+ All Categories
Home > Documents > A Model of Self-fulfilling Exchange Rate Crisis With ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~mulraine/erc.pdfA...

A Model of Self-fulfilling Exchange Rate Crisis With ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~mulraine/erc.pdfA...

Date post: 09-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 3 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
34
A Model of Self-fulfilling Exchange Rate Crisis With Sovereign Debts * Millan L. B. Mulraine University of Toronto April 2007 Abstract The collapse of Argentina’s currency board provides further evidence that fiscal profli- gacy (whether financed by domestic money creation or foreign debt) is incompatible with the maintenance of any fixed exchange rate regime. In this paper we analyze a dynamic general equilibrium model with a mixture of fiscal deficits, stochastic endowment, and sovereign debts. It offers an environment in which a loss of confidence in the sustain- ability of the government’s fiscal position creates an environment for exchange rate crises. The evidence provided demonstrates that the Argentine government’s decision to abandon the peg in 2002 - following the default on its international debts, was a self-fulfilling out- come of agent’s expectations based on the underlying economic environment. Moreover, we also show that in an essentially identical economic framework - where the equilibrium probability of default is low, the optimal action for the government would be to maintain the fixed exchange rate and issue new debts to finance the fiscal deficit. Keywords: Debt crisis, Exchange rate crisis, Sovereign debts, Sunspots. JEL Classification: F34, F41, H63 * This paper forms part of my Ph.D. Economics thesis at the University of Toronto. I wish to thank Paul Masson for his supervision of this effort, and the many others who offered helpful suggestions and comments. All remaining errors are mine. Corresponding address: Department of Economics, University of Toronto, 150 St. George Street, Toronto, ON M5S 3G7, Canada. Tel: 1 (416) 824 8069, Email: [email protected]
Transcript

A Model of Self-fulfilling Exchange Rate Crisis

With Sovereign Debts∗

Millan L. B. Mulraine†

University of Toronto

April 2007

Abstract

The collapse of Argentina’s currency board provides further evidence that fiscal profli-

gacy (whether financed by domestic money creation or foreign debt) is incompatible with

the maintenance of any fixed exchange rate regime. In this paper we analyze a dynamic

general equilibrium model with a mixture of fiscal deficits, stochastic endowment, and

sovereign debts. It offers an environment in which a loss of confidence in the sustain-

ability of the government’s fiscal position creates an environment for exchange rate crises.

The evidence provided demonstrates that the Argentine government’s decision to abandon

the peg in 2002 - following the default on its international debts, was a self-fulfilling out-

come of agent’s expectations based on the underlying economic environment. Moreover,

we also show that in an essentially identical economic framework - where the equilibrium

probability of default is low, the optimal action for the government would be to maintain

the fixed exchange rate and issue new debts to finance the fiscal deficit.

Keywords: Debt crisis, Exchange rate crisis, Sovereign debts, Sunspots.

JEL Classification: F34, F41, H63

∗This paper forms part of my Ph.D. Economics thesis at the University of Toronto. I wish to thank Paul

Masson for his supervision of this effort, and the many others who offered helpful suggestions and comments.

All remaining errors are mine.†Corresponding address: Department of Economics, University of Toronto, 150 St. George Street,

Toronto, ON M5S 3G7, Canada. Tel: 1 (416) 824 8069, Email: [email protected]

1 Introduction

The first three generations of currency crisis models offer a rich literature for examining the

conditions under which a currency becomes susceptible to speculative attacks engendered by

the incompatibility between the exchange rate regime being pursued by the government and

the underlying macroeconomic fundamentals. In particular, this literature has been generally

successful in detailing both the timing and magnitude of these attacks and characterizing the

key fundamentals associated with them. However, despite the enormous insights provided by

these models they are unable to explain the three major1 episodes of international financial

crises that have occurred since the 1997 East Asian crisis. This inadequacy is principally

because the analysis provided by these models abstracts from one key component that has been

the hallmark of these three episodes of currency crises; namely the large and unsustainable

foreign-currency denominated sovereign debts.

In this paper we analyze a dynamic general equilibrium model with a mixture of persis-

tent fiscal deficits financed by foreign-currency denominated debt and stochastic exogenous

endowment. The paper offers an environment in which a sudden-stop in international finance

caused by a confidence crisis in the sustainability of the government’s fiscal position creates an

environment for an exchange rate crisis. As a consequence of the sudden-stop in the external

financing of the persistent fiscal deficits, the government is forced to default on its outstanding

debt payments and abandon the fixed exchange rate regime.

The objectives of the paper, therefore, are two-fold: firstly, the paper aims to characterize

the state-space in which a self-fulfilling debt crisis can arise in an environment in which there

are persistent fiscal deficits financed by foreign-currency denominated debt. In doing so, the

paper will also examine the conditions under which the government will choose to abandon the

fixed exchange rate regime after defaulting on its outstanding international debt obligations,

as opposed to implementing the requisite fiscal policy adjustments. Secondly, the paper will be

calibrated to match the stylized facts of the Argentine economy, and the proposed model will

then be simulated to explore its dynamic properties and to assess the welfare implications

of the decision of the Argentine government to abandon the currency board arrangement

following the default of 2002.1The three major crises are the Russian crisis, the Brazilian crisis, and the Argentine crisis.

2

The paper distinguishes itself from the previous generations of currency crisis models

and other related work in this area by providing an analysis of the welfare implications of

a government’s decision to default on its outstanding international debts and the post-crisis

decision regarding its policy choice of whether it should implement fiscal policy adjustments

in light of the incipient fiscal shortfall or abandon the fixed exchange rate regime. In doing

so the paper develops a general equilibrium model in which a debt crisis arising from the

self-fulfilling prophesy of agents results in a full-fledged currency crisis. The welfare analysis

conducted is aimed at offering some useful insights into the costs/benefits associated with a

government’s decision to default on its international debt obligations and the impact of that

decision on the welfare of agents in the economy.

The model developed here follows quite closely the experience of the collapse of the Ar-

gentine Convertibility Plan in which a cessation in the financing of the government’s fiscal

deficits by international investors due to their expectation on the probability of a government

default forced the Argentine government to default on its outstanding international sovereign

debt obligations in 2002 and subsequently abandon the Currency Board Arrangement (CBA).

While this model is based on the experience in a fixed exchange rate regime the model speci-

fication is general enough for consideration of other exchange rate regimes.

This paper is similar in scope to the work of Rebelo and Vegh (2002) which analyzes the

optimal time for a government to abandon its fixed exchange rate regime which has become

unsustainable when faced with exogenous fiscal shocks. The model to be analyzed extends the

insightful work of Cole and Kehoe (2000) in which a DGE model was developed to explain

the Mexican financial crisis of 1994-1995. This paper, however, differs from their work in a

number of key dimensions. Firstly, instead of characterizing the state-space within which a

debt crisis can occur2 a la Cole and Kehoe (2000), the paper focusses on the post-default

decision that a government must make when faced with a shortfall in its fiscal budget in the

absence of financing from international investors. Secondly, it provides a framework in which

the real depreciation of the exchange rate can be endogenously determined. Finally, the model

is driven by exogenous technological shocks to the production of the consumption good and2In their paper, the authors focus on characterizing the values of government debt and the debt’s maturity

structure under which a financial crisis can occur. They then go on to explore the policy options available to

the government when a financial crisis occurs.

3

shifts in the expectations of default on the debts by international investors - or sunspots.

In more recent work, Irwin (2004) attempts to explain the Argentine crisis by developing

a second generation currency crisis model that extends the work of the Obstfeld (1995), and

Drazen and Masson (1994), in which the policymaker has incomplete information about the

costs of devaluation and where unemployment is persistent. In their framework, the paper

shows that the persistence of unemployment causes the costs of maintaining the exchange rate

regime to be too high and forces the abandonment of the regime. Similarly, Komulaninen

(2004) considers the impact of foreign currency denominated debts in the context of the first

generation currency crisis model. In it he shows that international bond financing may not

necessarily delay the timing of these crises since the lower money demand due to the higher

risk premium may bring the timing of the crisis forward. He, however, concludes that if the

country’s indebtedness is low to moderate, bond financing will invariably delay the timing of

the crisis.

While the analysis provided in these papers is useful, they do not take account of the fact

that the currency crisis in Argentina was induced by the cessation of external financing of the

government’s fiscal deficits. More importantly, they do not consider the welfare implications

of the policy choices of the government, and as such they are unable to make judgements on

the optimality of the decision of the Argentine government to abandon the currency board

arrangement in favor of a free float following the default of 2002. For more detailed analysis

of the events leading up to the Argentine currency crisis, see Mulraine (2004).

The remainder of the paper is divided into six sections. In Section 2 of this paper the

two-period DGE model is presented, with its dynamic properties discussed in Section 3. In

Section 4 we explore the rational expectations equilibrium of the model. While in Section 5

the model will be simulated to provide insights into the decision of the Argentine government

to default on its external debts and to abandon the exchange rate upon defaulting. The paper

then concludes in Section 6.

2 The Benchmark Model

Consider a two-period dynamic general equilibrium small open economy model in which there

exist three types of economic agents. A representative consumer who makes consumption

4

decisions, a government (or public sector) that is responsible for all monetary and fiscal policy

decisions in this stylized economy, and a representative risk-neutral international investor who

purchases bonds issued by the government on the international capital market.

2.1 The Representative Consumer

This small open economy is populated by a large number of identical consumers of mass one

who live for two periods. Each period the representative consumer receives an exogenous

endowment of the consumption good yt, which is divided between consumption and financial

asset holdings - in the form of money. The discounted utility function for these agents can be

expressed as:

maxct,mt+1

u(ct) + βEtct+1, 0 < β < 1 (1)

where ct is the consumption level of the composite consumer good and β is assumed to be

the constant discount factor for agents in the economy. The first period utility functional

u(.) is assumed to be concave, continuously differentiable and monotonically increasing in its

argument. Following Drazen (1998), we assume that the representative consumer has linear

preferences in the second period3.

The consumer’s budget constraint for the first period is represented by:

ct + mt+1 + Γ(mt)ε ≤ (1− τt)ηtyt +mt

(1 + et)(2)

where mt+1 is the consumer’s decision on the holding of next period’s real money balance and

τt is the rate of taxation levied by the government on endowment. Note that the nominal

budget constraint for the consumer is given by ptct + Mt+1 + Γ(Mt)ε ≤ (1 − τt)ηtptyt + Mt,

where expectations are formed on the realization of the first period stochastic endowment,

and the default and post-default policy of the government. In particular, the relevant policy

decision which determines the price level will be whether or not the the government abandons

the exchange rate in favor of a free float - following a default in the first period, in which case

the relevant price level pt will be dictated by the rate of monetary expansion in that period.

Otherwise, the price level will remain unchanged.3The particular assumption has been made for analytical convenience only as it enables us to derive a

simplified money holdings function for the representative consumer.

5

Moreover, with the assumption of the law of one price, such that pt = Stp∗t where St

represents the nominal exchange rate4, the variable et = St−St−1

St−1will depict both the inflation

rate (or rate of domestic nominal money creation) and the rate of depreciation of the domestic

currency, following a float. Note that the opening stock of real money holdings, Mtpt

, can be

simplified by multiplying by pt−1

pt−1to get the expression mt

1+etshown in Eq. 2, where et = pt−pt−1

pt−1,

mt = Mtpt−1

, and mt+1 = Mt+1

pt. Thus, it becomes evident from this equation that real nominal

balances held by agents are eroded by inflation given by et.

The variable yt represents a first period exogenous stochastic endowment that is drawn

from a continuous distribution, with density function given by fy(·) about its mean of 1, and

has a cumulative distribution function Fy(·). In the second period, however, the exogenous

endowment yt+1 is assumed to be non-stochastic and is set equal to its expected value of unity.

Following Bulow and Rogoff (1989), (1 − ηt) is a multiplicative output loss which depends

on whether or not the government defaults on its outstanding debts. It reflects the fraction

of output loss each period following a default by the government as a result of the direct

sanctions imposed by the holders of government debts.

Similar to Greenwood (1983), we posit a transactionary motive for domestic agents to hold

positive levels of real money balances in equilibrium by assuming that money economizes on

real transaction costs. That is, in a motive akin to the Baumol-Tobin transactionary demand

for money, the real transactions cost function per period is represented as Γ(mt)ε = 1mt/(1+et)

ε,

where the ratio[

1mt/(1+et)

]represents the number of trips to the bank to finance the level

of consumption purchase ct with domestic currency, and the parameter ε capturing the fixed

cost per trip.5 As such, Γ(·) is a convex function of real money holding by agents, mt.

Moreover, since estimates by Marshall (1992) show that the fraction of income absorbed in

transactionary costs is relatively low - approximately 0.8% of output, the transactionary cost

is assumed to be positive, but small in real terms.4To take account of the Argentine Currency Board Arrangement we shall assume that the nominal exchange

rate St at the beginning of period 1 will be fixed at unity and normalize the foreign price level p∗t to one.5This form of money demand was chosen for convenience purpose only. See Feenstra (1986) and Walsh

(2003) for a further discussion of these models.

6

2.2 The Public Sector

The public sector issues money and produces the requisite level of nonproductive services

g each period. In light of the fiscal deficit facing the fiscal authority in the first period,

a decision is made on the amount of sovereign one-period zero-coupon bonds qtbt+1 to be

issued on the international capital market, where qt represents the price of these one-period

discounted bonds with face value bt+1 - specifying the amount to be repaid in period t + 1.

Moreover, since the government cannot commit ex-ante to full repayment of the outstanding

debts bt6 coming due in the first period, it must also make a strategic decision on whether

it should default on the current payments that have become due. The default decision is

captured by the indicator function Dt ∈ 0, 1, with 0 meaning a non-payment or full default

on the outstanding debt payments due and 1 indicating a full repayment. Note that if the

government defaults on its outstanding international debts in the first period the economy

faces a punishment factor 0 < 1− ηt < 1 on its exogenous endowment which captures events

such as loss of market access (embargo on trade) or tariffs imposed on it exports in both

periods. Moreover, we shall also assume that the government cannot default on its second

period debts bt+1.

The public sector is comprised of a benevolent government which considers the utility

function of the representative consumer as its own, and therefore maximizes the utility func-

tion of these agents given by Eq. 1 with respect to its choice of new bond holdings, bt+1 -

given its price qt, subject to the following fiscal budgetary constraints:

g + Dtbt ≤ ∆(τt)ηtyt + qtbt+1 + mt+1 −mt

(1 + et)(3)

Note that provided that the government has not defaulted previously, it will have access

to unlimited bond financing resources which it can obtain through the issuance of one-period

zero-coupon bonds bt+1 on the international capital market at a price qt = 11+ict

, with the

country-specific rate of interest given by ict = i∗ + φct(π1, bt), where i∗ is the constant world

interest rate, and φct(π1, bt) represents a country-specific spread charged by foreign investors for

holding the unsecured government bonds. φct(π1, bt) is an increasing function of the probability

6As part of the state of nature for the economy at the beginning of period 1, the opening stock of debt (bt)

- along with the opening stock of money (mt) - will be exogenously determined. However, they will collectively

capture the history of events for the Argentine economy.

7

of default π1, and a non-decreasing function of the bonds issued bt. In the absence of this

external avenue for financing its deficit - the loss of which occurs when the government has

defaulted on its outstanding debts - the government must finance its deficits by either money

creation or taxes.

Here, the level of additional real resources that is generated from seigniorage mt+1− mt(1+et)

(where Mt+1 = (1+et)Mt), depending on the nature of the exchange rate regime being pursued

by the government is given by the expression(

et1+et

)mt

7. That is, if the post-default policy

choice made by the government is to abandon the exchange rate regime in favor of a float, then

the government has the ability to garner additional real revenue by expanding the nominal

money supply such that M st+1 = (1+ξt)M s

t , where ξt represents the rate of nominal monetary

expansion. The increase in the nominal money supply raises current prices to ensure market

clearing of the real money supply. The resultant inflation along with the assumption of the

law of one price, therefore, causes a depreciation of the domestic currency by an amount

equivalent to the rate of price inflation, such that et = ξt. In the second period, however,

government loses its ability to use seigniorage as the end of the period holdings of real money

will be zero, consequently, inflation in that period will be zero.8

The function ∆(τt) represents the effective tax rate imposed by government on endowment.

It becomes relevant in the case where the government pursues a “tax policy” regime following

a default on its outstanding debts in the first period - indicated by a τ superscript. Following

Aizenman et al. (2000) we assume that adjusting the tax level in the first period beyond its

fixed initial level τ incurs additional cost to the fiscal authority. These costs may reflect the

inherent inefficiency in the tax collection system and thus they capture the distortions caused

by changes in the rate of taxation, alternatively, they can be seen as the additional collection

costs incurred by the government. As such, we specify a simplified function by assuming a

fixed portion φ of the tax collected is lost, in which case ∆(τt) = (1− φ)τ τt .

7Recall that the real seigniorage revenue given byMt+1

pt− Mt

ptcan be simplified by multiplying the second

expression bypt−1pt−1

to get mt+1 −mtmt

(1+et), where 1 + et = pt

pt−18Note that in the second period the government assumes the monetary liabilities of the previous period.

However, since this is financed by further taxation there will be no net change in real resources available to

agents in the economy as a result of this action.

8

2.3 The International Investor

There exist a large number of risk-neutral international investors with access to unlimited

funds - operating in a perfectly competitive international capital market. The representative

international investor holds a diversified portfolio of assets of which the sovereign debts of

this small open economy is a negligible part. As such, the combination of investment risk

neutrality of this agent and risk idiosyncracy of the sovereign bonds held ensures that the

problem of the international investor collapses to an arbitrage condition which equalizes the

expected gross interest rate earned from investing in one unit of the risky sovereign bonds

to the risk-free rate of return prevailing on the international capital market. That is, the

international investor will invest in domestic risky sovereign bonds up to the point where the

expected return from these bonds (1− π1)(1 + ict) becomes equal to the risk-free return from

other international bonds (1 + i∗t ), such that (1− π1)(1 + ict) = (1 + i∗t ). This implies that for

the international investor β∗Et(1+ ict) = 1, where 1β∗ represents the rate of time preference for

the international investor and π1 denotes the probability of a default by the fiscal authority

on its international debts.

From this condition it becomes apparent that the implicit country-specific spread de-

manded by international investors on their holdings of the international bond is an increasing

function of the probability of default. More specifically, we can see that as the probability

of default approaches 1 the country-specific spread approaches infinity, and conversely as the

default probability approaches zero the expected rate approaches the risk-free world interest

rate. That is, limπ1→1 ict+1 → ∞, and similarly limπ1→0 ict+1 → i∗t . Given the assumption of

unlimited financial resources available to the international investor and the collapse of the

problem of the international investor to the arbitrage condition outlined above, we can there-

fore remove the problem of this agent from further consideration, and instead focus on the

formation of the probability of default.

2.4 Timing of Events

In this framework the timing of events in the first period is particularly important since

it dictates the information set available to each agent at the time the requisite optimizing

decisions are being made by these agents. More specifically, at each point when these opti-

9

mizing decisions are being taken, all previous decisions (made by other agents) will be known.

Accordingly, the timing of events goes as follows:

1. The international investors set out a financial strategy regarding the purchasing of

government bonds, given their expectation on the probability of default π1 following the

realization of the sunspot variable9 π, and their current holdings of government bonds bt;

2. The consumer chooses the level of consumption ct, and consequently the ex-ante level

of money holdings mt+1 for the next period.

3. Given the price schedule for government bonds on the international capital market

qt(π1, bt) and the financing requirement of the government qtbt+1, the value of the second

period debt bt+1 will be determined;

4. The exogenous endowment yt is realized and the full state of nature Ωt(bt,mt, yt, π)

becomes known;

5. Given this state of nature, the government then chooses whether or not it should default

on its outstanding debt bt;

6. If the government defaults on its debt10, it then determines the post-default policy

decision of whether to abandon the exchange rate regime in favor of a free-float or to maintain

the exchange rate regime and implement tax reform; and

7. The government’s decision determines the ex-post money holding mπt+1

11, based on

the default and post-default decision of the government and the level of the first period

consumption ct.

8. Given the absence of uncertainty in the second period, the equilibrium actions of all

agents will be assumed to occur simultaneously.

Furthermore, we shall assume that a technology exists to enforce payment of the outstand-

ing debts bt+1 that have become due in the second period. Finally, given that the terminal

value of the money holdings and the outstanding debt stock12 must be equal to zero at the

end of period two, the tax rate invariably adjusts in this period to ensure fiscal solvency under

all policy regime - in which case we restrict the analysis to cases where τπt+1 < 1.

9This sunspot variable is assumed to be independently and uniformly distributed on the unit interval, such

that π ∈ [0, 1], and occurs as a shock to the expectations of international investors.10At the time that the government default decision arises its stock of outstanding debt will be bt and bt+1.11Where π ∈ n, s, τ depending on the policy decision of the government.12Note that there will be no new lending by the international investors to the government in that period.

10

Following Cole and Kehoe (2000), we shall assume that in the first period agents observed

an exogenous sunspot variable π, assumed to be uniformly distributed on the interval [0,

1]. In equilibrium, if the sunspot variable π ≤ π1, upon seeing this signal agents rationally

predict a default by the government on its outstanding debts. If so, agents will be unwilling

to pay a positive price for any new debt offered by the government. In which case the cost

of issuing new bonds to retire the old debts becomes prohibitively large for the government,

thus triggering a debt crisis. Conversely, for sunspot variable π > π1, international investors

rationally expect the government to repay in full the outstanding debts, and thus they will

be willing to make new loans to the government to finance it deficits. Since π is uniformly

distributed on the unit interval, we will have that π1 is both the crucial value of π and the

probability of default (that is, π ≤ π1).

3 Equilibrium Dynamics

Given this framework, we can now focus on the sequence of events outlined above. To solve the

problem at hand we shall revert to a framework in which we solve the problems of the agents

at the beginning of a period before which there has never been any default and expectations

are formed on the current period’s default and post-default decisions of the government.

3.1 The consumer’s optimal decisions

The consumer’s decision in the first period is affected by her expectations on the govern-

ment’s default and subsequent post-default decisions in that period. Since a default on the

outstanding debt payment will invariably mean that the government must balance its fiscal

budget by either abandoning the exchange rate regime or adjusting the tax rate, the consumer

must form expectations on these occurrences and take account of them in her problem. To

this end, the budget constraints given below are for the no-default (denoted by n), default

with floating exchange rate (denoted by s), and default with tax adjustment (denoted by τ),

respectively. Let us assume that the representative consumer expects the government will

default with probability π1, and upon defaulting abandons the exchange rate with probability

π2. As such, the consumer’s maximization problem at the beginning of the first period in

which she chooses the consumption level for the current period and the ex-ante level of next

11

period’s money holdings, given by ct and mt+1, respectively - where expectations are formed

over the respective government action and the stochastic exogenous endowment for the first

period yt - can be represented as:

maxct,mt+1

c1−γt − 11− γ

+ βEtct+1, 0 < β < 1 (4)

subject to

ct + mt+1 +[ 1mt/(1 + et)

]ε ≤ (1− τt)ηtyt +

[ mt

(1 + et)

](5)

ct+1 +1

mt+1ε ≤ (1− τt+1)ηt+1yt+1 + mt+1

Here the representative consumer maximizes expected utility subject to the three possible

equilibrium outcomes based on the default and post-default decisions of the government. The

variables cnt+1, c

τt+1 and cs

t+1 are the ex-post state-contingent second period consumption level

under a no-default, default and tax, and a default and float equilibrium, respectively. That

is, the consumer chooses the levels of consumption ct, and ex-ante money holding mt+1, with

the ex-post value of the asset portfolio mπt+1 where π ∈ n, s, τ, being determined by the

respective actions of the government and the choice of mt+1 in the first period.

The optimal equilibrium equations for first period consumption, expected second period

consumption and the ex-ante money holdings, respectively, can be restated as:

ct = Et(1− τt)ηtyt + Et

[ mt

1 + et

]− Et

[1 + et

mtε]− mt+1 (6)

Etct+1 = (1− π1)[(1− τn

t+1)yt+1 + mnt+1 −

1mn

t+1

ε]

+ π1(1− π2)[(1− τ τ

t+1)ηt+1yt+1 + mτt+1 −

1mτ

t+1

ε]

+ π1π2

[(1− τ s

t+1)ηt+1yt+1 + mst+1 −

1ms

t+1

ε]

(7)

and

mt+1 =[ βcγ

t

1− βcγt

ε] 1

2 (8)

Here, the superscripts n, s and τ on the ex-post variables capture the no-default, default

and float, and default and tax regimes, respectively, resulting from the first period actions of

the government. An important consideration for the analysis to follow will be the analytical

12

expressions for the ex-post equilibrium variables under the three possible policy choices of

the government. Recall that the consumer chooses the optimal level of consumption ct and

the ex-ante money holdings mt+1 in the first period prior to the revelation of the state of

nature. However, following the decision of the government in the first period, the consumer

consumes the optimal level of consumption regardless of the regime pursued and allows her

money holding to adjust ex-post to balance her budget. In the second period the agent will

consume the sum of her endowment (net of taxes) for that period and the money holdings

brought forward from the previous period, less the transaction cost.

As outlined above, in the first period the representative consumer-producer chooses the

unique13 ex-ante optimal level of consumption and lets the money holdings that are carried

forward into the second period depend on the government’s policy decision.

At the end of the first period when all uncertainties are resolved and the policy of the

government has been established, we can derive the level of capital stock associated with each

decision of the government, and consequently the implied levels of consumption in the second

period. More specifically, in an environment where the stochastic endowment is given by yt

and the government does not default on its debt obligations (in which case price remains

unchanged), the values for next period’s money stock and consumption become:

mnt+1 = (1− τ)yt + mt −

1mt

ε− ct (9)

and

cnt+1 = (1− τn

t+1)ηt+1yt+1 + mnt+1 −

1mn

t+1

ε, where ηt+1 = 1 (10)

If instead, the government defaults on its outstanding debt payment and decides to maintain

the exchange rate regime by implementing tax adjustments, the value for the next period’s

money holdings and consumption will be:

mτt+1 = (1− τ τ

t )ηtyt + mt −1

mtε− ct (11)

and

cτt+1 = (1− τ τ

t+1)ηt+1yt+1 + mτt+1 −

1mτ

t+1

ε (12)

13This consumption level is considered unique in the sense that the level of consumption by agent remains

invariant to the policy regime subsequently pursued by the government.

13

Finally, in a scenario where the government defaults on its debt payment and decides to

abandon the exchange rate regime while using seigniorage revenue to finance the budgetary

gap, the value for the next period’s money holding and consumption then become:

mst+1 = (1− τ)ηtyt +

[ mt

1 + et

]−

[(1 + et)mt

ε]− ct (13)

cst+1 = (1− τ s

t+1)ηt+1yt+1 + mst+1 −

1ms

t+1

ε (14)

From Eq. 6 - 8 above it becomes evident that the consumption level ct, and consequently the

ex-ante level of money holding mπt+1 depend explicitly on the ex-ante probabilities assigned

by agents to the policy choices of the government. This observation is particularly important

since it is the underpinning of the self-fulfilling nature of the model.

3.2 The government’s optimal decisions

Recall that the government’s decision on the optimal amount of new bonds to issue occurs

before the realization of the productivity innovation - thus there will still remain uncertainty

about the state of nature when the government makes its first move. This uncertainty, there-

fore, requires that the government’s decision on the optimal amount of bonds to issue be

contingent on its expectations of the realization of the productivity innovation in that period.

Moreover, given our assumption of risk neutrality and unlimited funds on the part of the

representative international investors, the government will be able to issue new bonds in the

first period equivalent to qtbt+1 to balance its budget.

By the time the government makes its default decision in the first period, the state of

nature Ωt(bt,mt, yt, πt) will be fully revealed. As a result, the problem for the government

when it makes the default decision can be described as:

V πg (π1, π2) = max

π

c1−γt − 11− γ

+ βcπt+1 (15)

subject to

g + bt ≤ τyt + qtbt+1 (16)

g ≤ (1− φ)τ τt ηtyt + qtbt+1 (17)

g ≤ τηtyt + qtbt+1 +( et

1 + et

)mt (18)

14

From these equations we can obtain the equilibrating values14 for qtbt+1, τ τt , and et that

will be required to balance the government’s budget in the first period in the no-default, the

default and tax, and the default and float equilibrium, respectively. In the case of a float, the

government uses seigniorage revenue given by(

et1+et

)mt

15, thus allowing the exchange rate to

depreciate endogenously to balance its budget. Similarly, we can also obtain the second period

equilibrating values for τnt+1, τ τ

t+1 and τ st+1 under the three policy regimes of the government.

Having fully characterized the optimal decisions of the representative consumer and the

behavior of the government, we are now interested in determining the regions of the state

space in the stochastic endowment and debt stock, yt, bt - for a given level of opening stock

of money holding mt - in which the default and post-default decisions of the government lie.

More specifically we are interested in finding the range in the state space for which it will

be optimal for the government to (i) default on its outstanding debts, and in so doing to (ii)

abandon the exchange rate regime. Given that the optimal levels of consumption in both

periods are functions of the underlying ex-ante probabilities assigned to the respective policy

options of the government, the above problem for the government implies that the authorities

will choose to default on the outstanding debt payments that have become due this period

iff :

V dg (π1, π2) ≥ V n

g (π1, π2) (19)

Where V dg (π1, π2) = maxV s

g (π1, π2), V τg (π1, π2). That is, the government will default ex-

post if the discounted value of defaulting exceeds the expected discounted value of not de-

faulting. If the government defaults then it must decide on whether or not it should adjust

taxes or float the exchange rate to balance its fiscal budget. Therefore, the authority will opt14Note that at the end of the second period we must have that mt+2 = 0 and bt+2 = 0, thus meaning that

taxes τπt+1 must adjust to ensure fiscal solvency. For a complete list of the ex-post equilibrating values for

the international borrowing qtbt+1, the tax rate ττt , and the rate of depreciation et in the first period for the

government under the no-default, default and tax, and default and float, respectively, and their associated

second period tax rates τπt+1 see Appendix 7.1.

15This expression for the seigniorage revenue emerges from the government’s budget constraint. In nominal

terms, the government’s budget constraint is given by ptg ≤ τηtptyt +qtptbt+1 +Mt+1−Mt, where the nominal

seigniorage revenue is Mt+1−Mt, after substituting Mt+1 = (1+et)Mt and dividing by pt we get the expression

for the real seigniorage revenue obtained by the government.

15

to abandon the fixed exchange rate regime iff :

V sg (π1, π2) ≥ V τ

g (π1, π2) (20)

that is, if the discounted expected value of floating after a default exceeds that of implementing

tax reform.

3.3 Value function properties

The analysis provided so far has focussed exclusively on outlining the decision rules that

govern the behavior of a benevolent government in determining its default and post-default

decisions. The analytical form of the ex-post value functions for the no-default policy options

for the government is given by:

V πg =

c1−γt − 11− γ

+ β[(1− τπ

t+1)I(ηt+1)yt+1 + mπt+1 −

ε

mπt+1

], where π ∈ (n, τ, s) (21)

and I(ηt) is an indicator function such that

I(ηt) =

1 if π = n;

ηt if π = τ ;

ηt if π = s.

For a complete list of the ex-post equilibrating values for the international borrowing qtbt+1,

the tax rate τ τt , and the rate of depreciation et in the first period for the government under the

no-default, default and tax, and default and float, respectively, and their associated second

period tax rates τπt+1 see Appendix 7.1. This then takes us to the next step of the analysis

- which is to discuss some properties of the government’s value function with respect to the

state variables and the underlying ex-ante probabilities. This we shall now do in the form of

a few theorems.

Theorem 3.1. The discounted value of not defaulting each period, V ng (π1, π2), is inversely

related to the ex-ante expected probability of a default, π1.

Proof. See Appendix 7.2.

The rationale for this theorem comes from the fact that higher ex-ante expectation of the

probability of default on the part of agents increases the country-specific spread φ(π1, bt), and

16

hence the country-specific interest rate ict charged on any new borrowing by the government.

This higher country-specific interest rate lowers the price for government bonds qt. Given that

for any given initial state characterized by Ωt(bt,mt, yt, πt), the sacrifice required in period

two to repay the accumulated debt bt+1 - resulting from higher taxation in that period -

will be an increasing function of ex-ante probability of default π1. It therefore implies that

the discounted value of not defaulting decreases with the ex-ante expected probability of a

default, that is dV ng (π1,π2)

dπ1< 0.

This observation is particularly important since it underpins the self-fulfilling nature of

the model being considered. That is, when agents expect the government to default with

certainty by setting π1 = 1, the costs of any new borrowing bt+1 becomes infinitely large,

and its price qt approaches zero. This makes it impossible for the government to repay its

outstanding debts since it will be unable to issue new bonds, making the prophesy of the

government’s default on outstanding debts self-fulfilling.

Theorem 3.2. The ex-ante expected probability of a default on the outstanding debts by the

government in a rational expectations, sunspot equilibrium, π116, will be an increasing function

of the debt stock, bt.

Proof. See Appendix 7.3

Essentially, this claim asserts that the greater the outstanding debt stock of the govern-

ment, the greater will be the amount of new bond issue required to finance the budget deficit

in that period, and consequently the greater will be the probability of a default. More pre-

cisely, as the debt stock moves toward the natural borrowing limit b17 the ex-ante probability

of default on these outstanding debts approaches unity.16The notion of a rational expectations, sunspot equilibrium follows the discussion outlined by Jeanne (1997)

and Jeanne and Masson (2000).17Here the natural borrowing limit (or debt ceiling) is defined as the maximal finite value of debt that the

government can afford to repay in all possible states if all revenues are devoted entirely to debt financing. See

Eaton and Gersovitz (1981) for further discussion on the debt ceiling.

17

4 Rational expectations, Sunspot Equilibrium

A rational expectations, sunspot equilibrium, therefore, in this framework is a one-to-one

mapping between the ex-ante probability assigned by agents to the respective government

actions (the default and post-default decisions) and the actual probability of the actions

taken by the government. As such, given the rationality of agents in the model the ex-ante

probability of default π1 and the ex-ante probability of a float π2 (following any default), will

be equal to the probability that the utility to the government of the requisite policy choice

exceeds that of the alternative option(s) available.

For example, we can derive the actual probability of a float π2 following a default, which

is given by:

π2 = Pr[V sg (π1, π2) ≥ V τ

g (π1, π2)] (22)

Which simplifies to:

π2 = Pr[cst+1 − cτ

t+1 > 0]

= Pr[( φ

1− φ

)(g − qtbt+1)−

( g − τηtyt − qtbt+1

mt + τηtyt + qtbt+1 − g

)( ε

mt

)> 0

](23)

Here, the actual probability of a float following a default on the outstanding debt will be

equal to the probability that the welfare loss to consumers in the form of higher transaction

cost - given by the second term in the bracket - is less than the welfare cost of higher taxation

expressed by the first term. As such, it becomes evident that the probability of a currency crisis

occurring following a debt crisis is strictly increasing with the size of the opening monetary

base, as the value of the real seigniorage revenue generated from this policy option increases

with the size of the opening monetary stock. The equilibrium probability of a float arising

from the above equation is an explicit function of the underlying economic fundamentals and

the stochastic process.

In a similar fashion, the equilibrium probability of the government defaulting on its out-

standing debts, given the state of nature must be equal to the probability that the discounted

welfare of defaulting is greater than that of not defaulting. Here, the expected welfare of a de-

fault will be directly related to the ex-ante probability assigned by agents on the post-default

actions of the government. That is, the probability of a default by the government, π1 on its

18

outstanding debts is given by:

π1 = Pr[V dg (π1, π2) ≥ V n

g (π1, π2)] (24)

Where V dg (π1, π2) and V n

g (π1, π2) are the value function for the government under default

and no-default, respectively. Given that consumption in the first period does not depend on

the policy decision of the government, the probability of a default in the first period then

simplifies to:

π1 = Pr[(1− π2)cτ

t+1 + π2cst+1 − cn

t+1 > 0]

(25)

Such that:

π1 = Pr[π2[(1− τ s

t+1)ηt+1yt+1 + mst+1 −

ε

mst+1

] + (1− π2)[(1− τ τt+1)ηt+1yt+1 + mτ

t+1 − ...

ε

mτt+1

] + (1− τnt+1)yt+1 + mn

t+1 −ε

mnt+1

> 0]

(26)

Given the complexity of the expression, this equation does not have a closed-form analyt-

ical solution, so in order to provide further insights into the properties of this model we shall

apply numerical methods. This approach will also provide us with the opportunity to assess

the implication of the model for the decision of the Argentine government to default on its

outstanding debts in 2002 and subsequently to abandon the fixed exchange rate regime.

5 Quantitative Assessment

5.1 Parameter Calibration

In this section we apply numerical methods to the model outlined above to ascertain the

relevant equilibrium probabilities, and to assess the welfare implications of the ex-ante proba-

bilities assigned by agents to the respective government’s actions. To do this, we shall calibrate

the stylized model as closely as possible to the Argentine economy at the end of 200118 - the

year before the Argentine government defaulted on its international debt. These calibrated

values were obtained by matching the empirical facts on the Argentine economy. Following

IMF (2003) the tax rate τ was set equal to 23.7% to reflect the total revenue of the Argentine

government in 2001 and the fixed amount of annual government spending g equal to 25%18See Table 1 for a summary of the parameter values used in the simulation.

19

of the expected endowment in the first period, which is equivalent to the ratio of primary

government expenditure to GDP in 2001. This takes into account the fact that at the end

of 2001 the Consolidated Government Account in Argentina had a primary deficit of 1.3% of

GDP. The stock of debt19 that came due in the first period was set at 4.6% of GDP, equivalent

to the total debt servicing by the Argentine government in 2001. Thus, the financing gap for

this period, which is the amount required to be raised on the international capital market,

was set at 5.9% of GDP.

We set the value of the opening stock of money holdings in the model to 12% of GDP to

reflect Argentina’s monetary base (measured by M2) at the end of 2001.20 Following Aguiar

and Gopinath (2004), we set the risk-free world interest rate at 4% and the endowment loss

or default penalty (1 − η) equal to 8% of output21. We set the constant discount rate β to

0.96 and follow the calibrated value of Yue (2005) by setting the coefficient of relative risk

aversion γ to 2. Using the functional form advocated by Aizenman et al. (2000), the tax

revenue loss φ resulting from implementing a tax policy adjustment was set equal to 1.5%.

Given the parameterization described above, the only remaining parameter to be determined

in this model will be ε - the fixed transaction cost. This parameter is particularly important

since it determines (to a large extent) the money holding decision of agents to the exogenous

process considered. Following Marshall (1992) we set ε equal to 0.0014 to obtain transaction

cost of 1% of GDP in the first period. To close the model, the experiment was conducted on

stochastic endowment yt in the first period, such that yt ∈ [0.65, 1.35], reflecting the vagaries

of annual per capita growth in Argentina22 - which moved from a high of +11% in 1991 to

a low of -15% in 2002, following the default23. Finally, the model was simulated with the19Given the two-periods dimension of the model, the debt considered in the simulation is the amount be-

coming due for the period. Note that a period in this framework was arbitrarily set to be equivalent to one

year. As such, the analysis conducted in the simulation exercises abstracts from the stock of debt in Argentina

which at the time of the crisis was close to 65% of GDP.20This value was obtained from Cline (2003).21In the case of Argentina the default penalty (or more precisely, the output loss) resulted from, inter alia, the

withdrawal of a number of international financial institutions - such as The Bank of Nova Scotia’s Scotiabank

Quilmes subsidiary in 2002 - and the higher costs of financial intermediation ensuing from the distress in the

Argentine financial sector following the default.22Note that the stochastic endowment spread was set arbitrarily wide to enhance the geniality of the results.23The Currency Board Arrangement was introduced in Argentina in April 1991 and abandoned in January

20

state-space grid being set to 20 possible outcomes.

5.2 Simulation Results

In Figure 1 we display the first period consumption level of the representative consumer in

the model, as functions of the ex-ante probability of the default and post-default policies

of the government. This consumer choice variable is an important gauge of the consumer’s

first period welfare in this stylized economy since they indicate how the perception of agents

toward the respective government actions affects their decision. In this framework, the agent’s

perception is reflected by the ex-ante probabilities assigned to the respective government

actions. Recall that the first period consumption level will be identical across all three policy

regimes, and as a consequence, it becomes a useful measure of how agents alter their decisions

based on what they perceive the government will do.

It becomes evident from the graph in Figure 1 that the first period consumption level for

the representative consumer is maximized in an environment where agents assign a value of

zero to the probability of the government defaulting on its outstanding debt. Conversely, the

representative consumer’s first period consumption level is at its lowest level when they assign

a high probability to the government defaulting on the outstanding debt with a concomitant

low ex-ante probability of a float, following a default by the government. That is, when the

probability combination of (π1, π2) is equal to (1,0).

The contrasting outcomes of these two polar cases highlight the fact that in an essen-

tially identical economic environment agents’ first period welfare will be higher if they expect

the government to repay its outstanding debt at the end of the period - compared to the

alternative of a default. This outcome emerges from the fact that the belief of a default

by government will result in all costs being passed on to them as the government will be

faced with higher borrowing costs on the international capital market - resulting from the

country-specific spread. This implies that for the Argentine economy, the pervasive view that

the government was about to default on its outstanding debts resulted in a sub-optimal out-

come for the Argentine people, in the sense that it resulted in lower first period consumption,

compared to an environment where the economic fundamentals would have dictated the ex-

2002. Between 1998 and 2002 real GDP per capital fell by as much as 25%.

21

pectation of agents to be one where they believe the government will repay its outstanding

debt.

On the other hand, the evidence provided by the model shows that the representative

agent’s first period consumption is higher when the government is expected to choose to

abandon the fixed exchange rate regime following a default, compared to the alternative of

pursuing a fiscal adjustment policy. The intuition for this is quite clear. Since agents can

only smooth consumption inter-temporally by holding money, in the event that they believe

that the government will pursue an expansionary monetary policy following a default, the

substitution effect will engender agents to increase their consumption in the first period to

avoid the confiscation of their money holdings by inflation. But there is also an income

effect that works in the opposite direction. In this case, the expectation of being poorer will

encourage the reduction in consumption and the accumulation of assets in the form of money.

Note, however, that the dominance of the substitution effect over the income effect is reversed

in the case where agents expect the government to pursue a fiscal agenda following the default.

In fact, in the case where agents expect the government to pursue fiscal policy following the

default there will be no substitution effect since inflation will be zero.

The unique equilibrium probability of a float, following a sovereign debt default, is equal

to 84%. That is, following a default, the probability of the government abandoning the fixed

exchange rate for a free float was very high. Regardless of the state of nature, there is a

high chance that the government will pursue an expansionary monetary policy to off-set any

budgetary deficit that may arise from the loss of access to the international capital market -

following a default on the international debt. In essence, this outcome mirrors the experience

of the Argentine crisis of 2002, in which the government abandoned the exchange rate peg

following a default in favor of a float. This result, therefore, is consistent with the ranking of

the first period consumer welfare discussed earlier, and arises naturally given that the default

and float equilibrium dominates the default and tax equilibrium over the entire state-space.

In Figure 2 - 3 we plot the actual probability (Figure 2) of a default by the government

as a function of the expected probability of a default, and the expected probability of a float

formed by agents in the model. Here the actual probability of default π1 increases non-linearly

with both the expected probability of a default and the expected probability of a float. The

actual probability takes into account the welfare of consumers in the second period, since the

22

relevant comparison in the analysis is between the expected benefit of a default V dg (π1, π2)

and the benefit of a no-default given by V ng (π1, π2). It can be seen from the graphical display

that at low values for the joint expected probability of default - irrespective of the expected

probability of a float - the actual probability of a default occurring is correspondingly low.

That is, in these regions the high cost of default (in terms of the loss of the relatively cheap

international capital) reduces the incentives for a default by the government thereby ensuring

the repayment of outstanding debts in both periods.

In subplot 1 of Figure 3 we display a two-dimensional plot of the equilibrium probability

of a default (for the given unique equilibrium value of a float, that is, π2 = 0.84) in the model.

The multiple points of intersections of the 45-line and the actual probability of the default

plot on the graph are fixed points, rational expectations equilibria where the belief of agents

(measured by the ex-ante probability of a default) and the actual probability of a default

are equal. It therefore becomes apparent from that graphical display that in the benchmark

calibration for Argentina in 2001, yields multiplicity in the equilibrium probability of a default

by the government on its international debts.

5.3 Sensitivity Analysis

In this section we conduct sensitivity analysis on the benchmark model to study the robust-

ness of the findings above to changes in the key structural parameter values of the model.

The parameters and variables of interest here are the output loss (1− η) - Model I, the con-

stant discount rate β - Model II, the fixed transaction cost parameter ε - Model III, the tax

adjustment cost φ - Model IV, and finally the opening stock of money - Model V. The de-

fault probability resulting from these sensitivity checks are presented in Figure 3, while their

associated post-default equilibrium probability of a float is displayed in Figure 4 below.

In Model I we lower the default penalty measured by the endowment loss (1−η) to 4% per

period, from 8% in the benchmark model. This resulted in the elimination of the multiplicity

of equilibria observed in the benchmark model to a unique value for the equilibrium probability

of default of 80%. That is, as would be expected in this framework, the probability of a default

is inversely related to the proportion of output loss. On the other hand, from subplot 1 of

Figure 4, we see the opposite relationship between the default penalty and the probability of

23

a float; with the the probability of a float being positively related to the output loss. The

reason for this is quite simple. Note that the tax base decreases with output, thereby making

a float more attractive to a tax policy adjustment following a default.

In Model II we lower the constant discount rate to β = 0.80, akin to the low values

used by Aguiar and Gopinath (2004) and Yue (2005). Here we see that the number of

equilibria increases to four, while the equilibrium probability of a float remains identical to

the benchmark model. The increase in the number of default equilibria arises as a natural

result of the greater impatience of the government. Note that the equilibrium probability of

a float (once a default has occurred) is independent of the constant discount factor.

We then experimented with a higher constant transaction cost parameter - which we set

to ε = 0.0018 in Model III. Here the optimal policy option is similar to that of the benchmark

model, with the optimal policy at the lower equilibrium values will be for the government to

maintain the fixed exchange rate and borrow on the international capital market to finance the

fiscal deficit. In the case of the equilibrium probability of a float, we see in Figure 4 that there

is an inverse relationship between the the probability of a float and the fixed transaction cost.

This outcome arises because the higher transaction cost makes the post-default monetary

policy option less attractive to the government, relative to the fiscal policy option.

For Model IV we lower the tax adjustment cost parameter to φ = 0.005, the equilibrium

default probability is presented in Figure 3. From this experiment it emerges that the equilib-

rium probability of a float increases non-linearly with the tax adjustment cost. This outcome

is consistent with expectations, since the welfare cost to consumers of implementing a tax

policy relative to using inflation tax increases with the tax adjustment costs. As such, the

probability of a float will be positively related to the cost of adjusting taxes.

Finally, in Model V we lower the initial money stock from 0.12 to 0.06 and present the

equilibrium default probability in Figure 3. In terms of the equilibrium probability of a float

following the default presented in Figure 4, we can observe concavity in the relationship

between the the opening stock of money and the probability of a float. This graph implies

a “Laffer Curve” type relationship between the money stock and the probability of a float

following a default. The nonlinear relationship is the result of two competing aspects of the

policy options in this model. At the lower end of the spectrum, an increase in the monetary

base provides an attractive target for the government to use inflation tax to generate the

24

requisite deficit financing seigniorage - hence the increase in the probability of a float following

the default. On the other hand, however, as the opening stock of money moves beyond a

certain threshold, the non-distortionary fiscal policy option dominates the monetary policy

alternative. That is, the tax policy option becomes more attractive at these levels because

consumers can use the higher money holdings to offset the higher tax payments and smooth

consumption over the two periods without the additional distortions.

6 Conclusion

In this paper we offer a framework in which a general equilibrium model with a mixture of

fiscal deficits, exogenous stochastic endowment and sovereign debt is analyzed to ascertain

the welfare implications of the Argentine government’s decision to abandon the CBA in 2002,

following the default on its international debt obligation. In particular, the primary aim of

the paper has been to offer a model which takes into account the default and post-default

decisions of a benevolent government with sovereign debts and to provide insights into the

welfare implications of these decisions. From the analysis conducted, we demonstrate that

the benchmark model possesses multiple equilibria in the probability of a debt crisis.

This observation is particularly important since it indicates that the occurrence of the

Argentine debt crisis may have been the realization of a “bad” equilibrium outcome - thereby

making the debt crisis self-fulfilling. Moreover, we also demonstrate that following a default,

the equilibrium probability of a float was high - at a value of 84%. The singularity in the

equilibrium probability of a float (following a default) implies that the Argentine currency

crisis of 2001 was not a self-fulfilling outcome of agent’s expectation. Instead, the conclusion

that can be drawn is that the float was triggered by the self-fulfilling debt crisis. More

importantly, the benchmark model presents evidence to support the view that the Argentine

Currency Board Arrangement was itself a sustainable mechanism in the absence of the debt

crisis.

25

APPENDIX

7 Derivations and Proofs

7.1 Equilibrating Values

Note that in the first period the government choices the policy option that maximizes its

welfare and balances its fiscal budget based on the policy option chosen. In the second period,

given that it must repay it holding of outstanding international debts with no possibility of

any new international borrowing (in the no-default equilibrium), and will be unable to issue

any new domestic money (in the default and float equilibrium), all three equilibria will be

characterized by an equilibrating rate of taxation τπt+1.

7.1.1 Period 1

bt+1 = [g + bt − τyt

qt]

τ τt =

[ g − qtbt+1

ηt(1− φ)yt

]et

1 + et=

[ g − τηtyt − qtbt+1

mt

]et =

[ g − τηtyt − qtbt+1

mt + τηtyt + qtbt+1 − g

]

7.1.2 Period 2

τnt+1 =

[ g + bt+1 + mnt+1

yt+1

]τ τt+1 =

[ g + mτt+1

ηt+1yt+1

]τ st+1 =

[ g + mst+1

ηt+1yt+1

]7.2 Proof of Theorem 3.1

From our discussion in Section 2.3, we can deduce that for any π11 < π2

1 we must of necessity

have q1t > q2

t . And thus for any given bt, the level of new bond issue required to bal-

ance the government’s budget in a no-default equilibrium must be such that b1t+1 < b2

t+1.

26

And consequently from Eq. 10 we must also have that cnt+1(π

11, π2) > cn

t+1(π21, π2) since

τnt+1(π

11, π2) < τn

t+1(π21, π2). Therefore,

V ng (π1

1, π2) = u(ct) + βEtu[cnt+1(π

11, π2)]

≥ u(ct) + βEtu[cnt+1(π

21, π2)]

= V ng (π2

1, π2)

7.3 Proof of Theorem 3.2

Consider two levels of outstanding debt stock that have become due in the first period,

given by b1t < b2

t . Ceteris paribus, this implies that the level of new bond issue required to

balance the government’s fiscal budget in a no-default equilibrium in the first period must

be such that b1t+1 < b2

t+1. Then from Eq. 10 we know that cnt+1(b

1t+1) > cn

t+1(b2t+1) since

τnt+1(b

1t+1) < τn

t+1(b2t+1). Hence must we have that V n

g (b1t+1) > V n

g (b2t+1) and consequently

π11 < π2

1.

27

References

Aguiar, M. and Gopinath, G. (2004). Defaultable debts, interets rates and the current account.

Forthcoming in the Journal of International Economics.

Aizenman, J., Gavin, M., and Housmann, R. (2000). Optimal tax and debt policy with

endogenously imperfect creditworthiness. Journal of International Trade and Economic

Development, 9(4):367–395.

Bulow, J. and Rogoff, K. (1989). A constant recontracting model of sovereign debt. Journal

of Political Economy, 97(1):155–178.

Cline, W. R. (2003). Restoring economic growth in Argentina. World Bank Policy Research

Working Paper 3158.

Cole, H. and Kehoe, T. (2000). Self-fulfilling debt crises. Review of Economic Studies, 67:91–

11.

Drazen, A. (1998). Towards a political-economic theory of domestic debts. In Calvo, G. and

King, M., editors, The Debt Burden and its Consequences for Monetary Policy, volume 118,

pages 159–176, London. The International Economic Association, MacMillan.

Drazen, A. and Masson, P. R. (1994). Credibility of policies versus credibility of policymakers.

The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(3):735–754.

Eaton, J. and Gersovitz, M. (1981). Debt with the potential repudiation: Theoretical and

empirical analysis. Review of Economic Studies, 48:289–309.

Feenstra, R. C. (1986). Functional equivalence between liquidity costs and and utility of

money. Journal of Monetary Economics, 17:271–291.

Greenwood, J. (1983). Expectations, the exchange rate, and the current account. Journal of

Monetary Economics, 12:543–569.

IMF (2003). Argentina: Request for Stand-By Arrangement and request for extension of

Repurchase Expectations. Technical Report No. 03/392, International Monetary Fund,

Washington, D.C.

28

Irwin, G. (2004). Currency boards and currency crises. Oxford Economics Papers, 56:64–87.

Jeanne, O. (1997). Are currency crises self-fulfilling? Journal of International Economics,

43:263–286.

Jeanne, O. and Masson, P. (2000). Currency crises, sunspots and markov-switching regimes.

Journal of International Economics, 50:327–350.

Komulaninen, T. (2004). Essays on Financial Crises in Emerging Markets. PhD thesis, Kurku

School of Economics and Business Administration, Helsinki.

Marshall, D. A. (1992). Inflation and asset returns in a monetary economy. The Journal of

Finance, 47(4):1315–1342.

Mulraine, M. L. B. (2004). An analysis of the 2002 Argentine currency crisis. University of

Toronto, Mimeo.

Obstfeld, M. (1995). Models of currency crises with self-fulfilling features. European Economic

Review, 40:1037–1047.

Rebelo, S. and Vegh, C. A. (2002). When is it optimal to abandon a fixed exchange rate.

Mimeo.

Walsh, C. E. (2003). Monetary Theory and Policy. The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts,

2nd edition.

Yue, V. Z. (2005). Sovereign default and debt renegotiation. New York University, Mimeo.

29

Table 1: Parameter Values Used:

Parameters: Definitions:

β = 0.962 Constant annual discount factor

r∗t = 0.040 Risk-free world interest rate

τ = 0.237 Constant tax rate

g = 0.250 Annual government expenditure

η = 0.92 One minus the endowment loss

σ = 2.000 Coefficient of Risk aversion

φ = 0.015 Tax policy adjustment loss

ε = 0.0014 Transaction cost parameter

30

Figure 1: First Period Consumption Level

00.2

0.40.6

0.81

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

10.78

0.79

0.8

0.81

0.82

0.83

0.84

0.85

0.86

Expected Probability of FloatExpected Probability of Default

First P

eriod C

onsum

ption

31

Figure 2: Actual probability of Default

00.2

0.40.6

0.81

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

Expected Probability of FloatExpected Probability of Default

Actu

al P

robability o

f D

efa

ult

32

Figure 3: Equilibrium Probability of a Default

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

0.5

1Benchmark

Expected Default Probability

De

fau

lt P

rob

ab

ility

45°−lineProbability

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

0.5

1Model I

Expected Default Probability

De

fau

lt P

rob

ab

ility

45°−lineProbability

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

0.5

1Model II

Expected Default Probability

De

fau

lt P

rob

ab

ility

45°−lineProbability

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

0.5

1Model III

Expected Default Probability

De

fau

lt P

rob

ab

ility

45°−lineProbability

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

0.5

1Model IV

Expected Default Probability

De

fau

lt P

rob

ab

ility

45°−lineProbability

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 10

0.5

1Model V

Expected Default Probability

De

fau

lt P

rob

ab

ility

45°−lineProbability

33

Figure 4: Equilibrium Probability of a Float

0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.120.78

0.8

0.82

0.84

0.86

0.88

0.9Model I

Output Loss

Pro

ba

bility o

f F

loa

t

← Benchmark

1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8

x 10−3

0.75

0.8

0.85

0.9

0.95Model III

Fixed Transaction Cost

Pro

ba

bility o

f F

loa

t

← Benchmark

0 0.005 0.01 0.015 0.020

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Model IV

Tax Adjustment Cost

Pro

ba

bility o

f F

loa

t

← Benchmark

0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25

0.65

0.7

0.75

0.8

0.85

0.9

0.95Model V

Opening Money Stock

Pro

ba

bility o

f F

loa

t

← Benchmark

34


Recommended