+ All Categories
Transcript

ls Ideological Polarisation by Age Group Growing inEurope?

Tom O’Grady∗

August 11, 2022

Abstract

Prominent theories claim that young Europeans are increasingly socialist as well asdivided from their elders on non-economic issues. This paper asks whether age-basedpolarisation is really growing in Europe, using new estimates of the ideological positionsof different age groups in 27 European countries across four issue domains from 1981-2018. The young in Europe turn out to be relatively libertarian: more socially liberalthan the old in most countries, but also more opposed to taxation and governmentspending. These age divides are not growing either: today’s differences over socialissues and immigration are similar in size to the 1980s, and if anything are startingto fall. Analysis of birth cohorts points to persistent cohort effects and period effectsas the explanation for these patterns; there is little evidence that European cohortsbecome uniformly more right-wing or left-wing with age. Hence age-based polarisationneed not be a permanent or natural feature of European politics, but is dependent onthe changing social, political and economic climate.

∗Associate Professor of Political Science, University College London. t.o’[email protected]. This replacesa previous version posted under the title “Is Europe becoming a ‘Gerontocracy’? New Evidence on AgeCleavages in Europe since the 1980s”

1

Age is becoming increasingly important in European politics. By 2100 the over-65s will ac-

count for 31% of Europe’s population, compared to 20% today and 10% in the mid 1980s.1

Large age gaps have opened up for voting in countries such as Spain and the UK, along-

side stark differences in turnout across the continent (Blais and Rubenson 2013; Orriols and

Cordero 2016; Sloam, Ehsan, and Henn 2018; Smets 2012). Here I look beyond demographic

change, voting and turnout to investigate a fourth potential source of age divides: ideological

polarisation. As I detail below, some sociologists and political scientists argue that ideolog-

ical age gaps should be growing too, with young people’s economic precarity pushing them

leftwards on economics at the same time as older voters are moving rightwards on social

issues and immigration.

How true are such claims? Existing evidence is incomplete at best, covering only short

periods, a handful of countries, or a narrow set of issues. Instead, I use a dataset of over one

hundred survey questions from all major pan-European surveys from 1981-2018, aggregating

them into dimension-specific ideological scales for age groups. I report three key empirical

findings. First, there is ideological polarisation by age on non-economic issues, but it has

not risen since the 1980s. Second, on tax and spending an age gap opened up in the last

twenty years, but the young are actually more conservative than the old; they are relatively

libertarian rather than more socialist. Third, cohort and period effects are the principle

source of evolving age gaps, making polarisation volatile over time rather than permanent.

Ideological Polarisation by Age: Theory and Existing

Evidence

Compared to older generations, young Europeans face higher unemployment, more insecure

labour markets, lower wealth, as well as inferior pensions and access to housing. These

patterns emerged strongly over the past two decades (Bell and Gardiner 2019; Hausermann,

Kurer, and Schwander 2015; Huttle, Wilson, and Wolff 2015; Lennartz, Arundel, and Ronald

2016; Seeleib-Kaiser and Spreckelsen 2018). Moreover, many came of age during the financial

crisis and its aftermath, an experience that typically leaves cohorts more left-wing through-

out their lives (Giuliano and Spilimbergo 2014). As a result, some sociologists of youth have

predicted growing polarisation over economic issues between age groups, with the ‘prole-

tarianisation’ of youth causing more left-wing demands for redistribution and government

intervention (Bessant, Farthing, and Watts 2017; Cote 2014; Furlong and Cartmel 2007).

Other scholars predict growing age divides over non-economic issues, exemplified by the

1. Eurostat and WHO data: see here and here

2

Brexit referendum where 66% of the over-65s voted to leave the European Union and 69% of

18-30s voted to remain (Ehsan and Sloam 2020). The ‘silent revolution’ theory argues that

older people are more socially conservative because younger generations were socialised in a

more affluent and liberal era when social equality and post-material values were more salient,

and they are better-educated and clustered in diverse urban areas. If younger cohorts are

outpacing liberalisation amongst older people, this leads to growing polarisation (Inglehart

2008; Norris and Inglehart 2019; Grasso et al. 2019). Ross (2018) also finds that growing up

amidst European integration and increasingly multiracial societies has eroded nationalism

and opposition to immigration amongst the European young, further dividing them from

their elders. Norris and Inglehart (2019) argue that a backlash against these progressive

social changes has begun to occur amongst older voters, who are turning further against

immigration and other social issues, exacerbating polarisation.

Recent elections in countries such as Germany, Great Britain, Ireland and Spain seem

to support the view that generational ideological polarisation is growing, featuring strong

age differences in party support (Orriols and Cordero 2016; Sloam, Ehsan, and Henn 2018).

Indeed, journalists often take voting patterns as prima facie evidence of greater ideological

polarisation. In the late 2010s The Independent claimed that “politics is being taken over

by children with a pipe dream of returning to the socialism I know doesn’t work.”2 whilst

The Economist fretted about a rise in “millennial socialists”, who “suffer from naivety about

budgets, bureaucracies and businesses”3. On non-economic issues, culture wars are also said

to divide increasingly ‘woke’ young people from the elderly.

However alternative theoretical perspectives, emphasising positions in the life cycle rather

than cohort effects, do not predict growing ideological polarisation by age. In theory the

elderly always have a stronger interest in higher government spending on pensions and health-

care, and decreased spending on education (Mulligan and Sala-i-Martin 1999; Poterba 1997).

Some social psychologists also argue that social conservatism rises with age due to natural

changes in personality and cognition. Ageing may lead to lower openness to new ideas as

well as an increased preference for certainty over ambiguity, traits that are strongly related

to social conservatism (Cornelis et al. 2009). Whether due to self-interest or differences in

cognition, these theories suggest that the young and old always hold different views but there

is no reason for polarisation to change over time. Consistent with this, a re-analysis of Nor-

ris and Inglehart (2019)’s data by Schafer (2021) finds no evidence of growing generational

polarisation for authoritarian values.

Existing empirical work has focused mainly on explaining why mass opinion has changed

2. See here3. https://www.economist.com/leaders/2019/02/14/millennial-socialism, 14th Feb 2019

3

or why age gaps exist: age, period or cohort effects? Studies of postmaterial and social issues

typically report a society-wide liberalisation of attitudes – period effects – alongside very

substantial cohort effects causing the young to be more socially liberal than the old (Andor,

Schmidt, and Sommer 2018; Inglehart 2008; Norris and Inglehart 2019; Peterson, Smith,

and Hibbing 2020). On economic issues, small age divides exist over spending on pensions

and healthcare, with somewhat greater divisions over education (Busemeyer, Goerres, and

Weschle 2009; Cattaneo and Wolter 2009; Hess, Nauman, and Steinkopf 2017; Sorensen

2013). However, almost none of these studies focus on whether age-based polarisation in

Europe is rising or falling, or why this is. Many also cover only a single country, a single

year, or a very limited set of political issues. For example, both Norris and Inglehart (2019)

and Schafer (2021) rely on European Social Survey data from 2002-14 only, and Busemeyer,

Goerres, and Weschle (2009) examine four survey questions from 1996. A key reason for this

spotty coverage is that existing cross-national survey data is sparsely and unevenly available,

often forcing scholars to rely on only a handful of survey items from a single survey. Data

is missing for a lot of countries, years and issues. Even repeated cross-national surveys

appear only occasionally over time. This makes it impossible to assess long-term change in

ideological polarisation by age group using survey questions alone.

The debate about age-based ideological polarisation is, therefore, far from settled and

we know very little about its long-term evolution. This article takes an exploratory and

descriptive approach, measuring age differences across multiple issue dimensions and many

countries from 1981-2018. My main aims are to ask (1) whether ideological polarisation by

age is increasing, (2) for which, if any, issue dimensions this is true and (3) what explains

changes in age-based polarisation over time.

Data and Methods

I do this using a new method developed by Caughey, O’Grady, and Warshaw (2019) and

implemented via the dgo package in R (Dunham, Caughey, and Warshaw 2017), which con-

verts sets of survey questions into multidimensional scaled ideological positions for subgroups

within multiple European countries. It allows many different surveys, covering various time

periods, countries and issues, to be aggregated together into scales that have much wider

geographic and temporal coverage than is possible using individual survey questions alone.

Their approach begins by estimating item response theory (IRT) models using survey ques-

tions, but differs from previous IRT models in two respects. First, it estimates ideological

positions for age groups within each country, rather than individual survey respondents. This

facilitates estimating scales for age-country groups even with just a handful of survey ques-

4

tions, when a standard IRT model for individuals would fail due to lack of data. Second, it

smooths the estimated ideological positions using a hierarchical model so that country-years

with little or no survey data borrow information from other periods and places. This allows

the model to produce estimates in country-years when survey data are sparse, or unavail-

able altogether. These features surmount the problem of sparse unevenly-available survey

data that has prevented previous studies from examining long-term changes in ideological

polarisation by age group. The model used in this paper is virtually identical to Caughey,

O’Grady, and Warshaw (2019), which includes extensive information on its estimation and

validation, including the scales’ internal consistency. The Supplementary Information for

this contains a more substantial verbal description of the modelling approach.

Underlying the estimated scales are over 100 individual survey questions across a wide

range of issues. They are taken from every existing cross-national European survey, in-

cluding the European Social Survey, Eurobarometer, ISSP modules, Pew Global Attitudes

Survey and the World Values Survey from 1981-2018. These all collect high-quality random

probability samples of the relevant national populations, with survey weights. Twenty-seven

European countries are included.4 I follow Caughey, O’Grady, and Warshaw (2019) in es-

timating scales for four ideological dimensions, each one estimated from a different set of

survey questions. These questions are identical to theirs, with the addition of two new years

of survey data in 2017 and 2018 and a small number of additional items. The Supplementary

Information fully details all survey questions used.

The first scale is labelled social and refers to social and post-material issues such as the

environment, abortion, gender equality and LGBT rights. The second is immigration and

includes questions on immigration and nationalism. The third is labeled relative economic

issues and is akin to ‘mood’ (Stimson 1991), using questions about the economic policy

status quo, primarily levels of taxation and government spending. The fourth is absolute

economic issues, using questions that ask about economic policy principles, such as the

desirability of redistribution in theory. The differential policy status quo across countries

means that citizens’ positions on the relative scale, but not the absolute scale, may reflect

existing levels of taxation and government spending as much as ideological beliefs, making

it vital to separate the two concepts. A country could, over time, desire greater government

spending because spending has fallen rather than due to changing views on the desirability

of spending in theory, which is captured by the absolute measure. This distinction is also

justified by the empirical results of both this paper and Caughey, O’Grady, and Warshaw

4. Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany,Great Britain, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Netherlands, Northern Ireland, Norway,Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland

5

(2019), which show that the two series are not correlated.

To maximise the availability of survey data for each observation, the scales are estimated

for two-year periods. They therefore show how left-wing or right-wing different age groups

have been every two years since the 1980s, across four issue dimensions and twenty-seven

European countries. With around one million individual survey items each and many param-

eters, there is a tradeoff between computational complexity and the number of age categories

for whom one can estimate ideological positions. I therefore estimated ideological positions

for six age categories of ten years each: those aged 18-27, 28-37, 38-47, 48-57, 58-67 and

68-77. The old are cut off at 77 so as to create groups of equal sizes. This is crucial in

allowing a comparison of cohorts over time, as shown below, and in practice there are few

survey respondents over 77. The estimates start in 1981-82 for social and absolute economic

issues, and in 1985-6 and 1989-90 respectively for relative economic issues and immigration,

as these are the first periods in which any survey data are available.

Ideological Polarisation over Time

Figure 1 shows how average ideological positions have evolved since 1981 for the six age

groups across all 27 countries.5 Higher scores on the ideological dimensions always represent

greater conservatism, e.g. opposition to redistribution, tax and spending, gender equality or

immigration. The scales are each identified by setting ideology to have a mean of zero and

variance of one across groups and periods.

Clear age differences on social issues are evident, alongside a broad liberalisation of

opinion for all age groups. Scores should be interpreted as standard deviations from the

overall mean of zero. Changes in social conservatism have been substantively large over

time: about 1.3 standard deviations for 68-77 year-olds from the early 1980s to the late

2010s. This is almost identical to the model-estimated difference between the average 68-

77 year-old in 2017-18 in Hungary – one of the most socially conservative countries – and

socially-liberal Germany. In the 2018 European Social Survey (ESS), which is in the scale,

30% of 68-77 year-olds in Hungary strongly disagreed with the statement “gay men and

lesbians should be free to live their life as they wish”, whereas just 2% did so in Germany.

However, my main interest here is in differences between age groups: polarisation. In the

average European country the ideological gap between the youngest and oldest age groups

5. These are posterior means for each age group, averaged across countries (without weighting by popula-tion): the model first outputs the position of each age group in each country. Effectively Figure 1 shows theideological position of age groups in the average country. Each model was estimated using four chains with2000 iterations each, with the first half of each chain as warmup. All conventional diagnostic tools, such asGelman-Rubin statistics, indicated that each model converged.

6

Absolute Economic Relative Economic

Social Immigration

1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010

−1.0

−0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

−1.0

−0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

Con

serv

atis

m

Age

18−27

28−37

38−47

48−57

58−67

68−77

Figure 1: Trends in average conservatism over time by age group and issue domain acrossEuropean Countries, 1981-82 to 2017-18 [lines = posterior means, shading = 95% credibleintervals, higher values = more conservative]

on social issues has barely changed over time, remaining relatively constant at around 1

standard deviation. Hungary again serves as a useful illustration, where in 2017-18 the

model-estimated difference between the youngest and oldest age groups was close to the

overall average of 1 (see Figure 2). In the 2018 ESS, 48% of Hungarian 68-77 year-olds either

7

agreed or strongly agreed with the same statement about LGBT rights above, compared to

26% of 18-27 year-olds. This shows that although age differences are unchanged, Europeans

have liberalised so much that a majority of all age groups in one of the most conservative

countries is not opposed to freedom for LGBT people, a point also made by Schafer (2021).

Polarisation certainly exists, but is not overwhelmingly large. Figure 1 also shows that the

youngest four age groups have become less distinguishable over time; the main difference

today is between the oldest citizens and all others. On immigration, a slightly smaller age

gradient has persisted as European countries slowly became more pro-immigration. Here

too, age differences have scarcely changed over time. Overall, ideological differences by age

on social issues and immigration are no larger today than they were in the 1980s.

Until recently young Europeans were somewhat more conservative than the old in abso-

lute terms, but age gaps have narrowed over the past decade, becoming very modest. For

relative economic conservatism age gaps widened from the late 1990s as the young became

more opposed to taxing and spending than the elderly. Although it narrowed a little over

the 2010s, at the end of the 2010s the age gradient in opinion on relative economic issues

remained almost as large as for immigration, but in the opposite direction. Millennials and

their younger counterparts would be better described as relatively libertarian rather than

relatively socialist: more socially liberal than older people, but also favouring smaller gov-

ernment. This finding may be surprising.6 In the Supplementary Information I show that

this aggregate measure faithfully reflects trends in the individual survey questions that com-

prise it; disaggregating by spending area does not alter these conclusions. Only on education

spending are young Europeans less conservative, but the gap has narrowed since the 1990s.

And as with social issues, there is substantial generational agreement: majorities of both the

young and old support higher pension spending, for instance.

To examine possible cross-country differences, Figure 2 plots estimates of the age gap

between the youngest and oldest groups for social issues and relative economic issues in

2017-18 and Figure 3 plots 95% credible intervals around them. Variation across countries

is mostly modest. In terms of mean differences, twenty of the twenty-seven countries occupy

the upper left libertarian quadrant, where the young are more liberal on social issues but

more conservative on tax and spending. Young people in Eastern European countries are

uniformly more libertarian, with generational differences on relative economic issues smaller

in Western and Southern Europe. Figure 3 shows that in only two countries can the youngest

and oldest not be distinguished statistically in their ideology on social issues, but in several

places they are not statistically different in terms of relative economic conservatism. No

country except Denmark, however, shows any evidence that the young prefer higher tax and

6. Although Barnes, Blumenau, and Lauderdale (2021) present similar findings (for the UK only)

8

AT

BE

BU

CY

CZDK

EST

FI

FR

DE

GB

GR

HU

IRL

IT

LA

LT

NL

NIRL

NO

PL

PT

SK

SI

ESP

SWE

SWI

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

−2 −1 0 1

Age Gap for Relative Economic Conservatism (Old − Young)

Age

Gap

for

Soc

ial C

onse

rvat

ism

(O

ld −

You

ng)

Figure 2: Age Differences in Conservatism (Old minus Young) by Country for Social Issuesand Relative Economic Issues, 2017-18 [Difference in posterior means between 68-77 year-olds and and 18-27 year-olds, by country. Positive = old people more conservative thanyoung people]

spending than the old. Figures S5 and S6 in the Supplementary Information show Figure 1

separately for Eastern and Western European countries. Although all age groups in Eastern

Europe have liberalised more slowly on non-economic issues – consistent with a later arrival

of the silent revolution there (Walczak, Van der Brug, and de Vries 2012) – age polarisation

has evolved almost identically in all regions across all dimensions. Whether one looks at

Europe as a whole, at individual countries or at European regions, the conclusions about

polarisation are the same.

9

10

−1

0

1

2

3

−4 −2 0 2

Age Gap for Relative Economic Conservatism (Old − Young)

Age

Gap

for

Soc

ial C

onse

rvat

ism

(O

ld −

You

ng)

Figure 3: 95% Credible Intervals for Age Differences in Conservatism (Old minus Young)by Country for Social Issues and Relative Economic Issues, 2017-18 [red=social issues,blue=relative economic issues]

Cohort Patterns

Why has age-based polarisation not grown over time? To answer this question I convert the

results for age groups into birth cohorts, using the fact that by looking ten years apart, we

observe the same cohort on multiple occasions. For example, those aged 18-27 in 1987-8 will

be 38-47 in 2007-8.7

I start with social issues, where age differences are largest. The evolution of each cohort’s

ideological position from 1987-8 to 2017-18 (mean positions and 95% credible intervals) is

shown in Figure 4. Some intra-cohort liberalisation is clear for all cohorts. However, within-

cohort change did not keep pace with overall change. The three generations for which we

have complete data liberalised by substantially less than the total change for age groups in

Europe over the period. On the other hand, diagonal comparisons across periods and cohorts

show different cohorts at the same ages. The 1960-70 cohort was aged 18-27 in 1987-8 with

an estimated ideology of -0.014, compared to the 1970-80 cohort who were 18-27 in 1997-8

with an estimated ideology of -0.53. This shows that in addition to within-cohort change

there have been large cohort replacement effects. Each cohort began its political life more

liberal than its predecessor and maintained this distinctiveness over time.

Thus age gaps in ideology on social issues have persisted (Figure 1) because despite all

cohorts liberalising over time, each new cohort has also been persistently more socially liberal

than its predecessor. The combination of within-cohort and cohort replacement effects left

polarisation between different age groups roughly unchanged. There is some evidence that

these cohort effects are slowing down. Younger cohorts are more homogenous than older

ones, beginning their political lives closer to the middle-aged than in the past. This helps

explain why, in Figure 1, the greatest age difference is observed between the oldest citizens,

and the middle-aged and below.

Figure 4 unambiguously demonstrates large cohort effects, but aggregate data on cohorts

cannot separate out age and period effects as explanations for within-cohort change. Theo-

retically, period effects are the more likely explanation. Existing theories of ageing predict

greater conservatism as a natural feature of ageing, and that age effects should primarily

kick in as people go past middle age. Yet Figure 2 shows that all cohorts became more

7. Strictly speaking, there is some very slight overlap at the edges of these groups due to the use of two-yearperiods to estimate ideological positions: someone born in 1960 observed in 1987-8 could appear in eitherthe 1950-60 cohort (aged 27 in 1987) or in the 1960-70 cohort (aged 28 in 1988). However such effects areminimal. This also assumes no differential mortality between left-wingers and right-wingers within cohorts(Rodriguez 2018). However wealth (and therefore life expectancy) may be positively related to economicconservatism and negatively related to social conservatism. For social issues and immigration, therefore, thepatterns in this paper might slightly over-state the contribution from within-cohort change and under-statethe contribution from cohort replacement, because social conservatives die younger.

11

−1.0

−0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

1987−8 1997−8 2007−8 2017−18

Soc

ial C

onse

rvat

ism

Cohort

1910−20

1920−30

1930−40

1940−50

1950−60

1960−70

1970−80

1980−90

1990−2000

Figure 4: Social Conservatism by Birth Cohort in Europe, 1987-8 to 2017-18 [higher values= more conservative, grey shading = 95% credible intervals]

left-wing on social issues, and that this continued when cohorts became elderly. It was not

the case that the elderly turned more conservative while the young became more liberal.

Period effects, as the prevailing social climate became more socially liberal, are a much more

plausible explanation for why all cohorts liberalised throughout their lives.

Figures 5 and 6 do the same exercise for immigration and relative economic issues for

1989-9 to 2009-10 and 1987-8 to 2017-18 respectively, because the immigration data do not

start until 1989-90. For immigration, within-cohort changes were mostly negligible, although

since 2000 there was some increased conservatism amongst older cohorts, consistent with a

backlash against Europe’s prevailing liberal consensus on the issue (Norris and Inglehart

2019). As with social issues, cohort replacement effects were large and consequential, with

new cohorts more pro-immigration than their predecessors at equivalent ages.

For relative economic issues, within-cohort changes were larger than for either immigra-

tion or social issues, and their direction also fluctuated over time. Cohorts tended to change

together over time, but behaved differently at equivalent ages. The 1950-60 cohort became

more conservative over the 1987/88 to 1997/98 period as they aged from 28-37 to 38-47

12

−1.0

−0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1989−90 1999−00 2009−10

Imm

igra

tion

Con

serv

atis

m Cohort

1912−22

1922−32

1932−42

1942−52

1952−62

1962−72

1972−82

1982−92

Figure 5: Immigration Conservatism by Birth Cohort in Europe, 1989-90 to 2009-10 [highervalues = more conservative, grey shading = 95% credible intervals]

whilst between the same ages, the 1970-80 cohort became more left-wing from 2007/8 to

2017/18. In other words, period effects operating on all cohorts at once were dominant.

Effects of ageing, on the other hand, would imply that at equivalent ages cohorts changed

in the same way. This is intuitive: changes in the size of governments as well as economic

booms and busts occur more often and more rapidly than the kinds of social change that

influence social conservatism. Since the mid-1990s new cohorts such as Millennials did in

fact begin their political lives more left-wing than previous cohorts were at an equivalent

age: compare the 1970-80 cohort at ages 18-27 (in 1997-8) to the 1980-90 cohort at the

same age (in 2007-8). But within-cohort change has outpaced the impact of these cohort

replacement effects. Older cohorts became so much more left-wing over the financial crisis

and its aftermath that at a given time, older age groups were more left-wing. Period effects

– but amongst groups older than millennials – have been the predominant influence.

13

−1.0

−0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1987−8 1997−8 2007−8 2017−18

Rel

ativ

e E

cono

mic

Con

serv

atis

m

Cohort

1910−20

1920−30

1930−40

1940−50

1950−60

1960−70

1970−80

1980−90

1990−2000

Figure 6: Relative Economic Conservatism by Birth Cohort in Europe, 1987-8 to 2017-18[higher values = more conservative, grey shading = 95% credible intervals]

5. Conclusion

This paper carried out a comprehensive examination of age differences in ideologies in Europe

since the 1980s, addressing unresolved theoretical and empirical debates. Some sociologists

and political scientists such as Cote (2014) and Norris and Inglehart (2019) have predicted

widening generational gaps on both economic and social issues, with the media depicting

young Europeans as increasingly socialist and ‘woke’ in the wake of widening age gaps in

terms of vote choice. Other scholars have cast doubt on this, whether taking issue with

previous empirical analyses (Schafer 2021) or arguing that age rather than cohort effects

dominate (e.g., Mulligan and Sala-i-Martin 1999). My analysis helped resolve these debates

by extending the analysis of age polarisation over a much longer time period, more issue

dimensions, and more countries than any previous study.

I found no evidence that the young and old are becoming increasingly ideologically op-

posed. Nor is it true that young Europeans today are much more socialist than the elderly,

or that age divisions over ‘woke’ issues are wider than in the past. In most places the young

14

are more opposed to tax and government spending than the elderly. Today’s age divides over

social issues and immigration are similar in size to the 1980s and if anything are starting

to fall, as the young and middle-aged become more similar. And despite these age gaps, on

issues such as LGBT rights and pension spending, majorities of the young and old support

the same policies. However, polarisation has not remained fairly constant for non-economic

issues due to age effects being dominant: there is little evidence that ageing naturally leads

to greater conservatism. Today’s age divides have arisen from a sometimes complex inter-

action of cohort and period effects, with cohort effects especially important for social issues

and immigration. Hence age-based polarisation need not be a permanent or natural feature

of European politics, but depends on changing social, political and economic climates. If

cohort replacement effects for social issues continue to slow down, age divides will fall.

If ideological age gaps are largely unchanged, why have age gaps for voting widened

recently? A likely explanation is that the emergence of new parties with more extreme

positions on social issues and immigration over the past thirty years – and more emphatic

communication of these stances – has helped the young and old to better express their long-

standing non-economic differences when voting. Age divides might appear to have grown

due to the actions of parties, but in reality young and old voters in Europe are not more

polarised than in the past.

15

References

Andor, Mark, Christoph M. Schmidt, and Stephan Sommer. 2018. “Climate Change, Pop-

ulation Ageing and Public Spending: Evidence on Individual Preferences.” Ecological

Economics 151:173–183.

Barnes, Lucy, Jack Blumenau, and Benjamin E. Lauderdale. 2021. “Measuring Attitudes

toward Public Spending Using a Multivariate Tax Summary Experiment.” American

Journal of Political Science 66 (1): 205–221.

Bell, Torsten, and Laura Gardiner. 2019. “My Generation, Baby: The Politics of Age in

Brexit Britain.” The Political Quarterly 90 (S2): 128–141.

Bessant, Judith, Rys Farthing, and Rob Watts. 2017. The Precarious Generation: A Political

Economy of Young People. New York: Routledge.

Blais, Andre, and Daniel Rubenson. 2013. “The Source of Turnout Decline: New Values or

New Contexts?” Comparative Political Studies 46 (1): 95–117.

Busemeyer, Marius, Achim Goerres, and Simon Weschle. 2009. “Attitudes towards redis-

tributive spending in an era of demographic ageing: the rival pressures from age and

income in 14 OECD countries.” Journal of European Social Policy 19 (3): 195–212.

Cattaneo, M. Alejandra, and Stefan C. Wolter. 2009. “Are the elderly a threat to educational

expenditures?” European Journal of Political Economy 25:225–236.

Caughey, Devin, Tom O’Grady, and Christopher Warshaw. 2019. “Policy Ideology in Euro-

pean Mass Publics, 1981-2016.” American Political Science Review, 113 (3): 674–693.

Cornelis, Ilse, Alain Van Hiel, Arne Roets, and Malgorzata Kossowska. 2009. “Age Differences

in Conservatism: Evidence on the Mediating Effects of Personality and Cognitive Style.”

Journal of Personality 77 (1): 51–88.

Cote, James. 2014. “Towards a New Political Economy of Youth.” Journal of Youth Studies

17 (4): 527–543.

Dunham, James, Devin Caughey, and Christopher Warshaw. 2017. dgo: Dynamic Estimation

of Group-Level Opinion. R package version 0.2.14. https://jamesdunham.github.io/

dgo/.

Ehsan, Rakib, and James Sloam. 2020. “Resources, Values, Identity: Young Cosmopolitans

and the Referendum on British Membership of the European Union.” Parliamentary

Affairs 73 (1): 46–65.

16

Furlong, Andy, and Fred Cartmel. 2007. Young People and Social Change: New Perspectives

(2nd ed.) New York: Open University Press.

Giuliano, Paola, and Antonio Spilimbergo. 2014. “Growing up in a Recession.” Review of

Economic Studies 81 (2): 787–817.

Grasso, Maria Teresa, Stephen Farrall, Emily Gray, Colin Hay, and Will Jennings. 2019.

“Thatcher’s Children, Blair’s Babies, Political Socialization and Trickle-down Value

Change: An Age, Period and Cohort Analysis.” British Journal of Political Science

49 (1): 17–36.

Hausermann, Silja, Thomas Kurer, and Hanna Schwander. 2015. “High-skilled outsiders?

Labor market vulnerability, education and welfare state preferences.” Socio-Economic

Review 13 (2): 235–258.

Hess, Moritz, Elias Nauman, and Leander Steinkopf. 2017. “Population Ageing, the Inter-

generational Conflict, and Active Ageing Policies – a Multilevel Study of 27 European

Countries.” Population Ageing 10 (1): 11–23.

Huttle, Pia, Karen Wilson, and Guntram B. Wolff. 2015. “The Growing Intergenerational

Divide in Europe.” Bruegel Policy Contribution No. 2015.17, Breugel, Brussels.

Inglehart, Ronald. 2008. “Changing Values Amongst Western Publics, 1970-2006: Postma-

terialistic Values and the Shift from Survival Values to Self-Expression Values.” West

European Politics 31 (1-2): 130–146.

Lennartz, Christian, Rowan Arundel, and Richard Ronald. 2016. “Younger Adults and Home

Ownership in Europe Through the Global Financial Crisis.” Population, Space and Place

22 (8): 823–835.

Mulligan, Casey, and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1999. “Gerontocracy, Retirement and Social Se-

curity.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 7117.

Norris, Pippa, and Ronald Inglehart. 2019. Cultural Backlash: Trump, Brexit, and Authori-

tarian Populism. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Orriols, Lluis, and Guillermo Cordero. 2016. “The Breakdown of the Spanish Two-Party Sys-

tem: The Upsurge of Podemos and Ciudadanos in the 2015 General Election.” Southern

European Society and Politics 21 (4): 469–492.

Peterson, Johnathan C., Kevin B. Smith, and John R. Hibbing. 2020. “Do People really

Become More Conservative as they Age?” Journal of Politics 82 (2).

17

Poterba, James. 1997. “Demographic Structure and the Political Economy of Public Educa-

tion.” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 16 (1): 48–66.

Rodriguez, Javier M. 2018. “Health disparities, politics, and the maintenance of the status

quo: A new theory of inequality.” Social Science & Medicine 200:36–43.

Ross, Alastair. 2018. “Young Europeans: A New Political Generation?” Societies 8 (3).

Schafer, Armin. 2021. “Cultural Backlash? How (Not) to Explain the Rise of Authoritarian

Populism.” British Journal of Political Science, published online.

Seeleib-Kaiser, Martin, and Thees F Spreckelsen. 2018. “Youth labour market outsiderness:

The ‘Nordic model’ compared with Britain and Germany.” In Youth, Diversity and Em-

ployment: Comparative Perspectives on Labour Market Policies, edited by R. Halvovsen

and Bjorn Hvinde. Edward Elgar.

Sloam, James, Rakib Ehsan, and Matt Henn. 2018. “‘Youthquake’: How and Why Young

People Reshaped the Political Landscape in 2017.” Political Insight 9 (1): 4–8.

Smets, Kaat. 2012. “A Widening Generational Divide? The Age Gap in Voter Turnout

Through Time and Space.” Journal of Elections, Public Opinion & Parties 22 (4): 407–

430.

Sorensen, Rune J. 2013. “Does Aging Affect Preferences for Welfare Spending? A Study

of Peoples’ Spending Preferences in 22 Countries, 1985–2006.” European Journal of

Political Economy 29:259–271.

Stimson, James. A. 1991. Public Opinion in America: Moods, Cycles and Swings. Boulder,

CO: Westview Press.

Walczak, Agnieszka, Wouter Van der Brug, and Catherine de Vries. 2012. “Long- and short-

term determinants of party preferences: Inter-generational differences in Western and

East Central Europe.” Electoral Studies 31:273–284.

18

Supplementary Information for “ls Ideological Polarisation by Age

Group Growing in Europe?”

19

1 Explanation of the Modelling Procedure

Readers interested in the technical details of the model, its estimation, and validation of the

resultant scales, are referred to Caughey, O’Grady and Warshaw (2019). As explained below,

it contains very extensive validation exercises that justify a four-dimensional structure for

European opinion and that establish the internal consistency of each scale.

1.1 How similar is this paper’s modelling approach to Caughey,

O’Grady and Warshaw (2019)?

The modelling approach is the same as theirs, with one minor change: whereas they estimate

opinion for three age groups and two genders, I estimate opinion for six age groups. It is

computationally very difficult to estimate for many more than six demographic groups, and

in some cases the number of responpents in a given country-year would be too small for

certain groups defined by age and gender. The model that produces these scales is identical

in both papers, as is the R package that implements it.

This paper also uses slightly more data than Caughey, O’Grady and Warshaw (2019):

mainly due to extending their data from 2016 to 2018, but also because a few additional

items that were missed in their paper (such as opinions about welfare provision in the ESS)

were also added.

A comparison of Figure 2 in their paper to Figure 1 in this paper shows that the two

approaches produce near-identical results, as should be expected.

1.2 Why is this methodological approach needed? Why not use

other approaches?

The core problem solved by this methodological approach is that existing survey data is

sparsely available across both time and countries. The same question, for instance on redis-

tribution, might appear only in five years for the whole 1981-2018 period, and even in those

years it is unlikely to be available across all European countries. This sparseness presents

three key problems that the Caughey, O’Grady and Warshaw model solves.

First, a naive model of ideological change would be difficult to interpret. Suppose, for

example, that one simply measured conservatism in each available year by taking the propor-

tion of left- or right-wing responses across all questions asked in that year. Such a measure

would be sensitive to differences in baseline support across questions when questions appear

unevenly. Suppose that in different years, 10% of respondents in a survey in year t disagreed

that “it should be the government’s responsibility to provide healthcare for the sick,” but

20

50% of respondents in a survey in year t+2 disagreed that “it should be the government’s

responsibility to provide a decent standard of living for the unemployed.” Suppose further

that we tried to use the percentage disagreeing with each one as a measure of conservatism

in each year. Then, we could not tell whether the difference in opposition was due to a

genuine rise in conservatism, or because equally-conservative respondents prefer supporting

sick citizens to supporting the unemployed.

Second, this problem potentially motivates the use of more nuanced scaling techniques

such as a standard IRT model or principle component analysis, but these approaches are also

impossible with standard cross-national surveys. In most years, there are at best a handful

of questions per respondent on any particular dimension, but an IRT model estimated for

individual respondents requires many more responses for estimation.

Third and most crucially, some time periods feature either no survey questions at all,

a tiny handful of questions, or a tiny handful of countries. A naive model would simply

produce no estimates for these country-years (in the case of wholly missing data), or it

would be very unstable and sensitive to the actual questions asked (in the case of only one

or two questions). Because a large number of country-years are missing any data at all, there

would be a lot of missingness in any estimates of cross-national/over-time ideologies. This

is conceptually similar to the familiar problem of missing responses within a given survey.

Indeed, one way of thinking of the Caughey-O’Grady-Warshaw model is that in years where

data are very sparse or non-existent, it imputes the missing data in a similar fashion to

multiple imputation procedures.

1.3 How does the method work? How does it solve the problems

presented by sparse and unevenly-available data?

The model essentially contains two main components.

1. The first is an ordinal IRT model of ideology (within each of the four issue domains)

for age groups within countries rather than for individual survey respondents. In a

standard way, this assumes that for a given survey question, the probability of an in-

dividual from a particular age group selecting level k of a question’s response scale is

positively related to that group’s conservatism as well as the question-specific thresh-

old for a conservative response, with the “discrimination” of each survey item (i.e., the

strength of its relationship to conservatism) also estimated. The number of individuals

in a given group giving a particular response is then estimated with a standard multi-

nomial sampling model, adjusted for survey weights, implying a likelihood function

and hence estimates of country-age-group ideological positions.

21

2. The second stage takes these country-age-group estimates and smooths them across

time and countries using a hierarchical model for the group means. The magnitude

of change between years is constrained by a prior that predicts the group’s ideological

position based on its value in adjacent time periods. The final posterior estimates of

ideology are a compromise between this prior and the likelihood implied by stage 1.

This overcomes the three problems mentioned above:

1. Estimating the relationship of each question to latent conservatism greatly reduces the

model’s sensitivity to which questions are asked when.

2. Although each individual answers only a few questions in each survey, there are many

survey responses from each group (e.g., 18-27 year-olds in Germany), making an IRT

model at the level of groups feasible.

3. The hierarchical model facilitates estimation of ideology when data is sparse. When a

lot of survey data are available for a given country-year, the likelihood will be given

more weight by the model. With less survey data, the prior gets more weight. If no

survey data are available at all, this prior acts as a predictive model that imputes

ideology.

1.4 How do we know that the scales have the same meaning over

time?

This is, of course, a problem that can affect any long-term measure of conservatism, whether

looking only at individual survey questions or using alternative algorithms such as Stimson’s

dyad ratios procedure. Different survey items might give a different picture of conservatism,

and they are unevenly available over time and space.

The use of an IRT model helps deal with the concern about different questions having

different meanings for responents (or to put it in the language of IRT models: each ques-

tion has a different relationship to latent conservatism; some survey items are better than

others at discriminating between left- and right-wing groups). IRT models such as the one

used in the paper deal with that problem by directly estimating the discrimination of each

survey item. That means that the model is sensitive to which questions are being asked

when: the threshold parameters governing the relationship between survey items and latent

conservatism are different for each survey question, so that not every survey item ‘affects’

the scales in the same way.

A more technical issue is whether or not the model should allow these threshold parame-

ters to evolve over time, capturing the notion that the relationship between survey items and

22

latent conservatism might be different at different times. This more flexible model would

come with significant downsides however. First, it would mean that the substantive meaning

of ‘conservatism’ is not fixed over the course of the estimation. We could not say whether

a given country-age group has become more conservative over time, only whether they have

become more or less conservative in terms of their alignment with prevailing definitions of

‘conservatism’ at given times. Second, such a model would be likely to under-estimate ide-

ological change by attributing some of it to changes in the item thresholds. During their

review process, Caughey, O’Grady and Warshaw also carried out extensive comparisons of

model results with fixed and evolving thresholds. These yielded substantially almost identi-

cal results, suggesting that the assumption of fixed thresholds is empirically defensible. For

those reasons the Caughey-O’Grady-Warshaw model uses fixed threshold parameters that

do not change over time and in effect pre-suppose that ‘social conservatism’, for instance,

means the same thing in the 1980s as in the 2010s. This is not unreasonable: someone who

opposes abortion and gender equality would be considered conservative in both periods.

1.5 How do we know that survey items within the four domains

‘belong’ together? Why these four scales and not others?

As Caughey, O’Grady and Warshaw (2019: 678-9) put it, “we emphasize that our catego-

rization of questions [into scales] was based on ex ante substantive judgment and not on

statistical criteria for selecting the “correct” number of latent dimensions, making it anal-

ogous to confirmatory rather than exploratory factor analysis.” This makes sense because

there is surely no single correct answer to the question: “how many issue dimensions are

there in European politics?” Rather, there are more and less useful ways to summarise

conservatism in terms of underlying sets of survey questions.

Nonetheless, their measures are derived explicitly from substantive theories about the

content of different issue dimensions, as theorised by scholars such as Ronald Inglehart,

Herbert Kitschelt and Hanspeter Kriesi. Theories of (for instance) post-material values

state that opinions on issues as diverse as marijuana legalisation, abortion rights and same-

sex marriage are all related to an underlying socially conservative/socially liberal dimension

and should be expected to move together over time, for instance in line with economic

development.

The fact that all four scales are poorly correlated over time provides a clear empirical

justification for separating them.8 Notably, they show that their results for the social issues

8. Although across Europe as a whole, immigration and social conservatism move together, this is nottrue of individual countries: see Caughey, O’Grady and Warshaw 2019, p. 684.

23

scale are unaffected by removing items related to the environment, which are classified as

‘postmaterial’ issues by Inglehart but might be thought of as theoretically unrelated to issues

such as gender equality and LGBT rights. Moreover, they also provide extensive confirmatory

factor analysis of all the scales in their Supplementary Information. Their analysis, including

scree plots, demonstrates that each scale is explained primarily by a single dimension. And

within each scale, virtually all survey items are positively correlated with each other. These

provide further empirical justification for the scales.

1.6 What other problems might exist with these scales?

There are a number of potential limitations, all of which could affect the cross-country

or over-time comparability of all cross-national survey data or measures derived from it,

including our scales and previous measures of European ideology such as self-placement on

a left-right scale. These limitations include: differences in sampling procedures or survey

response patterns that lead to measured cross-country or over-time differences in opinion in

the absence of genuine differences; differential item functioning, such that different people in

different countries or periods interpret the same questions differently; or differential influence

from the policy ‘status quo’ across countries (whereby, for instance, equally-conservative

respondents respond differently to the question “should gays and lesbians be free to live

their lives as they wish?” based on the prevailing levels of LGBT rights in their country).

24

2DetailsofSurv

eyItemsIn

cluded

inth

eM

odels

Key

toda

tase

ts:

ISSP

=In

tern

atio

nal

Surv

eyP

rogr

am;

RO

G=

“Rol

eof

Gov

ernm

ent”

surv

eym

odule

s;IN

EQ

=“S

oci

al

Ineq

ual

ity”

surv

eym

odule

s;E

NV

=“E

nvir

onm

ent”

surv

eym

odule

s;N

I=

“Nat

ional

Iden

tity

”su

rvey

module

s;F

+G

=“F

amily

and

Gen

der

”su

rvey

module

s;E

SS

=E

uro

pea

nSoci

alSurv

ey;

EV

S=

Euro

pea

nV

alues

Surv

ey;

EB

VA

L=

Euro

bar

omet

er

spec

ial

surv

eys

onso

cial

valu

es;

EB

EM

P=

Euro

bar

omet

ersp

ecia

lsu

rvey

son

emplo

ym

ent

and

soci

alp

olic

y;

EB

PO

V=

Euro

bar

omet

ersp

ecia

lsu

rvey

son

pov

erty

and

soci

alex

clusi

on;

PE

W=

Pew

Glo

bal

Att

itudes

Surv

ey

Table

S1:Variablesincludedin

theAbso

lute

Eco

nomic

Sca

le

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

govre

dis

t1IS

SP

RO

G,

1985

,19

90,

1992

,W

hat

isyo

ur

opin

ion

ofth

efo

llow

ing

stat

emen

t:5-

poi

nt

ISSP

INE

Q.,

1993

,19

96,

“it

isth

ere

spon

sibilit

yof

the

gove

rnm

ent

to1

=ag

ree

stro

ngl

y,5

=dis

agre

est

rongl

y

ISSP

EN

V19

99,

2000

,re

duce

diff

eren

ces

inin

com

eb

etw

een

thos

ew

ith

2009

,20

10hig

hin

com

esan

dth

ose

wit

hlo

win

com

es”

wag

econ

tIS

SP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96“H

ere

are

som

eth

ings

the

gove

rnm

ent

mig

ht

do

5-p

oint

for

the

econ

omy.

Ple

ase

show

whic

hac

tion

syo

u1

=st

rongl

yfa

vor,

5=

stro

ngl

yag

ainst

are

infa

vor

ofan

dw

hic

hyo

uar

eag

ainst

”..

.

contr

olof

wag

esby

law

pri

ceco

nt

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96[a

sab

ove]

...c

ontr

olof

pri

ces

by

law

5-p

oint

1=

stro

ngl

yfa

vor,

5=

stro

ngl

yag

ainst

govjo

bs

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]..

.finan

cing

ofpro

ject

sto

crea

tenew

5-p

oint

2006

jobs

1=

stro

ngl

yfa

vor,

5=

stro

ngl

yag

ainst

govin

dust

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]..

.supp

ort

for

indust

ryto

dev

elop

new

5-p

oint

2006

pro

duct

san

dte

chnol

ogy

1=

stro

ngl

yfa

vor,

5=

stro

ngl

yag

ainst

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

25

Tab

le1

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

govdec

line

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]..

.supp

ort

for

dec

linin

gin

dust

ries

5-p

oint

2006

,20

16to

pro

tect

jobs

1=

stro

ngl

yfa

vor,

5=

stro

ngl

yag

ainst

govw

eek

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]..

.red

uci

ng

the

wor

kin

gw

eek

to5-

poi

nt

2006

,20

16cr

eate

mor

ejo

bs

1=

stro

ngl

yfa

vor,

5=

stro

ngl

yag

ainst

unem

pin

flIS

SP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96If

the

gove

rnm

ent

had

toch

oos

eb

etw

een

keep

ing

2-p

oint

dow

nin

flat

ion

orke

epin

gdow

nunem

plo

ym

ent,

to1

=unem

plo

ym

ent,

2=

inflat

ion

whic

hdo

you

thin

kit

shou

ldgi

veth

ehig

hes

t

pri

orit

y?

ownel

ect

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96W

hat

do

you

thin

ksh

ould

be

the

1=

Ow

nit

gove

rnm

ent’

sro

lein

each

ofth

ese

indust

ries

2=

contr

olpri

ces

and

pro

fits

,don

’tow

n

and

serv

ices

shou

ldb

e?..

.Ele

ctri

city

3=

nei

ther

ownban

ks

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96[a

sab

ove]

...B

ankin

gan

dIn

sura

nce

As

abov

e

resp

job

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

On

the

whol

e,do

you

thin

kit

shou

ldor

4-p

oint

2006

,20

16sh

ould

not

be

the

resp

onsi

bilty

ofth

e1

=defi

nit

ely

shou

ldb

e

gove

rnm

ent

to..

.pro

vid

ea

job

for

4=

defi

nit

ely

shou

ldnot

be

ever

yone

who

wan

tson

e

resp

hea

lth

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]..

.pro

vid

ehea

lthca

refo

rth

esi

ckA

sab

ove

2006

,20

16

resp

old

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]..

.pro

vid

ea

dec

ent

stan

dar

dof

As

abov

e

2006

,20

16livin

gfo

rth

eol

d

resp

ind

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]..

.pro

vid

ein

dust

ryw

ith

the

hel

pit

As

abov

e

2006

,20

16nee

ds

togr

ow

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

26

Tab

le1

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

resp

um

pIS

SP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]..

.pro

vid

ea

dec

ent

stan

dar

dof

As

abov

e

2006

,20

16livin

gfo

rth

eunem

plo

yed

govre

dis

t2IS

SP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]..

.red

uce

inco

me

diff

eren

ces

As

abov

e

2006

,20

16b

etw

een

the

rich

and

poor

resp

stud

ISSP

RO

G19

90,

1996

,[a

sab

ove]

...g

ive

finan

cial

hel

pto

As

abov

e

2006

,20

16univ

ersi

tyst

uden

tsfr

omlo

w-i

nco

me

fam

ilie

s

resp

hou

seIS

SP

RO

G19

90,

1996

,[a

sab

ove]

...p

rovid

edec

ent

hou

sing

for

As

abov

e

2006

,20

16th

ose

who

can’t

affor

dit

equal

opp

ESS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,“I

tis

imp

orta

nt

that

ever

yp

erso

nin

the

wor

ld6-

poi

nt

10,

12,

14,

16,

18sh

ould

be

trea

ted

equal

ly,

and

ever

yone

shou

ldto

p3

resp

onse

sin

dic

ate

dis

agre

emen

t

hav

eeq

ual

opp

ortu

nit

ies

inlife

.”

unem

pjo

bE

VS

1990

,19

99-0

0,[a

sab

ove]

1=

peo

ple

who

are

unem

plo

yed

10-p

oint

2008

-10

shou

ldhav

eth

eri

ght

tore

fuse

ajo

bth

ey

do

not

wan

t..

.10

=p

eople

who

are

unem

plo

yed

shou

ldhav

eto

take

any

job

avai

lable

orlo

seth

eir

unem

plo

ym

ent

ben

efits

secf

air

EV

S19

81-2

,19

90“I

mag

ine

two

secr

etar

ies,

ofth

esa

me

age,

doi

ng

2-p

oint

1999

-00

pra

ctic

ally

the

sam

ejo

b.

Inyo

ur

opin

ion

isit

fair

1=

unfa

ir,

2=

fair

ornot

fair

that

one

secr

etar

yis

pai

dm

ore

than

,

the

other

ifsh

eis

quic

ker,

mor

eeffi

cien

tan

dm

ore

reliab

leat

her

job?”

free

dom

EV

S19

81-2

,19

90W

hat

ism

ore

imp

orta

nt,

free

dom

or3-

poi

nt

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

27

Tab

le1

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

1999

-00,

2008

-10

equal

ity?

1=

equal

ity,

3=

free

dom

concu

mp

EV

S19

90,

1999

-00,

To

what

exte

nt

do

you

feel

conce

rned

abou

t5-

poi

nt

2008

-10

the

livin

gco

ndit

ions

ofth

eunem

plo

yed?

1=

very

much

,5

=not

atal

l

diff

nec

ISSP

INE

Q19

87,

1992

,In

order

toge

tp

eople

tow

ork

har

d,

do

you

4-p

oint

2009

thin

kla

rge

diff

eren

ces

inpay

are

nec

essa

ry?

1=

defi

nit

ely

not

,4

=ab

solu

tely

incp

rosp

ISSP

INE

Q19

87,

1992

,D

oyo

uag

ree

ordis

agre

ew

ith

thes

e5-

poi

nt

1999

stat

emen

ts..

.“la

rge

diff

eren

ces

inin

com

e1

=st

rongl

ydis

agre

e,5

=st

rongl

yag

ree

are

nec

essa

ryfo

ra

countr

y’s

pro

sper

ty”

unip

oor

ISSP

INE

Q19

87,

1992

Ple

ase

show

how

much

you

agre

eor

5-p

oint

dis

agre

ew

ith

thes

est

atem

ents

...“

the

1=

stro

ngl

yag

ree,

5=

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e

gove

rnm

ent

shou

ldpro

vid

em

ore

chan

ces

for

childre

nfr

omp

oor

fam

ilie

sto

goto

univ

ersi

ty”

resp

job1

ISSP

INE

Q19

87,

1992

[as

abov

e]..

.“th

ego

vern

men

tsh

ould

pro

vid

e5-

poi

nt

ajo

bfo

rev

eryo

ne

who

wan

tson

e”1

=st

rongl

yag

ree,

5=

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e

resp

um

p1

ISSP

INE

Q19

87,

1992

[as

abov

e]..

.“th

ego

vern

men

tsh

ould

pro

vid

e5-

poi

nt

2009

adec

ent

stan

dar

dof

livin

gfo

rth

eunem

plo

yed”

1=

stro

ngl

yag

ree,

5=

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e

bas

icin

cIS

SP

INE

Q19

87,

1992

[as

abov

e]..

.“th

ego

vern

men

tsh

ould

pro

vid

e5-

poi

nt

ever

yone

wit

ha

guar

ante

edbas

icin

com

e”1

=st

rongl

yag

ree,

5=

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e

taxri

ch1

ISSP

INE

Q19

87,

1992

,D

oyo

uth

ink

that

peo

ple

wit

hhig

hin

com

es5-

poi

nt

1999

,20

09sh

ould

pay

ala

rger

shar

eof

thei

rin

com

ein

taxes

1=

much

larg

ersh

are

than

thos

ew

ith

low

inco

mes

,th

esa

me

shar

eor

5=

much

smal

ler

shar

e

asm

alle

rsh

are?

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

28

Tab

le1

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

pri

vent

ISSP

EN

V19

93,

2000

,H

owm

uch

do

you

agre

eor

dis

agre

ew

ith

the

5-p

oint

2010

follow

ing

stat

emen

ts..

.“pri

vate

ente

rpri

seis

1=

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e,5

=st

rongl

yag

ree

the

bes

tw

ayto

solv

em

yco

untr

y’s

pro

ble

ms”

free

com

pE

BV

AL

2006

,20

08,

For

each

ofth

efo

llow

ing

pro

pos

itio

ns,

tell

me

4-p

oint

2009

ifyo

uag

ree

ordis

agre

e..

.“F

ree

com

pet

itio

nis

1=

tota

lly

dis

agre

e,4

=to

tally

agre

e

the

bes

tgu

aran

tee

for

econ

omic

pro

sper

ity

eqju

stE

BV

AL

2006

,20

08,

[as

abov

e]..

.“W

enee

dm

ore

equal

ity

and

just

ice

4-p

oint

2009

even

ifth

ism

eans

less

free

dom

for

the

indiv

idual

”1

=to

tally

dis

agre

e,4

=to

tally

agre

e

govre

dis

t3E

BP

OV

2009

,20

10F

orea

chof

the

follow

ing

pro

pos

itio

ns,

tell

me

4-p

oint

ifyo

uag

ree

ordis

agre

e..

.“th

ego

vern

men

t1

=to

tally

agre

e,4

=to

tally

dis

agre

e

shou

lden

sure

that

the

wea

lth

ofth

eco

untr

yis

redis

trib

ute

din

afa

irw

ayto

all

citi

zens”

nofi

ght

EB

PO

V20

02,

2010

[as

abov

e]“T

her

eis

no

poi

nt

intr

yin

gto

figh

t4-

poi

nt

pov

erty

,it

will

alw

ays

exis

t”1

=to

tally

dis

agre

e,4

=to

tally

agre

e

diff

nec

1E

BP

OV

2009

,20

10[a

sab

ove]

“Inco

me

ineq

ual

itie

sar

enec

essa

ry4-

poi

nt

for

econ

omic

dev

elop

men

t”

1=

tota

lly

dis

agre

e,

som

ear

ep

oor

4=

tota

lly

agre

e

free

mkt

PE

W20

02,

07,

08,

09M

ost

peo

ple

are

bet

ter

offin

afr

eem

arke

t4-

poi

nt

econ

omy,

even

thou

ghso

me

peo

ple

are

rich

1=

com

ple

tely

dis

agre

e,

and

som

ear

ep

oor

4=

com

ple

tely

agre

e

inte

rfer

eP

EW

2002

,09

,11

,12

what

’sm

ore

imp

orta

nt

in(s

urv

eyco

untr

y)

4-p

oint

soci

ety

–th

atev

eryo

ne

be

free

topurs

ue

1=

opti

on2,

2=

opti

on1

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

29

Tab

le1

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

thei

rlife

’sgo

als

life

’sgo

als

wit

hou

t

inte

rfer

ence

from

the

stat

e,or

that

the

stat

epla

yan

acti

vero

lein

soci

ety

soas

to

guar

ante

eth

atnob

ody

isin

nee

d?

Table

S2:Variablesincluded

inth

eRelativeEco

nomic

Sca

le

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

cuts

pen

dIS

SP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

Infa

vour

orop

pos

ecu

tsin

5-p

oint

2006

,20

16go

vern

men

tsp

endin

g1

=st

rongl

yag

ainst

,5

=st

rongl

yin

favo

r

less

reg

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

Infa

vour

orop

pos

ele

ss5-

poi

nt

2006

,20

16go

vern

men

tre

gula

tion

sof

1=

stro

ngl

yag

ainst

,5

=st

rongl

yin

favo

r

busi

nes

s

spen

dhea

lth

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

Lis

ted

bel

owar

eva

riou

sar

eas

5-p

oint

2006

,20

16of

gove

rnm

ent

spen

din

g.P

leas

e1

=sp

end

much

mor

e,5

=sp

end

much

less

show

whet

her

you

wou

ldlike

to

see

mor

eor

less

gove

rnm

ent

spen

din

gin

each

area

.

Rem

emb

erth

atif

you

say

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

30

Tab

le2

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

“much

mor

e”,

itm

ight

requir

e

ata

xin

crea

seto

pay

for

it

...“

Hea

lth”

spen

ded

uc

ISSP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]“E

duca

tion

”5-

poi

nt

2006

,20

161

=sp

end

much

mor

e,5

=sp

end

much

less

spen

dol

dIS

SP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]“O

ldA

geP

ensi

ons”

5-p

oint

2006

,20

161

=sp

end

much

mor

e,5

=sp

end

much

less

spen

dum

pIS

SP

RO

G19

85,

1990

,19

96,

[as

abov

e]“U

nem

plo

ym

ent

5-p

oint

2006

,20

16B

enefi

ts”

1=

spen

dm

uch

mor

e,5

=sp

end

much

less

taxhig

hin

cIS

SP

RO

G,

1987

,19

92,

1996

,T

axes

for

thos

ew

ith

hig

h5-

poi

nt

INE

Q20

06,

2016

inco

mes

are

too

hig

hor

too

1=

much

too

low

,5

=m

uch

too

hig

h

low

taxm

idin

cIS

SP

RO

G,

1987

,19

92,

1996

,T

axes

for

thos

ew

ith

mid

dle

5-p

oint

INE

Q20

06,

2016

inco

mes

are

too

hig

hor

too

1=

much

too

low

,5

=m

uch

too

hig

h

low

taxlo

win

cIS

SP

RO

G,

1987

,19

92,

1996

,T

axes

for

thos

ew

ith

low

5-p

oint

INE

Q20

06,

2016

inco

mes

are

too

hig

hor

too

1=

much

too

low

,5

=m

uch

too

hig

h

low

incd

iffIS

SP

INE

Q19

87,

1992

,19

99,

Diff

eren

ces

inin

com

ein

my

5-p

oint

2009

countr

yar

eto

ola

rge

1=

Str

ongl

yA

gree

,5

=Str

ongl

yD

isag

ree

less

ben

sIS

SP

INE

Q19

87,

1992

,T

he

gove

rnm

ent

shou

ldsp

end

5-p

oint

2009

less

onb

enefi

tsfo

rth

ep

oor

1=

Str

ongl

yD

isag

ree,

5=

Str

ongl

yA

gree

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

31

Tab

le2

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

unip

oor

ISSP

INE

Q19

87,

1992

The

gove

rnm

ent

shou

ldpro

vid

e5-

poi

nt

mor

ech

ance

sfo

rch

ildre

nfr

om1

=st

rongl

yag

ree,

5=

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e

poor

fam

ilie

sto

goto

univ

ersi

ty

govre

dis

tE

SS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,T

he

gove

rnm

ent

shou

ldta

ke5-

poi

nt

10,

12,

14,

16,

18m

easu

res

tore

duce

diff

eren

ces

in1

=ag

ree

stro

ngl

y,5

=dis

agre

est

rongl

y

inco

me

leve

ls

ben

seco

nE

SS

2008

,20

16Soci

alb

enefi

ts/s

ervic

espla

ce5-

poi

nt

too

grea

tst

rain

onec

onom

y1

=ag

ree

stro

ngl

y,5

=dis

agre

est

rongl

y

ben

sbus

ESS

2008

,20

16Soci

alb

enefi

ts/s

ervic

esco

st5-

poi

nt

busi

nes

ses

too

much

inta

xes

/1

=ag

ree

stro

ngl

y,5

=dis

agre

est

rongl

y

char

ges

ben

slaz

yE

SS

2008

,20

16Soci

alb

enefi

ts/s

ervic

esm

ake

5-p

oint

peo

ple

lazy

1=

agre

est

rongl

y,5

=dis

agre

est

rongl

y

unem

ptr

yE

SS

2008

,20

16-

Mos

tunem

plo

yed

peo

ple

do

5-p

oint

not

real

lytr

yto

find

ajo

b1

=ag

ree

stro

ngl

y,5

=dis

agre

est

rongl

y

enti

tled

ESS

2008

,20

16M

any

man

age

toob

tain

5-p

oint

ben

efits

/ser

vic

esnot

enti

tled

1=

agre

est

rongl

y,5

=dis

agre

est

rongl

y

to

taxhig

her

EB

PO

V20

09,

2010

Peo

ple

who

are

wel

l-off

shou

ldpay

4-p

oint

hig

her

taxes

soth

ego

vern

men

t1

=to

tally

agre

e,4

=to

tally

dis

agre

e

has

mor

em

eans

tofigh

tp

over

ty”

eqin

cent

EV

S19

90,

1999

-00,

“How

wou

ldyo

upla

ceyo

ur

vie

ws

”10

-poi

nt

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

32

Tab

le2

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

2008

-10

onth

issc

ale?

1=

inco

mes

shou

ld

be

mad

em

ore

equal

,10

=w

enee

d

larg

erin

com

ediff

eren

ces

as

ince

nti

ves

free

firm

sE

VS

1999

-00,

[as

abov

e]1

=th

est

ate

shou

ld10

-poi

nt

2008

-10

contr

olfirm

sm

ore

effec

tive

ly

...1

0=

the

stat

esh

ould

give

mor

efr

eedom

tofirm

sto

pro

vid

e

for

them

selv

es

pro

vid

eE

VS

1990

,19

99-0

0,[a

sab

ove]

1=

the

gove

rnm

ent

10-p

oint

2008

-10

shou

ldta

kem

ore

resp

onsi

bilit

y

toen

sure

that

ever

yone

is

pro

vid

edfo

r,10

=p

eople

shou

ld

take

mor

eres

pon

sibilit

yfo

r

pro

vid

ing

for

them

selv

es

Table

S3:Variablesincluded

inth

eSocialand

PostmaterialIssu

esM

odel

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

mee

tings

ISSP

RO

G19

90,

1996

,T

her

ear

em

any

way

sp

eople

or4-

poi

nt

2006

,20

16or

ganis

atio

ns

can

pro

test

agai

nst

a1

=defi

nit

ely,

4=

defi

nit

ely

not

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

33

Tab

le3

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

gove

rnm

ent

acti

onth

eyst

rongl

yop

pos

e.

Ple

ase

show

whic

hyo

uth

ink

shou

ldb

e

allo

wed

and

whic

hsh

ould

not

be

allo

wed

:“O

rgan

izin

gpublic

mee

tings

topro

test

agai

nst

the

gove

rnm

ent’

pro

test

sIS

SP

RO

G19

90,

1996

,[a

sab

ove]

“Org

anis

ing

pro

test

mar

ches

4-p

oint

2006

,20

16an

ddem

onst

rati

ons”

1=

defi

nit

ely,

4=

defi

nit

ely

not

kid

job

ISSP

F+

G,

1988

,19

94,

To

what

exte

nt

do

you

agre

eor

5-p

oint

2002

,20

12,

dis

agre

e...?

“Apre

-sch

ool

child

is1

=st

rongl

ydis

agre

e,5

=st

rongl

yag

ree

like

lyto

suff

erif

his

orher

mot

her

wor

ks”

wor

km

oth

ISSP

F+

G19

88,

1994

,[a

sab

ove]

“Aw

orkin

gm

other

can

5-p

oint

2002

,20

12es

tablish

just

asw

arm

and

secu

rea

1=

stro

ngl

yag

ree,

5=

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e

rela

tion

ship

wit

hher

childre

nas

a

mot

her

who

does

not

wor

k”

fam

job

ISSP

F+

G19

88,

1994

,[a

sab

ove]

“All

inal

l,fa

mily

life

5-p

oint

2002

,20

12su

ffer

sw

hen

the

wom

anhas

a1

=st

rongl

ydis

agre

e,5

=st

rongl

yag

ree

full-t

ime

job”

hou

sew

ife

ISSP

F+

G19

88,

1994

,[a

sab

ove]

“Bei

ng

ahou

sew

ife

isju

stas

5-p

oint

2002

,20

12fu

lfillin

gas

wor

kin

gfo

rpay

”1

=st

rongl

ydis

agre

e,5

=st

rongl

yag

ree

husb

wif

eIS

SP

F+

G19

88,

1994

,[a

sab

ove]

“Am

an’s

job

isto

earn

mon

ey5-

poi

nt

2002

,20

12a

wom

an’s

job

isto

look

afte

rth

e1

=st

rongl

ydis

agre

e,5

=st

rongl

yag

ree

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

34

Tab

le3

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

hom

ean

dfa

mily”

singp

aren

tIS

SP

F+

G19

88,

1994

,[a

sab

ove]

“One

par

ent

can

bri

ng

up

a5-

poi

nt

2002

,20

12ch

ild

asw

ell

astw

opar

ents

toge

ther

”1

=st

rongl

yag

ree,

5=

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e

wor

kkid

ISSP

F+

G19

88,

1994

,D

oyo

uth

ink

that

wom

ensh

ould

wor

k3-

poi

nt

2002

,20

12w

ork

outs

ide

the

hom

efu

ll-t

ime,

1=

wor

kfu

ll-t

ime,

3=

stay

athom

e

par

t-ti

me

ornot

atal

lunder

the

follow

ing

circ

um

stan

ces?

“When

ther

eis

ach

ild

under

school

age”

wor

ksc

hool

ISSP

F+

G19

88,

1994

,[a

sab

ove]

“Aft

erth

eyo

unge

stch

ild

3-p

oint

2002

,20

12st

arts

school

”1

=w

ork

full-t

ime,

3=

stay

athom

e

envfu

ture

ISSP

EN

V19

93,

1990

,H

owm

uch

do

you

agre

eor

dis

agre

e5-

poi

nt

2010

wit

hea

chof

thes

est

atem

ents

...

1=

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e,5

=st

rongl

yag

ree

“we

wor

ryto

om

uch

abou

tth

efu

ture

of

the

envir

onm

ent

and

not

enou

ghab

out

pri

ces

and

jobs

today

envpro

gIS

SP

EN

V19

93,

1990

,[a

sab

ove]

“Peo

ple

wor

ryto

om

uch

5-p

oint

2010

abou

thum

anpro

gres

shar

min

gth

e1

=st

rongl

ydis

agre

e,5

=st

rongl

yag

ree

envir

onm

ent”

envhta

xIS

SP

EN

V19

93,

1990

,H

oww

illing

wou

ldyo

ub

eto

pay

much

5-p

oint

2010

hig

her

taxes

inor

der

topro

tect

the

1=

very

willing,

5=

very

unw

illing

envir

onm

ent?

envst

dIS

SP

EN

V19

93,

1990

,H

oww

illing

wou

ldyo

ub

eto

acce

pt

cuts

5-p

oint

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

35

Tab

le3

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

2010

inyo

ur

stan

dar

dof

livin

gin

order

to1

=ve

ryw

illing,

5=

very

unw

illing

pro

tect

the

envir

onm

ent?

envla

ws

ISSP

EN

V19

93,

1990

,If

you

had

toch

oos

e,w

hic

hof

the

2-p

oint

2010

follow

ing

wou

ldb

ecl

oses

tto

your

vie

ws?

1=

seco

nd

stat

emen

t,

vie

ws?

“gov

ernm

ent

shou

ldle

tor

din

ary

2=

firs

tst

atem

ent

peo

ple

dec

ide

for

them

selv

eshow

to

pro

tect

the

envir

onm

ent,

even

ifit

mea

ns

they

don

’tal

way

sdo

the

righ

tth

ing”

,or

“gov

ernm

ent

shou

ldpas

sla

ws

tom

ake

ordin

ary

peo

ple

pro

tect

the

envir

onm

ent

,ev

enif

itin

terf

eres

wit

hp

eople

’sri

ghts

tom

ake

thei

row

ndec

isio

ns”

envbla

ws

ISSP

EN

V19

93,

1990

,[A

sab

ove

-su

bst

itute

2-p

oint

2010

“busi

nes

ses”

for

“ord

inar

yp

eople

”]1

=se

cond

stat

emen

t,

2=

firs

tst

atem

ent

kid

job1

EV

S19

90,

1999

-00,

To

what

exte

nt

do

you

agre

eor

4-p

oint

2008

-10

dis

agre

e...?

“Apre

-sch

ool

child

is1

=st

rongl

ydis

agre

e,4

=st

rongl

yag

ree

like

lyto

suff

erif

his

orher

mot

her

wor

ks”

envta

x1

EV

S19

90,

1999

-00,

Iam

now

goin

gto

read

out

som

e3-

poi

nt

2008

-10

stat

emen

tsab

out

the

envir

onm

ent.

1=

stro

ngl

yag

ree,

4=

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e

For

each

one

read

out,

can

you

tell

me

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

36

Tab

le3

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

whet

her

you

agre

est

rongl

y,ag

ree,

dis

agre

eor

stro

ngl

ydis

agre

e?“I

wou

ld

agre

eto

anin

crea

sein

taxes

ifth

eex

tra

mon

eyis

use

dto

pre

vent

envir

onm

enta

l

pol

luti

on”

auth

orit

yE

VS

1981

-2,

1990

Her

eis

alist

ofva

riou

sch

ange

sin

our

3-p

oint

1999

-00,

2008

-10

way

oflife

that

mig

ht

take

pla

cein

the

1=

good

thin

g,3

=bad

thin

g

nea

rfu

ture

.P

leas

ete

llm

efo

rea

chon

e,

ifit

wer

eto

hap

pen

whet

her

you

thin

kit

wou

ldb

ea

good

thin

g,a

bad

thin

g,or

don

’tyo

um

ind?

jobsc

arce

EV

S19

90,

1999

-00,

Do

you

dis

agre

eor

agre

ew

ith

the

3-p

oint

2008

-10

follow

ing

stat

emen

ts:

“When

jobs

are

1=

dis

agre

e,3

=ag

ree

scar

ce,

men

hav

em

ore

righ

tto

ajo

b

than

wom

en”

singp

aren

t1E

VS

1981

-2,

1990

[as

abov

e]“I

fso

meo

ne

says

ach

ild

nee

ds

3-p

oint

1999

-00,

008-

10a

hom

ew

ith

bot

ha

fath

eran

da

mot

her

1=

dis

agre

e,3

=ag

ree

togr

owup

hap

pily,

wou

ldyo

ute

nd

to

agre

eor

dis

agre

e?

wor

km

oth1

EV

S19

90,

1999

-00,

Peo

ple

talk

abou

tth

ech

angi

ng

role

sof

4-p

oint

2008

-10

men

and

wom

ento

day

.F

orea

chof

the

1=

agre

est

rongl

y,4=

dis

agre

est

rongl

y

follow

ing

stat

emen

tsI

read

out,

can

you

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

37

Tab

le3

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

tell

me

how

much

you

agre

ew

ith

each

:

“Aw

orkin

gm

other

can

esta

blish

just

as

war

man

dse

cure

are

lati

onsh

ipw

ith

her

childre

nas

am

other

who

does

not

wor

k”

hw

inco

me

EV

S19

90,

1999

-00,

[as

abov

e]“B

oth

the

husb

and

and

wif

e4-

poi

nt

2008

-10

shou

ldco

ntr

ibute

tohou

sehol

din

com

e1

=ag

ree

stro

ngl

y,4=

dis

agre

est

rongl

y

hom

osex

EV

S19

81-2

,19

90“P

leas

ete

llm

efo

rea

chof

the

follow

ing

10-p

oint

1999

-00,

2008

-10

stat

emen

tsw

het

her

you

thin

kit

can

1=

alw

ays

just

ified

,

alw

ays

be

just

ified

,nev

erb

eju

stifi

ed,

or10

=nev

erju

stifi

ed

som

ethin

gin

bet

wee

n:

“hom

osex

ual

ity”

abor

tion

EV

Sas

abov

e[a

sab

ove]

“Ab

orti

on”

asab

ove

div

orce

EV

Sas

abov

e[a

sab

ove]

“Div

orce

”as

abov

e

euth

anE

VS

asab

ove

[as

abov

e]“E

uth

anas

ia(t

erm

inat

ing

asab

ove

the

life

ofth

ein

cura

bly

sick

)”

pot

use

EV

Sas

abov

e[a

sab

ove]

“Tak

ing

the

dru

gm

arij

uan

aas

abov

e

orhas

his

h”

trad

itio

nE

SS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,“I

tis

imp

orta

nt

totr

yto

follow

the

6-p

oint

10,

12,

14,

16,

18cu

stom

shan

ded

dow

nby

religi

onor

top

3re

spon

ses

indic

ate

agre

emen

t

fam

ily”

stro

ngg

ovE

SS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,“I

tis

imp

orta

nt

that

the

6-p

oint

10,

12,

14,

16,

18go

vern

men

tis

stro

ng

and

ensu

res

top

3re

spon

ses

indic

ate

dis

agre

emen

t

safe

ty”

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

38

Tab

le3

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

gayri

ghts

ESS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,“T

ow

hat

exte

nt

do

you

agre

eor

5-p

oint

10,

12,

14,

16,

18dis

agre

eth

atga

ym

enan

dle

sbia

ns

1=ag

ree

stro

ngl

y,5=

dis

agre

est

rongl

y

shou

ldb

efr

eeto

live

thei

rlife

as

they

wis

h?

over

thro

wE

SS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,“T

ow

hat

exte

nt

do

you

agre

eor

5-p

oint

10dis

agre

eth

atp

olit

ical

par

ties

that

wis

h1=

dis

agre

est

rongl

y,5=

agre

est

rongl

y

toov

erth

row

dem

ocr

acy

shou

ld

be

ban

ned

?

hom

osex

1P

EW

2002

,07

,11

,13

,“H

omos

exual

ity

isa

way

oflife

that

2-p

oint

shou

ldb

eac

cepte

dby

soci

ety”

1=ag

ree,

2=dis

agre

e

envgr

owth

PE

W20

02,

07,

08,

09,

“Pro

tect

ing

the

envir

onm

ent

shou

ldb

e4-

poi

nt

10gi

ven

pri

orit

y,ev

enif

itca

use

s1=

com

ple

tely

agre

e,

slow

ergr

owth

and

som

elo

ssof

jobs”

4=co

mple

tely

dis

agre

e

Table

S4:Variablesincluded

inth

eIm

migra

tion

Model

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

trad

sIS

SP

NI

1995

,20

03,

2013

How

much

do

you

agre

eor

dis

agre

e5-

poi

nt

wit

hth

efo

llow

ing

stat

emen

ts?

“It

is1=

dis

agre

est

rongl

y,5=

agre

est

rongl

y

isim

pos

sible

for

peo

ple

who

do

not

shar

eth

isco

untr

y’s

cust

oms

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

39

Tab

le4

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

and

trad

itio

ns

tob

ecom

efu

lly

[nat

ional

ity]”

imm

crim

eIS

SP

NI

1995

,20

03,

2013

[as

abov

e]“I

mm

igra

nts

incr

ease

5-p

oint

crim

era

tes”

1=dis

agre

est

rongl

y,5=

agre

est

rongl

y

imm

econ

ISSP

NI

1995

,20

03,

2013

[as

abov

e]“I

mm

igra

nts

are

gener

ally

5-p

oint

good

for

this

countr

y’s

econ

omy’

1=ag

ree

stro

ngl

y,5=

dis

agre

est

rongl

y

take

jobs

ISSP

NI

1995

,20

03,

2013

[as

abov

e]“I

mm

igra

nts

take

jobs

5-p

oint

away

from

peo

ple

who

wer

eb

orn

in1=

agre

est

rongl

y,5=

dis

agre

est

rongl

y

this

countr

y.”

imm

pro

veIS

SP

NI

2003

,20

13[a

sab

ove]

“Im

mig

rants

impro

ve5-

poi

nt

this

soci

ety

by

bri

ngi

ng

innew

1=ag

ree

stro

ngl

y,5=

dis

agre

est

rongl

y

idea

san

dcu

lture

s”

lega

lrig

hts

ISSP

NI

2003

,20

13[a

sab

ove]

“Leg

alim

mig

rants

to5-

poi

nt

this

countr

yw

ho

are

not

1=ag

ree

stro

ngl

y,5=

dis

agre

est

rongl

y

citi

zens

shou

ldhav

eth

esa

me

righ

tsas

citi

zens”

imp

orts

ISSP

NI

1995

,20

03,

2013

[as

abov

e]“W

esh

ould

lim

itth

e5-

poi

nt

imp

ort

offo

reig

npro

duct

sin

1=dis

agre

est

rongl

y,5=

agre

est

rongl

y

order

topro

tect

the

nat

ional

econ

omy”

imm

good

ESS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,Is

itge

ner

ally

good

orbad

for

the

11-p

oint

10,1

2,14

,16,

18co

untr

y’s

econ

omy

that

1=go

od,

11=

bad C

onti

nu

edon

nex

tpa

ge

40

Tab

le4

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

peo

ple

com

eto

live

her

efr

om

other

countr

ies?

imm

cult

ESS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,Is

the

countr

y’s

cult

ura

llife

11-p

oint

10,1

2,14

,16,

18ge

ner

ally

under

min

edor

1=en

rich

ed,

11=

under

min

ed

enri

ched

by

imm

igra

nts

com

ing

to

live

her

e?

imm

bet

ter

ESS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,Is

the

countr

ya

bet

ter

11-p

oint

10,1

2,14

,16,

18or

wor

sepla

ceto

live

asa

1=en

rich

ed,

11=

under

min

ed

resu

ltof

imm

igra

nts

com

ing

to

live

her

e?

imm

sam

eE

SS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,T

ow

hat

exte

nt

do

you

thin

kth

is4-

poi

nt

10,1

2,14

,16,

18co

untr

ysh

ould

allo

wp

eople

top

3si

gnal

agre

emen

t

ofth

esa

me

race

oret

hnic

grou

p

asm

ost

ofth

eco

untr

yto

com

ean

d

live

her

e?

imm

diff

ESS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,[a

sab

ove]

...d

iffer

ent

race

or4-

poi

nt

10,1

2,14

,16,

18et

hnic

grou

p?

top

3si

gnal

agre

emen

t

imm

poor

ESS

2002

,04

,06

,08

,[a

sab

ove]

...p

eople

from

the

4-p

oint

10,1

2,14

,16,

18p

oor

erco

untr

ies

outs

ide

Euro

pe?

top

3si

gnal

agre

emen

t

scar

ceim

ms

EV

S19

90,

1999

-00,

‘When

jobs

are

scar

ce,

emplo

yers

3-p

oint

2008

-10

shou

ldgi

vepri

orit

yto

nat

ive

1=dis

agre

e,3=

agre

e

peo

ple

over

imm

igra

nts

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

41

Tab

le4

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

conci

mm

sE

VS

1999

-00,

To

what

exte

nt

do

you

feel

5-p

oint

2008

-10

conce

rned

abou

tth

elivin

g1=

very

much

,5=

not

atal

l

condit

ions

ofim

mig

rants

in

your

countr

y?

lim

itfo

rsE

VS

1999

-00,

‘Whic

hon

eof

the

follow

ing

do

4-p

oint

2008

-10

you

thin

kth

ego

vern

men

tsh

ould

top

2:pro

hib

it/p

lace

lim

its

do

abou

tp

eople

from

less

dev

elop

edco

untr

ies

com

ing

her

e

tow

ork?

fori

nfl

PE

W20

02,

07,

‘Our

way

oflife

nee

ds

tob

e4-

poi

nt

09,

12pro

tect

edag

ainst

fore

ign

1=co

mple

tely

dis

agre

e,

influen

ce’

4=co

mple

tely

agre

e

socr

ight

EB

VA

L19

97,

2000

,‘L

egal

lyes

tablish

edim

mig

rants

2-p

oint

2003

from

outs

ide

the

Euro

pea

n0=

agre

e,1=

dis

agre

e

Unio

nsh

ould

hav

eth

esa

me

soci

alri

ghts

asci

tize

ns.

sendum

pE

BV

AL

1997

,20

00,

‘Leg

ally

esta

blish

edim

mig

rants

2-p

oint

2003

from

outs

ide

the

Euro

pea

n0=

dis

agre

e,1=

agre

e

Unio

nsh

ould

be

sent

bac

kto

thei

rco

untr

yof

orig

inif

they

are

unem

plo

yed.’

sendal

lE

BV

AL

1997

,20

00,

‘Leg

ally

esta

blish

edim

mig

rants

2-p

oint

Con

tin

ued

onn

ext

page

42

Tab

le4

–C

onti

nu

edfr

ompr

evio

us

page

Var

iable

Surv

eyY

ears

Ques

tion

Wor

din

gR

esp

onse

Opti

ons

Nam

eC

over

ed

2003

from

outs

ide

the

Euro

pea

n0=

dis

agre

e,1=

agre

e

Unio

nsh

ould

all

be

sent

bac

k

toth

eir

countr

yof

orig

in’

allh

ome

EB

VA

L19

97,

2000

,‘A

llille

gal

imm

igra

nts

shou

ldb

e2-

poi

nt

2003

sent

bac

kto

thei

rco

untr

yof

orig

in0=

dis

agre

e,1=

agre

e

wit

hou

tex

cepti

on’

43

3 Analysis of Individual Survey Items in the Relative

Economic Issues Scales

As discussed in the main text, the finding that young people have become more right-wing

on tax and spending over the past two decades may be surprising. Here I show that this

finding faithfully reflects patterns in the underlying survey data, both in aggregate and for

individual countries. I do this using the two sets of surveys questions with the longest

temporal coverage: the ISSP Role of Government and Inequality surveys. The former were

carried out in 1985, 1990, 1996, 2006 and 2016 and the latter in 1987, 1992, 1999 and 2009.

Figures S1 and S2 display over-time trends in age differences for the main tax, spending and

inequality questions from these surveys: the variable names in the figures match those in

Table S2 above.

−0.4

−0.2

0.0

0.2

1990 2000 2010

Age

Diff

eren

ce in

Con

serv

atis

m (

Old

min

us Y

oung

)

Spending Item

spendhealth

spendeduc

spendold

spendump

Figure S1: Differences in mean preference between old and young for higher governmentspending in four policy areas (ISSP Role of Government Surveys), and associated 95% con-fidence intervals [positive = old people more conservative]

44

In both figures, the old are defined as those aged 58-77 (the two oldest groups in the main

paper’s analysis) and the young as those aged 18-37 (the two youngest groups), as in Figure

2 of the main paper.9 They include the average for all available coutnries in each year;

individual countries are shown below. Negative numbers imply that the young are more

conservative (opposed to higher spending). Figure S1 shows that in the 1980s and early

1990s, across most issues the old were at least as conservative, or more conservative, than

the young. But over the 1990s to the 2000s, the young became relatively more conservative,

preferring lower spending on health and unemployment as well as pensions. They also

became relatively more conservative on both education and pensions spending, although on

education they have, unsurprisingly, always preferred higher spending to the old. These

patterns closely match those in Figure 1 of the main text: the age gap in ideology was small

in the 1980s and early 1990s but widened by the late 1990s, remaining high throughout the

2000s and 2010s.

Figure S2 shows similar patterns for questions on inequality, benefits spending and pro-

gressive taxation from the ISSP Inequality surveys. These again show, overall, a pattern of

increasing age gaps in conservatism from the 1980s to the late 2000s. The old were more

conservative than the young on benefits spending in the 1980s (Lessbens), but became more

conservative thereafter. On taxing those with high incomes, the young became considerably

more conservative, relative to the old, over the same period (Taxhighinc). On perceptions

of inequality (Incdiff ), the young were more conservative in all periods and this grew over

the 2000s, but there was no aggregate change over the whole period. Again, taken together,

these closely match the estimates in the main paper which show a large age gap from the

1990s onward.

Figures S1-2 are not balanced samples. Different countries appear in different years,

although the coverage becomes increasingly comprehensive over time. In case these patterns

are affected by the countries that happen to appear in a given year, Figures S3 and S4 look at

all available countries and years for each measure, presenting the same age gap in ideology as

in Figures S1-2. Although there is some variation, in the majority of cases the same patterns

occur within countries: age gaps were larger from the late 1990s onwards, and particularly

in the 2000s, compared to the 1980s and early 1990s.

Figure S3 also shows that age gaps for most of these measures are relatively modest.

This is particularly the case for health, where most point estimates are centered very close

to zero, despite the elderly using more healthcare on average than the young. The evidence

for education points to a modest age gap in the expected direction, although the differences

9. The results do not differ if single age groups are used. However, this results in very small groups forestimation by country, which appears below.

45

−0.2

0.0

0.2

1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Age

Diff

eren

ce in

Con

serv

atis

m (

Old

min

us Y

oung

)

Survey Item

Lessbens

Taxhighinc

Incdiff

Figure S2: Differences in mean preference between old and young on inequality, benefitsspending and progressive taxation (ISSP Inequaity Surveys), and associated 95% confidenceintervals [positive = old people more conservative]

are generally very small. The mean cross-country age gap of 0.101 for the countries shown

in the figure corresponds to one eighth of a standard deviation of the question’s response

scale. In fact, baseline support for greater education spending is very high across both age

groups. The only difference is in intensity, with the young slightly more likely to want ‘much

higher’ spending. In 2016 42.9% and 28.8% of those aged 30 and under wanted ‘higher’ and

‘much higher’ education spending, compared to 44.9% and 21.8% of those aged 65 and over.

Even in France where the 2016 gap is highest, a majority (53%) of the elderly supported

higher or much higher spending, compared to 65% of the young. inally, for spending on

pensions the average age difference is a bit larger, with the old more likely to want higher

spending. Again though, virtually nobody – young or old – wanted lower spending: 4.4% of

the young and 1.3% of the old in 2016. Majorities of both age groups again favored higher

spending, with 44.8% and 18.1% of the young wanting it higher and much higher compared

46

to 41.4% and 31.4% of the old. Age differences in preferences for ‘much higher’ pensions

spending are therefore large, but otherwise there is quite substantial agreement. Pensions

spending remains a popular spending item across age groups. It is arguably important to

distinguish between areas where the young and old have preferences for completely different

policies versus areas where they want the same things, but with differing degrees of intensity.

Education and pensions spending, classic valence items, clearly fall into the latter camp.

47

48●

●●

●●●

●●

●● ●

●●●● ●

●●●●●

●●●●

● ●

●●

●●●

●●●●

●●

●●●

●●●

● ●●

● ●●

●●

●●●

●●

●● ●

●●●●●

●●● ● ●

●●● ●

● ●

●●

● ●●

●●●●

● ●

● ●●

●●●

●●●

●●●

●●●

● ●●

●●

●● ●

●●●●●

● ●●●●

●●●●

●●

●●

●●●

●●●●

●●

●●●

●● ●

●●●

●●●

●●●

●● ●

●●

●● ●

●●●●●

● ●●●●

●●●●

●●

● ●

●● ●

●●●●

● ●

●● ●

●●●

●●●

●●●

Pensions Unemployment

Health Education

−1.0 −0.5 0.0 0.5 −1.0 −0.5 0.0 0.5

SwitzerlandSweden

SpainSloveniaSlovakiaPortugal

PolandNorway

NetherlandsLithuania

LatviaItaly

IrelandHungary

GermanyGreat Britain

FranceFinland

DenmarkCzech Republic

CyprusBulgariaBelgiumAustria

SwitzerlandSweden

SpainSloveniaSlovakiaPortugal

PolandNorway

NetherlandsLithuania

LatviaItaly

IrelandHungary

GermanyGreat Britain

FranceFinland

DenmarkCzech Republic

CyprusBulgariaBelgiumAustria

Old versus Young (Difference in Means)

Survey Year

2016

2006

1996

1990

1985

Figure S3: Differences in mean preference between old and young for higher governmentspending in four policy areas (ISSP Role of Government Surveys), and associated 95% con-fidence intervals, by country and year

49

●●●

●●

●●

●●

●●

●●

●●

● ●●

●●

●●

● ●●

●●●

●● ●

●●

●●

●●

●●

●●

● ●

●● ●●

●●●

●●

●●

●●

●●●●

●● ●●

●●● ●

●●

● ●●

●●

●● ●

● ●●

●●

● ●●

●●

Lessbens Taxhighinc Incdiff

−1.0 −0.5 0.0 0.5 −1.0 −0.5 0.0 0.5 −1.0 −0.5 0.0 0.5

Switzerland

Sweden

Spain

Slovenia

Slovakia

Portugal

Poland

Norway

Netherlands

Lithuania

Latvia

Italy

Hungary

Germany

Great Britain

France

Finland

Estonia

Denmark

Czech Republic

Cyprus

Bulgaria

Austria

Old versus Young (Difference in Means)

Survey Year

2009

1999

1992

1987

Figure S4: Differences in mean preference between old and young on inequality, benefitsspending and progressive taxation (ISSP Inequality Surveys), and associated 95% confidenceintervals, by country and year

4 Trends in Conservatism by Age Group and European

Region

Absolute Economic Relative Economic

Social Immigration

1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010

−1

0

1

−1

0

1

Con

serv

atis

m

Age

18−27

28−37

38−47

48−57

58−67

68−77

Figure S5: Trends in conservatism over time by age group and issue domain in WesternEurope, 1981-82 to 2017-18.

50

Absolute Economic Relative Economic

Social Immigration

1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010

−1

0

1

−1

0

1

Con

serv

atis

m

Age

18−27

28−37

38−47

48−57

58−67

68−77

Figure S6: Trends in conservatism over time by age group and issue domain in EasternEurope, 1981-82 to 2017-18.

Western Europe = Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Great Britain,

Ireland, Italy, Netherlands, Northern Ireland, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland

Eastern Europe = Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland,

Slovakia, Slovenia

51


Top Related