Efficiency and Inefficiency in Humanitarian Financing€¦ · How humanitarian actors define...

Post on 11-Jul-2020

3 views 0 download

transcript

EfficiencyandInefficiencyinHumanitarianFinancingDecember2017AbbyStoddard,LydiaPoole,GlynTaylorandBarnabyWillitts-KingwithShoaibJillaniandAlanPotter

ii

ThisstudyismadepossiblebythegeneroussupportoftheAmericanpeoplethroughtheUnitedStatesAgencyforInternationalDevelopment(USAID).ThecontentsaretheresponsibilityofHumanitarianOutcomesanddonotnecessarilyreflecttheviewsofUSAIDortheUnitedStatesGovernment.

iii

TableofContents

Acknowledgments..................................................................................................................iv

Acronyms................................................................................................................................v

ExecutiveSummary................................................................................................................1

1.Introduction.......................................................................................................................51.1Backgroundandobjectives................................................................................................................51.2Researchapproachandmethods......................................................................................................61.3Caveatsandlimitations......................................................................................................................8

2.Definingefficiency..............................................................................................................92.1Typesofefficiency.............................................................................................................................9Figure1:Efficiencyinfunding:Conceptualframework.........................................................................112.2Causesofinefficiencyinhumanitarianfunding...............................................................................11

3.Efficiencyfindingsforfundingmodalities..........................................................................133.1Directgrants.............................................................................................................................13Figure2:Globalproportionsofemergencycontributions,2015–2016.................................................13Table1:AveragesfromsampledcontributionsinEthiopia,Iraq,andMyanmar(2015and2016).......143.2Bilateralgrantintermediaries..........................................................................................................183.3Global-levelpooledfunding(CERFandStart)..................................................................................223.4Country-basedpooledfunds............................................................................................................243.5Consortiaandframeworkagreements............................................................................................273.6Corefundingandinternalinstruments............................................................................................28

4.Otherissues:Multiyeartimeframesandearmarking.........................................................304.1Multiyearfunding............................................................................................................................304.2Earmarking.......................................................................................................................................30

5. Conclusionsandsuggestedguidanceforconsideringefficiencyinfundingdecisions......315.1Areasforaction................................................................................................................................315.2Guidingprinciplesfordonordecision-makingregardingefficiency................................................345.3Enhancingefficiencythroughamorecoordinated,evidence-basedapproach...............................36

References............................................................................................................................37

Annex1:Listofpeopleinterviewed.......................................................................................39

Annex2:Quantitativeanalysisdetails...................................................................................42

iv

Acknowledgments

ThisstudywouldnothavebeenpossiblewithouttheconsiderablesupportandcooperationofthefollowingAdvisoryGroupmembers,whohelpedguidedthemethodologydevelopment,sharedtheirinsightsininterviews,andcooperatedinprovidingquantitativedatafromtheirfieldofficestoassistintheanalysis.HelenAlderson,ICRCSandraAviles,IASCHFTT/FAOAndreadeDomenico,OCHAFCSLisaDoughtenandMichaelJensen,IASCHFTTandCERFSecretariatChrisKaye,WFPChristopherLockyear,ACFJemilahMahmood,IFRCPatriciaMcIlreavy,InterActionJamesMunn,NRCMarkPryce,OCHASanjanaQuazi,UNICEFDeeptiSastry,StartJenniferSime,IRCJulianSrodecki,WorldVisionDonaTarpeyandHirokoAraki,UNHCRTheauthorswouldalsoliketopayspecialthankstotheInternationalRescueCommitteeforhostingthefieldresearchvisittoErbil,Iraq.AdvisoryGroupmemberswerenotunifiedintheiropinionsontheissuesdiscussedinthispaper,reflectingthediversityofviewsfoundthroughoutthesector.Theanalysisandconclusionsexpressedinthereport,aswellasanyerrorsoffact,belongtotheauthorsalone.

v

Acronyms

CBPFs Country-BasedPooledFundsCERF CentralEmergencyResponseFundDAC DevelopmentAssistanceCommitteeDEC DisasterEmergencyCommittee(UK)DFID DepartmentforInternationalDevelopment(UK)DRC DemocraticRepublicoftheCongoDREF DisasterReliefEmergencyFundEC EuropeanCommissionECHO EuropeanCommissionHumanitarianAidOfficeERC EmergencyResponseCoordinatorEU EuropeanUnionFAO FoodandAgricultureOrganizationFTS FinancialTrackingServiceGHD GoodHumanitarianDonorshipHC HumanitarianCoordinatorIASC Inter-AgencyStandingCommitteeonHumanitarianAffairsICRC InternationalCommitteeoftheRedCrossIFRC InternationalFederationofRedCross/RedCrescentSocietiesIRA ImmediateResponseAccount(WFP)NGO Non-governmentalOrganizationOCHA UNOfficefortheCoordinationofHumanitarianAffairs

OECDDAC OrganisationforEconomicCooperationandDevelopment’sDevelopmentAssistanceCommittee

OFDA OfficeofU.S.ForeignDisasterAssistanceUNHCR UnitedNationsHighCommissionerforRefugeesUNICEF UnitedNationsChildren’sFundUSAID UnitedStatesAgencyforInternationalDevelopmentWFP WorldFoodProgram

1

ExecutiveSummary

Thegoalofthisstudywastodefineandmeasureefficiencyinthecontextofinternationalfundingforhumanitarianresponse.CommissionedbytheOfficeofU.S.ForeignDisasterAssistance(OFDA),theresearchwasconductedtohelpinformdonordecision-makingatatimeofsurgingfinancialdemandforhumanitarianaidandnewmomentumforchangeinthehumanitariansectorfollowingtheWorldHumanitarianSummitinMay2016.

Efficiencyisjustonenarrowcriterionbywhichtoassessthehumanitarianfundingarchitectureandcannotbeconsideredinisolationfromfundingeffectivenessandbroadergoalsofthehumanitarianresponse.1However,inaresource-scarceandlargelyreactiveenvironment,howefficientlymoneymovestoenableresponseisacriticallyimportantcomponent,andonewhichhasreceivedlittlein-depthattentionatthesystemlevel.

Howhumanitarianactorsdefinefundingefficiencydependsonwheretheysitinthesector.Forthelargeinternationalagencies,efficientfundingisthatwhichisthemostflexible(i.e.,least“earmarked”bythedonorforspecificpurposes)andtimely(eitherrapidlydisbursedorreliablypredictable)whilerequiringthefewestadministrativeinputs.Smallerandlocalorganizationsfinditmostefficienttoreceivefundingdirectlyfromthedonorratherthanthroughanintermediaryagency,whichcanbeslowtodisburseandrestrictivewithoverheadallowances.Andfordonors,efficiencyoftenmeanshavingfewer,largerchannelsthroughwhichtochanneltheirhumanitarianfunding,preventingtheadministrativebottleneckscausedbytheneedtoindividuallymanagenumerousgrants.Itiseasytoseehowthesedifferentvantagepointscanbeatoddswitheachother,andnoneofthemalonespeaktowhatconstitutesfundingefficiencyforthewholesector.

Thestudydefinesoverallefficiencyofthehumanitarianfinancingsystemasacombinedmeasureofbothtechnicalefficiency(thespeedandsmoothnessofthepipelinesfromdonortoaffectedpeople)andallocativeefficiency(theappropriateallocationofresourcestospecificproblemsorobjectives).Bothmeasuresarerequiredforaholisticassessmentofthevariousfundingmechanismsthatconsiderstheirdifferentpurposesandvalueadded.

Theresearchteammadefieldvisitstothreehumanitarianresponsesettings—Ethiopia,Myanmar,andIraq—togatherdetailedinformationonthepracticalexecutionofdifferenttypesofcontributions.Theanalysisinvolvedexaminingthetransactionchainsinasampleofcontributionsforeachofthemainhumanitarianfundingmodalities:directgrants(bothpublicandprivate)andpooledfundingmechanismsattheglobalandcountrylevels.Usingthedataprovidedbyagencies,thestudycomparedthedifferentfundingmodalitiesintermsoftheirtimeliness,sufficiency,transactioncosts,andotherindicatorsoftechnicalandallocativeefficiency.Inadditiontoa

1Effectivenessoffundingwouldbeameasureofwhetherandhowwellthefundingachieveditsintendedresults.

2

quantitativeanalysisofthisdata,thereportincorporatedqualitativeevidencefrom86keyinformantinterviewsaswellasagloballiteratureandfundingreview.

Theresearchyieldedfourkeyfindings:

1. The primary modes of funding have not yet proved efficient for rapid response. 2. Disproportionate requirements and inflexibility hinder efficiency at all levels. 3. The added value of intermediary agencies in multi-link (pass-through) grants is inconsistent, and

they often create net inefficiencies. 4. Allocative efficiency and the stated goals of localization are impeded by risk perception and

capacity constraints on the part of donor governments.

Eachisdiscussedbelow.

Theprimarymodesoffundingarestillinefficientforrapidresponsepurposes.

Insuddenonsetcrises,fundingmustbeavailabletospendwithindays—notweeksormonths—ifitistosupporttimelyresponseefforts.Becauseonlyafewhumanitarianactorshavestandbyfundsthatcanbetappedinadvanceofdonorfunding,thismeansthatagrantmustberequested,approved,anddisbursedwithinaveryshorttimeframeforittofunctionasarapidresponseresource.Thestudyfoundthatnecessaryspeedindisbursementsforrapidresponsewaslackinginallthreecaseexamplesandacrossthemajormodalities,includingthosedesignedspecificallyforthepurpose.Anarrayoftransactioncosts,includingoverlyheavybureaucraticstructures,currentlyworksagainsttechnicalefficiencyoffundingflows.

Inthecaseofbilateralgrants,becausetheproposal-to-awardperiodtypicallyrepresentsthelongesttimelag,donorsshouldprovidegreater“pre-positioned”fundingwithindividualagenciesand/ormultiagencyconsortiacapableofputtingthemoneytoworkimmediatelyintheeventofasuddencrisis.StrongUN-NGOpartnershipsinsomechroniccrisissettings,andtheexperienceoftheStartFund,illustratehowthispreparednessapproachcanreducefundingdelaysandsupportrapidresponse.Pooledfundgrantsweredecidedmorequicklythangrantsfrombilateraldonors,butneverthelessfaceddelaysonboththefrontandbackendsoftheapprovalprocess.Thiscouldbeimprovedbywaivingtherequirementforjoined-upproposalsincaseswherethisprocesswouldhindercriticalrapidaction,andoverlyheavycluster-levelprocessesingeneral.

Thebiggestgainintimeliness,however,canonlycomethroughinternalagencyreformstoremediatethelongdelaysfromtheinitialawardtotheonwardcontractingofanddisbursementtopartners.

Disproportionaterequirementsandinflexibilityhinderefficiencyatalllevels.

Thesmallestandshortest-durationgrantshavetheheaviesttransactioncosts,andthesmallestNGOstypicallybearthegreatestadministrativeburdenfortheleastreward.Theallocativeefficienciesgainedbystrategiccoordinationandground-leveldecision-making(thelogicbehindthepooledfunds)canbeoutstrippedbythesetechnicalinefficiencies.Inordinatelyhightransactioncostsonsmall-sizedgrantsareinefficientfordonorandgranteesalike.Theseshouldbeaddressed

3

bymakingtherequirementscommensuratewiththesizeandtimelinesofthegrantsandbymaximizingtheflexibilitytomodifythemtosuitchangingconditions,withintheboundsofappropriateaccountabilitycontrolsandpragmaticriskmanagement.

Theaddedvalueofintermediaryagenciesinmulti-linkgrantsisinconsistentandtheyoftencreatenetinefficiencies.

Thehumanitarianfundingsystemneedsamindsetshiftandachangeinstandardoperatingproceduresthatrequireabusinesscaseforusinganintermediaryagency,demonstratinghowitwouldaddvalueasopposedtoautomaticallyassumingitwill.Inadditiontoscalabilityandeffectivenessjustifications,partofthecasefortheintermediarywouldincludedemonstratedhigherefficiencyinfunding,contracting,andflexiblemanagementofgrantscomparedtodirectfunding.

Allocativeefficiencyandthestatedgoalsoflocalizationareimpededbyriskperceptionandcapacityconstraintsonthepartofdonorgovernments.

Donorgovernments,foravarietyofdomesticpoliticalandregulatoryreasons,havenotbeenwillingtofundlocalactorsdirectly,deemingittoogreatarisk.TheGrandBargaincommitmentsinthisareahavesofarfocusedmainlyonincreasingindirectfundingtolocalactorsthroughintermediaryagencies(whichmayhelpbuildgreaterlocalcapacitybutdoesnotfosterameaningfulshiftinresponsibility)anddirectfundingtotheactorsthroughthecountry-basedpooledfunds(whichrepresentonlyatinysliverofhumanitarianfundingatpresent).Totheextentpossible,donors(includingpooledfundsdonors)shouldconsidersubsidiarity2indeterminingatwhatleveltomakegrants.Unlesstheallocativeefficienciesandvalueaddedofhavinganintermediarycanbedemonstrated,directfundingshouldbepreferred.Targetedcapacityinvestmentsinlocalorganizations(i.e.,corefundinggrants)canbolsterandenhancetherangeofoptionsavailableinfuturefordonorsseekingtomaximizeefficiencyaswellaseffectiveness.Country-basedpooledfunds,wheretheyarefunctioningwellandallocatingdirectlytolocalNGOs,maybeameansforsomedonorstoachievesubsidiarityandlocalizationobjectiveswhileavoidingthetradeoffinefficienciesofmanagingnumeroussmallgrantstolocalentities.

***Thereportconcludeswithbroadguidingprinciplesforconsideringefficiencyinmakingfundingdecisions:

Maintainthewidestpossiblerangeofoptionsandtoolstoemployfordifferentneeds,usingacombinationofmodalitiestoachieveareasonablebalanceofpredictability,responsivenessandallocativeefficiencybothatthecountryandgloballevels,whileretainingcontingencyfundingatthegloballevelincaseofunforeseenneeds.

2Theorganizingprinciplethatresponsibilityshouldbelocatedwiththemostproximate(leastcentralized)competententity.

4

Startingfromthespecificsofthecontextandhumanitarianneeds,matchgoalswiththefundinginstrumentsbestsuitedtoefficientlyservicethem:

• Forrapidresponse,workingthroughpre-arrangedframeworkagreementsorothermechanismswithprovenspeedydisbursementtimeswillbemoreefficientthantraditionalbilateralgrants.

• Large-scale,complex,andprotractedemergenciescausingsimilarneedsamongwidesegmentsofthepopulationmaybebestservedbylargeumbrellagrantingtocompetentcoordinatingbodies(UNagencies,NGOs,orconsortia)thataddtechnicalvalueandprovideeconomiesofscale.

• Specificgapsandunderfundedneedscanbeaddressedwitheitherflexiblebilateralgranting,earliercontributionstopooledfundwindowsforthatpurpose,orboth.

• Smallpocketsofneed,andhighlylocation-specificneedsinindividualareas,willoftenbemoreefficientlyfundedbyeliminatingtheintermediaryandgivingtolocallybasedorganizationsdirectly.

Determineandconsiderotherdonors’plansasfactorsinefficiencydecisions.

Totheextentthatanydonorhasflexibilityofchoiceinfundingmechanisms,thatchoiceshouldbeusedtohelpbalancetheneedsofbothtechnicalandallocativeefficiency,consideringwhatcounterpartsaredoingwithinthelargerpictureofstrategicpriorities.

Agreeonacommonsetofmetricsforassessingefficiency

TheGoodHumanitarianDonorshipinitiativecouldbenefitfromusingaquantifiedefficiencyframeworktoassessfundingmechanismsandagenciesseekingintermediaryroles.Suchaframeworkwouldencouragetransparencyandefficiencyinfundingdecisions,andsupporttheGrandBargaincommitments.

5

1.Introduction

1.1Backgroundandobjectives

The“GrandBargain”reformsannouncedattheWorldHumanitarianSummitinMay2016committhemajorhumanitariandonorgovernmentsandagenciestoworktowardaseriesofgoals,manyofwhichareintendedtoimproveefficiencyinthefundingrelationship.Theyincludecommitmentstoreduceduplicationandmanagementcosts,reducedonorearmarking(i.e.,increaseflexibilityinfunding),lightenandsimplifyreportingrequirements,improvefinancialtransparency,increasedirectfundingtonationalfirstresponders,increasecash-basedprogramming,andincreasetheuseofmulti-yearfunding.

Althoughtheoperationalizationofthesecommitmentsisnotyetfleshedout,itisanopportunemomentfordonorstosurveythecurrentmechanismsandchannelstheyuseforhumanitarianfundingtoseehowtheyserve—orhinder—thepursuitofthesegoals.Forthisreason,theOfficeofU.S.ForeignDisasterAssistance(OFDA)commissionedHumanitarianOutcomestoundertakeacomparativeanalysisoftheefficiencyofhumanitarianfinancingtoolsandinstruments.

Official(i.e.,government)humanitarianassistancefundingflowsthroughthefollowingchannels,indescendingorderofpercentage:

• directgrantsforspecificprojectsorprograms• globalpooledfundingmechanisms(theCERF,Start)• country-basedpooledfunds(CBPFs)• un-earmarkedcorefundingcontributionsorframeworkagreements• government-to-governmentaid• global-levelrapiddraw-downfunds(ex-anteagreementsforrapidresponse)(e.g.,IFRC’s

DREF)

Arecentdescriptivebackgroundpaperontheseinstruments,alsocommissionedaspartofthisstudy,foundthatnotonlyhastherecentsurgeinhumanitarianfundingbeenoverwhelminglyfinancedbyasmallgroupoflargedonorgovernmentsandtheEU(justfivedonorsrepresent65percentofofficialhumanitarianflows),butalsothatithasgonethroughthedirect,earmarkedgrantmodality.Theever-increasingpercentagechanneledthroughdirectgrantstoindividualagencieshasdwarfedothermodalitiessuchaspooledfundsandcorefunding(Stoddard,2017).Further,thereportshowedthatdonors’decisionsonhumanitarianfinancingcontinuetobedeterminedmorebypastexperienceandinternalconstraintsthanbyevidenceandcoordinatedstrategy.

Veryfewdonorsoragencieshaveundertakenanin-depthcomparativeanalysisofefficienciesindifferentmodesoffunding,andthecriterionofefficiencytendstogetshortshriftinhumanitarianevaluationsgenerally(Palenberg,2011;Stoddardetal.,2015).ExceptingUKDFID’sextensivedoctrinalworkon“valueformoney,”mostdonorsfactoralooseworkingdefinitionofefficiencyintodecision-making,forinstancelookingbroadlyatprogramsupportcostsversusoutputs.Other

6

humanitarianactorsadmit,inthewordsofoneNGOrepresentative,that“wearesotime-constrainedwedon’tconsiderwhatwouldbemaximallyefficient.”

Whenitcomestomeetingurgenthumanitarianneedsincomplexandhighlyvariedcontexts,efficiencyinanarrowcost-per-outputsensewillneverbetheprimaryconsideration.However,ifefficiencyisneverdeliberatelyexaminedasonecriterioninanevidence-baseddecision-makingprocess,thendecisionswilldefaulttopath-dependentpatternsthatareun-strategicandpotentiallysuboptimal.Inthewordsofonedonorinterviewedforthisstudy,“Weareallstrugglingwiththisquestionofwhywearechoosingoneinstrumentoveranother.Sometimeswedon’tnecessarilyknowwhywearefundingparticular[entities/partners],orwhattheircomparativeadvantagesare.”

ItishopedthisstudywillcontributetotheGrandBargainfollow-upbysynthesizingcurrentissuesinefficiencyandidentifyingsystem-widetrendsandgaps.

1.2Researchapproachandmethods

Thedefinitionalframeworkofefficiencyusedforouranalysis,detailedinChapter2,considersthedifferenttypesofefficiencyandperspectivesofactorsatdifferentlevelsandcombinesthemforasystem-levelassessment.ThemethodologyinceptionnoteforthestudyincorporatedtheinputofthehumanitarianpractitionerssittingontheAdvisoryGroupandoutlinedanapproachforassessingandcomparingefficiencythatproceededfromthebelowassumptions.

1.2.1Assumptions

Efficiencyisonlyonecriterioninforminganyjudgment,andseldomthemostimportant.Itispossibletodothewrongthingwithultimateefficiency.Therefore,theconceptofefficiencycannotbedivorcedfromeffectivenesswhenexaminingfinancingmechanismswithdifferentgoals.Theresearchwillbeclearonthispoint,ensuringthatfindingsarenuancedwithrespecttobroaderobjectives(seemorebelow,in“caveatsandlimitations”)andmodestaboutmakingprescriptiveconclusions.Humanitarianfinancingislimitedtothepresentmodalitiesfortheforeseeablefuture.Despiteproposalsfornewglobalfinancingplatforms,andlimitedexperimentationwithvehiclessuchashumanitarianimpactbonds,nowhollynewhumanitarianfinancingmechanismsareonthehorizonyet.Therefore,thescopeofthestudywaslimitedtowhatcurrentlyexistsfordonorgovernmentstochoosefromintermsoffundingmodalities,aslistedabove.

Optimalefficiencyforthesystemwilloftenmeansuboptimalefficiencyatthelevelofindividualactors.Whatismostefficientforonehumanitarianactormaynotbeefficientforotheractorsorfortheoverallsystem.Trade-offsareinevitableandneedbemanagedinawaythatoptimizesefficiencyforhumanitarianfundingwritlarge.Forthisreason,andtoaccountforthedifferentobjectivesofthedifferentpiecesofthehumanitarianfinancingarchitecture,themeasureofefficiencyforthisinquiryisdefinedontwolevels—systemandcomponent—asdetailedbelow.

7

1.2.2Global-leveldatagatheringandanalysis

Theresearchersanalyzedhumanitarianfinancingdatafor2013–2016downloadedfromtheUNFinancialTrackingService(FTS).FTSwastheprimarydatasourceusedforfundingfigures,augmentedwhereappropriatebydatafromtheCERFandCountry-BasedPooledFunds(CBPF)data,UNagency/NGOannualfinancialreports,andinformationprovideddirectlybydonorsandagencies.Thefindingsfromtheglobal-levelanalysisinformedandcomplementedthefieldresearchandkeyinformantinterviews.AlthoughthevoluntarybasisonwhichhumanitarianactorsreporttoFTSmeansthatitfailstocapturethefullextentofhumanitarianfinancing,itisstillthemostcomprehensiveandtimelysourceofthisdataandthebestoptionfortrackingglobaltrends.DatafromtheInternationalAidTransparencyInitiative(IATI)werereviewed,butdeterminedtobestillfartooincompletetocontributetoanyrigorousanalysis(althoughintheorythisdatabaseshowspromisetohelpimproveefficiencyinthefuturebyprovidingincreasedtransparencyofthetransactionchain).

Aglobal-levelliteraturereviewencompassedreports,evaluations,andanalysesofhumanitarianfinancingaswellasrelevantagencyandinter-agencypolicystatements.Thisservedasbackgroundinformationandtoindicatethecurrentpointsofcontentionorconsensusonfinancingissues.

Theresearchteamalsoconductedsemi-structuredinterviewswithselectedindividualsrepresentingmajorandemergingdonorgovernments,implementingagencies,andhumanitariancoordinationandfundingbodies.Interviewfindingswereusedtoconfirmandquerythedatafindings,aswellastogleanperspectivesonthekeyfinancialissuesandtrendsinthesector.Inall,86individualswereinterviewedforthestudy(listattachedasAnnex1).

1.2.2Fieldresearch

AfterexploringoptionswiththeinputofAdvisoryGroupmembers,theteamidentifiedthreecasescenariosforfieldresearch:Ethiopia(2016),Iraq(2016),andMyanmar(2015floods).Theselectionofthesethreecasesaimedforregionaldiversityaswellasacombinationofslow-andsudden-onsetemergencies,naturalaswellasconflict-related,andwidelyvaryinguniquecontextualchallenges.

FieldtripstookplaceinFebruaryandMarch,2017.Theresearchcombineddetailedqualitativeinterviewswithhumanitarianorganizationsanddonorrepresentativestocapturearangeofviews,experiences,andcontextualconsiderationsintheassessmentoffundingefficiency.Inaddition,thefieldresearchgathereddataonasampleofhumanitariancontributionsforquantitativeanalysis,describedbelow.

1.2.3Quantitativeanalysis

Theresearchersineachfieldlocationrequestedinterviewsubjectstofillininformationonaspreadsheetcontainingasampleofcontributionsreceivedbytheiragenciesthroughdifferentfundingchannels,asreportedtoFTS.Theworksheetsincludedthefollowingdataquestionsforcompletion:

8

• the number of iterations that took place before the proposal was accepted, • the number of days from proposal submission to award, • the number of days from award to disbursement of funds, • staff hours expended on administrative requirements, and • the perceived administrative burden in terms of staff time and inputs required (ranked on a scale

from 1 (light) to 5 (heavy).

Outof32formalrequests,theresearchteamreceived16completedspreadsheetsintotalfrom5UNand11NGOofficescomprising209observations(totalcontributions).Ofthose,149contributionswerebilateralgrantsfromdonorgovernments,49werecountry-basedpooledfundsallocations,9wereCERFallocations,and2wereStartFundallocations.Thespecificdependentvariablesforeachmechanism(dayselapsed,etc.)wereaveragedwithinandacrosscountries,andthedifferencesbetweenthemwerefoundtobestatisticallysignificantbyanindependentsamplest-test.3Thequantitativefindingsagainstthevariousfundingchannelsarepresentedintherelevantsectionsofthepaper.

Becausetimelinessandtransactioncostsarejusttwoindicatorsofonetypeofefficiency,thepaperiscarefulnottooveremphasizethesequantitativefindings,astheywillalwaysneedtobebalancedbyotherfactorsinanydecision.Nevertheless,havingconcretemeasurestoconsideralongsidethequalitativeinformationisuseful.

1.3Caveatsandlimitations

Thestudyaimedtobeasempiricalandquantitativeaspossible,providingconcretemeasuresforwhathasbeenpurelyanecdotalorassumedtodate.However,becauseofthetimeandlabor-intensivenatureofgatheringdatapointsfromfieldoffices,wenecessarilyendedupwithasmallsample.Whilethefindingsofthequantitativeanalysisofthefielddatacorrespondtoglobalfigures(e.g.,theproportionsoffundingthrougheachmechanismareroughlyequivalenttooverallglobalproportions),weneverthelessmustbemodestinclaimingthattheyarerepresentativeofefficiencyperformanceinallemergencieseverywhere.

Eachhumanitarianresponsecontextisuniqueinmanyaspects,andtheabilitytocoveronlythree(Ethiopia,Iraq,andMyanmar)necessarilyinfluencedthefindings.AsobservedbyanAdvisoryGroupmember,“Alotofthethingsthatdon’tworkinIraq,Ethiopia,orMyanmar,arethingsthatactuallyworkquitewellinotherplaces.”Wehopewehavestruckabalancebetweenpointingoutthecase-specificproblemsweobservedandnotover-generalizingfromtheresults.

Finally,theteamiscognizantofvalidopinions,includingamongourAdvisoryGroup,thatleadtoskepticismofastudyonefficiencyinisolationofothervariables.Ourframingoftheefficiencydefinitioninthefollowingchapterspecificallyaddressesthisproblem,and,webelieve,offersasolutionadequatetothegoalsofthestudy.

3Theindependentsamplest-testcomparesthemeansoftwoindependentgroupstodetermineiftheassociatedpopulationmeansaresignificantlydifferent.

9

2.Definingefficiency

Practitionersinterviewedforthisstudyofferedwidelydifferingdefinitionsofefficiencyinhumanitarianfunding,from“leastpossiblewaste”to“flexibleandresponsivetoneeds”to“directaspossible,withfewestlinksinthechain.”Notsurprisingly,opinionswerecoloredbytheinterviewees’vantagepointsinthehumanitariansector.Donorintervieweeswereconsistentthatefficiencyfromtheirperspectivemostlymeantminimizingtheirownadministrativeburdenbylimitingthenumberofcontractsundertheirdirectmanagement.Inotherwords,funnelinglargeramountsthroughfewer(knownandtrusted)recipientagencies.First-levelrecipientagencies(UNagenciesandlargeinternationalNGOs)sawefficientfundingasthatwhichwasmaximallyflexiblewithminimaltransactioncosts.(Theidealinstrument,describedbyUNagencyrepresentatives,wasanun-earmarkedglobalcontributionwithlittleproposal,reporting,orcompliancerequirements.)NationalNGOsstressedsufficiencyingrantstoenableexecutionandcontinuityoftheiroperations(inotherwords,reasonableoverheadallowances)andtheneedforlessoneroustransactioncostsandbarrierstoentry.Allagreedthatspeedwasacriticalelementforefficientfunding,buttheneedforspeedcouldbeoffsetbypredictabilityiftherecipientagencywaslargeenoughtohavethecapacitytoadvancethenecessaryfundsforrapidresponseorinslow-onsetemergenciesorchronic-crisisenvironments.

Whenviewedthroughthelensofdifferentactors’interestsatdifferentlevelsinthesystem,efficiencycanappearasazero-sumgame,inwhichefficiencygainsforonepartycreatesinefficienciesforanother.Forexample,donorsmaymaximizetheirefficiencybymakinglargerumbrellagrants,therebyshiftingtheadministrativeburdentoagencies,andinternationalagenciesmayreducecostsbyrestrictingoverheadallowancesfortheirNGOpartners,creatinginefficienciesatthesubcontractorlevel.Forthatreason,toarriveatanobjectiveassessmentoffundingefficiencyatthesystemlevelrequiresadefinitionthatcanbalancecompetinginterestsofdifferentactorsalongthetransactionchainandwhichiscenteredonthebroaderfundingefficiencyofthecollectiveresponse.

2.1Typesofefficiency

Tobeginwithsomebasicdefinitionsofefficiencyineconomicterms,initssimplestdescription,efficiencyismeasuredbyaratioofoutputstoinputs.Thehighertheusefuloutputproducedrelativetoinputorcost(inmoney,fuel,staffing,time,energy,etc.),thehighertheefficiency.Ifeffectivenessis“gettingthingsdone,”i.e.,achievingobjectives,efficiencyis“doingthingswell”byreducingwaste,optimizingresources,andmaximizingdesiredoutputs.

Forourpurposes,itusefultounpacktheconceptfurtherwiththedistinctionsoftechnical(oroperational)efficiencyandallocativeefficiency.

Technicalefficiencyinhumanitarianfundingcanbeviewedasameasureofhowfundinggetsfromdonortoenduser(theaidrecipient)withaminimumofimpediments,transactioncosts,anddelays.Examplesoftechnicalefficiencyinafundingmechanismwouldthereforeincludetimeliness(meaningeitherspeedorpredictabletiming).Tobetechnicallyefficient,moreover,requiresahighratioofsufficiency(thesizeofthecontribution)tothetransactioncostsentailed(e.g.,hours

10

requiredforproposalwriting,negotiation,reporting,andotheradministrativeandcompliancetasks).Economiesofscaleisatypeoftechnicalefficiencyachievedwhencostsarereducedasafunctionofenlargingthedistributivechannelsorimplementationmechanisms,therebyconsolidatingandstreamlininginputs.Anintermediaryagencyorumbrellagrantmanagercansometimesprovidethistypeofefficiency,forinstancebycoordinatingcountrywideeffortsofnumerouspartnerstowardacommonoutcomeobjectiveandprovidingasingleprocurementpipelineorlogisticalplatform,thusavoidingduplicativecosts.

Allocativeefficiencyisconcernedwithdirectingfundingtowhereitwillhavethelargestbenefit,andthereforerelatestorelevance/appropriatenessandprioritizingthemosturgentneeds(Palenberg,2011).Examplesofallocativeefficiencywouldbefundingmechanismsthatfillgapsormitigateagainstduplicationofresources.Similarly,fundingmechanismswillhaveallocativeefficiencyiftheyhavetheflexibilitytoredirectormodifyspendingaswarrantedbychanginghumanitarianconditionsandpriorities.Somehumanitarianactorshavealsosuggestedatemporalperspectiveofefficiencyinsettingsofchronicvulnerability,namelytheimpactorreturnoninvestmentofdifferentfundingstrategiesinthelongterm.Subsidiarityreferstotheprincipleoflocatingresponsibilityoractionatthelevelnearesttowhichitisrequired.Thesubsidiarityprinciplecanoftensupportanefficiencyargumentfor“localization,”i.e.,facilitatingtheassumptionoflargerrolesbylocalactorsintheprovisionofaidtotheirownpopulations(inadditiontotheeffectivenessandsustainabilityarguments.)Incaseswherelocalactorsarebestplacedtoresponddirectlytospecificsituationsandneeds,channelingtheirfundingthroughintermediariesisinefficient.However,subsidiarityandlocalizationarenotalwayssynonymous.Situationswilloccurwhereabroaderscopeofactionprovidesgreaterallocativeefficiencyand/orwhereinternationalactorswillrepresentaddedvalue,forinstancebyprovidingtechnicalassistance,capacityinputs,centralizedprocurement,andcoordinationofmultipleeffortsforacommonoutcome.Wehavethereforeincluded“addedvalue”inthesamecategory,asacorollarytosubsidiarity.

Itisimportanttoconsideralltheaboveinoursystem-levelefficiencyassessment,astheyrelatetodifferentaspectsandobjectivesofhumanitarianresponse.Afterall,thehumanitariansectorisnotafactoryorfree-marketenterprise,butratherauniquehybridofpublicgoodsprovisionandcompetitiveinterestsengagedincomplexandvariedactivities.So,forexample,onefundingmodalitymayhavesuperiortechnicalefficiencybutmaynotbescalable,whileanothermayentailheavytransactioncostsbutneverthelessresultinallocativeefficiencies.Theprincipleofhumanityandtheprioritizationofthemostvulnerablealsooftenrequiremoredifficultandexpensiveinterventions,forinstance,reachingremote,hard-to-accesspopulations.Insum,differentfundingmechanismsorarrangementscangenerateefficienciesindifferentways,soshouldnotbeheldtoareductivemeasureofinputs-to-outputs.4

Manyintervieweeshighlightedwhattheyperceivedasbroader“structuralinefficiencies”inthehumanitariansystemrelatingtomandates,architecture,andprocesssuchasclustercoordination.

4AsimilarlogicisfoundinUKDFID’s“valueformoney”formulation,inwhichefficiencyislinkedtoeffectivenessinpursuitofadesiredoutcomeanddependentonthespecificcircumstancesofthecontext.

11

Thisstudyhasfocusedontechnicalandallocativeefficiencyasthelevelofanalysistomakeitsscopemanageable,whilereferencingsuchissueswhererelevant.

Figure1:Efficiencyinfunding:Conceptualframework

2.2Causesofinefficiencyinhumanitarianfunding

Themainimpedimentstoefficiencyinhumanitarianfunding,regardlessofthemodality,canbegroupedunderfourareas:transactioncosts,riskperception,informationasymmetry(i.e.,lackoftransparency),andcompetingobjectives.

Transactioncostsinhumanitarianfundingareanyrequiredoutlaysorinputsthatsloworreducethefundingflowbetweentheoriginaldonorandend-userecipient.Organizationaladministrativeprocessesrequiredforthefundingtoflowareconsideredatypeoftransactioncost,sometimesmorepreciselytermed“institutionalcosts”(Cheung,1987).Whilesomeleveloftransactioncostsisinevitable,minimizingthemiscentraltotechnicalefficiency.Forourpurposes,thedefinitionoftransactioncostsiswideenoughtoincludeallthefollowing:

• multiplelinksinthetransactionchain,leadingtoaccumulatedoverheadcosts;• bureaucraticprocedures,processrequirements,andadministrativeburdensrequiringstaff

timeandattimesevenadditionalstaffpositions;and• proceduraldelaysinfinaldisbursementandactivitystart-up.

Technicalinefficiencyofthistypecanbebuiltintofundingstructuresandprocedures,orcausedbytheirpoorimplementation.Inthecontextofrapid-onsetemergencies,speedwillbeaprimarycasualty.Slownessinfundingcanalsocreateallocativeinefficienciesbecauseoftenbythetimethefundsarrive—weeksormonthsaftertheinitialshock—theresponsetheywereintendedtofundwilllikelynolongerbewhatismostneeded.

TechnicalefficiencyTimeliness

(speed/predictability)

Sufficiency/limitedtransactioncosts

Economiesofscale

Allocativeefficiency

Flexibility

Subsidiarity

Addedvalue

12

Liketimeliness,insufficiency,islinkedtotransactioncosts,inthatthereisapointofdiminishingreturnsafterwhichthesizeofthegrantistoosmallfortheinvestmentintransactioncoststobeconsideredworththeeffort.

Effortsbydonorstoreducepotentialrisks—includingfraud,waste,ordiversion—havedriventheincreasingcomplianceburdenonagencies.Theseaccountabilitycontrolscangeneratetechnicalinefficiencies.5Totheextentthatriskconsiderationsalsodrivewherefundingisdirected,theycanalsonegativelyaffectallocativeefficiency(nottomentionpotentiallycompromisingthehumanitarianprincipleofimpartiality).Riskconcernsconstrainthewillingnessofdonorstopursuesubsidiarity,thuscreatebarrierstoamorelocalizedresponse.Governmentdonorsgenerallywillnotfundnationalactorsdirectlyforreasonsofperceivedfiduciaryriskand,asoneputit,the“needtobeaccountabletoourtax-payers.”Likedonors,theUNagenciesandinternationalNGOsthatsub-contracttosmallerorlocalorganizationscanalsocreaterisk-driveninefficiencies.Forinstance,becausecommonagreementsorstandardsforvettingpotentialpartnersdonotexist,oftenthesameorganizationmustbevettedbynumerousagenciesandineachnewoperatinglocation,takingconsiderabletimeandeffort.

Informationasymmetry,orwhatmanyinthehumanitariansectorlabel“lackoftransparency,”isalsoadriverofinefficiency.Theclustersystemhasarguablyimprovedtransparencyamonghumanitarianactors,butaccordingtointervieweesforthisstudyseriousissuesremain.One,inMyanmar,notedthattheoveralllackoftransparencyamonghumanitarianactors,andbetweentheimplementersandtheirdonors,madeitverydifficulttogetaholisticviewoftransactionchains.Insuchasituation,onecan’tevenidentifywheretheinefficienciesaretoaddressthem.Onedonorrepresentativelamenteda“totallackoftransparency—wereallycannottellwhatitisthatagencies,particularlytheUN,dowiththemoney.Thereisnodata,soitisveryhardtoknowwhatisefficient.”(Agenciestendtoframetheissuemuchdifferently,andspeakofa“lackoftrust”onthepartofdonorsfortheirpartners.)Othertypesofinefficiency,likedelays,canbemadeworsebylackofinformation.OneINGOrepresentativereportedbeingunabletomobilizeinBorno,Nigeria,despitehavingateamontheground,intheabsenceofreliableinformationfromthedonorthatfundingwouldultimatelycomethrough.

Finally,competingobjectivesandincentivesonthepartofhumanitarianactorscancreateallocativeinefficiencies.Donors’fundingconsiderationsgobeyondjustmeetinghumanitarianneeds,andpoliticalvariableshavethepotentialtoimpactefficiency(Beck,2006).OECDguidelinesfordonorssuggestincreasingthetransparencyoffundingdiscussionsasatooltolimitpoliticalincentivesfromovershadowinghumanitarianpriorities(OECD,2012).Implementingagencieslikewisehaveorganizationalinterestsforgrowthandcompetitiveadvantageovercounterparts,anddecisionsdrivenbytheseinterestsarelikelynottofavormaximumefficiency.

5AnINGOintervieweegavetheexampleofaChadprograminwhich80%ofalltheINGO’ssupportcostswerebeingusedtoaddressadonor’srequirementsforfinancialreporting,monitoring,andcompliancechecks.ThedonorwasneverthelesspressuringtheINGOtosignificantlyreducetheirsupportcostsfromthebudget(withnochangeinreportingrequirements).

13

3. Efficiencyfindingsforfundingmodalities

Usingtheaboveframingofefficiencytypes,thissectionpresentstheresearchonthedifferenthumanitarianfundingmodalitieswithinspecifichumanitarianresponsesinEthiopia,Iraq,andMyanmar.Thefindingsforeachmodalityareorganizedunderthethemesoftimeliness,sufficiency/limitedtransactioncosts,economiesofscale,flexibility,subsidiarity,andaddedvalue.

Contextplaysanimportantroleinassessingefficiencyinallthesecases.Therearebigdifferences,forinstance,betweenwhatmakesfundingefficientinsudden-onsetnaturaldisastersorrapidpopulationdisplacementsversusongoingprotractedcrisesorstaticrefugeesituations.Intheformer,rapidityisofcentralimportance,whilethelatterstandstobenefitmorefromlonger-term,predictablecycles,consolidatedsupportstructures,andeconomiesofscale.Ineachofthethreefieldcasesexaminedforthisstudy,sudden-onsetemergenciesorrapidnewdevelopmentsoccurredamidlong-runningcomplexorconflict-drivenemergencies,affordingtheopportunitytolookatbothscenarios.

3.1 Directgrants

Byfarthelargestpercentageofhumanitarianfundsdirectedtoemergenciesacrosstheworldeachyearcomesintheformofdirect(“bilateral”)grantsfromdonorgovernments(includingtheEU)torecipientagencies(Figure2).

Figure2:Globalproportionsofemergencycontributions,2015–2016

Source:OCHAFTS(ftsarchive.unocha.org)Whennaturaldisastersareexaminedinisolationfromcomplex(conflict-relatedorprotracted)emergenciesduringthesameperiod,theproportionschangesomewhat,withgovernmentdirectgrantsstillrepresentingthemajoritybutdroppingto63percentofthetotal,privatecontributionsat22percent,andpooledfundsat10percent.FundingpatternsinEthiopia,Iraq,andMyanmar(allcomplexemergencies)roughlyfollowedtheglobalnorm,withdirectgrantsrepresenting85percent,92percent,and90percentoftotalhumanitarianflowsrespectively.

Donorgovernmentdirectgrants

90%

Pooledfunds(combined)

5%

Private3%

Other2%

14

3.1.1Technicalefficiency

Thoughitvariesfromdonortodonor,overallthedirectgrantingmodalityisseenashavinghighertechnicalefficienciesintermsofpredictabilityandsufficiency(i.e.,largerandrelativelypredictablecontributions).Andwhilethetransactioncostscouldbehighforsomedonors’grants,thesedonorstendtobetheonesprovidinglargersums,sothesufficiency-to-transactioncostsratiocanremainfavorable.

Comparedtotheotherfundingmodalities,however,directgrantsareoveralllessefficientintermsoffundingspeedrequiredforrapidresponseandlowerstillforsubsidiarityefficiency—inthatdonorconstraintsoftenrequirethattheyfunneltheircontributionsthroughlargerchannels,regardlessofwhetherthisisthemostdirectandefficientwayforfundingtoreachtheactorbestplacedtoimplement.

Table1:AveragesfromsampledcontributionsinEthiopia,Iraq,andMyanmar(2015and2016)

Sizeofcontribution(USDmillions)

Days:proposaltoaward

Days:awardtodisbursement

Numberofiterationsinproposalprocess

Perceivedadministrativeburden:1(light)to5(heavy)

Bilateral(direct)grants 6.10 47 18 3 2CERF 1.70 10* 13* 5 4CBPFs 0.70 46** 28** 5 3

StartFund 0.16 2 0 0 1

Privategrants 0.18 2 3 0 2

*TheCERFSecretariatnotesinresponsethattheirdatabaseshow6daysfromproposaltoawardratherthan10and2daysfromawardtodisbursementratherthan13.**FCSdataonCBPFsshow39daysfromproposaltoawardand12daysfromawardtodisbursementTimeliness(speed/predictability)

Oneofthekeydrawbacksofdirectgrantinginsuddenonsetemergenciesisthatmostbilateralinstrumentsareusuallynotcapableofrespondingtosignalsandmobilizingwithinanacceptabletimeframetoenableatimelyresponse.Inoursamplethedirectdonorgovernmentgrantstookanaverageof47daysfromthetimeofproposalsubmissiontoawarddecisionandafurther18daysfromawarddecisiontodisbursementoffunds.

The2016droughtresponseinEthiopia—largeinscaleandwell-organized,withthegovernmentplayingakeyroleincoordinationandresponse—wasconsideredtohavebeenasuccessoverall,havingavertedsignificantexcessmortality.However,evaluationsidentifiedsomeseriousweaknesses,particularlyregardingtimelinessoftheresponse,includingdelayedarrivaloffunding(OCHA,2017).Intervieweescommentedonthedifficultiesinconvincingdonorcapitalsthatadeterioratingslow-onsetsituationwouldimminentlyrequirearapidresponse.Donordecision-

15

makersunderstandverywellthelogicofearlymitigatingaction,butincaseswheretheyhavealimitedpotoffundstoallocatetoexistingacuteneeds,prioritizingnewneedswhicharelikelybuthavenotyetoccurredisanextremelydifficultcasetomake.Inaddition,thesedonorswillhavecompetingprioritiesandemergencieselsewhereintheworldtoconsider.

TheproposalprocessprovedtobethegreatestpracticalimpedimenttotimelinessindirectgrantinginEthiopia.Adonorissuesacallforproposals,andbythetimeproposalsaresubmitted,reviewed,amendedandcontracted,itiscommonforthreetofourmonthstohaveelapsed,ataminimum.Acrucialexceptionisincaseswheredonorscanmodifytheirexistinggrantagreements,or,similarly,whereintermediaries(UNagenciesorinternationalNGOs)canmodifyagreementswithlocalactors.Inthesescenarios,thistime-lagmaybealmosteliminated.DFID,forexample,wasthefirstbilateraldonortorespondtothecrisis,inJuly2015,anddidsobytoppingupexistingmulti-yearagreementswiththeiraid-providerpartners,obviatingtheneedforadditionalgrantprocedures.TheUnitedStatesandSwedenmanagedtodothesameandmovedfundingfromtheirdevelopmentbudgetstotheirhumanitarianbudgets.Thisarrangementplayedacrucialrolefortheoverallresponseandshouldbefurtherexplored.

HumanitarianactorsinMyanmaralsocontendedwithdelayedfundingresponsesinthe2015floodsthataffectedlargeareasofthecountry,includingthosewherehumanitarianswereengagedinongoingassistancetoconflict-displacedpeople.Delaysintheapprovalanddisbursementprocessmeanttheinternationalhumanitariancommunitytookupwardsoftwomonthstoproperlybegintheresponsetothefloodemergency.

Theslownessinbilateralfundingneednotbeinevitable,assomerareexamplesshow.DFIDhasgivenapprovalauthoritytosomelocalofficesforuptoGBP2million,forinstance,whichcanenablefundstobereleasedveryquickly—amodelwhichwouldservehumanitarianactiontobereplicated.

Wheredirectgrantsdohaveatimelinessadvantageoverothermodalitiesisinpredictabilityoffundingforlong-termchronicemergencyresponses.Forsuchfunding,donorstypicallyhavesetdisbursementschedulesaccordingtotheirfiscalyears,participateinpledgingconferencestosignalintentions,andhavelong-termworkingrelationshipswithoperationalorganizations.InIraq,thefundingarrangementsdeemedmostefficientbyoperationalactorsweredirectgrantsoflongdurationthattendedtobetiedtolong-standingrelationshipsthatincludedanelementoftrust.

Sufficiency/transactioncosts

Directgrantingscoreshigherinsufficiencythanmostotherfundingmodalities.Whileindividualgrantsrunthegamutfromverysmalltoverylarge,onaveragetheyareseventimeslargerthanallocationsmadethroughthepooledfundmechanisms.However,mostefficienciesarerealizedwhenthesizeofthegrantislargerelativetothecosttothegranteeinthetimeandadministrationburdentoobtainandadministerit.Andtheinflexibilityofsomeofthesegrantscanbeconsiderable.Severalhumanitarianorganizationrepresentativesspokeoftheproblemscausedbybeinglockedintonarrowbudgetlineitemsandstaffingplansfromproposals,hinderingthemakingofanynecessaryadjustmentsthatmayariselater.

16

Theproposalprocessentailsanadditionalsetoftransactioncosts,alsorepeatedlyflaggedbyhumanitarianactorsasatimeburdenandinefficiency.TheGrandBargainandrecentresearchinitiatives(Rosellietal.,2016;Caccavaleetal.,2016)havedelvedintotheissueofreportingrequirementsandmadethecaseforharmonizedreportingformatsacrossdifferentdonors.

OFDAandECHOarelargelyconsideredtobeefficientsourcesofdirectgrants,despiteheavyadministrativerequirements(muchofwhichisenshrinedinlaw)andhighbarrierstoentryforgrantees.Afundingrelationship,onceitisestablishedandcompliancesystemsaresetup,becomesapredictable(iflabor-intensive)propositionwithahighbenefit-to-costratioandthusworththeinvestment.However,directfundingrelationshipswithhighentrycostsandlowflexibility(evenwithacceptablereportingcosts)wereconsideredlessefficientwhenthetotalamountoffundingwasrelativelylow.

Thedonorsperceivedashavinglow“entrycosts,”relativeflexibility,andlightproposalandreportingrequirementswereclearlyalsoperceivedbyhumanitarianorganizationsasthemostefficientsourcesoffunding(Switzerland,Norway,Sweden,andGermanywerenotedasexamples).(However,another,perhapslessvisible,formofentrybarrieriswhendonorspreferentiallygranttoINGOsbasedintheirowncountries,whichappliestosomeoftheabove.)

Fundingvolumeisnotalwaysofprimaryimportance,however,andhumanitarianactorsdonotalwaysviewsmallgrantsasinefficient.AsoneINGOrepresentativepointedout,thoughsmallgrantsarerelativelycostly,theycanattimesbeveryvaluableforallocativeefficiency“iftheygiveyoumoneyforsomethingyoureallywanttodo,andmayopenthedoorforotheropportunities.”Somethinginefficientintheshorttermcanthuspayoffinthelongrunaswellasaddothervalue.

InIraq,evidenceshowsthat,eventhoughtheyhaveefficiencyproblemsstemmingfromthecombinationofmultiplefundingstreams,operationalactorsprefercertaindirectgrantingarrangements.Highlydivergentadministrativeandreportingrequirementsbydifferentdonorswereclearlyandconsistentlycitedaskeyissuesforoperationalactors,andthenotionofasystemparalyzedbymultiplelayersofreportingrequirementswasraisedinmorethanoneinterview.Gulfstatedonorswerecitedbyagenciesasparticularlyproblematic,requiringextensivefeedbackanddetailedreporting.Therelationshipbetweenthedonorandrecipientagency,accordingtoonesenioragencyinterviewee“feelsmuchmoreunequal,andwedon’tunderstandwhatexactlytheywant.”

Economiesofscale

Withverylargebilateralgrants,economiesofscalecanbecreatedinthesamewaytheyarethroughpooledfundingallocationstolargeorganizations(UNagenciesormajorINGOs)andclusterleadstocoordinateandmanagelarge-scaleresponseswithmultiplepartners.Becauseofthegranular,fragmentednatureofthehumanitariansector,thisisoftentheonlyconceivablewaytoproduceresultsatscaleacrossalargearea/population.Forexample,UNICEF’s$1milliongrantfromOFDAforthe2015responsetotheRakhinecrisisinMyanmarallowedittoworkatscalethroughmultiplepartners.TheINGOIRChasconductedefficiencyanalysisoflatrine-constructionprogramsinEthiopia,findingthat“thedifferenceincostperperson-yearoflatrineaccessdiffered

17

morethantwentytimesbetweenthesmallestandthelargestprograms.Thisisroutinelytrueacrossprogrammingsectorswhichincurfixedcosts,”suchaswaterandsanitation,andlesstrueforsectorslikeprotectionwhicharestaff-intensive.6

3.1.2Allocativeefficiency

Flexibility

InMyanmar,manyofthechiefcomplaintsaboutdirectgrantfundingrelatedtothosegrantsthatdidnotallowtheflexibilitytomakenecessarychangesmidstream.FortheinternationalRedCrossmovemententities,earmarkedgrantsatthesubnationallevelmeantafarmorerestrictiveformoffundingandonewhichleftthemwithunderfundedneeds,suchaslogistics,thatmostdonorsfeltweretoo“unsexy”toresource.AnINGOrespondentalsoquestionedsomedonors’insistencethattheyhireadditional(muchmorecostly)senior-levelinternationalstaff“for‘accountability’purposes.Youbegintoquestionhowefficientthisis.”

Thetwolargesthumanitariandonors,theU.S.governmentandECHO,arerelativelyrestrictiveaccordingtotheirofficialguidance.However,withthehelpofdonorfieldofficers,partnerscanextractmoreflexibilityfromtheofficialrules.Forexample,OFDAadvisespartnerstousebroadergeographicaldelineationsratherthanhighlyspecificlocationsandtoinclude“trip-wires”ortriggersandthresholdsforresponseoradaptionwithouthavingtorequestaformalmodificationtothegrant.ECHOrequiresalotofdetailintheproposalpreparationstageandisrelativelyinflexiblewhenitcomestoadaptingprogramswithoutundergoingatime-consumingmodification.However,partnersareallowedavarianceacrossbudgetlines,providingspendingflexibility.Constraintsonpurchaseofdrugswerefelttobeoneofthemostrestrictivedonorconditions,whichappliestoboththeU.S.andECHO.TheU.S.hasextensiverestrictionsondrugprocurement.ECHOmeanwhilerequiresinternationalprocurementtomeetitsorganizationalqualitystandards,whichcantakeuptosixmonths,includingshipping,customsclearance,andinternaltransportinsomecontexts.Mostorganizationsconsiderthisimpossibleforrapidresponse.Therefore,organizationsmayoftenhavetoseekalternativefundingforprocurementofdrugsandmedicalsuppliestoworkaroundtheU.S.’sandECHO’srestrictions.

Subsidiarity(localization)

Putsimply,localNGOscanoftenoperateatlowercostandclosertocommunities,whichinmanycasescanbemoreefficient(aswellaseffective)forhumanitarianresponse,buttheylackdirectaccesstofinancialresourcesofthesortinternationaldonorscanprovide,butforthemostpartdonot.Whiletheneedforgreaterlocalizationofhumanitarianresponse,wherepossible,wasaprominentthemeattheWorldHumanitarianSummitandintheGrandBargain,donorgovernmentshavetodateofferedupmorerhetoricalsupportforitthanconcreteaction.DonorsinMyanmar,forexample,spokeofageneral“consensustofundasdirectlyandaslocallyaspossible,”withone

6CommentprovidedtothestudythroughtheAdvisoryGroupreviewprocess.Dataavailableathttps://www.rescue.org/report/cost-efficiency-latrine-building-camps.

18

donorrepresentativesayingtherewas“noreasonwhy10yearsfromnowinternationalorganizationsshouldstillbestillrunningtheshow,”butthesesentimentshavebeenslowtomaterialize.Fairlyorunfairly,accountabilityrisks(oftencementedindonors’operationalregulationsorevenindomesticlegislation)preventmanydonorgovernmentsfromfundingnationalaidorganizationsdirectly.Inthewordsofonedonorinterviewee,“Woulditbemoreefficienttogodirecttothebottomline(localproviders)?Possibly—butwedon’thavethecounterfactualbecausewearenotwillingtotakethatrisk.”

Somesignsofincrementalchangeinthisareaarevisible,however.USAID/OFDAcurrentlyfundsonenationalBurmeseNGOdirectly—anorganizationcalledMetta,whichhadtheinstitutionalcapacitytoundergoandpassarigorousorganizationalaudit.Someinitialpracticaldifficultiesofthisnovelarrangementstemmingfromregulationssoonbecameevident,includingproblemsmakingbanktransferstotheNGOin-country.Intervieweesalsonoted,asencapsulatedbyonerespondent,therisksometimesbornebyhighperformers:“WhendonorsfindastronglocalNGO,theytendtogivethemalotofmoney,makingitdifficultfortheNGOtohandlelargescalegrowthinashortperiodoftime,whichsometimescreatesperformanceissues.”

ItisnoteworthythatOFDAisamongthemostoperationalofdonors,withgreatercapacityforindividualgrantmanagementinthefieldthanmany.Fordonorswithsignificantresourcestospendbutlimitedstafftodeployinthefield,theincentiveistowritelargergrantsforfewerprojects.Forthistheyrequirepartnerswithlargecapacitytoeitherimplementormanagesub-grantees.Thisofcoursemilitatesagainstdirectfundingofsmalleractorsandhenceagainstlocalizationeffortsandsubsidiarity.

Addedvalue

Thedonorsthatwereheaviestintermsofadministrativerequirementsandtransactioncosts(OFDAandECHO)werealsonotedbytheirgranteesashavingaddedsomesignificanttechnicalvalue.AnINGOintervieweegavearecentexamplewheretheOFDAstaffinNigeriawerewellversedinboththecontextandtechnicalaspectsofprogramming,andsocouldmeaningfullycontributetoandimproveprogramdesigns,andafterthedesignphasewerehandsoffintermsoftheimplementation,“whichisareallygoodbalance.”

IntervieweesinMyanmaralsospokeofgovernmentbilateraldonorssuchasDFIDandOFDAasaddingvalueandarguablypromotingallocativeefficiencybytakinga“portfolioapproach”totheirfunding,wheretheirdifferentgranteesprovidedifferentadvantagesandcomplementeachother’seffortsintheaggregate.However,evenwithdonors’attemptstocoordinateandensurecoverageorcomplementarityintermsofsectors,inpracticebothneedsassessmentandcoordinationareimperfect,efficiencymetricsarelimited,andfundingisawardedprimarilytoknownandtrustedpartnerswithcapacity,accessandtrackrecords.

3.2Bilateralgrantintermediaries

Asubsetofefficiencyissuescomeswiththegrantswithmorethanonelinkinthetransactionchain,i.e.,thataresub-grantedfromtheprimaryrecipientagencies(UNorlargeINGOs)tosmaller

19

operationalactors.Thesetendtobeslowerandentailgreatercumulativetransactioncosts.However,theycanattimesbejustifiedbytheirallocativeefficiencybenefitsandthetechnicalorlogisticalvalueaddedbytheprimaryrecipientagencytotheimplementingpartners.Inotherwords,therightrelationshipwithanintermediarycanoffsettechnicalefficiencylossesbyaddingallocativeefficiencyandultimatelyenhancingeffectiveness.Particularlyforsmalllocalactorsthatundertakehumanitarianinterventionsinfrequently,thevalueaddedinsustainedmentoringrelationshipswithINGOsorUNagencies,whentheseareofhighquality,canbesignificant.

Forthethreecasesstudied,intervieweescriticizedthesearrangementsascumbersomeandthevalueaddedasminimal.Thesearrangementsweredeemedparticularlyinefficientwhentheywereusedtodeliverprojectsthatinvokedtheconceptof“provideroflastresort.”Forexample,aUNagencywasrequiredtosub-contractacertaintechnicalinventionthroughapartnerundercircumstanceswheretherewasnoestablishedrelationshipwiththepartnerandthepartnerwasaskedtoworkinanarea(“thematic”or“geographical”)whereitwasnotalreadyestablished.

3.2.1Technicalefficiency

Becausemorethanonesetofproposalreviewandrevisionproceduresusuallyexist,aswellasadditionallinksinthechainthatmoneymovesalong(entailingadditionaltimeonthepartsofboththeorganizationsandtheirfinancialinstitutions),thetimelinewillbelongerforamulti-linkcontribution,evenbarringsnagsalongtheway.Differentintermediarygrantershadvaryingreputationsforbeingrelativelyfastorslow,withUNICEFcominginforthegreatestamountofcriticisminthisarea.Totheagency’scredit,staffhaverecognizedtheproblemwithbothspeedandflexibilityfortheirpartners(moreonthisbelow)andareworkingtoaddressit.Partoftheproblemmaybeanorganizationalmindsetwhereagenciesdonotperceivethemselvesas“donors”—whichinpracticetheyincreasinglyareinthesecases—andthusarenotattunedtogooddonorshipprinciplesandhowtheyshouldapplytotheirpartnershipswithsub-grantees.

InthecaseofIraq,undercertaincircumstances,partnershiparrangementsbetweenUNagenciesandpartnerswereseenassimilartoefficientpartnershipswithefficientdonors.Again,thekeywastheestablishednatureoftherelationship.Inonecase,theINGOpartnerhadlongsinceacceptedthattherulesoftherelationshipwererelativelyrigid,buthavinglearnedtherulesandacceptedthem,adegreeofflexibilitywasinherentinimplementation.OnelocalNGOreferredtoaflexibleandefficientpartnershipwithUNICEF,basedonalong-standingrelationshipandadegreeoftrust.Inotherinstances,however,partnershaddeclinedfundingfromUNICEFandUNHCRbecauseofinefficiency(overlyhighentryandtransactioncosts).Indeed,moreoftenthannot,INGOpartnerssawlittleornoaddedvalueinUNsub-contractingfortheirindividualorganizationsandprogramming,whereasdonorsfeltthatpassingmoneyviaUNagencieshadcreatedeconomiesofscaleinprocurementandcoordination.AkeyissueforthemappearedtobetheUN’sspecialrelationshipwiththeIraqigovernment.

AnintervieweefromonemajorNGOreported,“AlotofthetimewithUNgrantsitactuallycostsustoaccepttheirsub-grants,becausetheydon’tprovideenoughinoverheads.”Thiswasnottheonlyorganizationrepresentativeinterviewedthatspokeofoccasionallydecliningsub-grantsforinefficiencyreasons.ThesituationismoredifficultforlocalNGOs,whicharenotaffordedthe

20

customary7percentoverheadcostsgiventoINGOs.InMyanmar,thejustificationgivenwasthatINGOshaveglobalHQcostswhichneedtobecontributedtowhereaslocalNGOsdonot.Oftentheselocalorganizationsareallowedtochargemarginsontheirdirectcoststopayforinstitutionalexpenses,butbynomeansalways.Thisresultsintheend-chainimplementerofthegrantreceivingtheleastinindirectcostrecovery,whiletheintermediariesreceivethemost,ininverseproportiontotheirproximitytotheactualprogram.ThelackofsufficientoverheadforsmallerandlocalNGOscontributestothestuntingeffectthatthefinancingsystem—particularlythebilateralgrantmodality—imposesonthem.Smallorganizationstendtogetsmallgrants,whichnotonlyhavetheproportionallylargesttransactioncostsintermsofreporting(Caccavale,Haver,&Stoddard,2016),butalsomaketheleastavailabletotheorganizationtofundthecapacityneededtomeetthosecosts.Ratherthanusingeachsuccessivegranttobuildthecapacitytogrow,thenationalNGOsattheendofthetransactionchainremainsmallandoperatehandtomouth.

Somerepresentativesofintermediaryagencieshavesaidthattheyarerequiredbytheiroriginaldonorstodemandacertainlevelofcompliancefromtheirsubcontractors,anduntilandunlesstheyreceivemoreflexibilityfromdonors,theirhandsaretied.OneUNagencyrepresentativethatparticularlywhenthesubcontractorisalocalorganization,thedemandsbecomemorestringentasthedonorstrytoextendtheirriskmitigationefforts:“Themorewetalkaboutlocalization,theconditionsaregettingmoreandmoregranularintermsofwhatwemustgivebacktoourdonors,soitisnotefficientforus.”

Whetherdonor-drivenornot,thehighertransactioncostsforsubcontractorsversusprimaryagencyrecipientisrealandwell-known.The“LessPaperMoreAid”reportfoundthat“overallUNagenciesrequiremorefrequentreportscomparedtoinstitutionaldonors.OnaveragetheUNagenciesexaminedrequiredaminimumofsixreportstoamaximumofeightperyear.Theinstitutionaldonorsexamined,requiredonaverage,aminimumoftworeportstoamaximumofsixperyear”(Roselli,Fabbri,&CollingwoodEsland,2016).Similarly,arecentHumanitarianOutcomesanalysisfoundthat“reportingrequirementsarefarlessonerousforUNagencies.Thisdifferenceisduetothefactthat(1)donorsdonotplayaroleinthegovernanceofNGOsandhencedonothelpshapetheirinternalaccountabilitymechanismsashappenswith[UNagencies];and(2)NGOfundingismorefrequentlyconnectedtospecificprojects(i.e.,earmarked)andthereforeisseentorequiredetailed,project-specificreportingtoensureaccountability...”(Caccavale,Haver,&Stoddard,2016).

Theissueofagencyoverheadisoneofthemorecomplexexamplesoftransactioncoststohumanitarianfundingandoneofthemostchallengingtomeasure.Acertainamountofindirect,institutionalfundingtosupportandsustaintheorganizationanditsactivitiesisofcourseanecessity,particularlyifsaidorganizationreceiveslittleornocorebudgetsupportfromdonors.Thisbecomeshardertojustifywhenlongmulti-levelgrantingchainsseepercentageswithdrawnateachlevel,leavingultimatelylessmoneyfortheaidrecipient.Previousstudiestacklingtheissueofagencyoverheadhavestruggledwiththefactthatthereisnosinglecommondefinitionoraccountingformulafortheseindirectcosts,andcomparingdifferentactors’costsislikecomparingapplestooranges.Forthisstudy,wetookadeliberatelysimplerapproachofusingagencyself-reportedfigures(i.e.,thepercentagestakeninoverhead,asdefinedbytheagenciesthattookthem)

21

oneachcontributiontransactionchainstudied.Whatthisshowedwasthatdirectgrantswithnointermediarieslost11percentonaverageinoverhead,comparedtoacumulative14percentonaveragefortwo-linktransactionchains.Bythemselvesthesefiguresarenotinstructive:Itstandstoreasonthatmultiplelinkswillamounttomoreoverheadwithdrawnfromtheprincipalamountremainingforprogrammingactivities.However,itbecomessomethingtoconsideragainstthequalitativefindingsinthefieldonwhethertheintermediariescreatedeconomiesofscaleoraddedvaluetotheprogramming.

3.2.2Allocativeefficiency

Intermediaryfundingorganizations,whetheraUNagencyorlargeINGO,cantheoreticallycreatesystem-levelefficienciesandaddvalueinthe“middle-man”roleofahumanitarianresponseinavarietyofways,forexample,by

• coordinatingmultiple,geographicallydispersedeffortsunderasingleprogramtowardcommonoutcomes;

• assistingadvocacyeffortsandaccessnegotiations;• providingtechnicalexpertiseandguidanceandoverseeingstandardsinprogramming;or• directlyandindirectlyhelpingtostrengthencapacityofsmallerpartnersthroughtechnical

assistance,training,andbeingaconduittointernationalpublicandprivatefundingotherwiseinaccessible.

Ofcourse,theextenttowhichintermediariesaddvaluedependsonhowlimitedthecapacityofsub-granteesare—andtheintermediary’sownlimitations.InMyanmar,forinstance,WFPhasrobustsupplychainsandprocurementpipelineswhichcreateeconomiesofscaleinRakhineState,butcurrentlycannotbringphysicalcommoditiesintoKachin,solocalorganizationsaretakingonalargerindependentrolethere.

InEthiopiaaswell,UNagencieswereabletorealizeeconomiesofscale,whichisakeyconsiderationfordonorsinacrisiswherelargenumbersofpeopleareaffected,wheretheresponseiscommodity/logistics-heavyandwherelargegeographicalareasneedtobecovered.OnedonorcommentedthatwhentheyfundWFP,theyknowthattheycanmovequicklyandatscale,evenbeforetheyhavesignedanagreementbecausetheyhave“deeppockets”andestablishedsystems.ThatUNagenciesalsohaveestablishedrelationshipswithgovernment,whichhelpstofacilitatemoretimelyresponse,wasalsonotedasanadvantage.InadditiontotheestablishedroleofUNagenciesinclustercoordination,governmentliaisonandtheirabilitytocoordinateresponsesatscale,itisimportanttorememberthattheseagenciesaremandatedtobepresentinhumanitarianemergencies,whereasNGOpresenceisvoluntaryandhighlyvariable.

Asmentionedabove,thebulkofhumanitarianfundinggoesthroughbilateralgrantsfromlargegovernmentdonors.Andmostofthesedonorsareunableorunwillingtogranttonationalorganizationsdirectly,leavingaverythinsliceofthepieavailableforlocalactorstoaccesswithouthavingtobesubcontractedbyaninternationalorganization(mainlyCBPFallocationsandgrantsfromprivateorganizations).Whilewesawabovethatallocativeefficienciesresultingfromeconomiesofscaleandvalueaddedcanbebroughttobearincertainsituations(andgenerallyare

22

farmoreappreciatedbydonorsandlargeagenciesthanbytheNGOcommunity),unquestionablyinsomecasesthevalueaddedislackingornotcommensuratewiththetransactioncostsgenerated.AlocalNGOrepresentativeinMyanmaropinedsuccinctly,“Efficiencyisdeliveringintheshortesttimewheremostneeded.Bureaucraticmechanismswhichaskfortoomuchinformationareinefficient.”

Notallintermediaryorganizationscameinforcriticism.CaritasInternationalisreportedlyverylightonreportingandquiteflexibleintermsofchangingprogrammingmidstreamasneeded;OxfamaddsvaluethroughinformalsupporttogranteesapplyingtotheMyanmarHumanitarianFund.WFP,incontrasttootherUNagencyintermediaries,occasionallyreceivedsomepraiseas“astraightforwardcontract,veryfamiliar,goodmechanism,negotiatedlocally.”Thissuggeststhatorganizationsthathavebeendesignedfromtheoutsettoworkthroughpartnershipshaveworkedoutsomeefficienciesthatothersmayyetlack.

Atpresent,thelackofclearandreadilyavailableinformationonsub-grantinghindersthoroughanalysis.FTShasonlybeguntotrytocapturesecondaryandtertiarylevelsofgrantingintheirdatabaseasofthisyear,andinmanycasestheoriginaldonorsthemselvesarenotawareofwhatpercentageoftheirgrantsweresub-grantedtolocalNGOs.Asonedonorsaid,“Whenweaskedourpartners,theystruggledtotellushowmuchtheywerechannelingtolocalorganizations,andsecondly,itwasn’tthepartnersweexpected.ICRCendedupbeingourlargestsupporteroflocalpartners!”

3.3Global-levelpooledfunding(CERFandStart)

Sinceitsexpansionin2006,theCERFhasfunctionedtoproviderapid-responsefundingtosuddenonsetemergenciesandtofillgapsin“under-funded”emergencies.Withfundinglevelsclosetoits$500milliontargetforthepastfewyears,theCERFisnowanticipatedtodoubleinsizeto$1billion,followingcommitmentsmadeattheWorldHumanitarianSummitandendorsedbytheGeneralAssembly.Bydesign,theCERFexiststocreatebothtechnicalefficiencies(movingmoneyrapidly)andallocativeefficiencies(fillinggaps).Anestimated50percentofCERFfundsareusedtoprocurereliefitems.3.3.1Technicalefficiency

Timeliness(speed/predictability)

Regardingspeedofresponse,theCERFhasshownthatitcanmakeveryrapid(evenwithin24hours)decisionsanddisbursements.InEthiopiaforexample,theCERFwasnotedtohaveprovidedaverytimelyinjectionofcash,withanallocationinNovember2015,beforeotherdonorshadmobilized.CERFalsoallowsback-datingrequestsuptosixweekssothatagenciescanbeginprogrammingwiththeirinternalreservesassoonastheyareconfidentthattheywillreceivetheCERFallocation.

Whereproblemsarise,however,isonthefrontandbackendofthetransactions,withdelaysoccurringinthepre-proposalsubmissionprocessandfollowingtheinitialdisbursement.IntheMyanmar2015floodresponse,CERFfundstookanaverageof30daystoreachthesecondary

23

(implementing)agencies,whichislengthywhendealingwithfirst-responseneedsinasudden-onsetemergency.

ManyintervieweespinnedpartoftheblameforthisonCERF’spreferenceforreceivingjoinedupagencyapplicationsratherthanconsideringseparateproposalsastheycomein.Whilethisismeanttopromotestrategiccoordinationofactivities(anexampleofaddingvalueandallocativeefficiency),itmeansthattheapplicationprocessmovesasfastastheslowestmember,andobserversnoteanelementof“piesharing”isclearlyatplayaswell.Moreover,intervieweeswerenotconvincedthattheextratimetakentocombineproposalsinfactenabledprioritizationandplanning.AUNrepresentativeinthefielddescribeditas“creatingachapeaudocumentandinventingastrategicoverlayafterthefact.”AndsincetheCERFsecretariatstillneedstoreviewalltheseparateproposals,itdoesnotsavetimeatthegloballeveleither.

Beyondthedelaysintheproposalprocess,incaseswheretheprimaryrecipientagencymovesslowlytocontractpartnersandbecomesabottleneckforsub-grants—afrequentoccurrence—monthshavebeenknowntoelapsebeforethemoneyhitsthegroundforthestartofprojectactivities.Giventhatgrantsaretypicallysmallinvolumeandofshortduration,thetimelinessinefficienciesofsuchinstancesareclear.ForonesuchallocationinMyanmar,afterdelaystheNGOadvancedotherfundstostarttheproject.Butsincemanyimplementerslacklargeadvancereserves,thisisoftennotpossible.ThiscomponentofthedelayisnotthefaultoftheCERFmechanism,butratherlieswithinternalagencyprocesses.

TheStartFundisthefinancingcomponentofa“collectivelyowned”networkofNGOs(41internationaland6national),whichwasspecificallydesignedtomovefundingfastertoenablearapidresponseontheground.Start’sownglobaldatareportsacall-to-disbursementtimeofthreedays.Thisboreoutinoursample(albeitofonlytwoStartcontributions),wherethedisbursementtimewastwodays.Significantly,however,theStartFundisalsoamuchsmallermechanismthantheCERFanditsgrantsarerelativelysmallsumsofmoneyforsmall-to-mediumemergenciesthatreceivelittleinternationaldonorattention.Whileitisgearedforrapidresponse,itisnotlookingtosupportmajorcoordinatedresponsesatscale,astheCERFis,andthereforecannotbemeasuredbythesameyardstick.Indeed,itsrelativeefficienciesmaybelargelydependentonitslimitedsizeandremit.

Sufficiency/transactioncosts

AlthoughtheCERFiswithinthepurviewoftheUN,theyareadmittedlyunaccustomedtotherelativelystringentearmarkingandaccountabilityrequirementsattachedtoCERFgrants.Particularlywhenthegrantamountswererelativelysmall(inourthree-countrysurveytheyaveraged$1.7million,butsomewereassmallas$300,000),recipientagenciesfoundthisasourceoffrustration.Indeed,manyCERFallocationsrepresentedafractionofwhattheagencyoriginallyproposedfortheactivities(10percentinthecaseofoneinstanceinMyanmar),andthebalancehadtobemadeupfromotherdonors,creatingmoreworkandtimedelays.

Inadditiontoaspeedydisbursementmechanism,theStartfundalsohadthelightestperceivedtransactionscostsandadministrativeburden(onafive-pointscalewith1beingthelightestand5

24

beingheaviest,itscoreda1,ascomparedwitha4fortheCERFanda3fortheCBPFs).Atthesametimeofcourse,itsdisbursementsarethesmallestonaverageofanyofthemechanismssampled,includingprivatecontributions(whichaveraged$157,000inoursample).

3.3.2Allocativeefficiency

Throughthe“underfunded”window,theCERFfillsgapsresultingfromthefragmentednatureofthebilateralgrantingsystem.However,thefactthatUNagenciesarethesoledirectrecipientsofitsallocationsmeansthattheCERFcancometobeusedasasafetynetandsharedresourceratherthanastrategicinput.InMyanmar,CERFfundrecipientsspokeofbeingaskedtoputinonlyacertainpercentageoftheirprojectrequirementssothatallappealingagenciescouldgetashare.

Subsidiarity

BecauseitonlyfundsUNagencies,theCERFcannotdirectlyfacilitategreatersubsidiarityefficiencywhenlocalNGOcapacitiesmakethispossible.AlthoughasizablepercentageoftheCERFallocationsendsupinthehandsoflocalNGOs,thereisnoevidencethatthisisanydifferentfromwhathappenswithbilateralgrantsthroughintermediaries.

AlthoughtheStartFundhasrecentlyaddedmorenationalNGOmembers,itisonlybeginningtothinkabouthowtomorestrategicallyapproachthequestionsoflocalizationandsubsidiarity.Arguablybymakingsmallgrantsdirectlytoimplementersontheground,itismakingsomesubsidiaritygains,butbecauseitisamembers-onlyproposition,thereisnowaytoensurethattherightactorattherightlevelcanhaveequalaccesstoitsresources.

Addedvalue

Coordinationasanaddedvalueisaprincipalobjectiveofpooledfundingandmostintervieweesdidallowthatthishasbeensomethingthatthesemechanismscanandhaveachieved,bybothincentivizingandhelpingtostructurecommonplanningprocesses.TheStartFundhasalsonotedthatitsabilitytoleveragefundingtocatalyzeresponsestootherwiseforgottencrisesisaconsiderableaddedvalueaswell.

3.4Country-basedpooledfunds

Donorsacknowledgethatevaluationsandanecdotalevidencestronglyindicatethatcountry-basedpooledfunds(CBPFs)areimprovingyearbyyearandbecomingreasonablyefficientandeffectivefundingmechanisms.Asbilateralgrantsledthesurgeinfundingoverthepastfewyears,however,pooledfundsarebecomingasmallerandsmallerpercentageofthetotalfundingpoolandarguablylessrelevantandlessabletoleveragecomparativeadvantageandaddvalueaspartofadiverse“fundingecosystem”(Stoddard,2017).

Unliketheglobalpooledfunds,theCBPFs’performanceistiedtothatofthecoordinatedhumanitarianstructuresineachcountrywheretheyoperate.PoorhumanitariancoordinationinacountrycanhinderCBPFs,butconversely,well-runandwellappliedCBPFcanhelptostrengthencoordinationstructuresbyincentivizingactorsandunderpinningastrategicplan.InEthiopia,the

25

qualitativeevidencesupportstheclaimthattheCBPFprovidesanefficiencybenefitatthestrategic,systemlevel.ThiswasnotthecaseinIraq,wheredifficultiesarerootedinbroadercoordinationfailure—clustersnotfunctioningwell,disagreementonapproach,andsevereproblemsinhumanresources.

3.4.1Technicalefficiency

Timeliness(speed/predictability)

TheCBPFshaveshownvariableperformanceintermsofrapidityoffunding,thoughtheytypicallyimproveovertime.Onaverage,pooledfundsaretwiceasquickasbilateralgrantsfromtheproposaltodecisionstage,thoughtimelinessefficienciescanbelostinthedisbursementphase.

EfficiencyisakeyprincipleelaboratedinthestandardizedCBPFguidance(aswellasinclusiveness,transparency,accountability,andtimeliness),andthestatedgoalistoenableatimelyandstrategicresponsetolocallyidentifiedneeds(UNOCHA,FundingCoordinationSection,2016)whileminimizingtransactioncostsandmaximizingtransparency.

TheCBPFinEthiopiainthepastpre-positionedsmallamountsoffunding(around$20,000)withagenciestoallowthemtorespondimmediatelytorapidcrisesbasedonaphonecalloremailapproval.Althoughintervieweesreportedthishadasubstantialimpactinthefirsthoursanddaysofacrisisforarelativelysmallamountofmoney,itwasdeterminedtobetoohighacorporateriskforOCHAtocontinue.

Asdiscussed,timelinessisnotjustafunctionofspeed;itis,moreimportantly,makingsurethatmoneyisavailableattherighttimes,whichinthecaseofEthiopiaareeasytopredict.Inmanycases,fundingcyclesfollowdonoradministrativeyears;however,thisimpactsdirectlyontheabilityoftheCBPF(knownastheEthiopiaHumanitarianFundorEHF)tomakeallocationsinsyncwiththeseasonalcalendar.TheEHFtypicallyreceivesalargevolumeofcontributionsinDecember,asdonorslooktoallocateunspentfunds.ThesefundsarerolledintotheEHF’sfollowingallocationyear,whereuponthesizeoftheEHF’sendofyearbalanceisquestionedbydonors.

TheMyanmarCBPF(orMHF)hashadarockyinceptionandbymanyaccountsisstillnotperformingoptimally,althoughitisreasonablywellfundedanddonorsgenerallysupportitsrole.Agencyintervieweescomplainedthatitisslowtodisburseandcumbersomeintermsofitsprocesses.ThemaincomplaintswerethatitisinflexibleandnotsufficientlyaccessibletolocalNGOs(anexamplecitedwasthatapplicationsmustbemadeonlineinEnglish—requiringbothreliableinternet,whichisoftennotthecaseinMyanmar,andlanguageskills).Mosttellingofitschallenges,theMHFtookbetweentwoandthreemonthstodisbursesomegrantsforthe2015floodresponse.

Sufficiency/transactioncosts

CBPFsgrantstendtobequiteabitsmaller,onaverage,thaneitherbilateralorglobalpooledfundgrants.Inpartthisisbydesignaccordingtotheirfundingobjectives(addressingsmaller,discretecrisesandfundingsmaller,localorganizationswhentheyarebestsuitedtorespond).But,as

26

previouslydescribed,thesmallerthegrant,thelargertherelativetransactioncosts,whichareallthesameintheCBPFsystemnomattertheamountofthegrant.Infact,inMyanmarseveralintervieweesreferredtotheMHFastheheaviestofanyfundingtheygetintermsofadministrativeburden.(Forthisreason,somediscussionhasoccurredinOCHAonsettingaminimumgrantsize.)ItisnonethelessafundingsourcewhichNGOscontinuetoapplyto,oftenknowingthattheprocesswillbepainful.

ThefinancingsysteminEthiopiaisexcessivelycomplexgiventherelativelypredictablenatureofneedsandtheestablishedpresenceofhumanitarianactors,responsemechanisms,coordination,andprioritizationprocesses.Bilateraldonorstendtocreatenewmechanismsaswork-aroundstobureaucraticimpediments,whichmayshortendisbursementtimeswhileaddingtotransactioncosts,andmanyrespondingactorscomplainedofhighlyfragmentedportfoliosandhightransactioncostsassociatedwithnavigatingcomplexnetworksoftransactions,relationships,andinstruments.

3.4.2Allocativeefficiency

Flexibility

Accordingtointerviewees,theproceduresandgrantmanagementmechanismsfortheCBPFswerenotparticularlyflexiblewhenitcametomidstreammodifications(inthatformalchangesmustbemadetotheonlinesystem),buttheywerenonethelessabletobechangedwhenneeded.

Amoreextensivenotionofflexibilityefficiency,however,hastodowithusingafundingmechanismtorespondtochangingneedsasandwheretheyoccurwithoutbeinghamstrungbybureaucraticorproceduralconstraints.TheCBPFsaretypicallytootightlycircumscribedintheirroletoactnimblyandflexibly,despitetheiraspirations.However,theycanfillgaps,forinstancebyprovidingfundingforneglectedemergencies(suchassmall-scalenaturaldisasters)withinlargercrisiscontexts.

Subsidiarity

TheCBPFsstartedtopreferentiallyfundNGOs,andparticularlynationalNGOswhenpossibleandefficient/effectivetodoso.BecausesomedonorsinMyanmarmustgothroughtheMHFtofundlocalactorsbecausetheregulationswon’tallowthemtoprovidedirectfunding,onecouldarguethatsubsidiarityispromotedbytheexistenceoftheCBPFfromwhichnationalorganizationscanapplyforandwintheirowngrantsasopposedtoworkinginpartnershiparrangementswithinternationalactors.Itmaybesubsidiarity“onceremoved”butitisstillawaytoreducethenumberoflinksinthechainwhenthisisdesirable.

TheIraqHumanitarianFund(IHF)highlightedthechallengesofearmarkingfornationalNGOswithinpooledfunds.InlinewithdonorcommitmentstolocalizationintheGrandBargain,donorshavepressuredtheIHFtoopenaspecialwindowfornationalNGOs.Thisrunscontrarytothegloballevelunderstandingthatcontributionstopooledfundsmaynotbeearmarked.Asaresult,thesecontributionshavebeenthesubjectoflengthynegotiationswithOCHAandinefficientonthesupplysideoftheIHF.

27

OnenationalactorinIraqnotedthatcontributionsfromthepooledfunddidnotmeettheirowndefinitionofefficiency;i.e.,fundswereofshortduration,hadhighreportingcosts,andallowedforonlyminimalsupport(overhead)costs.Moreover,thefundingdeliveredbytheIHFwasnotaccompaniedbyasustainedrelationship,withcapacitybuildingaroundfinancialmanagementandreporting,thatthepartneracknowledgedtheyneeded

Addedvalue

AninternalOCHAreportontheCBPFspresentsthreebroadwaysinwhichtheycanaddvalue:

1. CBPFscanprovidefundingtolocalNGOsthatmanydonorsareunabletododirectly.2. CBPFssupportmulti-yearplanning.3. CBPFsfundingcanbe“strategicallyandtimelyallocatedinawaythatpromotesahigh

degreeofcoordination,quality,accountabilityandtransparency”(UNOCHA,2016).

Intermsofthethirdpoint,notallactorsexpressappreciationfortheuseoffundingmechanismsasleverageforparticularstrategicorcoordinationends.Agencieshavecomplainedofdonorscolludingwiththemanagersofthepooledfundstoincentivizeactorstochangetackandworkinareasthattheydeemunderserved—perceivedasgainsayingtheagencies’judgementonwhereandhowtoprogram.

3.5Consortiaandframeworkagreements

Intermsofspeedandlimitedtransactioncosts,bilaterallyfundedinstrumentsinvolvingprearrangedpartnerscanbequitetechnicallyefficient.Largebilateraldonorscanestablishtheseentitieseitheratthecountrylevelorglobally.AnexampleisDFID’sRapidResponseFacility,whereagroupofUK-basedNGOsareonstandbyagreementstoproviderapidresponsetosudden-onsetdisasters.Whentheyworkwell,theseconsortiaandframeworkagreementsareconsideredthesecondorthirdfastestwaytomobilizemoney(afterinternalreservesandtheStartFund).Mostdonorsandorganizationsinvolvedinsuchbodiesaregenerallyhappywiththearrangements,althoughtheresearchersdidheartheoccasionalobservationfromNGOrepresentativesthattheydon’talwaysdecreasetransactioncosts,duetotheamountofinternaldiscussionrequired.Insomecases,includingaframeworkagreementinMyanmar,forNGOstheyaresimply“amarriageofconvenience”andawayfordonorstoshifttheadministrativeandmanagementburdendowntheline.

Atthegloballevel,passingfundsfromaffiliateofficestooperationalINGOentitiesatthecountrylevelisacommonpractice,andonenotoftendiscussed.SavetheChildrenSwedenforexample,willcontractfundsfromSidaandpasstheseontoSavetheChildrenInternationalinEthiopiatocarryoutchildprotectionprogramming.Theaffiliatethatreceivesthegrantfromitshomedonorwillchargeapass-throughfee,insomecasesaddingabudget-lineforits“addedvalue”activities.Theefficiencyofthesepracticesisrarelyquestionedbydonorsorimplementingorganizations,despitethecleartransactioncoststhatcouldhavebeenavoidedhadthedonorfundedtheimplementingaffiliatedirectly.

28

Mostdonorsseeconsortiaasameansforreducingtheirmanagementoverhead,andsothetrendistowardsmanagingfewergrants.ButthismilitatesagainstprovidingmoredirectfundingforlocalNGOs—howthetensionbetweenthesetwoobjectiveswillbemanagedisunclear.NeitherishowgrantapplicationswillbemademoreaccessibletolocalNGOswhilemaintainingcurrentstandardsofduediligence.Donorsmanagingtoomanygrantsexperiencebottleneckswhichslowdowngrants.

InMyanmar,theHumanitarianandResilienceProgramme(HARP)isauniqueframeworkfundinginstrumentdesignedbyDFIDtofunnelallitsgrantsinthecountry(exceptthosethatgothroughthepooledfunds)intoasinglecontractmanagedbyCrownAgentsandcombiningbothhumanitarianandresilienceprogramming.TwonotablenoveltiesareHARP’sabilitytofundlocalNGOsdirectlyandonamulti-yearbasis.Thisdecisionwasreportedlydrivenbyefficiencyconcerns,inacontextwheretheneedsarediverseandfarflung,requiringmanydifferentpartnersformanydifferenttypesofwork,withthevarietyofaccesschallenges.

3.6 Corefundingandinternalinstruments

Someofthemostresponsiveandcost-efficientfinancinginstrumentsarefoundintheinternalfinancinginfrastructureoflargehumanitarianorganizationsandassuchareoftennotvisiblewithinofficiallyreportedfinancingdata.

ThemajorUNhumanitarianagencies,andsomeofthelargestINGOs,maintaineitherinternalcashreservesorinternalemergencyfunds,whichcanadvancefundingforactivitiesuntiladonorgrantcomesonline.InEthiopia,forexample,WorldVisionInternationalreceivedaround42percentofitsfundingin2016fromprivatesources,whichitusesacrossavarietyofinstrumentsdesignedtosupportmoreefficientandtimelyresponse.WorldVisionallows20percentofitsprivatefundstobelinkedtoacrisismodifier,whichcanthenberedeployedonthedecisionofnationalleadershipwithouthavingtoseekpermissionuptheline.Inaddition,ithasaninternaldraw-downmechanismandcanputaside5percentofprivatefundseachyearasareserveforpreparednessandresponseactivities.

WFPusestheworkingcapitalitholdsatthegloballeveltoovercomethedelaysandcash-flowproblemsofbilateraldonorfundingandenableittorespond,procure,transport,andprepositionfoodandscaleupresponsesasneedsoccurratherthanwhenafundingcontractissigned.ThisadvancefundingisabigcontributortoeconomiesofscaleinthatmuchofthefoodclusterresponsedependsonWFPtosetupthelogisticscapacityforallpartners(andemergencytelecomsservicesforthewiderhumanitariancommunity).

IFRCoperatesitsownDisasterReliefEmergencyFund(DREF)toprovidequickresourcestotheitsNationalSocietiesintheeventofemergency.Similarly,UNICEFinMyanmarreceivesroughlyathirdofitsfundingfromprivatesourcesthroughitsnationalcommittees,whichcanbeinvaluableforemergencyadvancefunding.

UNHCRreceivesdonorcontributionsinthreedifferentloci:country-levelfunds,regionalfunds(e.g.,theAfricabureau),orun-earmarkedcorefunding.Thiscorefundingisrecycledthroughthe

29

yearandisdirectedfromthegloballeveltowhereitisneeded.Insomecases,itisdirectedtotheprotectionandnormativeworkthatispartoftheorganization’sofficialmandatebutwhichhasbeendifficulttogetdonorstofund.UNHCRhasimprovedpredictabilityforcountryofficesthroughasystemofguaranteedminimumoperatingbudgetssothatcountry-levelresourcescanbemaintainedandcushionedfromfluctuationsindonorcontributionstospecificcrises.

Newtoolstoharnesssocialimpactinvestingarestartingtobeusedbyhumanitarianorganizationsinwaysthatboostcorefundingforemergencies.Forexample,UNICEF’sUSAchapterhasaBridgeFundthatleveragespermanentgrantstoattractprivateinvestments,andisusedasarotatinglendingtooltobridgethegapbetweenemergencyonsetandreceiptofgrantfundingforresponse.

Onanindividualagencylevelthisisthefastest,mostefficientwayoffinancingrapidresponse,butitislimitedinvolumeanddurationofleadtimeandisbeyondthescopeofmosthumanitarianactors,henceun-scalable.Becausetheseorganizationsdonotfunctiononabusinesscycleofreinvestmentandgrowth,butratheronlimitedcostrecovery,establishingthistypeofresourceisoutofreachwithoutsomesignificantinfusionofflexiblecorefundingfromeitherpublicorprivatesources.

30

4. Otherissues:Multiyeartimeframesandearmarking

4.1Multiyearfunding

Thesubjectofmulti-yearfundingandhowitmayaffectefficiencyisrelevanttoallthecurrentfundingmodalities,sinceintheoryallofthemcouldbeadaptedtolongertimeframes.Bothhumanitariananddevelopmentactorshaveexpressedgrowingrecognitionthatinchroniccrisissettings,repeatedlarge-scalehumanitarianresponsestopredictabledisastersareprofoundlyinefficient.Asaresult,donorsarenowexperimentingwithextendingthehumanitarianfundingandprogrammingcyclesbeyondthestandard12-monthgrant.BothMyanmarandEthiopiaareexamplesofhow“resilience”programmingisgaininggroundincontextspreviouslylimitedtotraditionalhumanitarianprogramming.

Ethiopiahasservedasalaboratoryforresilienceprogramminginthewakeofthe2011HornofAfricafoodsecuritycrisis.Here,resilienceprogrammingfollowedthelogicofaddressingunderlyingvulnerabilitiesinordertograduatefromthecycleofcrisisandresponsetopredictableriskandmitigation.ThenewHARPfundingframework,initiatedbyDFIDinMyanmar,aimsatsimilarobjectives,intendingtogainbothtechnicalefficienciesandbroaderstrategicefficienciesforaddressingthecountry’sneeds.

Theexistenceofmultiyearfunding(oratleast“predictablefundingformultiyearprograms”—donorsarenotabletoallocatemorethanoneyear’sworthoffundinginadvance)couldhaveclearbenefitstofundingefficiencyinbothtechnicalandallocativeaspects.

4.2Earmarking

Theissueof“earmarking”contributions,thatisdonorsdirectingwhereandhowhumanitarianfundingshouldbespent(typicallyonaprojectbasis),hasbeenthesubjectofcontentionforaslongasthemodernhumanitariansystemhasexisted.NGOslargelyacceptitasthenormwhendealingwithdonorgovernments.ThoseNGOsluckyenoughtohavefullyormostlyflexible(un-earmarked)resourceshaveachievedthisbygeneratinglargeprivatesumsfromprivateandindividualdonations.UNagencies,ontheotherhand,seeearmarkingasabanetoefficiencyandstrategiceffectivenessinundertakingtheirmandates.UNagencyandICRC/IFRCrepresentativesinterviewedforthisstudywereunanimousintheirassertionthatfundingefficiencyissynonymouswithflexibility,andearmarkingistheantithesisofit.Theyalsounanimouslyexpressedconcernthatearmarkinghasgrowntighterinrecentyearswhiletheproportionoftheirfundingthatisun-earmarkedhasdeclined.

TheGrandBargainhastakenupthisissuewith“aninitialtargetfordonorstoremoveearmarksfor30percentoftheirfundsprovidedtohumanitarianagenciesby2020”(HighLevelPanelonHumanitarianFinancing,2016).ItisdifficulttoforeseehowdonorswillapproachthistargetinpracticeandwhethertheirreciprocaldemandsforgreatertransparencyfromtheagencieswillultimatelyamounttoanygreaterflexibilityornetefficienciesSomeagencyrepresentativeshaveaccuseddonorsofbeingdisingenuousonthisscore,sayingtheunderlyingproblemisreallyaboutthedonors’“distrust”oftheirimplementingpartners.

31

5. Conclusionsandsuggestedguidanceforconsideringefficiencyinfundingdecisions

Thefollowingsummarizesthemaintakeawaysfromourfindingsonefficiencyinhumanitarianfunding.Thestudywasnottaskedtoproduceexplicitpolicyrecommendations,butwhereconclusionsfromthefindingslogicallysuggestpotentialactionsforimprovement,wenotethemhere.Inaddition,thissectioncontainsasetofguidingprinciplesforconsideringefficiencyalongsidetheotherfactorsindecisionmakingaroundhumanitarianfunding,andaproposalformorefarreachingstrategiccoordinationamongdonors.

5.1Areasforaction

Asshownintheprecedingpages,thedifferentfundingmodalitiespromotedifferenttypesofefficiencyaccordingtotheirobjectives.Thissupportstheargumentformaintainingadiversityofinstrumentstoemployfordifferentpurposesandthenotionoftheutilityofafinancingecosystem,asopposedtoasinglefavoredchannel.However,eachmodalityhasmuchroomforimprovement,andsomerebalancingbetweenthemwouldimproveefficiencyforhumanitarianresponseoverall.

Tobeginwithwhatneedsimproving,eachfundinginstrumentwasalsofoundtoincurcertaininefficiencies.Itisimportantheretoseparateinefficienciesthatareunavoidablebydesign—thatis,theinevitabletrade-offofonetypeofefficiencyinthepursuitofothergoals—andthosethatareduetopoorexecutionormanagementorareneedlessbureaucraticartifactsthatcanbeeliminated.

Theprimarymodesoffundingarestillinefficientforrapidresponsepurposes.

Themostefficientmechanismsformovingmoneyquicklytoenablerapidresponsearealsotheleastusedinthehumanitariansystem,asaproportionoftotalfunding.Theseare(1)pre-arrangedagreements,includingmulti-yearagreements,betweendonorsandagencypartnersatthecountryleveland(2)theemergencyreservesofoperationalorganizationsestablishedandmaintainedthroughcorefunding.

TheCERFhasaprovenmethodologyforrapidlyapprovingprojectproposalsandreleasinginitialdisbursements,butthisefficiencyishinderedbydelaysonthefrontend,whentheprocesstoprioritizefundsisprolongedanddelaysdisbursements,andontheback-endwhenagenciesareslowtocontractanddisbursetopartnersfortheactualimplementationofactivities.Asaglobalrapidresponsemechanism,themuchsmallerStartFundhasworkedbetterintermsofspeedefficiency,butislimitedinscopeofcountriesandisfocusedonsmalleremergencies—whetheritcanscaletothelevelnecessarytomeetneedsinalargecrisisisnotclear.ThespeedoftheCBPFsvaryfromonecountrytothenext,butinthesamplelookedatforthisstudy,weresimilarlydisappointingintermsofdayselapsedbetweeninitialproposalandfinaldisbursement.

Slowestofallisthetraditional(andpredominant)bilateralgrantmodality,whichinoursampletookanaverageof65daystogetfromtheproposalsubmissiontothestartofprojectactivities.Asaresult,itcanonlysupportrapidresponseiftherecipientagencyhasboththecapacitytoadvance

32

fundingfortheinitialoutlaysandahighdegreeofconfidencethatthedonorwillfollowthroughonstatedintentions.

Technicalefficiencycanbeimprovedacrossallmodalitiesforbetterrapidresponsefunding:

Ø Insuddenonsetorrapidlyevolvinghumanitariancrisesfundedthroughtherapidresponsewindow,CERFproposalvettingandallocationdecisionsshouldnotwaitforaconsolidatedsubmissionofproposals.ThestrengthoftheproposalandtheadviceoftheHumanitarianCoordinatorshouldsufficetoindicateiftheproposedinterventionrepresentsanecessaryandappropriateresponsetocurrentconditions.Thiswillalsohelpworkagainsttheperverseincentivestogiveeachagencyits“fairshare.”However,thebiggesttimelinessgaincanonlycomethroughinternalagencyreformsthatpreventlongdelaysbetweendisbursementandonwardgranting.Agenciesidentifiedashavingproblemsinthisregardhavearesponsibilitytoundertakeathoroughoperationalreview(asUNICEFandUNFPAarecurrentlydoing)andenactsystemimprovementstoaddressthem.

Ø CBPFscouldimprovetheirtechnicalefficiencybymakingaggressiveeffortstomaketheprocessaslightand“userfriendly”aspossible,and/orbyhavingminimumgrantthresholdssothattheawardisworththetransactioncosts.

Ø Intheirbilateralgranting,donorsshouldincreasethe“pre-positioning”ofadvancefundswithindividualagenciesand/ormultiagencyconsortiacapableofputtingthemoneytoworkimmediatelyintheeventoftherapidonsetcrisis.Ascapacityinvestmentsinwell-placedorganizations,donorscouldconsiderincreasingboththeamountsofprepositionedadvancefundsandcorefunding.

Ø Increasingthepracticeofmulti-yearfunding,withbuilt-inmodifiersystemstoallowpartnerstoadapttochangingcircumstanceswithoutundergoingtime-consumingformalmodifications,couldsimilarlybolsterflexibilityandspeed.

Disproportionaterequirementsandinflexibilityhinderefficiencyatalllevels.

Asevidencedinthisstudyaswellasotherrecentresearch,thesmallestandshortest-durationgrantstendtohavethehighesttransactioncostsintermsoftherelativeamountofadministrativeworkrequired,andconsequentlythesmallestNGOstypicallybearthegreatestadministrativeburdenfortheleastreward.Evenlargeorganizations,whiletheyhaveacceptedandadaptedtotherequirementsoftheirdonors,saidthatformanytheburdenofreportingandcompliancewasexcessive,disproportionatetotheactualrisks(andinfactnotaneffectivemeansofreducingfiduciaryrisk),andhadnegativeimpactsontheirabilitytocarryouttherealbusinessofhumanitarianresponse.

Inordinatelyhightransactioncostsonsmall-sizedgrantsisinefficientfordonorandgranteesalike,asostensiblyeveryadditionalpieceofreportingorextraworkneededforcontractmodificationrequiredoftheagencyinturnmustbeprocessedbythedonor.Thepreliminaryproposalsforharmonizedreportingareastepintherightdirection,butamorerationalapproachwillalsorequiredonors(includingbothdonorgovernmentsandagenciesthataresub-grantingtoimplementingpartners)toreevaluatetheirgrantingproceduresalongthefollowinglines:

33

Ø Reportingrequirements,bothprogressandfinancial,shouldbemadecommensuratewithtimelinesandoverallsizeofgrants,ratherthanbeingappliedthroughaone-size-fits-alltemplate.Inaddition,onceanorganizationhasbeenthroughinitialcompetencyvetting,itshouldnotbemadetofacesimilarhurdlesinsubsequentprojectcontracts(orindifferentlocations).

Ø Proceduresregardingmodificationstoprojectsshouldbeestablishedwithaneyetoallowingmaximumflexibilitywhilemaintainingappropriateaccountabilitycontrols.Thiscouldincludebroaderbudgetcategoriesandexplicitpermissiontomovebetweenlineswithoutrequiringamidstreammodificationifitdoesnotsubstantiallyalteranyoftheprojectobjectives.

Theaddedvalueoftheintermediaryroleinmulti-linkgrantsisinconsistentandoftencreatesnetinefficiencies.

Insomecases,economiesofscalecanbecreatedthroughmulti-linkgrants,andaneffectiveintermediarycanaddvalueintermsoftechnicalassistanceandcoordination.Inothercases,however,theallocativeefficienciesgainedbyintermediariescanbeeasilyoutstrippedbytechnicalinefficienciessuchasdelaysrelatedtoonwardcontracting.Toguardagainstthis,anagency’spotentialeffectivenessinthisroleandforagivensetofcircumstancesshouldthereforebedemonstratedandnotassumed:

Ø Abusinesscaseforvalueaddedbyanintermediaryagencyshouldberequiredintheirproposals,whichanswersnotonlythequestionofwhyfundingthroughanintermediaryisnecessaryorpreferabletodirectfundingofimplementersintheparticularsituation,butalsohowthisagency,asopposedtoanother,isbestsituatedtoplaytheintermediaryrole.Partofthecaseforpotentialvalueaddedbytheprospectiveintermediaryagencymustincludeprovenefficiencyinfunding,contracting,andflexiblemanagementofgrants.

Allocativeefficiencyandthestatedgoalsoflocalizationareimpededbyriskperceptionandcapacityconstraintsonthepartofdonorgovernments.

Currentlocalizationeffortsappeartoaimatincreasingend-chainfundingtolocalactors,notmeaningfullyincreasingtheirdirectaccesstointernationalresources.Theoverwhelmingmajorityofhumanitariancontributionsgoesthroughbilateralgovernmentgrants,whichrarelyaccruedirectlytolocalorganizations.Therefore,forlocalizationgoalstobemet,oneoftwothingsneedstohappen:(1)Donorgovernmentsfindwaystobegingrantingdirectlytolocalactorsfarmorethantheycurrentlydo(whichinmostcasesisnotatall)or(2)thecountry-basedpooledfundsincreaseinsizetoallowforastepupinthenumbersandsizesofgrantsprovidedtolocalactors.

Donorgovernments,foravarietyofdomesticpoliticalandregulatoryreasons,havenotbeenwillingtodirectlyfundlocalactors,asitrepresentstoogreataperceivedrisk.Signsthatthismaybechangingcanbefound,buttheyarevanishinglyfewandfarbetween.Inaddition,somemajordonorssimplydonothavethecapacityonthegroundtomanagemorethanasmallnumberofgrants,meaningtheymustdisbursemoneyinallotmentstoolargeforasmallorganizationto

34

absorbandputtouse.Inthemeantime,whileinsomecasesfundingalocalorganizationdirectlymightbemoreefficient,itwillnotbedone.Inotherwords,caseswillremainwheretheprincipleofsubsidiaritycannotberealizedandwheretheinefficienciesofmulti-linkfundingchainsareunavoidable:

Ø Totheextentpossible,donors(includingdonorsofpooledfunds)shouldconsidersubsidiarityindeterminingatwhatleveltomakegrants.Unlesstheallocativeefficienciesandaddedvalueofhavinganintermediarycanbedemonstrated,directfundingshouldbepreferred.

Ø Targetedcapacityinvestmentsinlocalorganizations(corefundinggrants)canbolsterandenhancetherangeofoptionsavailablefordonorsseekingtomaximizeefficiencyaswellaseffectiveness.

Ø CBPFs,wheretheyarefunctioningwellandallocatingdirectlytolocalNGOs,shouldbeconsideredasatoolforpromotingsubsidiarityefficiencybydonorsthatremainunabletofundtheseorganizationsdirectly.Iftheirrapidresponseperformanceandadministrativeprocedurescancontinuetoimprove,theCBPFsmayultimatelybethekeytoreconcilingthetensionbetweendonors’supportforlocalizationontheonehandandtheinefficiency(andperceivedrisk)ofprovidingnumeroussmallgrantstolocalentitiesontheother.

5.2Guidingprinciplesfordonordecision-makingregardingefficiency

Toreiterate,whenmakinghumanitarianfundingdecisions,theefficiencycriterionisclearlysupersededbyotherconsiderations,aboveallbeinghowthefundingwillbestenableaneffectiveresponsetopeople’sneeds.Butdonorsmustbecognizantthatefficiencyfactorsintoeffectiveness,andthatcumulativeinefficienciescandetractfromdesiredoutcomes.

Whendecidinghowtoallocatetheirannualenvelopes,donorsneedtoemploydifferentmodalitiestoachieveareasonablebalanceofpredictabilityandresponsiveness,andallocativeefficiencybothatthecountryandgloballevels,whileretainingcontingencyfundingatthegloballevelincaseofunforeseenneeds.Ontopofthat,theyneedtomanagetheirownpolicycommitments,accountabilityrequirements,andcapacityconstraints.Eachinstrumenthasamixofcomparativeadvantagesthatrespondtoelementsofthesedifferentpriorities.Currently,donorsadmitthatknowingiftheyhavethebalancerightisverydifficult.TheissueismorecomplexthantheGrandBargaincommitmentswouldappeartosuggest,becauseeachdecisionentailsopportunitycosts.Forexample,dedicatinglargeamountstomulti-yearfundingagreementsprovidesincreasedpredictabilitybutreducedflexibilityifcircumstanceschange.

Maintainthewidestpossiblerangeofoptionsandtoolstoemployfordifferentneeds.

Donorsshouldseektoexpandtheirrangeofoptionsbeyondoneortwoinstrumentsforfunding,knowthatdifferentsituationswillbemoreamendabletodifferentinstrumentsorcombinationsofinstruments.Ablanketrejectionofpooledfunding(orconversely,aninabilitytomakedirectgrantstoimplementers),forexample,reducesthescopeforeffectivenessindonorship.

35

Tothisend,donorsshouldundergoaninternaloftheircapacitytosupportefficientfinancing.Thiscouldbeassimpleasaquestionnairecontainingthefollowing:

• Whatproportionofourfundingisspentinprotractedcrises?

• Howoftendowemodifyandextendgrants?

• Areweabletoworkflexiblyacrosshumanitariananddevelopmentfundingstreams?

• Howwellsetuparetheytorespondtorapidresponse?

• Dowehaveagoodrangeofglobalandnationalresponsivemechanisms(Includingsupporttointernalfundingfacilitiesandinstruments)?

• Whatadditionalevidencedoweneedfromgranteestoimprovefuturedecision-making?

Theanswerstotheabovemayprovideausefulsteerfordonorsseekingtomaximizetheefficiencyandeffectivenessoftheircontributions.Forexample,ifalargepercentagegoestoprotractedconflictswhereno-costextensionsarecontinuallyrequired,thismaybeanefficiencyargumentforashifttomoremulti-yearfunding.

Startingfromthespecificsofthecontextandhumanitarianneeds,matchgoalswiththefundinginstrumentsbestsuitedtoefficientlyservicethem.

Iftheneedisforrapidresponse(asmaybepredictableincountrieswithfluidconflictconditionsorfrequentsudden-onsetemergencies),applyingforbilateralgrantswillbelessefficientthanworkingthroughpre-arrangedframeworkagreementsorapplyingforpooledfundsthathaveprovenspeedydisbursementtimes.

Large-scale,chronicemergenciescausingsimilarneedsamonglargesegmentsofthepopulationcouldbemoreefficientlyfundedthroughlargeumbrellagrantstocompetentcoordinatingagenciesthataddtechnicalvalueandprovideeconomiesofscalewithlogisticalandprocurementinfrastructures.

Specificgapsandunderfundedneedscanbeaddressedwitheitherflexiblebilateralgrantingorearliercontributionstopooledfundwindowsdesignedforthatpurpose,orboth.

Smallpocketsofneedandhighlylocation-specificneedsinindividualareaswilloftenbemoreefficientlyfundedbyeliminatingtheintermediaryandfundinglocallybasedorganizationsdirectly.

Finally,manycountrycontextswillatdifferenttimesorsimultaneouslyexperienceallfourofthescenariosdescribedabove.Thebalanceofdifferentfundingneedsandobjectivesshouldbereflectedwithinorbetweendonorportfoliostotheextentpossible.

Determineandconsiderotherdonors’plansasfactorsinefficiencydecisions.

Finally,becauseinmostmajorhumanitariancrises,nodonorcansinglehandedlyprovidethefullcomplementofresourcesneededtomeetneeds,ideallyfundingdecisionswillbemadeinconcert

36

withotherdonors.Attheleast,theywillnotbemadeinisolation.Donorchoicebetweenfundingmechanismsshouldbeusedtohelpbalancetheneedsofbothtechnicalandallocativeefficiencyinlightofwhatcounterpartsaredoing,withinthelargerpictureofstrategicpriorities.

Strategiccoordinationoffundingdecisionsbetweendonorsissomethingthatgoesontovaryingdegrees,butinanadhocandinconsistentway.Buildingthisstepintoaframeworkforefficiencycalculationcouldpotentiallybringaboutmorerobustcoordinationandrigorousdecisionmaking,creatingavirtuouscircle.

5.3Enhancingefficiencythroughamorecoordinated,evidence-basedapproach

Theaboveareasforactionpre-supposethecurrentlevelofdonorcoordination.Whatfollowsisaproposalforconsiderationofadditionalcommontoolsthatwouldhelpstrengthenamorestrategicallycoordinatedapproachtofundingdecisions.

Agreeonacommonsetofmetricsforassessingefficiency

Donorsrequirebetterevidenceonwhichtomakedecisionsaboutwhoandhowtheyfund.Efficiencywouldonlybeoneconsiderationinthesedecisions,butanimportantone.Todothatwouldrequiregreatertransparency(opendata)onbudgetsandtransactiontimesofthedifferentchannels,includingumbrellagranteesaswellaspooledfundmechanisms.

ThemembersoftheGoodHumanitarianDonorshipinitiativeshouldthereforeconsidercommissioninganeutralentity,e.g.anauditingbody,todevelopanefficiencyframeworkwithexplicitstandardsthatcouldcomparetheefficienciesandvalueaddedofdifferenttypesofpooledfundsandpotentialintermediaries.Thiswouldhavethebenefitofincentivizingallactorstoimprovetheareasofweaknessthatarecurrentlycausingunnecessaryinefficienciesand,intheprocess,wouldfacilitatethefulfillmentoftheGrandBargaincommitments.

37

References

Bailey,S.,&Harvey,P.(2017)."TimeforChange:HarnessingthePotentialofHumanitarianCash

Transfers."ODI.Bayat-Renoux,F.,&Glemarec,Y.(2014)."FinancingRecoveryforResilience."UNDP.Beck,T.(2006)."EvaluatingHumanitarianActionUsingtheDACCriteria."London:ALNAP.Bruned,J.M.(2016)."TheGrandBargain:ASharedCommitmenttoBetterServePeopleinNeed."

IASC.Buchanan-Smith,M.,Cosgrave,J.,&Warner,A.(2016)."EvaluatingHumanitarianActionGuide."

London:ALNAP.Caccavale,J.,Haver,K.,&Stoddard,A.(2016)."DonorReportingRequirementsResearch."

HumanitarianOutcomes.CERF.(2014)."AnalysisofDatafrom2013RC/HCReports—ValueAdded."UnitedNationsOfficefor

theCoordinationofHumanitarianAffairs.CERF.(2016)(a)."BriefingNoteonCERFandtheGrandBargain."UnitedNationsOfficeforthe

CoordinationofHumanitarianAffairs.CERF.(2016)(b)."PartnershipsinHumanitarianAction."UnitedNationsOfficefortheCoordination

ofHumanitarianAffairs.CERF.(n.d.)."AnalysisofLessonsLearnedfrom2013RC/HCReportsontheUseofCERFFunds."

UnitedNationsOfficefortheCoordinationofHumanitarianAffairs.Cheung,S.N.(1987)."EconomicOrganizationandTransactionCosts."InTheNewPalgrave:A

DictionaryofEconomics,v.2editedbyJohnEatwell,MurrayMilgate,andPeterNewman,(pp.55–58).London,NewYork,Tokyo:MacmillanStocktonPressMaruzen.

AhmedandCordell.(2015)."AComparisonReviewofUNProjectPartnershipAgreementsfromNGOImplementationofHumanitarianProjects."InternationalCouncilofVoluntaryAgencies.

DeBettignies,J.-E.,&Ross,T.W.(2004)."TheEconomicsofPublic-PrivatePartnerships."CanadianPublicPolicy30(2).

DGECHO.(2013)."CashandVouchers:IncreasingEfficiencyandEffectivenessacrossAllSectors."EuropeanCommission.

ECHO.(n.d.)."Howmuchfundingreachesthebeneficiary?MethodologyOutline."ICAI.(2017)."TheEffectsofDFID’sCashTransferProgrammesonPovertyandVulnerability."

IndependentCommissionforAidImpact.(2015)."IndependentFinancialReviewoftheUNAgenciesResponsetoProtractedCrises."OCHA.(2017)."EthiopiaLessonsLearnedfromtheElNinoDrought,2015–16.OCHASTAITMission

RetreatOutcomes."UnitedNationsOfficefortheCoordinationofHumanitarianAffairs.OECD.(2012)."TowardsBetterHumanitarianDonorship:12LessonsfromDACPeerReviews."

OrganisationforEconomicCo-operationandDevelopment.Palenberg,M.A.(2011)."ToolsandMethodsforEvaluatingtheEfficiencyofDevelopment

Interventions."Berlin:BMZEvaluationDivision,GermanFederalMinistryforEconomicCooperationandDevelopment.

Pallage,S.,Robe,M.A.,&Bérubé,C.(2006)."OnthePotentialofForeignAidasInsurance."IMFStaffPapers53(3),453–475.

PandemicFinancingStakeholdersMeetingWorldBankGroup.(2015).PandemicEmergencyFinancingFacility.

PaulinaOdame,D.S.(2015)."UnderstandingHumanitarianNeedFromaFinancingPerspective:TheDriversofCost."OCHA.

Poole,L.(n.d.)."Financingfor21stCenturyRisk."

38

Roselli,C.,Fabbri,P.,&CollingwoodEsland,P.(2016)."LessPaperMoreAid."ICVA.Schenkenberg,E.(2016)."TheChallengesofLocalisedHumanitarianAidinArmedConflict."MSF.Stoddard,A.(2017)."InternationalHumanitarianFinancing:ReviewandComparativeAssessment

ofInstruments,UpdatedEdition."HumanitarianOutcomes.Stoddard,A.,&Willitts-King,B.(2014)."Activity-BasedCostingforHumanitarianAppeals."IASC

HumanitarianProgrammeCycleSteeringGroup.Sutton,K.,Wynn-Pope,P.,&Holden,C.(2012)."HumanitarianFinancinginAustralia:Scoping

ReportonComparativeMechanisms."HumanitarianPartnershipAgreement.Thomas,M.(2017)."PooledFunds:MappingandIdentifyingLessons."UNHCR.(2016)."UNHCR’sUseofUnearmarkedFundingin2015."OfficeoftheUnitedNationsHigh

CommissionerforRefugees.UNHLPHF.(2016)."TooImportanttoFail:AddressingtheHumanitarianFinancingGap."High

LevelPanelonHumanitarianFinancing.UNDP.(2016)."TheRoleofUNPooledFinancingMechanismstoDeliverthe2030Sustainable

DevelopmentAgenda."UnitedNationsDevelopmentGroup.UNOCHA,FundingCoordinationSection.(2016)."Country-BasedPooledFunds:ANimbleFunding

MechanismtoBoostFrontlineResponse."NewYork:UnitedNationsOfficefortheCoordinationofHumanitarianAffairs.

WFP.(2014)."EarmarkingofDirectedMultilateralContributionstoWFPin2013."WorldFoodProgramme

Willitts-King,B.(2015)."StudyontheAddedValueofaReformedCentralEmergencyResponseFund."UNOfficefortheCoordinationofHumanitarianAffairs.

Yussuf,M.,Larrabure,J.L.,&Terzi,C.(2007).VoluntaryContributionsinUnitedNationsSystemOrganisations:ImpactonProgrammeDeliveryandResourceMobilizationStrategies."Geneva.

39

Annex1:Listofpeopleinterviewed

GlobalHelen Alderson DirectorofFinancialResourcesandLogistics ICRC

Marc Cohen SeniorResearcher Oxfam/CfC

Paul Currion IndependentConsultant Independent

Andrea DeDomenico Chief,FundingCoordinationSection(FCS) OCHA

Lisa Doughten Chief,CERFSecretariat OCHA

Jessica Eliasson HumanitarianPolicySpecialist Sida

Michael Jensen Chiefofsection OCHACERFSecretariat

Chris Kaye DirectorofGovernmentPartnerships WFP

Christopher Lockyear DirectorofOperations ACF

Jemilah Mahmood UnderSecretaryGeneral,Partnerships IFRC

David Matern HeadofDonorRelationsandReportsUnit UNICEF

Michael Mosselmans HeadofHumanitarianprogrammepractice,policyandadvocacy

ChristianAid

James Munn Director NRC

Lamade Nicolas SeniorManager,Security,RecoveryandPeace GIZ

Melissa Pitotti HeadofPolicy ICVA

Mark Pryce HPCInformationServicesUnit OCHAFTS

Sanjana Quazi SeniorAdviser UNICEF

Deepti Sastri HeadofEvidence StartNetwork

Rachel Scott TeamLeader:Conflict,FragilityandResilience OECD/DAC

Dhananjayan Sriskandarajah SecretaryGeneral CIVICUS/HLP

Julian Srodecki TechnicalDirectorforHumanitarianGrants WorldVision

Anne Street HeadofHumanitarianPolicy CAFOD/CfC

Hans vanderHoogen HumanitarianAdvisor MinistryofForeignAffairs,TheNetherlands

James Weatherill CoordinationandResponseDivision(CRD) OCHA

Hesham Youssef AssistantSecretary-GeneralforHumanitarianAffairs

OrganisationofIslamicCooperation(OIC)

Ethiopia

YoucefAitChellouche HeadofDelegation IFRCEthiopia

40

John Aylieff

WFP

Kati CsabaMinister-CounsellorandSeniorDirector(Development),Ethiopia GovernmentofCanada

Anna Ekman DonorRelations UNICEF

Aurelie Ferial DeputyRegionalOperationsDirector ACF

Daniel Holmberg SeniorHumanitarianAdvisor OFDA

Abera Lulessa DirectorofFinance EthiopianRedCross

Tim Mander EthiopiaHumanitarianFundManager OCHA

Richard Markowski DeputyCountryDirector CRSEthiopia

Charlie Mason CountryDirectorSavetheChildrenEthiopia

Phinias Muziva ProgrammeManager NRCEthiopia

James Reynolds HeadofDelegation ICRC

Esther Salazar CountryDirector MercyCorpsEthiopia

Hanspeter Schwaar HeadofDevelopmentCooperation BMZ

Marijana Simic CountryDirector IRCEthiopia

Alex Whitney CountryDirector WorldVisionEthiopiaIraq

Andrew Barash SeniorInter-AgencyCoordinationAdvisor UNHCR

Alex Beattie HumanitarianAffairsOfficer(CHASEOT) DFID

Mike Bonke CountryDirector Welthungerhilfe

Julie Davidson

NRC

Lotti Douglas Director IraqCashConsortium

Ivo Freijsen HeadofOffice OCHA

Sally Haydock CountryDirector WFP

Nicholas Hutchings TechnicalAssistantEuropeanCommission

Jason Kajer ActingCountryDirector IRC

DanielMunoz-Rojas HeadofSub-Delegation-Erbil ICRC

PeggittyPollard-Davey ReportsSpecialist UNICEF

Michael Prendergast AssociateExternalRelationsandReportingOfficer,UNHCR

Olga Prorovskaya IraqHumanitarianFund OCHAAndresGonzalez Rodriguez CountryDirectorIraq Oxfam

Aneta Sama CountryDirector ACF-Iraq

41

Diana Tonea

NRC

Basil Yousif FoodSecurityProgrammeManager RNVDOMyanmar

Suresh Bartlett NationalDirector WorldVisionMyanmar

Kim Bawi ExecutiveCommitteeMember MyanmarRedCrossSociety

Edward Benson Shelter/NFI/CCCMClusterCoordinator UNHCR

Sophie Ford HumanitarianProgrammeAdvise OxfaminMyanmar

Brian Heidel RegionalAdvisorforEastAsiaandthePacific USAID/OFDA

Michael Hemling HeadofFinanceandAdministration WFP

Chris Hyslop DeputyHeadofOffice OCHA

Gwenolenn LeCouster SeniorProgramOfficer UNHCR

Laura Marshall HeadofProgram NRC

Leslie McCracken SeniorHumanitarianAssistanceAdvisor USAID

Esther Perry FirstSecretary AustralianEmbassy

Narciso Rosa-BerlangaSeniorHAO OCHA

Dom ScalpelliWFPResidentRepresentativeandCountryDirector WFP

Gum Shah

Metta

Masae Shimimura EmergencyPreparednessandResponseOfficer WFP

Mark Silverman Delegate ICRC

Kelland Stevenson CountryDirector PlanInternational

Jane Strachan EmergencySpecialist UNICEF

Moe Thu AssociateDirector-HEA WorldVisionMyanmar

42

Annex2:Quantitativeanalysisdetails

An independent-samples t-test was conducted to compare admin burden for bilateral grants and pooled fund grants. There was a significant difference in the scores across the pooled funds (M=4.42, SD=0.36) and bilateral grant (M=2.26, SD=0.13) conditions, t(14.2)=-5.64 p=0.00. These results suggest that the processing of pooled funds poses a greater administrative burden to organizations than the processing of bilateral grants. An independent-samples t-test was used to compare time lags (days between proposal and award) for bilateral grants and pooled funds grants. Once again, there was a statistically significant difference between the scores for pooled funds (M=27.25, SD=6.80) and bilateral grants (M=46.53, SD=8.14), t(46.6)=1.82 p=0.08. Comparing time delays between awards and disbursement, we once again note significant differences between the scores for pooled funds (M=32.42, SD=3.48) and bilateral grants (M=18.3, SD=1.88), t(18.1)=-3.56 p=0.002. However, in this case, pooled funds appear to be slower.