+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Chapter Objective:

Chapter Objective:

Date post: 22-Feb-2016
Category:
Upload: anja
View: 71 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
International Parity Relationships and Forecasting Foreign Exchange Rates. 6. Chapter Six. Chapter Objective: This chapter examines several key international parity relationships, such as interest rate parity and purchasing power parity. 6- 0. Chapter Outline. Interest Rate Parity - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
Popular Tags:
57
Chapter Objective: This chapter examines several key international parity relationships, such as interest rate parity and purchasing power parity. 6 Chapter Six International Parity Relationships and Forecasting Foreign Exchange Rates 6-1
Transcript
Page 1: Chapter Objective:

Chapter Objective:

This chapter examines several key international parity relationships, such as interest rate parity and purchasing power parity.

6Chapter Six

International Parity Relationships and Forecasting Foreign Exchange Rates

6-1

Page 2: Chapter Objective:

Chapter Outline Interest Rate Parity Purchasing Power Parity The Fisher Effects Forecasting Exchange Rates

Interest Rate Parity Covered Interest Arbitrage IRP and Exchange Rate Determination Reasons for Deviations from IRP

Purchasing Power Parity The Fisher Effects Forecasting Exchange Rates

Interest Rate Parity Purchasing Power Parity

PPP Deviations and the Real Exchange Rate Evidence on Purchasing Power Parity

The Fisher Effects Forecasting Exchange Rates

Interest Rate Parity Purchasing Power Parity The Fisher Effects Forecasting Exchange Rates

Interest Rate Parity Purchasing Power Parity The Fisher Effects Forecasting Exchange Rates

Efficient Market Approach Fundamental Approach Technical Approach Performance of the Forecasters

Interest Rate Parity Purchasing Power Parity The Fisher Effects Forecasting Exchange Rates

6-2

Page 3: Chapter Objective:

Interest Rate Parity Interest Rate Parity Defined Covered Interest Arbitrage Interest Rate Parity & Exchange Rate

Determination Reasons for Deviations from Interest Rate Parity

6-3

Page 4: Chapter Objective:

…almost all of the time!

Interest Rate Parity Defined IRP is an “no arbitrage” condition. If IRP did not hold, then it would be possible for

an astute trader to make unlimited amounts of money exploiting the arbitrage opportunity.

Since we don’t typically observe persistent arbitrage conditions, we can safely assume that IRP holds.

6-4

Page 5: Chapter Objective:

S$/£ ×F$/£ = (1 + i£)(1 + i$)

Interest Rate Parity Carefully DefinedConsider alternative one-year investments for $100,000: 1. Invest in the U.S. at i$. Future value = $100,000 × (1 + i$)

2. Trade your $ for £ at the spot rate, invest $100,000/S$/£ in Britain at i£ while eliminating any exchange rate risk by selling the future value of the British investment forward.

S$/£

F$/£Future value = $100,000(1 + i£)×

S$/£

F$/£(1 + i£) × = (1 + i$)

Since these investments have the same risk, they must have the same future value (otherwise an arbitrage would exist)

6-5

Page 6: Chapter Objective:

IRP

Invest those pounds at i£

$1,000

S$/£

$1,000

Future Value =

Step 3: repatriate future value to the

U.S.A.

Since both of these investments have the same risk, they must have the same future value—otherwise an arbitrage would exist

Alternative 1: invest $1,000 at i$ $1,000×(1 + i$)

Alternative 2:Send your $ on a round trip to Britain Step 2:

$1,000S$/£

(1+ i£) × F$/£

$1,000S$/£

(1+ i£)

=

IRP

6-6

Page 7: Chapter Objective:

Interest Rate Parity Defined The scale of the project is unimportant

(1 + i$) F$/£

S$/£

× (1+ i£)=

$1,000×(1 + i$) $1,000

S$/£

(1+ i£) × F$/£=

6-7

Page 8: Chapter Objective:

Interest Rate Parity Defined

Formally,

IRP is sometimes approximated as

i$ – i¥ ≈S

F – S

1 + i$

1 + i¥ S$/¥

F$/¥=

6-8

Page 9: Chapter Objective:

Interest Rate Parity Carefully Defined Depending upon how you quote the exchange rate

(as $ per ¥ or ¥ per $) we have:

1 + i$

1 + i¥

S¥/$ F¥/$ =

1 + i$

1 + i¥ S$/¥

F$/¥=or

…so be a bit careful about that.

6-9

Page 10: Chapter Objective:

Interest Rate Parity Carefully Defined No matter how you quote the exchange rate ($ per ¥

or ¥ per $) to find a forward rate, increase the dollars by the dollar rate and the foreign currency by the foreign currency rate:

…be careful—it’s easy to get this wrong.

1 + i$

1 + i¥F$/¥ = S$/¥ ×or1 + i$

1 + i¥F¥/$ = S¥/$ ×

6-10

Page 11: Chapter Objective:

IRP and Covered Interest Arbitrage

If IRP failed to hold, an arbitrage would exist. It’s easiest to see this in the form of an example.

Consider the following set of foreign and domestic interest rates and spot and forward exchange rates.

Spot exchange rate S($/£) = $2.0000/£360-day forward rate F360($/£) = $2.0100/£

U.S. discount rate i$ = 3.00%

British discount rate i£ = 2.49%

6-11

Page 12: Chapter Objective:

IRP and Covered Interest Arbitrage

A trader with $1,000 could invest in the U.S. at 3.00%, in one year his investment will be worth

$1,030 = $1,000 (1+ i$) = $1,000 (1.03)Alternatively, this trader could 1. Exchange $1,000 for £500 at the prevailing spot rate, 2. Invest £500 for one year at i£ = 2.49%; earn £512.453. Translate £512.45 back into dollars at the forward rate

F360($/£) = $2.01/£, the £512.45 will be worth $1,030.

6-12

Page 13: Chapter Objective:

Arbitrage I

Invest £500 at i£ = 2.49%

$1,000

£500

£500 = $1,000×$2.00

£1

In one year £500 will be worth

£512.45 = £500 (1+ i£)

$1,030 = £512.45 ×£1

F£(360)

Step 3: repatriate to the U.S.A. at

F360($/£) = $2.01/£ Alternative 1:

invest $1,000 at 3%FV = $1,030

Alternative 2:buy pounds

Step 2:

£512.45

$1,030

6-13

Page 14: Chapter Objective:

Interest Rate Parity & Exchange Rate Determination

According to IRP only one 360-day forward rate, F360($/£), can exist. It must be the case that

F360($/£) = $2.01/£

Why?

If F360($/£) $2.01/£, an astute trader could make money with one of the following strategies:

6-14

Page 15: Chapter Objective:

Arbitrage Strategy I

If F360($/£) > $2.01/£ i. Borrow $1,000 at t = 0 at i$ = 3%.ii. Exchange $1,000 for £500 at the prevailing spot rate, (note that £500 = $1,000 ÷ $2/£) invest £500 at 2.49% (i£) for one year to achieve £512.45iii. Translate £512.45 back into dollars, if F360($/£) > $2.01/£, then £512.45 will be more than enough to repay your debt of $1,030.

6-15

Page 16: Chapter Objective:

Arbitrage I

Invest £500 at i£ = 2.49%

$1,000

£500

£500 = $1,000×$2.00

£1

In one year £500 will be worth

£512.45 = £500 (1+ i£)

$1,030 < £512.45 ×£1

F£(360)

Step 4: repatriate to the U.S.A.

If F£(360) > $2.01/£ , £512.45 will be more than enough to repay your dollar obligation of $1,030. The excess is your profit.

Step 1: borrow $1,000

Step 2:buy pounds

Step 3:

Step 5: Repay your dollar loan with $1,030.

£512.45

More than $1,030

6-16

Page 17: Chapter Objective:

Arbitrage Strategy II

If F360($/£) < $2.01/£

i. Borrow £500 at t = 0 at i£= 2.49% .

ii. Exchange £500 for $1,000 at the prevailing spot rate, invest $1,000 at 3% for one year to achieve $1,030.iii. Translate $1,030 back into pounds, if F360($/£) < $2.01/£, then $1,030 will be more than enough to repay your debt of £512.45.6-17

Page 18: Chapter Objective:

Arbitrage II

$1,000

£500

$1,000 = £500×£1

$2.00

In one year $1,000 will be worth $1,030 > £512.45 ×

£1F£(360)

Step 4: repatriate to

the U.K.

If F£(360) < $2.01/£ , $1,030 will be more than enough to repay your dollar obligation of £512.45. Keep the rest as profit.

Step 1: borrow £500

Step 2:buy dollars

Invest $1,000 at i$ = 3%

Step 3:Step 5: Repay

your pound loan with £512.45 .

$1,030

More than £512.45

6-18

Page 19: Chapter Objective:

IRP and Hedging Currency RiskYou are a U.S. importer of British woolens and have just ordered

next year’s inventory. Payment of £100M is due in one year.

IRP implies that there are two ways that you fix the cash outflow to a certain U.S. dollar amount:

a) Put yourself in a position that delivers £100M in one year—a long forward contract on the pound. You will pay (£100M)($2.01/£) = $201M in one year.

b) Form a money market hedge as shown below.

Spot exchange rate S($/£) = $2.00/£360-day forward rate F360($/£) = $2.01/£

U.S. discount rate i$ = 3.00%

British discount rate i£ = 2.49%

6-19

Page 20: Chapter Objective:

IRP and a Money Market Hedge

To form a money market hedge:1. Borrow $195,140,989.36 in the U.S.

(in one year you will owe $200,995,219.05).2. Translate $195,140,989.36 into pounds at the spot

rate S($/£) = $2/£ to receive £97,570,494.68 3. Invest £97,570,494.68 in the UK at i£ = 2.49% for

one year.4. In one year your investment will be worth £100

million—exactly enough to pay your supplier.6-20

Page 21: Chapter Objective:

Money Market HedgeWhere do the numbers come from? We owe our supplier £100

million in one year—so we know that we need to have an investment with a future value of £100 million. Since i£ = 2.49% we need to invest £97,570,494.68 at the start of the year.

How many dollars will it take to acquire £97,570,494.68at the start of the year if S($/£) = $2/£?

£97,570,494.68 = £100,000,000

1.0249

$195,140,989.36 = £97,570,494.68 × $2.00£1.00

6-21

Page 22: Chapter Objective:

Money Market Hedge This is the same idea as covered interest arbitrage. To hedge a foreign currency payable, buy a bunch

of that foreign currency today and sit on it. Buy the present value of the foreign currency payable

today. Invest that amount at the foreign rate. At maturity your investment will have grown enough to

cover your foreign currency payable.

6-22

Page 23: Chapter Objective:

Money Market Hedge: an Example

Step 6Pay supplier £100 million

Step 1Order Inventory; agree to pay supplier £100 in 1 year.

0 1Step 5Redeem £-denominated investment receive £100 million

Suppose that the spot dollar-pound exchange rate is $2.00/£ andi$ = 1%i£ = 4%

Step 4 Invest £96,153,846 at i£ = 4%

Step 3Buy £96,153,846 =at spot exchange rate.

£100,000,0001.04

Step 2Borrow $192,307,692 at i$ = 1%

Step 7Repay dollar loan with $194,230,769

($192,307,692 = £96,153,846×$2/£)

6-23

Page 24: Chapter Objective:

Another Money Market HedgeA U.S.–based importer of Italian bicycles

In one year owes €100,000 to an Italian supplier. The spot exchange rate is $1.50 = €1.00 The one-year interest rate in Italy is i€ = 4%

$1.50€1.00Dollar cost today = $144,230.77 = €96,153.85 ×

€100,0001.04€96,153.85 = Can hedge this payable by buying

today and investing €96,153.85 at 4% in Italy for one year.At maturity, he will have €100,000 = €96,153.85 × (1.04)

6-24

Page 25: Chapter Objective:

Another Money Market Hedge

$148,557.69 = $ 144,230,77 × (1.03)

With this money market hedge, we have redenominated a one-year €100,000 payable into a $144,230,77 payable due today.

If the U.S. interest rate is i$ = 3% we could borrow the $144,230,77 today and owe in one year

$148,557.69 =€100,000(1+ i€)T (1+ i$)T×S($/€)×

6-25

Page 26: Chapter Objective:

Generic Money Market Hedge: Step One

Suppose you want to hedge a payable in the amount of £y with a maturity of T:i. Borrow $x at t = 0 on a loan at a rate of i$ per year.

$x = S($/£)× £y

(1+ i£)T

0 T

$x –$x(1 + i$)TRepay the loan in T years

6-26

Page 27: Chapter Objective:

Generic Money Market Hedge: Step Two

at the prevailing spot rate.

£y(1+ i£)Tii. Exchange the borrowed $x for

Invest at i£ for the maturity of the payable. £y(1+ i£)T

At maturity, you will owe a $x(1 + i$)T. Your British investments will have grown to £y. This amount will service your payable and you will have no exposure to the pound.6-27

Page 28: Chapter Objective:

Generic Money Market Hedge

1. Calculate the present value of £y at i£

£y(1+ i£)T

2. Borrow the U.S. dollar value of receivable at the spot rate.

$x = S($/£)× £y(1+ i£)T

3. Exchange for £y(1+ i£)T

4. Invest at i£ for T years. £y(1+ i£)T

5. At maturity your pound sterling investment pays your receivable.

6. Repay your dollar-denominated loan with $x(1 + i$)T.6-28

Page 29: Chapter Objective:

Forward Premium It’s just the interest rate differential implied by

forward premium or discount. For example, suppose the € is appreciating from

S($/€) = 1.25 to F180($/€) = 1.30 The forward premium is given by:

F180($/€) – S($/€) S($/€) ×

360180f180,€v$ = =

$1.30 – $1.25$1.25 × 2 = 0.08

6-29

Page 30: Chapter Objective:

Reasons for Deviations from IRP

Transactions Costs The interest rate available to an arbitrageur for borrowing,

ib may exceed the rate he can lend at, il. There may be bid-ask spreads to overcome, Fb/Sa < F/S Thus

(Fb/Sa)(1 + i¥l) (1 + i¥

b) 0 Capital Controls

Governments sometimes restrict import and export of money through taxes or outright bans.

6-30

Page 31: Chapter Objective:

Transactions Costs Example Will an arbitrageur facing the following prices be

able to make money?  Borrowing Lending

$ 5.0% 4.50%€ 5.5% 5.0%  Bid Ask

Spot $1.42 = €1.00 $1.45 = €1,00Forward $1.415 = €1.00 $1.445 = €1.00

(1 + i$)(1 + i€)

F($/ €) = S($/ €) ×

(1+i$)b

(1+i€)l S0($/€)a

F1($/€) =b (1+i$)l

(1+i€)b S0($/€)b

F1($/€) =a

6-31

Page 32: Chapter Objective:

0 1IRP

No arbitrage forward bid price (for customer):Buy € at spot ask

$1m ×S0($/€)a

1

Step 2

Sell € at forward

bid

Step 4

$1m ×S0($/€)a

1 ×(1+i€)×l F1($/€) =b $1m×(1+i$)b

$1m $1m×(1+i$)bBorrow $1m at i$

Step 1b

invest € at i€l $1m ×S0($/€)a

1 ×(1+i€)lStep 3

(All transactions at retail prices.)

F1($/€) =b (1+i$)b

S0($/€)a

1 ×(1+i€)l

(1+i$)b

(1+i€)lS0($/€)a

=

= $1.4431/€

6-32

Page 33: Chapter Objective:

0 1

buy € at forward

ask

Step 4

sell €1m at spot bid

Step 2

€1m × S0($/€)b lend at i$

Step 3l

IRP€1m×(1+i€)b€1m × S0($/€) × (1+i$) ÷ F1($/€) =b l a

€1m×(1+i€)b€1m Step 1borrow €1m at i€b

(All transactions at retail prices.)

No arbitrage forward ask price:

F1($/€) =a (1+i$)l

(1+i€)bS0($/€)b

= $1.4065/€

€1m × S0($/€) × (1+i$) b l

6-33

Page 34: Chapter Objective:

At these forward bid and ask prices the customer is indifferent

between a forward market hedge and a money market hedge.

Why This Seems Confusing On the last two slides we found “no arbitrage”

Forward bid prices of $1.4431/€ and Forward ask prices of $1.4065/€

Normally the dealer sets the ask price above the bid—recall that this difference is his expected profit.

But the prices on the last two slides are the prices of indifference for the customer NOT the dealer.

6-34

Page 35: Chapter Objective:

Setting Dealer Forward Bid and Ask Dealer stands ready to be on opposite side of every trade

Dealer buys foreign currency at the bid price Dealer sells foreign currency at the ask price Dealer borrows (from customer) at the lending rates

Dealer lends to his customer at the borrowing rate

  Borrowing Lending

$ 5.0% 4.50%€ 5.5% 5.0%  Bid Ask

Spot $1.42 = €1.00 $1.45 = €1.00Forward $1.415 = €1.00 $1.445 = €1.00

l li$ = 4.5% and i€ = 5.0% b bi$ = 5.0%, i€ = 5.5%.

6-35

Page 36: Chapter Objective:

Setting Dealer Forward Bid PriceOur dealer is indifferent between buying euro today at spot bid price and buying euro in 1 year at forward bid price.

spot

bid He is willing to spend

$1m today and receive

$1m ×S0($/€)b

1

$1m

$1m ×S0($/€)b

1

Invest at i$b $1m×(1+i$)b

Invest at i€b

×(1+i€)b$1m ×S0($/€)b

1

forw

ard

bid

F1($/€) =b (1+i$)b

(1+i€)bS0($/€)b

He is also willing to buy at

6-36

Page 37: Chapter Objective:

Setting Dealer Forward Ask PriceOur dealer is indifferent between selling euro today at spot ask price and selling euro in 1 year at forward ask price.

Invest at i€b €1m×(1+i€)b

forw

ard

ask

F1($/€) =a (1+i$)b

(1+i€)bS0($/€)a

He is also willing to buy at

spot

ask He is willing to spend

€1m today and receive

€1m × S0($/€)b

€1m

€1m × S0($/€)b

Invest at i$b ×(1+i$)b€1m × S0($/€)b

6-37

Page 38: Chapter Objective:

Purchasing Power Parity Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate

Determination PPP Deviations and the Real Exchange Rate Evidence on PPP

6-38

Page 39: Chapter Objective:

Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate Determination The exchange rate between two currencies should

equal the ratio of the countries’ price levels:

S($/£) = P£

P$

S($/£) = P£

P$

£150$300

= = $2/£

For example, if an ounce of gold costs $300 in the U.S. and £150 in the U.K., then the price of one pound in terms of dollars should be:

6-39

Page 40: Chapter Objective:

Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate Determination Suppose the spot exchange rate is $1.25 = €1.00 If the inflation rate in the U.S. is expected to be

3% in the next year and 5% in the euro zone, Then the expected exchange rate in one year

should be $1.25×(1.03) = €1.00×(1.05)

F($/€) = $1.25×(1.03)€1.00×(1.05)

$1.23€1.00

=

6-40

Page 41: Chapter Objective:

Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rate Determination

The euro will trade at a 1.90% discount in the forward market:

$1.25€1.00

= F($/€)S($/€)

$1.25×(1.03)€1.00×(1.05) 1.03

1.051 + $

1 + €

= =

Relative PPP states that the rate of change in the exchange rate is equal to differences in the rates of inflation—roughly 2%6-41

Page 42: Chapter Objective:

Purchasing Power Parity and Interest Rate Parity Notice that our two big equations today equal

each other:

= = F($/€)S($/€)

1 + $

1 + €

PPP

1 + i€

1 + i$ =F($/€)S($/€)

IRP

6-42

Page 43: Chapter Objective:

Expected Rate of Change in Exchange Rate as Inflation Differential We could also reformulate

our equations as inflation or interest rate differentials:

= F($/€) – S($/€)

S($/€)1 + $

1 + €– 1 =

1 + $

1 + €–

1 + €

1 + €

= F($/€)S($/€)

1 + $

1 + €

= F($/€) – S($/€)

S($/€)$ – €

1 + €

E(e) = ≈ $ – €

6-43

Page 44: Chapter Objective:

Expected Rate of Change in Exchange Rate as Interest Rate Differential

= F($/€) – S($/€)

S($/€)i$ – i€

1 + i€E(e) = ≈ i$ – i€

6-44

Page 45: Chapter Objective:

Quick and Dirty Short Cut Given the difficulty in measuring expected

inflation, managers often use

≈ i$ – i€$ – €

6-45

Page 46: Chapter Objective:

Evidence on PPP PPP probably doesn’t hold precisely in the real

world for a variety of reasons. Haircuts cost 10 times as much in the developed world

as in the developing world. Film, on the other hand, is a highly standardized

commodity that is actively traded across borders. Shipping costs, as well as tariffs and quotas can lead to

deviations from PPP. PPP-determined exchange rates still provide a

valuable benchmark.

6-46

Page 47: Chapter Objective:

Approximate Equilibrium Exchange Rate Relationships

E($ – £)

≈ IRP≈ PPP

≈ FE ≈ FRPPP

≈ IFE ≈ FEP

SF – S

E(e)

(i$ – i¥)

6-47

Page 48: Chapter Objective:

The Exact Fisher Effects An increase (decrease) in the expected rate of inflation

will cause a proportionate increase (decrease) in the interest rate in the country.

For the U.S., the Fisher effect is written as:1 + i$ = (1 + $ ) × E(1 + $)

Where $ is the equilibrium expected “real” U.S. interest rateE($) is the expected rate of U.S. inflationi$ is the equilibrium expected nominal U.S. interest rate

6-48

Page 49: Chapter Objective:

International Fisher Effect

If the Fisher effect holds in the U.S. 1 + i$ = (1 + $ ) × E(1 + $)

and the Fisher effect holds in Japan,1 + i¥ = (1 + ¥ ) × E(1 + ¥)

and if the real rates are the same in each country$ = ¥

then we get the International Fisher Effect:

E(1 + ¥)E(1 + $)1 + i$

1 + i¥ =6-49

Page 50: Chapter Objective:

International Fisher Effect

If the International Fisher Effect holds,

then forward rate PPP holds:

E(1 + ¥)E(1 + $)1 + i$

1 + i¥ =

and if IRP also holds

1 + i$

1 + i¥

S¥/$ F¥/$ =

E(1 + ¥)E(1 + $)

=S¥/$ F¥/$

6-50

Page 51: Chapter Objective:

PPP

FRPPPFE

FEPIFE

Exact Equilibrium Exchange Rate Relationships

$/

$/ )(

¥

¥

SSE

$/

$/

¥

¥

SF

IRP

E(1 + ¥)E(1 + $)

1 + i$

1 + i¥

6-51

Page 52: Chapter Objective:

Forecasting Exchange Rates Efficient Markets Approach Fundamental Approach Technical Approach Performance of the Forecasters

6-52

Page 53: Chapter Objective:

Efficient Markets Approach Financial Markets are efficient if prices reflect all

available and relevant information. If this is so, exchange rates will only change when

new information arrives, thus:St = E[St+1]

andFt = E[St+1| It]

Predicting exchange rates using the efficient markets approach is affordable and is hard to beat.

6-53

Page 54: Chapter Objective:

Fundamental Approach Involves econometrics to develop models that use a

variety of explanatory variables. This involves three steps: step 1: Estimate the structural model. step 2: Estimate future parameter values. step 3: Use the model to develop forecasts.

The downside is that fundamental models do not work any better than the forward rate model or the random walk model.

6-54

Page 55: Chapter Objective:

Technical Approach Technical analysis looks for patterns in the past

behavior of exchange rates. Clearly it is based upon the premise that history

repeats itself. Thus it is at odds with the EMH

6-55

Page 56: Chapter Objective:

Performance of the Forecasters Forecasting is difficult, especially with regard to

the future. As a whole, forecasters cannot do a better job of

forecasting future exchange rates than the forward rate.

The founder of Forbes Magazine once said: “You can make more money selling financial advice than following it.”

6-56

Page 57: Chapter Objective:

End Chapter Six

6-57


Recommended