined are

higher irrigation water prices nitrogen fertilizer taxes standards limiting nitrogen

9

Table 4 Results of alternative policy measures by soil type

Welfare (euroha)

Quasi-rent (euroha)

Yield (tonsha)

Water (m3ha)

Nitrogen (kgha)

Soil nitrogen content (kgha)

Leaching (kgha)

Chacilla soil Base Scenario 1400 1456 161 6588 2772 2984 454

006 eurom3 1111 1160 158 5711 2676 3009 402 Water price 009 eurom3 950 997 154 5181 2601 3028 378 09 eurokg 1319 1373 161 6537 2757 2934 441 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 1238 1290 160 6483 2740 2880 427

Nitrogen standard 1370 1404 155 5942 2500 2248 274 Emission tax 1454 1505 160 6440 2724 2831 415

Planteros soil Base Scenario 823 993 126 6569 3225 1589 1386

006 eurom3 535 699 123 5676 3126 1779 1332 Water price 009 eurom3 375 536 119 5146 3055 1914 1312 09 eurokg 747 898 125 6513 3056 1431 1235 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 676 809 123 6457 2879 1273 1085

Nitrogen standard 851 947 119 6345 2500 955 781 Emission tax 965 1077 121 6404 2667 1089 911

Corraletes soil Base Scenario 1008 1177 141 6159 3434 2346 1374

006 eurom3 731 899 139 5417 3391 2573 1366 Water price 009 eurom3 575 743 136 4961 3360 2742 1375 09 eurokg 944 1078 139 6136 3120 2013 1095 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 887 988 137 6114 2799 1688 821

Nitrogen standard 1064 1134 133 6094 2500 1396 574 Emission tax 1126 1189 132 6096 2420 1318 510

10

fertilization and pollution emissions taxes The model is run under these alternative

scenarios generating the time paths for variables yield input use nitrogen stock in soil and

leaching

First the steady-state solution for each soil type is generated under the base scenario of

present corn production conditions in the area and then the steady-state solution for the

different alternative control measures are generated Ranking of the pollution control

measures is based on these steady-state solutions comparing welfare quasi-rent and

nitrogen leaching for each soil and for the whole irrigation district

Table 4 shows the steady-state solution under the base scenario for welfare quasi-rent

corn yield input consumption soil nitrogen content and nitrogen leaching This optimal

solution differs from actual behavior of farmers which are using excessive quantities of

nitrogen and water as noted by Oruacutes et al (2000) The reason for this excessive application

is that farmers cover the risk of underapplying inputs in parts of the field (Helfand and

House 1995) Corn producers maximize quasi-rent and are aware of the effects of

production decisions on the nitrogen stock in the soil

The base scenario approximates the actual conditions in the area related to the initial

nitrogen stock in soil corn and input prices and costs and subsidies per hectare Nitrogen

pollution levels are higher for low (Planteros) and intermediate (Corraletes) productive

soils because fertilizer consumption is higher in these soils than in the more productive

soil (Chacilla) Nitrogen leaching reaches 336 tons for the whole Flumen irrigation district

which is the sum of 54 tons from Chacilla-type soil 68 tons from Planteros and 214 tons

from Corraletes (Table 5)

The first scenario simulates an increase in water prices from 001 to 006 and 009

eurom3 This price increase reduces water and fertilizer application per hectare in the three

soil categories but nitrate emissions show a slight decrease in Chacilla and Planteros soils

and none in Corraletes soil (Table 4) The emission reduction in Chacilla and Planteros

soils is only 8 kgha when water price reaches 009 eurom3 and there is no reduction in

Corraletes because of the high level of soil nitrogen content Cost to farmers from the first

scenario is very high because quasi-rent losses are between 280 and 300 euroha for the 006

eurom3 price and between 430 and 460 euroha for the 009 eurom3 price For the whole district a

rise in water price to 006 eurom3 abates emission by only 11 tons but reduces social welfare

by 091 million euro and a 009 eurom3 water price reduces leaching by 13 tons and reduces

social welfare by 143 million euro Taxing water prices is a very inefficient instrument to curb

nitrogen emissions

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

3

Nitrate pollution in Spain affects specially the Southeast Mediterranean coast and the

Ebro and Guadalquivir watersheds inside the country Nitrate loads depend on different

factors such as input use type of crops and soil characteristics The studies by Feijooacute et al

(2000) and Martiacutenez (2002) indicate the importance of considering these factors in

environmental policy analysis Cost efficient abatement of leaching emissions depends

critically on the correct evaluation of different pollution control measures Several studies

have examined the cost-efficiency of alternative measures for some crops corn (Yadav

1997 Vickner et al 1998) wheat and barley (Miettinen 1998 Schmid 2001) corn wheat

barley rice sunflower and alfalfa (Martiacutenez 2002) and cotton (Khanne et al 2000)

Ranking of measures is contingent not only upon crop type but also upon soils since the

effect of soils on the cost-efficiency of measures may be significant Information on these

effects is scarce and limited to corn and alfalfa with three soil classes (Thomas and Boisvert

1994) and lettuce with two soils (Helfand and House 1995)

This study analyzes the cost-efficiency of several policy instruments to curb nitrogen

pollution and the effects of soil heterogeneity on the cost-efficiency of measures This

procedure gives information on the robustness of cost-efficiency rankings when

instruments are applied to different soil types The policy instruments examined are water

use taxes nitrate use taxes fertilization limits and taxes on nitrate emissions An important

feature of this study is the use of optimal control techniques since nitrogen pollution is an

intertemporal process The dynamics of nitrogen pollution is driven by soil nitrogen

content which affects yields and nitrogen leaching throughout the planning horizon

2 Study area

The Flumen-Monegros irrigation district includes sixteen villages with important

irrigation agricultural activities The area has an extension of 77841 ha with 60000 ha

cultivated and 45898 ha (75) under irrigation (Table 1)

Table 1 Land use in the study area (ha)

Source DGA (1999)

Dryland Irrigated acreage Total district

Cultivated land 14250 45781 60031 Pastures 1418 0 1418 Forest 4924 117 5041 Other 11351 0 11351 Total acreage 31943 45898 77841

4

Table 2 Soil classification

Soil

Unit Series Productivity

Acreage (ha)

WHCa Efficiencyb ECc

AG0 Chacilla High 2478 1800 60 25 AG1 Planteros Low 7558 730 40 25 AG2 Corraletes Intermediate 17263 2043 60 80 AG3 Valfonda Low (high salinity) 4944 2680 80 120 AG4 Planteros Low (dryland) 691 1350 - 28

a Water-holding capacity (m3ha) b Irrigation efficiency () c Salinity (Electric conductivity dSm) Source Nogueacutes (2002)

The climate is semi-arid with insufficient rain throughout the entire year and clearly

irrigation is essential for agricultural production The water resources origin is the Gaacutellego

river through the Sotonera dam with 187 hm3 of capacity and the Cinca river through the

Cinca canal system Surface irrigation is the common irrigation system although sprinkle

irrigation is being introduced in some locations A map of soils from Noguumleacutes (2002) and

Noguumleacutes et al (1999) has been used so corn yield water and fertilizer application and

percolation and leaching can be differentiated by soil type The main crops in the zone are

winter cereals (barley and wheat) corn sunflower rice and alfalfa for which statistical data

are available on crop acreage (Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999) Another source on crop spatial

distribution is Casterad and Herrero (2003) and their procedure combines remote-sensing

information with estimations from field surveys Crop costs are published by MAPA

(2000) and other information has been collected on agronomic data and crop management

operations weather information and water management practices by irrigation user

associations

The physical and socio-economic characteristics of the irrigation district are described

in Martiacutenez (2002) Five soil types are identified in the district as defined by Noguumles (2002)

with the parameters shown in table 2 Corn is planted only in soils Chacilla (AG0)

Planteros (AG1) and Corraletes (AG2) and the analysis focus on these three soils which

cover 27300 ha Valfonda (AG3) and dryland Planteros (AG4) soils are not suitable for

corn cultivation because Valfonda is the most salt affected and Planteros (AG4) is dryland

Figure 1 shows corn location by soil type 1560 ha on Corraletes soils 1180 ha on Chacilla

and 490 ha on Planteros

Although there is not specific data about nitrate concentrations in the irrigation district

the RICA network (Water Quality Integrated Network) provides water quality data on

some adjacent locations that approximates the pollution emission levels Figure 2 shows

nitrate concentration in the River Flumen at Sarintildeena located at the end of the irrigation

5

Figure 2 Map of corn by soil type in the Flumen-Monegros irrigation district

Source Casterad and Herrero (2003)

6

Figure 2 Nitrate pollution from the irrigation district (1982-2002)

Flumen at Sarintildeena

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Period

Nit

rate

con

cent

rati

on m

gl

Source CHE (2003)

district The time series include 42 observations for the 1982-2002 period with one day

nitrate concentration measurements in January and September of each year These data

show that nitrate concentration levels throughout the period move between 15 and 30 mg

NO3l with extreme values reaching 35 and 10 mgl in some periods

3 Methodology

The study analyzes the effects of several pollution control policy measures on corn

crop in a dynamic context The economic model developed includes a pollution function

that allows to assess the importance of water pollution due to agricultural activities in the

Flumen-Monegros irrigation district of the Ebro Basin in Spain

Corn yield functions and nitrate pollution functions by soil type have been estimated

using the EPIC crop growth package (Mitchell et al 1998) incorporating local information

on climate soils and tillage and operation activities The procedure consist in generating

with the package yield and leaching data series for different levels of water and nitrogen

fertilization in order to estimate the yield and pollution functions The corn yield response

function and the pollution function are then used to define the dynamic model that is

driven by the control variables water and nitrogen fertilization The EPIC simulator has

been validated in the study area after calibration using survey information from farmers

7

and corn field experimental data on yields and nitrogen leaching (Saad and Quiacutelez 1998

Saad 1999)

31 Dynamic model

The problem is stated as the maximization of welfare from corn production and

welfare is the sum of corn quasi-rent and the damage cost of nitrogen leaching In absence

of nitrogen pollution measures farmers maximize the private corn quasi-rent selecting the

amount of nitrogen fertilizer and irrigation throughout the time planning horizon (t = 1hellip

T) subject to the dynamics of nitrogen content in the soil Under discrete time the model

is the following

[ ] sum=

sdotλminus+minusminusminussdot+

T

1tttntxtyt

nx)le()sknpxpyp(

)r1(1

Maxtt

[1]

subject to

tttttt uvlengg minusminusminus+=+1 [2]

The objective function has two components the first term in parenthesis is quasi-rent

and the second term λ let is the damage cost from nitrogen leaching The sum is social

welfare through the planning horizon from corn production activities The constraint

captures the dynamics of soil nitrogen content and is defined as the balance of nitrogen

entering and leaving the soil Quasi-rent is equal to revenue minus variable and fixed costs

of corn per hectare1 and nitrogen damage is defined as a linear function of leaching

The constraint equation [2] is the motion equation for nitrogen in soil or soil nitrogen

balance Soil nitrogen in period t+1 is equal to nitrogen in period t plus fertilization minus

leaching volatilization and nitrogen uptake by corn The inclusion of the stock of nitrogen

in the soil is a key feature in order to represent the dynamic relationships among time

periods In absence of intertemporal relations the nitrogen stock in the soil yields and

nitrogen leaching would be static and constant for all periods This dynamic aspect is

crucial to adequately represent the biophysic processes leading to nitrogen pollution

Corn yield and leaching are assumed to be quadratic functions of water applied

nitrogen fertilization and the stock of nitrogen in soil The corn yield function is defined as

1 Costs include direct and indirect expenditures costs from hired labor and machinery and amortization Water and nitrogen costs are shown separately in the objective function

8

Table 3 Estimated yield and pollution functions by soil type

Yield functions Pollution functions

Variable Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Chacilla Planteros CorraletesIntercept -4091

(324) -3946 (-223)

-278 (-731)

-16619 (-499)

-12859 (-1695)

-22184 (-1042)

Water (X) 00271 (1034)

00273 (809)

00349 (3855)

-00586 (-522)

0173 (959)

0293 (466)

Nitrogen (N) 00398 (1043)

00356 (222)

00252 (1704)

00079 (057)

00702 (134)

0134 (362)

N reserve (G) 00297 (2602)

00088 (121)

00054 (135)

0177 (122)

0660 (1694)

0659 (2338)

X2 -020110-4

(-812) -019910-4

(-101) -026910-4

(-3187) 096910-4

(927) 036210-5

(363) 013510-3

(719) N2 -056110-4

(-766) -048810-4

(-433) -033610-4

(-1317) 043410-4

(166) 023010-3

(398) 062510-3

(101) G2 -051310-4

(-189) -025410-4

(-109) -059710-4

(-044)

t-statistics shown in parentheses

2

652

432

210 ttttttt gagananaxaxaay ++++++= and the leaching function is defined as

tttttt gbnbnbxbxbble 52

432

210 +++++=

The variables are yt corn yield in metric tons per hectare (Tonsha) xt irrigation water

applied (m3ha) nt nitrogen fertilization (kgha) gt nitrogen stock in soil (kgha) let

nitrogen leaching (kgha) ut nitrogen uptake by corn (kgha) and vt is nitrogen

volatilization (kgha) Nitrogen uptake and volatilization are a proportion of yield

( tt yu sdot= γ ) and fertilization ( tt nv sdot= δ ) respectively The model parameters are p corn

price in eurokg px water price in eurom3 pn active nitrogen price in eurokg s direct subsidies in

euroha k fixed costs in euroha λ pollution cost in eurokg δ volatilization rate in kgha γ

nitrogen uptake rate in kgton r discount rate and g0 is the initial value of g The estimated

yield and pollution functions are shown in table 3

The optimal control problem include the control variables irrigation water and nitrogen

fertilizer and the state variable stock of nitrogen in soil which is driven by the equation of

motion This equation is an identity linking inputs and outputs of nitrogen in the soil

4 Results

The dynamic model is used to analyze the effects of different abatement measures to

control nitrate pollution and to rank their cost-efficiency The measures examined are

higher irrigation water prices nitrogen fertilizer taxes standards limiting nitrogen

9

Table 4 Results of alternative policy measures by soil type

Welfare (euroha)

Quasi-rent (euroha)

Yield (tonsha)

Water (m3ha)

Nitrogen (kgha)

Soil nitrogen content (kgha)

Leaching (kgha)

Chacilla soil Base Scenario 1400 1456 161 6588 2772 2984 454

006 eurom3 1111 1160 158 5711 2676 3009 402 Water price 009 eurom3 950 997 154 5181 2601 3028 378 09 eurokg 1319 1373 161 6537 2757 2934 441 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 1238 1290 160 6483 2740 2880 427

Nitrogen standard 1370 1404 155 5942 2500 2248 274 Emission tax 1454 1505 160 6440 2724 2831 415

Planteros soil Base Scenario 823 993 126 6569 3225 1589 1386

006 eurom3 535 699 123 5676 3126 1779 1332 Water price 009 eurom3 375 536 119 5146 3055 1914 1312 09 eurokg 747 898 125 6513 3056 1431 1235 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 676 809 123 6457 2879 1273 1085

Nitrogen standard 851 947 119 6345 2500 955 781 Emission tax 965 1077 121 6404 2667 1089 911

Corraletes soil Base Scenario 1008 1177 141 6159 3434 2346 1374

006 eurom3 731 899 139 5417 3391 2573 1366 Water price 009 eurom3 575 743 136 4961 3360 2742 1375 09 eurokg 944 1078 139 6136 3120 2013 1095 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 887 988 137 6114 2799 1688 821

Nitrogen standard 1064 1134 133 6094 2500 1396 574 Emission tax 1126 1189 132 6096 2420 1318 510

10

fertilization and pollution emissions taxes The model is run under these alternative

scenarios generating the time paths for variables yield input use nitrogen stock in soil and

leaching

First the steady-state solution for each soil type is generated under the base scenario of

present corn production conditions in the area and then the steady-state solution for the

different alternative control measures are generated Ranking of the pollution control

measures is based on these steady-state solutions comparing welfare quasi-rent and

nitrogen leaching for each soil and for the whole irrigation district

Table 4 shows the steady-state solution under the base scenario for welfare quasi-rent

corn yield input consumption soil nitrogen content and nitrogen leaching This optimal

solution differs from actual behavior of farmers which are using excessive quantities of

nitrogen and water as noted by Oruacutes et al (2000) The reason for this excessive application

is that farmers cover the risk of underapplying inputs in parts of the field (Helfand and

House 1995) Corn producers maximize quasi-rent and are aware of the effects of

production decisions on the nitrogen stock in the soil

The base scenario approximates the actual conditions in the area related to the initial

nitrogen stock in soil corn and input prices and costs and subsidies per hectare Nitrogen

pollution levels are higher for low (Planteros) and intermediate (Corraletes) productive

soils because fertilizer consumption is higher in these soils than in the more productive

soil (Chacilla) Nitrogen leaching reaches 336 tons for the whole Flumen irrigation district

which is the sum of 54 tons from Chacilla-type soil 68 tons from Planteros and 214 tons

from Corraletes (Table 5)

The first scenario simulates an increase in water prices from 001 to 006 and 009

eurom3 This price increase reduces water and fertilizer application per hectare in the three

soil categories but nitrate emissions show a slight decrease in Chacilla and Planteros soils

and none in Corraletes soil (Table 4) The emission reduction in Chacilla and Planteros

soils is only 8 kgha when water price reaches 009 eurom3 and there is no reduction in

Corraletes because of the high level of soil nitrogen content Cost to farmers from the first

scenario is very high because quasi-rent losses are between 280 and 300 euroha for the 006

eurom3 price and between 430 and 460 euroha for the 009 eurom3 price For the whole district a

rise in water price to 006 eurom3 abates emission by only 11 tons but reduces social welfare

by 091 million euro and a 009 eurom3 water price reduces leaching by 13 tons and reduces

social welfare by 143 million euro Taxing water prices is a very inefficient instrument to curb

nitrogen emissions

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

4

Table 2 Soil classification

Soil

Unit Series Productivity

Acreage (ha)

WHCa Efficiencyb ECc

AG0 Chacilla High 2478 1800 60 25 AG1 Planteros Low 7558 730 40 25 AG2 Corraletes Intermediate 17263 2043 60 80 AG3 Valfonda Low (high salinity) 4944 2680 80 120 AG4 Planteros Low (dryland) 691 1350 - 28

a Water-holding capacity (m3ha) b Irrigation efficiency () c Salinity (Electric conductivity dSm) Source Nogueacutes (2002)

The climate is semi-arid with insufficient rain throughout the entire year and clearly

irrigation is essential for agricultural production The water resources origin is the Gaacutellego

river through the Sotonera dam with 187 hm3 of capacity and the Cinca river through the

Cinca canal system Surface irrigation is the common irrigation system although sprinkle

irrigation is being introduced in some locations A map of soils from Noguumleacutes (2002) and

Noguumleacutes et al (1999) has been used so corn yield water and fertilizer application and

percolation and leaching can be differentiated by soil type The main crops in the zone are

winter cereals (barley and wheat) corn sunflower rice and alfalfa for which statistical data

are available on crop acreage (Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999) Another source on crop spatial

distribution is Casterad and Herrero (2003) and their procedure combines remote-sensing

information with estimations from field surveys Crop costs are published by MAPA

(2000) and other information has been collected on agronomic data and crop management

operations weather information and water management practices by irrigation user

associations

The physical and socio-economic characteristics of the irrigation district are described

in Martiacutenez (2002) Five soil types are identified in the district as defined by Noguumles (2002)

with the parameters shown in table 2 Corn is planted only in soils Chacilla (AG0)

Planteros (AG1) and Corraletes (AG2) and the analysis focus on these three soils which

cover 27300 ha Valfonda (AG3) and dryland Planteros (AG4) soils are not suitable for

corn cultivation because Valfonda is the most salt affected and Planteros (AG4) is dryland

Figure 1 shows corn location by soil type 1560 ha on Corraletes soils 1180 ha on Chacilla

and 490 ha on Planteros

Although there is not specific data about nitrate concentrations in the irrigation district

the RICA network (Water Quality Integrated Network) provides water quality data on

some adjacent locations that approximates the pollution emission levels Figure 2 shows

nitrate concentration in the River Flumen at Sarintildeena located at the end of the irrigation

5

Figure 2 Map of corn by soil type in the Flumen-Monegros irrigation district

Source Casterad and Herrero (2003)

6

Figure 2 Nitrate pollution from the irrigation district (1982-2002)

Flumen at Sarintildeena

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Period

Nit

rate

con

cent

rati

on m

gl

Source CHE (2003)

district The time series include 42 observations for the 1982-2002 period with one day

nitrate concentration measurements in January and September of each year These data

show that nitrate concentration levels throughout the period move between 15 and 30 mg

NO3l with extreme values reaching 35 and 10 mgl in some periods

3 Methodology

The study analyzes the effects of several pollution control policy measures on corn

crop in a dynamic context The economic model developed includes a pollution function

that allows to assess the importance of water pollution due to agricultural activities in the

Flumen-Monegros irrigation district of the Ebro Basin in Spain

Corn yield functions and nitrate pollution functions by soil type have been estimated

using the EPIC crop growth package (Mitchell et al 1998) incorporating local information

on climate soils and tillage and operation activities The procedure consist in generating

with the package yield and leaching data series for different levels of water and nitrogen

fertilization in order to estimate the yield and pollution functions The corn yield response

function and the pollution function are then used to define the dynamic model that is

driven by the control variables water and nitrogen fertilization The EPIC simulator has

been validated in the study area after calibration using survey information from farmers

7

and corn field experimental data on yields and nitrogen leaching (Saad and Quiacutelez 1998

Saad 1999)

31 Dynamic model

The problem is stated as the maximization of welfare from corn production and

welfare is the sum of corn quasi-rent and the damage cost of nitrogen leaching In absence

of nitrogen pollution measures farmers maximize the private corn quasi-rent selecting the

amount of nitrogen fertilizer and irrigation throughout the time planning horizon (t = 1hellip

T) subject to the dynamics of nitrogen content in the soil Under discrete time the model

is the following

[ ] sum=

sdotλminus+minusminusminussdot+

T

1tttntxtyt

nx)le()sknpxpyp(

)r1(1

Maxtt

[1]

subject to

tttttt uvlengg minusminusminus+=+1 [2]

The objective function has two components the first term in parenthesis is quasi-rent

and the second term λ let is the damage cost from nitrogen leaching The sum is social

welfare through the planning horizon from corn production activities The constraint

captures the dynamics of soil nitrogen content and is defined as the balance of nitrogen

entering and leaving the soil Quasi-rent is equal to revenue minus variable and fixed costs

of corn per hectare1 and nitrogen damage is defined as a linear function of leaching

The constraint equation [2] is the motion equation for nitrogen in soil or soil nitrogen

balance Soil nitrogen in period t+1 is equal to nitrogen in period t plus fertilization minus

leaching volatilization and nitrogen uptake by corn The inclusion of the stock of nitrogen

in the soil is a key feature in order to represent the dynamic relationships among time

periods In absence of intertemporal relations the nitrogen stock in the soil yields and

nitrogen leaching would be static and constant for all periods This dynamic aspect is

crucial to adequately represent the biophysic processes leading to nitrogen pollution

Corn yield and leaching are assumed to be quadratic functions of water applied

nitrogen fertilization and the stock of nitrogen in soil The corn yield function is defined as

1 Costs include direct and indirect expenditures costs from hired labor and machinery and amortization Water and nitrogen costs are shown separately in the objective function

8

Table 3 Estimated yield and pollution functions by soil type

Yield functions Pollution functions

Variable Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Chacilla Planteros CorraletesIntercept -4091

(324) -3946 (-223)

-278 (-731)

-16619 (-499)

-12859 (-1695)

-22184 (-1042)

Water (X) 00271 (1034)

00273 (809)

00349 (3855)

-00586 (-522)

0173 (959)

0293 (466)

Nitrogen (N) 00398 (1043)

00356 (222)

00252 (1704)

00079 (057)

00702 (134)

0134 (362)

N reserve (G) 00297 (2602)

00088 (121)

00054 (135)

0177 (122)

0660 (1694)

0659 (2338)

X2 -020110-4

(-812) -019910-4

(-101) -026910-4

(-3187) 096910-4

(927) 036210-5

(363) 013510-3

(719) N2 -056110-4

(-766) -048810-4

(-433) -033610-4

(-1317) 043410-4

(166) 023010-3

(398) 062510-3

(101) G2 -051310-4

(-189) -025410-4

(-109) -059710-4

(-044)

t-statistics shown in parentheses

2

652

432

210 ttttttt gagananaxaxaay ++++++= and the leaching function is defined as

tttttt gbnbnbxbxbble 52

432

210 +++++=

The variables are yt corn yield in metric tons per hectare (Tonsha) xt irrigation water

applied (m3ha) nt nitrogen fertilization (kgha) gt nitrogen stock in soil (kgha) let

nitrogen leaching (kgha) ut nitrogen uptake by corn (kgha) and vt is nitrogen

volatilization (kgha) Nitrogen uptake and volatilization are a proportion of yield

( tt yu sdot= γ ) and fertilization ( tt nv sdot= δ ) respectively The model parameters are p corn

price in eurokg px water price in eurom3 pn active nitrogen price in eurokg s direct subsidies in

euroha k fixed costs in euroha λ pollution cost in eurokg δ volatilization rate in kgha γ

nitrogen uptake rate in kgton r discount rate and g0 is the initial value of g The estimated

yield and pollution functions are shown in table 3

The optimal control problem include the control variables irrigation water and nitrogen

fertilizer and the state variable stock of nitrogen in soil which is driven by the equation of

motion This equation is an identity linking inputs and outputs of nitrogen in the soil

4 Results

The dynamic model is used to analyze the effects of different abatement measures to

control nitrate pollution and to rank their cost-efficiency The measures examined are

higher irrigation water prices nitrogen fertilizer taxes standards limiting nitrogen

9

Table 4 Results of alternative policy measures by soil type

Welfare (euroha)

Quasi-rent (euroha)

Yield (tonsha)

Water (m3ha)

Nitrogen (kgha)

Soil nitrogen content (kgha)

Leaching (kgha)

Chacilla soil Base Scenario 1400 1456 161 6588 2772 2984 454

006 eurom3 1111 1160 158 5711 2676 3009 402 Water price 009 eurom3 950 997 154 5181 2601 3028 378 09 eurokg 1319 1373 161 6537 2757 2934 441 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 1238 1290 160 6483 2740 2880 427

Nitrogen standard 1370 1404 155 5942 2500 2248 274 Emission tax 1454 1505 160 6440 2724 2831 415

Planteros soil Base Scenario 823 993 126 6569 3225 1589 1386

006 eurom3 535 699 123 5676 3126 1779 1332 Water price 009 eurom3 375 536 119 5146 3055 1914 1312 09 eurokg 747 898 125 6513 3056 1431 1235 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 676 809 123 6457 2879 1273 1085

Nitrogen standard 851 947 119 6345 2500 955 781 Emission tax 965 1077 121 6404 2667 1089 911

Corraletes soil Base Scenario 1008 1177 141 6159 3434 2346 1374

006 eurom3 731 899 139 5417 3391 2573 1366 Water price 009 eurom3 575 743 136 4961 3360 2742 1375 09 eurokg 944 1078 139 6136 3120 2013 1095 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 887 988 137 6114 2799 1688 821

Nitrogen standard 1064 1134 133 6094 2500 1396 574 Emission tax 1126 1189 132 6096 2420 1318 510

10

fertilization and pollution emissions taxes The model is run under these alternative

scenarios generating the time paths for variables yield input use nitrogen stock in soil and

leaching

First the steady-state solution for each soil type is generated under the base scenario of

present corn production conditions in the area and then the steady-state solution for the

different alternative control measures are generated Ranking of the pollution control

measures is based on these steady-state solutions comparing welfare quasi-rent and

nitrogen leaching for each soil and for the whole irrigation district

Table 4 shows the steady-state solution under the base scenario for welfare quasi-rent

corn yield input consumption soil nitrogen content and nitrogen leaching This optimal

solution differs from actual behavior of farmers which are using excessive quantities of

nitrogen and water as noted by Oruacutes et al (2000) The reason for this excessive application

is that farmers cover the risk of underapplying inputs in parts of the field (Helfand and

House 1995) Corn producers maximize quasi-rent and are aware of the effects of

production decisions on the nitrogen stock in the soil

The base scenario approximates the actual conditions in the area related to the initial

nitrogen stock in soil corn and input prices and costs and subsidies per hectare Nitrogen

pollution levels are higher for low (Planteros) and intermediate (Corraletes) productive

soils because fertilizer consumption is higher in these soils than in the more productive

soil (Chacilla) Nitrogen leaching reaches 336 tons for the whole Flumen irrigation district

which is the sum of 54 tons from Chacilla-type soil 68 tons from Planteros and 214 tons

from Corraletes (Table 5)

The first scenario simulates an increase in water prices from 001 to 006 and 009

eurom3 This price increase reduces water and fertilizer application per hectare in the three

soil categories but nitrate emissions show a slight decrease in Chacilla and Planteros soils

and none in Corraletes soil (Table 4) The emission reduction in Chacilla and Planteros

soils is only 8 kgha when water price reaches 009 eurom3 and there is no reduction in

Corraletes because of the high level of soil nitrogen content Cost to farmers from the first

scenario is very high because quasi-rent losses are between 280 and 300 euroha for the 006

eurom3 price and between 430 and 460 euroha for the 009 eurom3 price For the whole district a

rise in water price to 006 eurom3 abates emission by only 11 tons but reduces social welfare

by 091 million euro and a 009 eurom3 water price reduces leaching by 13 tons and reduces

social welfare by 143 million euro Taxing water prices is a very inefficient instrument to curb

nitrogen emissions

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

5

Figure 2 Map of corn by soil type in the Flumen-Monegros irrigation district

Source Casterad and Herrero (2003)

6

Figure 2 Nitrate pollution from the irrigation district (1982-2002)

Flumen at Sarintildeena

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Period

Nit

rate

con

cent

rati

on m

gl

Source CHE (2003)

district The time series include 42 observations for the 1982-2002 period with one day

nitrate concentration measurements in January and September of each year These data

show that nitrate concentration levels throughout the period move between 15 and 30 mg

NO3l with extreme values reaching 35 and 10 mgl in some periods

3 Methodology

The study analyzes the effects of several pollution control policy measures on corn

crop in a dynamic context The economic model developed includes a pollution function

that allows to assess the importance of water pollution due to agricultural activities in the

Flumen-Monegros irrigation district of the Ebro Basin in Spain

Corn yield functions and nitrate pollution functions by soil type have been estimated

using the EPIC crop growth package (Mitchell et al 1998) incorporating local information

on climate soils and tillage and operation activities The procedure consist in generating

with the package yield and leaching data series for different levels of water and nitrogen

fertilization in order to estimate the yield and pollution functions The corn yield response

function and the pollution function are then used to define the dynamic model that is

driven by the control variables water and nitrogen fertilization The EPIC simulator has

been validated in the study area after calibration using survey information from farmers

7

and corn field experimental data on yields and nitrogen leaching (Saad and Quiacutelez 1998

Saad 1999)

31 Dynamic model

The problem is stated as the maximization of welfare from corn production and

welfare is the sum of corn quasi-rent and the damage cost of nitrogen leaching In absence

of nitrogen pollution measures farmers maximize the private corn quasi-rent selecting the

amount of nitrogen fertilizer and irrigation throughout the time planning horizon (t = 1hellip

T) subject to the dynamics of nitrogen content in the soil Under discrete time the model

is the following

[ ] sum=

sdotλminus+minusminusminussdot+

T

1tttntxtyt

nx)le()sknpxpyp(

)r1(1

Maxtt

[1]

subject to

tttttt uvlengg minusminusminus+=+1 [2]

The objective function has two components the first term in parenthesis is quasi-rent

and the second term λ let is the damage cost from nitrogen leaching The sum is social

welfare through the planning horizon from corn production activities The constraint

captures the dynamics of soil nitrogen content and is defined as the balance of nitrogen

entering and leaving the soil Quasi-rent is equal to revenue minus variable and fixed costs

of corn per hectare1 and nitrogen damage is defined as a linear function of leaching

The constraint equation [2] is the motion equation for nitrogen in soil or soil nitrogen

balance Soil nitrogen in period t+1 is equal to nitrogen in period t plus fertilization minus

leaching volatilization and nitrogen uptake by corn The inclusion of the stock of nitrogen

in the soil is a key feature in order to represent the dynamic relationships among time

periods In absence of intertemporal relations the nitrogen stock in the soil yields and

nitrogen leaching would be static and constant for all periods This dynamic aspect is

crucial to adequately represent the biophysic processes leading to nitrogen pollution

Corn yield and leaching are assumed to be quadratic functions of water applied

nitrogen fertilization and the stock of nitrogen in soil The corn yield function is defined as

1 Costs include direct and indirect expenditures costs from hired labor and machinery and amortization Water and nitrogen costs are shown separately in the objective function

8

Table 3 Estimated yield and pollution functions by soil type

Yield functions Pollution functions

Variable Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Chacilla Planteros CorraletesIntercept -4091

(324) -3946 (-223)

-278 (-731)

-16619 (-499)

-12859 (-1695)

-22184 (-1042)

Water (X) 00271 (1034)

00273 (809)

00349 (3855)

-00586 (-522)

0173 (959)

0293 (466)

Nitrogen (N) 00398 (1043)

00356 (222)

00252 (1704)

00079 (057)

00702 (134)

0134 (362)

N reserve (G) 00297 (2602)

00088 (121)

00054 (135)

0177 (122)

0660 (1694)

0659 (2338)

X2 -020110-4

(-812) -019910-4

(-101) -026910-4

(-3187) 096910-4

(927) 036210-5

(363) 013510-3

(719) N2 -056110-4

(-766) -048810-4

(-433) -033610-4

(-1317) 043410-4

(166) 023010-3

(398) 062510-3

(101) G2 -051310-4

(-189) -025410-4

(-109) -059710-4

(-044)

t-statistics shown in parentheses

2

652

432

210 ttttttt gagananaxaxaay ++++++= and the leaching function is defined as

tttttt gbnbnbxbxbble 52

432

210 +++++=

The variables are yt corn yield in metric tons per hectare (Tonsha) xt irrigation water

applied (m3ha) nt nitrogen fertilization (kgha) gt nitrogen stock in soil (kgha) let

nitrogen leaching (kgha) ut nitrogen uptake by corn (kgha) and vt is nitrogen

volatilization (kgha) Nitrogen uptake and volatilization are a proportion of yield

( tt yu sdot= γ ) and fertilization ( tt nv sdot= δ ) respectively The model parameters are p corn

price in eurokg px water price in eurom3 pn active nitrogen price in eurokg s direct subsidies in

euroha k fixed costs in euroha λ pollution cost in eurokg δ volatilization rate in kgha γ

nitrogen uptake rate in kgton r discount rate and g0 is the initial value of g The estimated

yield and pollution functions are shown in table 3

The optimal control problem include the control variables irrigation water and nitrogen

fertilizer and the state variable stock of nitrogen in soil which is driven by the equation of

motion This equation is an identity linking inputs and outputs of nitrogen in the soil

4 Results

The dynamic model is used to analyze the effects of different abatement measures to

control nitrate pollution and to rank their cost-efficiency The measures examined are

higher irrigation water prices nitrogen fertilizer taxes standards limiting nitrogen

9

Table 4 Results of alternative policy measures by soil type

Welfare (euroha)

Quasi-rent (euroha)

Yield (tonsha)

Water (m3ha)

Nitrogen (kgha)

Soil nitrogen content (kgha)

Leaching (kgha)

Chacilla soil Base Scenario 1400 1456 161 6588 2772 2984 454

006 eurom3 1111 1160 158 5711 2676 3009 402 Water price 009 eurom3 950 997 154 5181 2601 3028 378 09 eurokg 1319 1373 161 6537 2757 2934 441 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 1238 1290 160 6483 2740 2880 427

Nitrogen standard 1370 1404 155 5942 2500 2248 274 Emission tax 1454 1505 160 6440 2724 2831 415

Planteros soil Base Scenario 823 993 126 6569 3225 1589 1386

006 eurom3 535 699 123 5676 3126 1779 1332 Water price 009 eurom3 375 536 119 5146 3055 1914 1312 09 eurokg 747 898 125 6513 3056 1431 1235 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 676 809 123 6457 2879 1273 1085

Nitrogen standard 851 947 119 6345 2500 955 781 Emission tax 965 1077 121 6404 2667 1089 911

Corraletes soil Base Scenario 1008 1177 141 6159 3434 2346 1374

006 eurom3 731 899 139 5417 3391 2573 1366 Water price 009 eurom3 575 743 136 4961 3360 2742 1375 09 eurokg 944 1078 139 6136 3120 2013 1095 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 887 988 137 6114 2799 1688 821

Nitrogen standard 1064 1134 133 6094 2500 1396 574 Emission tax 1126 1189 132 6096 2420 1318 510

10

fertilization and pollution emissions taxes The model is run under these alternative

scenarios generating the time paths for variables yield input use nitrogen stock in soil and

leaching

First the steady-state solution for each soil type is generated under the base scenario of

present corn production conditions in the area and then the steady-state solution for the

different alternative control measures are generated Ranking of the pollution control

measures is based on these steady-state solutions comparing welfare quasi-rent and

nitrogen leaching for each soil and for the whole irrigation district

Table 4 shows the steady-state solution under the base scenario for welfare quasi-rent

corn yield input consumption soil nitrogen content and nitrogen leaching This optimal

solution differs from actual behavior of farmers which are using excessive quantities of

nitrogen and water as noted by Oruacutes et al (2000) The reason for this excessive application

is that farmers cover the risk of underapplying inputs in parts of the field (Helfand and

House 1995) Corn producers maximize quasi-rent and are aware of the effects of

production decisions on the nitrogen stock in the soil

The base scenario approximates the actual conditions in the area related to the initial

nitrogen stock in soil corn and input prices and costs and subsidies per hectare Nitrogen

pollution levels are higher for low (Planteros) and intermediate (Corraletes) productive

soils because fertilizer consumption is higher in these soils than in the more productive

soil (Chacilla) Nitrogen leaching reaches 336 tons for the whole Flumen irrigation district

which is the sum of 54 tons from Chacilla-type soil 68 tons from Planteros and 214 tons

from Corraletes (Table 5)

The first scenario simulates an increase in water prices from 001 to 006 and 009

eurom3 This price increase reduces water and fertilizer application per hectare in the three

soil categories but nitrate emissions show a slight decrease in Chacilla and Planteros soils

and none in Corraletes soil (Table 4) The emission reduction in Chacilla and Planteros

soils is only 8 kgha when water price reaches 009 eurom3 and there is no reduction in

Corraletes because of the high level of soil nitrogen content Cost to farmers from the first

scenario is very high because quasi-rent losses are between 280 and 300 euroha for the 006

eurom3 price and between 430 and 460 euroha for the 009 eurom3 price For the whole district a

rise in water price to 006 eurom3 abates emission by only 11 tons but reduces social welfare

by 091 million euro and a 009 eurom3 water price reduces leaching by 13 tons and reduces

social welfare by 143 million euro Taxing water prices is a very inefficient instrument to curb

nitrogen emissions

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

6

Figure 2 Nitrate pollution from the irrigation district (1982-2002)

Flumen at Sarintildeena

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

Period

Nit

rate

con

cent

rati

on m

gl

Source CHE (2003)

district The time series include 42 observations for the 1982-2002 period with one day

nitrate concentration measurements in January and September of each year These data

show that nitrate concentration levels throughout the period move between 15 and 30 mg

NO3l with extreme values reaching 35 and 10 mgl in some periods

3 Methodology

The study analyzes the effects of several pollution control policy measures on corn

crop in a dynamic context The economic model developed includes a pollution function

that allows to assess the importance of water pollution due to agricultural activities in the

Flumen-Monegros irrigation district of the Ebro Basin in Spain

Corn yield functions and nitrate pollution functions by soil type have been estimated

using the EPIC crop growth package (Mitchell et al 1998) incorporating local information

on climate soils and tillage and operation activities The procedure consist in generating

with the package yield and leaching data series for different levels of water and nitrogen

fertilization in order to estimate the yield and pollution functions The corn yield response

function and the pollution function are then used to define the dynamic model that is

driven by the control variables water and nitrogen fertilization The EPIC simulator has

been validated in the study area after calibration using survey information from farmers

7

and corn field experimental data on yields and nitrogen leaching (Saad and Quiacutelez 1998

Saad 1999)

31 Dynamic model

The problem is stated as the maximization of welfare from corn production and

welfare is the sum of corn quasi-rent and the damage cost of nitrogen leaching In absence

of nitrogen pollution measures farmers maximize the private corn quasi-rent selecting the

amount of nitrogen fertilizer and irrigation throughout the time planning horizon (t = 1hellip

T) subject to the dynamics of nitrogen content in the soil Under discrete time the model

is the following

[ ] sum=

sdotλminus+minusminusminussdot+

T

1tttntxtyt

nx)le()sknpxpyp(

)r1(1

Maxtt

[1]

subject to

tttttt uvlengg minusminusminus+=+1 [2]

The objective function has two components the first term in parenthesis is quasi-rent

and the second term λ let is the damage cost from nitrogen leaching The sum is social

welfare through the planning horizon from corn production activities The constraint

captures the dynamics of soil nitrogen content and is defined as the balance of nitrogen

entering and leaving the soil Quasi-rent is equal to revenue minus variable and fixed costs

of corn per hectare1 and nitrogen damage is defined as a linear function of leaching

The constraint equation [2] is the motion equation for nitrogen in soil or soil nitrogen

balance Soil nitrogen in period t+1 is equal to nitrogen in period t plus fertilization minus

leaching volatilization and nitrogen uptake by corn The inclusion of the stock of nitrogen

in the soil is a key feature in order to represent the dynamic relationships among time

periods In absence of intertemporal relations the nitrogen stock in the soil yields and

nitrogen leaching would be static and constant for all periods This dynamic aspect is

crucial to adequately represent the biophysic processes leading to nitrogen pollution

Corn yield and leaching are assumed to be quadratic functions of water applied

nitrogen fertilization and the stock of nitrogen in soil The corn yield function is defined as

1 Costs include direct and indirect expenditures costs from hired labor and machinery and amortization Water and nitrogen costs are shown separately in the objective function

8

Table 3 Estimated yield and pollution functions by soil type

Yield functions Pollution functions

Variable Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Chacilla Planteros CorraletesIntercept -4091

(324) -3946 (-223)

-278 (-731)

-16619 (-499)

-12859 (-1695)

-22184 (-1042)

Water (X) 00271 (1034)

00273 (809)

00349 (3855)

-00586 (-522)

0173 (959)

0293 (466)

Nitrogen (N) 00398 (1043)

00356 (222)

00252 (1704)

00079 (057)

00702 (134)

0134 (362)

N reserve (G) 00297 (2602)

00088 (121)

00054 (135)

0177 (122)

0660 (1694)

0659 (2338)

X2 -020110-4

(-812) -019910-4

(-101) -026910-4

(-3187) 096910-4

(927) 036210-5

(363) 013510-3

(719) N2 -056110-4

(-766) -048810-4

(-433) -033610-4

(-1317) 043410-4

(166) 023010-3

(398) 062510-3

(101) G2 -051310-4

(-189) -025410-4

(-109) -059710-4

(-044)

t-statistics shown in parentheses

2

652

432

210 ttttttt gagananaxaxaay ++++++= and the leaching function is defined as

tttttt gbnbnbxbxbble 52

432

210 +++++=

The variables are yt corn yield in metric tons per hectare (Tonsha) xt irrigation water

applied (m3ha) nt nitrogen fertilization (kgha) gt nitrogen stock in soil (kgha) let

nitrogen leaching (kgha) ut nitrogen uptake by corn (kgha) and vt is nitrogen

volatilization (kgha) Nitrogen uptake and volatilization are a proportion of yield

( tt yu sdot= γ ) and fertilization ( tt nv sdot= δ ) respectively The model parameters are p corn

price in eurokg px water price in eurom3 pn active nitrogen price in eurokg s direct subsidies in

euroha k fixed costs in euroha λ pollution cost in eurokg δ volatilization rate in kgha γ

nitrogen uptake rate in kgton r discount rate and g0 is the initial value of g The estimated

yield and pollution functions are shown in table 3

The optimal control problem include the control variables irrigation water and nitrogen

fertilizer and the state variable stock of nitrogen in soil which is driven by the equation of

motion This equation is an identity linking inputs and outputs of nitrogen in the soil

4 Results

The dynamic model is used to analyze the effects of different abatement measures to

control nitrate pollution and to rank their cost-efficiency The measures examined are

higher irrigation water prices nitrogen fertilizer taxes standards limiting nitrogen

9

Table 4 Results of alternative policy measures by soil type

Welfare (euroha)

Quasi-rent (euroha)

Yield (tonsha)

Water (m3ha)

Nitrogen (kgha)

Soil nitrogen content (kgha)

Leaching (kgha)

Chacilla soil Base Scenario 1400 1456 161 6588 2772 2984 454

006 eurom3 1111 1160 158 5711 2676 3009 402 Water price 009 eurom3 950 997 154 5181 2601 3028 378 09 eurokg 1319 1373 161 6537 2757 2934 441 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 1238 1290 160 6483 2740 2880 427

Nitrogen standard 1370 1404 155 5942 2500 2248 274 Emission tax 1454 1505 160 6440 2724 2831 415

Planteros soil Base Scenario 823 993 126 6569 3225 1589 1386

006 eurom3 535 699 123 5676 3126 1779 1332 Water price 009 eurom3 375 536 119 5146 3055 1914 1312 09 eurokg 747 898 125 6513 3056 1431 1235 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 676 809 123 6457 2879 1273 1085

Nitrogen standard 851 947 119 6345 2500 955 781 Emission tax 965 1077 121 6404 2667 1089 911

Corraletes soil Base Scenario 1008 1177 141 6159 3434 2346 1374

006 eurom3 731 899 139 5417 3391 2573 1366 Water price 009 eurom3 575 743 136 4961 3360 2742 1375 09 eurokg 944 1078 139 6136 3120 2013 1095 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 887 988 137 6114 2799 1688 821

Nitrogen standard 1064 1134 133 6094 2500 1396 574 Emission tax 1126 1189 132 6096 2420 1318 510

10

fertilization and pollution emissions taxes The model is run under these alternative

scenarios generating the time paths for variables yield input use nitrogen stock in soil and

leaching

First the steady-state solution for each soil type is generated under the base scenario of

present corn production conditions in the area and then the steady-state solution for the

different alternative control measures are generated Ranking of the pollution control

measures is based on these steady-state solutions comparing welfare quasi-rent and

nitrogen leaching for each soil and for the whole irrigation district

Table 4 shows the steady-state solution under the base scenario for welfare quasi-rent

corn yield input consumption soil nitrogen content and nitrogen leaching This optimal

solution differs from actual behavior of farmers which are using excessive quantities of

nitrogen and water as noted by Oruacutes et al (2000) The reason for this excessive application

is that farmers cover the risk of underapplying inputs in parts of the field (Helfand and

House 1995) Corn producers maximize quasi-rent and are aware of the effects of

production decisions on the nitrogen stock in the soil

The base scenario approximates the actual conditions in the area related to the initial

nitrogen stock in soil corn and input prices and costs and subsidies per hectare Nitrogen

pollution levels are higher for low (Planteros) and intermediate (Corraletes) productive

soils because fertilizer consumption is higher in these soils than in the more productive

soil (Chacilla) Nitrogen leaching reaches 336 tons for the whole Flumen irrigation district

which is the sum of 54 tons from Chacilla-type soil 68 tons from Planteros and 214 tons

from Corraletes (Table 5)

The first scenario simulates an increase in water prices from 001 to 006 and 009

eurom3 This price increase reduces water and fertilizer application per hectare in the three

soil categories but nitrate emissions show a slight decrease in Chacilla and Planteros soils

and none in Corraletes soil (Table 4) The emission reduction in Chacilla and Planteros

soils is only 8 kgha when water price reaches 009 eurom3 and there is no reduction in

Corraletes because of the high level of soil nitrogen content Cost to farmers from the first

scenario is very high because quasi-rent losses are between 280 and 300 euroha for the 006

eurom3 price and between 430 and 460 euroha for the 009 eurom3 price For the whole district a

rise in water price to 006 eurom3 abates emission by only 11 tons but reduces social welfare

by 091 million euro and a 009 eurom3 water price reduces leaching by 13 tons and reduces

social welfare by 143 million euro Taxing water prices is a very inefficient instrument to curb

nitrogen emissions

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

7

and corn field experimental data on yields and nitrogen leaching (Saad and Quiacutelez 1998

Saad 1999)

31 Dynamic model

The problem is stated as the maximization of welfare from corn production and

welfare is the sum of corn quasi-rent and the damage cost of nitrogen leaching In absence

of nitrogen pollution measures farmers maximize the private corn quasi-rent selecting the

amount of nitrogen fertilizer and irrigation throughout the time planning horizon (t = 1hellip

T) subject to the dynamics of nitrogen content in the soil Under discrete time the model

is the following

[ ] sum=

sdotλminus+minusminusminussdot+

T

1tttntxtyt

nx)le()sknpxpyp(

)r1(1

Maxtt

[1]

subject to

tttttt uvlengg minusminusminus+=+1 [2]

The objective function has two components the first term in parenthesis is quasi-rent

and the second term λ let is the damage cost from nitrogen leaching The sum is social

welfare through the planning horizon from corn production activities The constraint

captures the dynamics of soil nitrogen content and is defined as the balance of nitrogen

entering and leaving the soil Quasi-rent is equal to revenue minus variable and fixed costs

of corn per hectare1 and nitrogen damage is defined as a linear function of leaching

The constraint equation [2] is the motion equation for nitrogen in soil or soil nitrogen

balance Soil nitrogen in period t+1 is equal to nitrogen in period t plus fertilization minus

leaching volatilization and nitrogen uptake by corn The inclusion of the stock of nitrogen

in the soil is a key feature in order to represent the dynamic relationships among time

periods In absence of intertemporal relations the nitrogen stock in the soil yields and

nitrogen leaching would be static and constant for all periods This dynamic aspect is

crucial to adequately represent the biophysic processes leading to nitrogen pollution

Corn yield and leaching are assumed to be quadratic functions of water applied

nitrogen fertilization and the stock of nitrogen in soil The corn yield function is defined as

1 Costs include direct and indirect expenditures costs from hired labor and machinery and amortization Water and nitrogen costs are shown separately in the objective function

8

Table 3 Estimated yield and pollution functions by soil type

Yield functions Pollution functions

Variable Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Chacilla Planteros CorraletesIntercept -4091

(324) -3946 (-223)

-278 (-731)

-16619 (-499)

-12859 (-1695)

-22184 (-1042)

Water (X) 00271 (1034)

00273 (809)

00349 (3855)

-00586 (-522)

0173 (959)

0293 (466)

Nitrogen (N) 00398 (1043)

00356 (222)

00252 (1704)

00079 (057)

00702 (134)

0134 (362)

N reserve (G) 00297 (2602)

00088 (121)

00054 (135)

0177 (122)

0660 (1694)

0659 (2338)

X2 -020110-4

(-812) -019910-4

(-101) -026910-4

(-3187) 096910-4

(927) 036210-5

(363) 013510-3

(719) N2 -056110-4

(-766) -048810-4

(-433) -033610-4

(-1317) 043410-4

(166) 023010-3

(398) 062510-3

(101) G2 -051310-4

(-189) -025410-4

(-109) -059710-4

(-044)

t-statistics shown in parentheses

2

652

432

210 ttttttt gagananaxaxaay ++++++= and the leaching function is defined as

tttttt gbnbnbxbxbble 52

432

210 +++++=

The variables are yt corn yield in metric tons per hectare (Tonsha) xt irrigation water

applied (m3ha) nt nitrogen fertilization (kgha) gt nitrogen stock in soil (kgha) let

nitrogen leaching (kgha) ut nitrogen uptake by corn (kgha) and vt is nitrogen

volatilization (kgha) Nitrogen uptake and volatilization are a proportion of yield

( tt yu sdot= γ ) and fertilization ( tt nv sdot= δ ) respectively The model parameters are p corn

price in eurokg px water price in eurom3 pn active nitrogen price in eurokg s direct subsidies in

euroha k fixed costs in euroha λ pollution cost in eurokg δ volatilization rate in kgha γ

nitrogen uptake rate in kgton r discount rate and g0 is the initial value of g The estimated

yield and pollution functions are shown in table 3

The optimal control problem include the control variables irrigation water and nitrogen

fertilizer and the state variable stock of nitrogen in soil which is driven by the equation of

motion This equation is an identity linking inputs and outputs of nitrogen in the soil

4 Results

The dynamic model is used to analyze the effects of different abatement measures to

control nitrate pollution and to rank their cost-efficiency The measures examined are

higher irrigation water prices nitrogen fertilizer taxes standards limiting nitrogen

9

Table 4 Results of alternative policy measures by soil type

Welfare (euroha)

Quasi-rent (euroha)

Yield (tonsha)

Water (m3ha)

Nitrogen (kgha)

Soil nitrogen content (kgha)

Leaching (kgha)

Chacilla soil Base Scenario 1400 1456 161 6588 2772 2984 454

006 eurom3 1111 1160 158 5711 2676 3009 402 Water price 009 eurom3 950 997 154 5181 2601 3028 378 09 eurokg 1319 1373 161 6537 2757 2934 441 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 1238 1290 160 6483 2740 2880 427

Nitrogen standard 1370 1404 155 5942 2500 2248 274 Emission tax 1454 1505 160 6440 2724 2831 415

Planteros soil Base Scenario 823 993 126 6569 3225 1589 1386

006 eurom3 535 699 123 5676 3126 1779 1332 Water price 009 eurom3 375 536 119 5146 3055 1914 1312 09 eurokg 747 898 125 6513 3056 1431 1235 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 676 809 123 6457 2879 1273 1085

Nitrogen standard 851 947 119 6345 2500 955 781 Emission tax 965 1077 121 6404 2667 1089 911

Corraletes soil Base Scenario 1008 1177 141 6159 3434 2346 1374

006 eurom3 731 899 139 5417 3391 2573 1366 Water price 009 eurom3 575 743 136 4961 3360 2742 1375 09 eurokg 944 1078 139 6136 3120 2013 1095 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 887 988 137 6114 2799 1688 821

Nitrogen standard 1064 1134 133 6094 2500 1396 574 Emission tax 1126 1189 132 6096 2420 1318 510

10

fertilization and pollution emissions taxes The model is run under these alternative

scenarios generating the time paths for variables yield input use nitrogen stock in soil and

leaching

First the steady-state solution for each soil type is generated under the base scenario of

present corn production conditions in the area and then the steady-state solution for the

different alternative control measures are generated Ranking of the pollution control

measures is based on these steady-state solutions comparing welfare quasi-rent and

nitrogen leaching for each soil and for the whole irrigation district

Table 4 shows the steady-state solution under the base scenario for welfare quasi-rent

corn yield input consumption soil nitrogen content and nitrogen leaching This optimal

solution differs from actual behavior of farmers which are using excessive quantities of

nitrogen and water as noted by Oruacutes et al (2000) The reason for this excessive application

is that farmers cover the risk of underapplying inputs in parts of the field (Helfand and

House 1995) Corn producers maximize quasi-rent and are aware of the effects of

production decisions on the nitrogen stock in the soil

The base scenario approximates the actual conditions in the area related to the initial

nitrogen stock in soil corn and input prices and costs and subsidies per hectare Nitrogen

pollution levels are higher for low (Planteros) and intermediate (Corraletes) productive

soils because fertilizer consumption is higher in these soils than in the more productive

soil (Chacilla) Nitrogen leaching reaches 336 tons for the whole Flumen irrigation district

which is the sum of 54 tons from Chacilla-type soil 68 tons from Planteros and 214 tons

from Corraletes (Table 5)

The first scenario simulates an increase in water prices from 001 to 006 and 009

eurom3 This price increase reduces water and fertilizer application per hectare in the three

soil categories but nitrate emissions show a slight decrease in Chacilla and Planteros soils

and none in Corraletes soil (Table 4) The emission reduction in Chacilla and Planteros

soils is only 8 kgha when water price reaches 009 eurom3 and there is no reduction in

Corraletes because of the high level of soil nitrogen content Cost to farmers from the first

scenario is very high because quasi-rent losses are between 280 and 300 euroha for the 006

eurom3 price and between 430 and 460 euroha for the 009 eurom3 price For the whole district a

rise in water price to 006 eurom3 abates emission by only 11 tons but reduces social welfare

by 091 million euro and a 009 eurom3 water price reduces leaching by 13 tons and reduces

social welfare by 143 million euro Taxing water prices is a very inefficient instrument to curb

nitrogen emissions

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

8

Table 3 Estimated yield and pollution functions by soil type

Yield functions Pollution functions

Variable Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Chacilla Planteros CorraletesIntercept -4091

(324) -3946 (-223)

-278 (-731)

-16619 (-499)

-12859 (-1695)

-22184 (-1042)

Water (X) 00271 (1034)

00273 (809)

00349 (3855)

-00586 (-522)

0173 (959)

0293 (466)

Nitrogen (N) 00398 (1043)

00356 (222)

00252 (1704)

00079 (057)

00702 (134)

0134 (362)

N reserve (G) 00297 (2602)

00088 (121)

00054 (135)

0177 (122)

0660 (1694)

0659 (2338)

X2 -020110-4

(-812) -019910-4

(-101) -026910-4

(-3187) 096910-4

(927) 036210-5

(363) 013510-3

(719) N2 -056110-4

(-766) -048810-4

(-433) -033610-4

(-1317) 043410-4

(166) 023010-3

(398) 062510-3

(101) G2 -051310-4

(-189) -025410-4

(-109) -059710-4

(-044)

t-statistics shown in parentheses

2

652

432

210 ttttttt gagananaxaxaay ++++++= and the leaching function is defined as

tttttt gbnbnbxbxbble 52

432

210 +++++=

The variables are yt corn yield in metric tons per hectare (Tonsha) xt irrigation water

applied (m3ha) nt nitrogen fertilization (kgha) gt nitrogen stock in soil (kgha) let

nitrogen leaching (kgha) ut nitrogen uptake by corn (kgha) and vt is nitrogen

volatilization (kgha) Nitrogen uptake and volatilization are a proportion of yield

( tt yu sdot= γ ) and fertilization ( tt nv sdot= δ ) respectively The model parameters are p corn

price in eurokg px water price in eurom3 pn active nitrogen price in eurokg s direct subsidies in

euroha k fixed costs in euroha λ pollution cost in eurokg δ volatilization rate in kgha γ

nitrogen uptake rate in kgton r discount rate and g0 is the initial value of g The estimated

yield and pollution functions are shown in table 3

The optimal control problem include the control variables irrigation water and nitrogen

fertilizer and the state variable stock of nitrogen in soil which is driven by the equation of

motion This equation is an identity linking inputs and outputs of nitrogen in the soil

4 Results

The dynamic model is used to analyze the effects of different abatement measures to

control nitrate pollution and to rank their cost-efficiency The measures examined are

higher irrigation water prices nitrogen fertilizer taxes standards limiting nitrogen

9

Table 4 Results of alternative policy measures by soil type

Welfare (euroha)

Quasi-rent (euroha)

Yield (tonsha)

Water (m3ha)

Nitrogen (kgha)

Soil nitrogen content (kgha)

Leaching (kgha)

Chacilla soil Base Scenario 1400 1456 161 6588 2772 2984 454

006 eurom3 1111 1160 158 5711 2676 3009 402 Water price 009 eurom3 950 997 154 5181 2601 3028 378 09 eurokg 1319 1373 161 6537 2757 2934 441 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 1238 1290 160 6483 2740 2880 427

Nitrogen standard 1370 1404 155 5942 2500 2248 274 Emission tax 1454 1505 160 6440 2724 2831 415

Planteros soil Base Scenario 823 993 126 6569 3225 1589 1386

006 eurom3 535 699 123 5676 3126 1779 1332 Water price 009 eurom3 375 536 119 5146 3055 1914 1312 09 eurokg 747 898 125 6513 3056 1431 1235 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 676 809 123 6457 2879 1273 1085

Nitrogen standard 851 947 119 6345 2500 955 781 Emission tax 965 1077 121 6404 2667 1089 911

Corraletes soil Base Scenario 1008 1177 141 6159 3434 2346 1374

006 eurom3 731 899 139 5417 3391 2573 1366 Water price 009 eurom3 575 743 136 4961 3360 2742 1375 09 eurokg 944 1078 139 6136 3120 2013 1095 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 887 988 137 6114 2799 1688 821

Nitrogen standard 1064 1134 133 6094 2500 1396 574 Emission tax 1126 1189 132 6096 2420 1318 510

10

fertilization and pollution emissions taxes The model is run under these alternative

scenarios generating the time paths for variables yield input use nitrogen stock in soil and

leaching

First the steady-state solution for each soil type is generated under the base scenario of

present corn production conditions in the area and then the steady-state solution for the

different alternative control measures are generated Ranking of the pollution control

measures is based on these steady-state solutions comparing welfare quasi-rent and

nitrogen leaching for each soil and for the whole irrigation district

Table 4 shows the steady-state solution under the base scenario for welfare quasi-rent

corn yield input consumption soil nitrogen content and nitrogen leaching This optimal

solution differs from actual behavior of farmers which are using excessive quantities of

nitrogen and water as noted by Oruacutes et al (2000) The reason for this excessive application

is that farmers cover the risk of underapplying inputs in parts of the field (Helfand and

House 1995) Corn producers maximize quasi-rent and are aware of the effects of

production decisions on the nitrogen stock in the soil

The base scenario approximates the actual conditions in the area related to the initial

nitrogen stock in soil corn and input prices and costs and subsidies per hectare Nitrogen

pollution levels are higher for low (Planteros) and intermediate (Corraletes) productive

soils because fertilizer consumption is higher in these soils than in the more productive

soil (Chacilla) Nitrogen leaching reaches 336 tons for the whole Flumen irrigation district

which is the sum of 54 tons from Chacilla-type soil 68 tons from Planteros and 214 tons

from Corraletes (Table 5)

The first scenario simulates an increase in water prices from 001 to 006 and 009

eurom3 This price increase reduces water and fertilizer application per hectare in the three

soil categories but nitrate emissions show a slight decrease in Chacilla and Planteros soils

and none in Corraletes soil (Table 4) The emission reduction in Chacilla and Planteros

soils is only 8 kgha when water price reaches 009 eurom3 and there is no reduction in

Corraletes because of the high level of soil nitrogen content Cost to farmers from the first

scenario is very high because quasi-rent losses are between 280 and 300 euroha for the 006

eurom3 price and between 430 and 460 euroha for the 009 eurom3 price For the whole district a

rise in water price to 006 eurom3 abates emission by only 11 tons but reduces social welfare

by 091 million euro and a 009 eurom3 water price reduces leaching by 13 tons and reduces

social welfare by 143 million euro Taxing water prices is a very inefficient instrument to curb

nitrogen emissions

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

9

Table 4 Results of alternative policy measures by soil type

Welfare (euroha)

Quasi-rent (euroha)

Yield (tonsha)

Water (m3ha)

Nitrogen (kgha)

Soil nitrogen content (kgha)

Leaching (kgha)

Chacilla soil Base Scenario 1400 1456 161 6588 2772 2984 454

006 eurom3 1111 1160 158 5711 2676 3009 402 Water price 009 eurom3 950 997 154 5181 2601 3028 378 09 eurokg 1319 1373 161 6537 2757 2934 441 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 1238 1290 160 6483 2740 2880 427

Nitrogen standard 1370 1404 155 5942 2500 2248 274 Emission tax 1454 1505 160 6440 2724 2831 415

Planteros soil Base Scenario 823 993 126 6569 3225 1589 1386

006 eurom3 535 699 123 5676 3126 1779 1332 Water price 009 eurom3 375 536 119 5146 3055 1914 1312 09 eurokg 747 898 125 6513 3056 1431 1235 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 676 809 123 6457 2879 1273 1085

Nitrogen standard 851 947 119 6345 2500 955 781 Emission tax 965 1077 121 6404 2667 1089 911

Corraletes soil Base Scenario 1008 1177 141 6159 3434 2346 1374

006 eurom3 731 899 139 5417 3391 2573 1366 Water price 009 eurom3 575 743 136 4961 3360 2742 1375 09 eurokg 944 1078 139 6136 3120 2013 1095 Nitrogen price 12 eurokg 887 988 137 6114 2799 1688 821

Nitrogen standard 1064 1134 133 6094 2500 1396 574 Emission tax 1126 1189 132 6096 2420 1318 510

10

fertilization and pollution emissions taxes The model is run under these alternative

scenarios generating the time paths for variables yield input use nitrogen stock in soil and

leaching

First the steady-state solution for each soil type is generated under the base scenario of

present corn production conditions in the area and then the steady-state solution for the

different alternative control measures are generated Ranking of the pollution control

measures is based on these steady-state solutions comparing welfare quasi-rent and

nitrogen leaching for each soil and for the whole irrigation district

Table 4 shows the steady-state solution under the base scenario for welfare quasi-rent

corn yield input consumption soil nitrogen content and nitrogen leaching This optimal

solution differs from actual behavior of farmers which are using excessive quantities of

nitrogen and water as noted by Oruacutes et al (2000) The reason for this excessive application

is that farmers cover the risk of underapplying inputs in parts of the field (Helfand and

House 1995) Corn producers maximize quasi-rent and are aware of the effects of

production decisions on the nitrogen stock in the soil

The base scenario approximates the actual conditions in the area related to the initial

nitrogen stock in soil corn and input prices and costs and subsidies per hectare Nitrogen

pollution levels are higher for low (Planteros) and intermediate (Corraletes) productive

soils because fertilizer consumption is higher in these soils than in the more productive

soil (Chacilla) Nitrogen leaching reaches 336 tons for the whole Flumen irrigation district

which is the sum of 54 tons from Chacilla-type soil 68 tons from Planteros and 214 tons

from Corraletes (Table 5)

The first scenario simulates an increase in water prices from 001 to 006 and 009

eurom3 This price increase reduces water and fertilizer application per hectare in the three

soil categories but nitrate emissions show a slight decrease in Chacilla and Planteros soils

and none in Corraletes soil (Table 4) The emission reduction in Chacilla and Planteros

soils is only 8 kgha when water price reaches 009 eurom3 and there is no reduction in

Corraletes because of the high level of soil nitrogen content Cost to farmers from the first

scenario is very high because quasi-rent losses are between 280 and 300 euroha for the 006

eurom3 price and between 430 and 460 euroha for the 009 eurom3 price For the whole district a

rise in water price to 006 eurom3 abates emission by only 11 tons but reduces social welfare

by 091 million euro and a 009 eurom3 water price reduces leaching by 13 tons and reduces

social welfare by 143 million euro Taxing water prices is a very inefficient instrument to curb

nitrogen emissions

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

10

fertilization and pollution emissions taxes The model is run under these alternative

scenarios generating the time paths for variables yield input use nitrogen stock in soil and

leaching

First the steady-state solution for each soil type is generated under the base scenario of

present corn production conditions in the area and then the steady-state solution for the

different alternative control measures are generated Ranking of the pollution control

measures is based on these steady-state solutions comparing welfare quasi-rent and

nitrogen leaching for each soil and for the whole irrigation district

Table 4 shows the steady-state solution under the base scenario for welfare quasi-rent

corn yield input consumption soil nitrogen content and nitrogen leaching This optimal

solution differs from actual behavior of farmers which are using excessive quantities of

nitrogen and water as noted by Oruacutes et al (2000) The reason for this excessive application

is that farmers cover the risk of underapplying inputs in parts of the field (Helfand and

House 1995) Corn producers maximize quasi-rent and are aware of the effects of

production decisions on the nitrogen stock in the soil

The base scenario approximates the actual conditions in the area related to the initial

nitrogen stock in soil corn and input prices and costs and subsidies per hectare Nitrogen

pollution levels are higher for low (Planteros) and intermediate (Corraletes) productive

soils because fertilizer consumption is higher in these soils than in the more productive

soil (Chacilla) Nitrogen leaching reaches 336 tons for the whole Flumen irrigation district

which is the sum of 54 tons from Chacilla-type soil 68 tons from Planteros and 214 tons

from Corraletes (Table 5)

The first scenario simulates an increase in water prices from 001 to 006 and 009

eurom3 This price increase reduces water and fertilizer application per hectare in the three

soil categories but nitrate emissions show a slight decrease in Chacilla and Planteros soils

and none in Corraletes soil (Table 4) The emission reduction in Chacilla and Planteros

soils is only 8 kgha when water price reaches 009 eurom3 and there is no reduction in

Corraletes because of the high level of soil nitrogen content Cost to farmers from the first

scenario is very high because quasi-rent losses are between 280 and 300 euroha for the 006

eurom3 price and between 430 and 460 euroha for the 009 eurom3 price For the whole district a

rise in water price to 006 eurom3 abates emission by only 11 tons but reduces social welfare

by 091 million euro and a 009 eurom3 water price reduces leaching by 13 tons and reduces

social welfare by 143 million euro Taxing water prices is a very inefficient instrument to curb

nitrogen emissions

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

11

Table 5 Yearly welfare and leaching by abatement measure and soil type in the district

Chacilla Planteros Corraletes Total District

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Welfare(1000 euro)

Leaching (Tons)

Welfare (1000 euro)

Leaching(Tons)

Base scenario 1652 54 403 68 1572 214 3627 336 Water price 006 eurom3 1311 47 262 65 1140 213 2713 325 009 eurom3 1121 45 184 64 897 214 2202 323 Nitrogen price 09 eurokg 1556 52 366 60 1473 170 3395 282 12 eurokg 1416 50 331 53 1384 128 3176 231 Nitrogen standard 1617 32 417 38 1660 90 3694 160 Emission tax 1716 49 473 44 1756 79 3945 172

Under the second scenario the price of active nitrogen increases from 06 eurokg to 09

and 12 eurokg These higher nitrogen prices diminish the water and fertilizer application less

than the water price increase For Planteros and Corraletes soils the leaching reduction is

larger than under the higher water prices scenario but not for Chacilla soil A 12 eurokg

nitrogen price reduces nitrogen emissions 63 kgha for Corraletes-type soil 30 kgha for

Planteros and only 8 kgha for Chacillan For the whole district welfare losses are

between 023 and 045 million euros much lower than taxing water and with a much larger

leaching abatement Therefore a tax on nitrogen is more cost efficient than a tax on water

The third scenario introduces a limit or standard on applied nitrogen which is fixed at

250 kgha following the Extension Service recommendations (Oruacutes et al 2000) This

instrument is similar to the Code of Good Agricultural Practices established by the

European Nitrate Directive and the advantage of this measure is that costs to farmers in

terms of quasi-rent are reasonable and there are welfare gains for society in Planteros and

Corraletes soils Leaching abatement is above 40 percent in every soil and quasi-rent losses

are always below 5 percent This is a second best type of instrument and our results show

that the cost-efficiency is superior to taxes on inputs because the large abatement of

nitrogen emissions and the moderate reduction in quasi-rent Welfare increases under the

standard for the whole district (Table 5) although the standard reduces welfare in Chacilla

soils indicating that no standard is needed in this soil

The main obstacle to implement a quantitative limit is the difficulty to control

farmer compliance The introduction of a subsidy system for farmers who reduce fertilizer

application is a method to implement the standard provided that subsidies are coupled

with emissions verification These controls could be implemented and enforced by

irrigation user associations through measurement of nitrogen content in return water flow

canals Another method of implementing the standard is licensing fertilizer application to a

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

12

specialist a figure known as ldquoenvironmental doctorrdquo The measure of establishing a

standard has been recommended in the literature (Knickel 1998 Miettinen 1998 Weinberg

y Wilen 2000) and in studies analyzing the same irrigation district by Martiacutenez et al (2001)

and Martiacutenez (2002)

The last scenario considers the first best instrument of taxing nitrogen emissions

with a unit emission cost equal to 123 eurokg that has been chosen equal to the cost of

eliminating nitrogen from water The quasi-rent for this instrument is calculated assuming

that the social planner gives the farmer a subsidy equal to the optimal nitrogen damage

cost provided that pollution is at the social optimum The tax causes a strong leaching

reduction diminishing pollution levels by soil type between 10 and 60 percent Farmer

quasi-rent increases so farmers will embrace this solution provided that the

implementation was feasible

A ranking of policy measures can be defined by comparing the welfare effects of each

measure for the whole irrigation district by soil type (Table 5) The first best measure of

taxing emissions increases welfare in the district by 032 million euro Among the second

best measures a standard on nitrogen application also increases welfare by 007 million

euro while taxes on nitrogen fertilizer reduce welfare between 023 and 045 million euro

Higher water prices are very inefficient since welfare falls between 091 and 143 million

euro with an almost negligible leaching abatement below 4 percent This finding is

important because the recently approved Water Framework Directive of the European

Union relies heavily on higher water prices called full recovery cost in order to reach

ldquogood statusrdquo for all waters

An issue that could modify the effects presented here is that the introduction of

control measures may induce changes in the relative profitability of different crops and

farmers may respond expanding the more profitable crops This question was examined in

the study area by Martiacutenez el al (2001) for a standard limiting nitrogen application The

acreage substitution effect was moderate for all crops and in the case of corn the fall in

acreage was 03 percent

In accordance with the results presented here the studies by Pan and Hodge (1994)

and Johnson et al (1991) find that an emission tax equal to the cost of nitrogen removal is

the social optimum measure Jonhson el al (1991) evaluate the cost of the emission tax at 5

percent of quasi-rent with an emission reduction above 30 percent Other studies

examining nitrogen standards by Mapp et al (1994) in USA and Schmid (2001) in Austria

find that the abatement costs to reduce nitrogen leaching are somewhat higher than the

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

13

costs calculated here2 Mapp et al recommend a standard that reduces leaching by 67

percent at a cost of 22 percent of quasi-rent and Schmid states that a standard reduces

leaching between 40 and 90 percent at a cost to farmers between 5 and 14 percent of quasi-

rent Martiacutenez (2002) calculates a 2 percent loss of quasi-rent to curb leaching by 44

percent assuming homogeneous soil

Helfand and House (1995) examine the cost-efficiency of control measures under two

soil types in the case of lettuce production in order to abate nitrogen leaching by 20

percent Their findings are that quasi-rent losses derived from using uniform instruments

are small so perfect instruments are not necessary and may entail significant transaction

costs3 They indicate also that a nitrogen tax and a nitrogen standard are both very

inefficient measures which have very high welfare costs a finding contrary to the results

obtained here for corn Our results indicate that a nitrogen standard is the second best

preferred measure in accordance with economic theory and most of the empirical

literature Also our empirical evidence indicates that a tax on nitrogen is much more cost

efficient than a tax on water The finding on the nitrogen standard efficiency by Helfand

and House is questionable because the dynamic aspect of nitrogen content in the soil is

not considered When the level of nitrogen input changes the nitrogen content in the soil

adjust over several periods They force a 20 percent leaching abatement within the

production period reducing nitrogen fertilization by 90 percent so costs of a nitrogen

standard or a tax are prohibitive In contrast our results indicate that the standard reduces

nitrogen fertilization in the district by 20 percent abating leaching by more than half4 As

indicated above a tax of water is a very inefficient measure in our case with leaching

abatement below 4 percent and very high costs in terms of quasi-rent and welfare

Thomas and Boisvert (1994) simulate the introduction of a market for nitrogen

pollution permits and estimate that a permit price reducing 10 percent nitrogen emissions

reduces gross income by 15 percent5 This pollution permit instrument can be compared

with the emission tax examined here The cost calculated by these authors is much higher

2 For the whole district the nitrogen standard abates leaching by 176 tons (-52) with a cost of 015 million euro (-37) in quasi-rent 3 The loss of quasi-rent for any uniform measure is below 2 percent compared with 016 losses under a first-best heterogeneous measure 4 For the whole district nitrogen fertilization is 1020 tons and the standard reduces fertilization by 212 tons These figures come from table 4 and corn acreage by soil 5 Thomas and Boisvert (1994) use a procedure different from the present study They consider nitrogen pollution as a fraction of the remaining nitrogen that is not taken by the plant or degraded by denitrification

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

14

than the cost obtained in table 5 for an emission tax which abates leaching by 50 percent

in the region increasing welfare and quasi-rent6

The results of the present study on nitrate pollution control under soil heterogeneity

indicate the possibility of differentiating application of control by soil type The preferred

second best instrument is a standard but the instrument will be applied only in vulnerable

soils Corn leaching in Chacilla soils is only 45 kgha which is below the leaching levels in

the other soil types applying any abatement measure An alternative for nitrogen leaching

control would be to implement control instruments only in Planteros and Corraletes soils

which have high pollution potential For the whole district implementing a nitrogen

standard in Planteros and Corraletes soils but not in Chacilla improves welfare by 1

percent over a homogeneous nitrogen standard in the district This small loss in welfare

from using a homogeneous instead of an heterogeneous standard confirms the finding by

Helfand and House (1995) that losses from uniform instruments are small and perfect

instruments are not necessary

Discrimination of control measures could depend also on the particular crop planted

so control could be linked to the land use decision by the farmer for each soil type

Information on nitrogen leaching in the district indicates that wheat barley sunflower and

alfalfa have all leaching levels below 45 kgha in absence of abatement measures (Martiacutenez

2002) so these crops would not be subject to abatement while other more polluting crop

production activities such as corn and rice would be subject to control in vulnerable soils

This discrimination by crop and soil could be implemented using a land use tax adapted to

crop and soil provided that the land tax has adequate cost efficiency and transaction costs

5 Conclusions

The evaluation of efficiency for alternative nitrogen abatement measures requires the

consideration of biophysical aspects such soil class and crop type The effects of selected

abatement measures have been examined through a dynamic model for corn production in

three different soils of the Flumen irrigation district in the Ebro basin This evaluation is

useful to rank different instruments by their efficiency as a contribution to the policy

decision process The results agree with previous literature and indicate that a fertilizer

standard is the more efficient second best measure to control nitrogen pollution

6 As indicated above the emission tax instrument is linked to a subsidy equal to optimal nitrogen damage cost Therefore quasi-rent under the emission tax is above quasi-rent under the base scenario

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

15

The observed farmer behavior differs from the optimal solution of the model under

the base scenario because there is an excess input utilization that aggravates the nitrogen

pollution problem in the district Alternative emissions reduction measures have been

simulated and compared to the base scenario

An increase in water prices reduces only slightly nitrogen discharges at very large costs

to farmers and society A tax on nitrogen utilization results in more significant pollution

reduction at much lower costs A standard on nitrogen application curbs emissions by

more than half with a very moderate impact on quasi-rent and gains in welfare The

introduction of subsidies linked to the standard could be a good second best alternative to

achieve nitrogen pollution control

The original contribution of this study is the following a quantitative assessment has

been performed that demonstrates that abatement measures may be taken only in

vulnerable soils with crops that have high pollution potential So the results show that

differentiating the application of control by soil type enhances welfare although this

welfare gain from a differentiated standard is small compared with an homogeneous

standard in the case of corn An important question for the choice of the correct pollution

control instrument is related with the implementation costs of the instrument The more

suitable measures are associated with implementation difficulties and policy makers should

evaluate the trade-off between cost-efficiency and implementation simplicity

Acknowledgements

Support for this research was provided by projects CICYT AGL2001-2333-C02 and

INIA RTA02-090 from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology The INIA

funded also research contacts with the Department of Agricultural Economics of the

University of Newcastle upon Tyne This study was made possible by the technical

assistance of Joseacute Cavero Jesuacutes Noguumles Dolores Quilez Juan Herrero and Auxi Casterad

from the Laboratorio Asociado de Agronomiacutea y Medio Ambiente (CSIC-CITA Aula Dei

Campus Zaragoza)

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

16

References Albiac J Uche J Valero A Serra L Meyer A Tapia J 2003 The Economic

Unsustainability of the Spanish National Hydrologic Plan International Journal of Water Resources Development 19 (3) 437-458

Casterad A Herrero J 2003 Irrivol database Unidad de Suelos y Riegos Servicio de Investigacioacuten Agroalimentaria Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Confederacioacuten Hidrograacutefica del Ebro 2003 Water quality data series CHE Ministerio de Medio Ambiente Zaragoza Available at wwwchebroes

Gobierno de Aragoacuten 1999 Base de datos 1T de superficie de cultivos por teacutermino municipal para Aragoacuten 1987-99 Servicio de Estudios y Planificacioacuten Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica Departamento de Agricultura Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Feijooacute M Calvo E Albiac J 2000 Economic and environmental policy analysis of the Flumen-Monegros irrigation system in Huesca Spain Geographical Analysis 32 (3) 187-204

Hanemann M 2003 Economics Findings and Recommendations Appendix C Economics In Horne A Dracup J Hanemann M Rodriguez-Iturbe I Means E Roth J (The US Technical Team) A Technical Review of the Spanish National Hydrological Plan (Ebro River Out-of-basin Diversion) Fundacioacuten Universidad Politeacutecnica de Cartagena University of Cartagena Cartagena

Helfand G House B 1995 Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution Under Heterogeneous Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77 1024-1032

Howitt R 2003 A Review of Economic Hydrologic Planning Pertaining to the Ebro River Transfer Proposal In Biswas A (Ed) Spanish National Hydrologic Plan Reports of International Experts Gobierno de Aragoacuten Zaragoza

Johnson S Adams R Perry G 1991 The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73 1063-1073

Khanna M Isik M Zilberman D 2000 Incentive-based Policies for Conservation Technology Adoption Implications for Pollution and Output Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural of Economics Association Tampa Florida

Knickel K 1998 First Results of Model Calculations In Gazzola L Roest K (Eds) Economic Instruments for Nitrogen Control in European Agriculture Research Center on Animal Production Reggio Emilia

Mapp H Bernardo D Sabbagh S Geleta S Watkins K 1994 Economic and Environmental Impacts of Limiting Nitrogen Use to Protect Water Quality A Stochastic Regional Analysis American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76 889-903

Martiacutenez Y Uku S Albiac J 2001 El control de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Economiacutea Agraria y Recursos Naturales 2 (2) 115-131

Martiacutenez Y 2002 Anaacutelisis econoacutemico y ambiental de la contaminacioacuten por nitratos en el regadiacuteo Doctoral dissertation Department of Economic Analysis University of Zaragoza Zaragoza

Miettinen A 1993 The Effectiveness and Feasibility of Economic Incentives of Input Control in the Mitigation of Agricultural Water Pollution Agricultural Science in Finland 2 453-464

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 1999 Anuario de Estadiacutestica Agraria MAPA Madrid

Ministerio de Agricultura Pesca y Alimentacioacuten 2000 Hechos y Cifras del Sector Agroalimentario Espantildeol 2000 Secretariacutea General Teacutecnica MAPA Madrid

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945

17

Mitchell G Griggs R Benson V Williams J 1996 The EPIC Model Environmental Policy Integrated Climate Userrsquos Guide Texas Agricultural Experiment Station Temple

Nogueacutes J Herrero J Rodriacuteguez R Boixadera J 1999 Land evaluation in a salt-affected irrigated district using an index of productive potential Environmental Management 25 143-152

Nogueacutes J 2000 Mapa de Suelos (E 125000) de Barbueacutes y Torres de Barbueacutes (Huesca) Aplicaciones para Modernizacioacuten de Regadiacuteos Consejo de Proteccioacuten de la Naturaleza de Aragoacuten Serie Investigacioacuten Zaragoza

Oruacutes F Quiacutelez D Betraacuten J 2000 El Coacutedigo de Buenas Praacutecticas Agrarias (I) Fertilizacioacuten Nitrogenada y Contaminacioacuten por Nitratos Direccioacuten General de Tecnologiacutea Agraria (DGA) Informaciones Teacutecnicas Nordm 93 Zaragoza

Pan J Hodge I 1994 Land use permits as an alternative to fertiliser and leaching taxes for the control of nitrate pollution Journal of Agricultural Economics 45(1) 102-112

Saad J Quiacutelez D 1998 Efecto de la dosis de abonado y el riego sobre el lavado de nitrato en cultivo de maiacutez Paper presented at the XVI Congreso Nacional de Riegos Palma de Mallorca

Saad J 1999 The effects of fertilization and irrigation on nitrate leaching in maize PhD dissertation Escuela Teacutecnica Superior de Ingenieros Agroacutenomos Universidad de Leacuterida Leacuterida

Schmid E 2001 Efficient Policy Design to Control Effluents from Agriculture Doctoral dissertation Department of Economics Politics and Law University of Agricultural Sciences Vienna

Thomas A Boisvert R 1994 Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater Taxes Quantity Restrictions and Pollution Permits Department of Agricultural Resource and Managerial Economics Cornell University Working paper 94-07

Vickner S Hoag D Frasier W Ascough J 1998 A Dynamic Analysis of Nitrate Leaching in Corn Production under Nonuniform Irrigation Conditions American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80 397-408

Weinberg M Wilen J 2000 Efficiency Benefits versus Transaction Costs in Non-point Source Pollution Control Working document Department of Environmental Science and Policy University of California Davis

Yadav S 1997 Dynamic Optimization of Nitrogen Use When Groundwater Contamination Is Internalized at the Standard in the Long Run American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 931-945


Recommended