+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Economics and Electing the President

Economics and Electing the President

Date post: 23-Feb-2016
Category:
Upload: nathan
View: 44 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
Economics and Electing the President. The work of Ray Fair. http:// fairmodel.econ.yale.edu / http:// fairmodel.econ.yale.edu / vote2008 / index2.htm http:// fairmodel.econ.yale.edu / RAYFAIR /PDF/ 2006CHTM.HTM. Presidential Election Links http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/ - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
Popular Tags:
24
Economics and Electing the President
Transcript
Page 1: Economics and Electing the President

Economics and Electing the President

Page 3: Economics and Electing the President

Presidential Election Links 

http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/ http://www.apsanet.org/content_58382.cfm http://www.douglas-hibbs.com/Election2012/2012Election-MainPage.htm

Page 4: Economics and Electing the President

Economic Growth and the United States Presidency:Can You Evaluate the Players Without a Scorecard?

David J. BerriDepartment of Applied Economics

California State University – BakersfieldBakersfield, California 93311

[email protected]

James PeachP. O. Box 30001/ MSC 3CQDepartment of Economics

New Mexico State UniversityLas Cruces, NM 88003

[email protected]

Page 5: Economics and Electing the President

ABSTRACT In several academic papers and a book, Ray Fair (1978, 1996, 2002) has demonstrated a link between the state of the macroeconomy and the outcome of the Presidential Election in the United States. Beginning with the 1916 election, Fair’s model, based on such factors as economic growth, inflation, and incumbency, was able to accurately predict the winner in virtually every election. The purpose of this research is to take the Fair model back to the 19th century. The question we address is as follows: Can a version of Fair’s model accurately predict in an environment where economic data was not made available to the voter?

Page 6: Economics and Electing the President

LOUIS BEAN (1948) HOW TO PREDICT ELECTIONS “Business depressions played a powerful role in throwing the Republicans out of office in 1874, after 1908, and in 1932, and they had exactly the same influence in ousting Democrats after the panic of 1858 and during the economic setbacks of 1894 and 1920.”

“Harding in 1920, McKinley in 1896, and Cleveland in 1884 were also depression-made presidents. Had the deciding electoral vote been cast for the candidate who had the majority of the popular vote in 1876, Tilden too, would have been a depression-made President.”

Page 7: Economics and Electing the President

THE WORK OF RAY FAIR Fair, Ray C. 1978. “The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for President.” The Review of Economics and Statistics (Vol. LX, No. 2):159-173 May 1978.

Fair, Ray C. 1978. “The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for President: 1980 Results.” The Review of Economics and Statistics (Vol. 64, No. 2):322-25 May 1978.

Fair, Ray. C. 1996. “Econometrics and Presidential Elections.” Journal of Economic Perspectives (Vol. 10, No 3):89-102 (Summer 1996).

Fair, Ray C. 2002. “The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for President: 2000 Update.” http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/RAYFAIR/PDF/2002DHTM Downloaded Feb 2, 2006.

Fair, Ray C. 2002. Predicting Presidential Elections and other things. Stanford: Stanford Business Books.

Page 8: Economics and Electing the President

A FAIR MODELVOTE= a1 + a2GROWTH+ a3INFLATION +

a4PARTY + a5PERSON +

a6DURATION + a7GOODNEWS + ε

Page 9: Economics and Electing the President

DEFINING THE VARIABLES EMPLOYEDHTTP://FAIRMODEL.ECON.YALE.EDU/RAYFAIR/PDF/2002DHTM.HTM

VOTE = Incumbent share of the two-party presidential vote.

GROWTH = annual growth rate of real per capita GDP in the first three quarters of the election year.

INFLATION = absolute value of the growth rate of the GDP deflator in the first 15 quarters of the administration (annual rate) except for 1920, 1944, and 1948, where the values are zero.

Page 10: Economics and Electing the President

DEFINING THE VARIABLES EMPLOYEDHTTP://FAIRMODEL.ECON.YALE.EDU/RAYFAIR/PDF/2002DHTM.HTM

PARTY = 1 if Democrats are in power, = -1 if Republicans are in power

PERSON = 1 if the president is running, = 0 otherwise DURATION = 0 if the incumbent party has been in power for one term, 1 if the incumbent party has been in power for two consecutive terms, 1.25 if the incumbent party has been in power for three consecutive terms, 1.50 for four consecutive terms, and so on.

WAR = 1 for the elections of 1920, 1944, and 1948 and 0 otherwise

GOODNEWS = number of quarters in the first 15 quarters of the administration in which the growth rate of real per capita GDP is greater than 3.2 percent at an annual rate except for 1920, 1944, and 1948, where the values are zero.

Page 11: Economics and Electing the President

Table One The Accuracy of the Fair Model

1916-2000

Year Incumbent Party

Candidate Challenger

Actual VOTE received by incumbent

Predicted VOTE received by incumbent Error

Actual Winner

Predicted Winner

1916 Wilson Hughes 51.7 50.9 -0.8 Wilson Wilson 1920 Cox Harding 36.1 39.2 3.1 Harding Harding 1924 Coolidge Davis 58.2 57.3 -1.0 Coolidge Coolidge 1928 Hoover Smith 58.8 57.6 -1.2 Hoover Hoover 1932 Hoover Roosevelt 40.8 38.8 -2.1 Roosevelt Roosevelt 1936 Roosevelt Landon 62.5 63.8 1.4 Roosevelt Roosevelt 1940 Roosevelt Willkie 55.0 55.7 0.7 Roosevelt Roosevelt 1944 Roosevelt Dewey 53.8 52.5 -1.2 Roosevelt Roosevelt 1948 Truman Dewey 52.4 50.5 -1.8 Truman Truman 1952 Stevenson Eisenhower 44.6 44.4 -0.2 Eisenhower Eisenhower 1956 Eisenhower Stevenson 57.8 57.3 -0.5 Eisenhower Eisenhower 1960 Nixon Kennedy 49.9 51.6 1.7 Kennedy Nixon 1964 L. Johnson Goldwater 61.3 61.1 -0.3 L. Johnson L. Johnson 1968 Humphrey Nixon 49.6 50.2 0.6 Nixon Humphrey 1972 Nixon McGovern 61.8 59.4 -2.4 Nixon Nixon 1976 Ford Carter 48.9 48.9 0.0 Carter Carter 1980 Carter Reagan 44.7 45.7 1.0 Reagan Reagan 1984 Reagan Mondale 59.2 62.0 2.9 Reagan Reagan 1988 G. Bush Dukakis 53.9 51.3 -2.6 G. Bush G. Bush 1992 G. Bush Clinton 46.5 51.7 5.1 Clinton G. Bush 1996 Clinton Dole 54.7 53.7 -1.0 Clinton Clinton 2000 Gore G.W. Bush 50.3 48.9 -1.3 G.W. Bush G.W. Bush

Source: http://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu/RAYFAIR/PDF/2002DHTM.HTM

Page 12: Economics and Electing the President

SUMMARIZING FAIR: 1916-2000 Only incorrect in three elections: 1960, 1964, 1992.

Average absolute error: 1.5 Results are driven by economic variables with no consideration of a candidate’s appearance, debating talents, advertisements, or general campaign skills.

Page 13: Economics and Electing the President

TAKING FAIR BACK TO 1824 New measures of growth and inflation are needed.

Louis Johnston and Samuel H. Williamson, "The Annual Real and Nominal GDP for the United States, 1789 - Present." Economic History Services, April 2002, URL : http://www.eh.net/hmit/gdp/

This data has been updated. Updated data did not change our general findings.

Page 14: Economics and Electing the President

THE MODELS TO BE ESTIMATEDModel 1 Original Fair Model (1916-2000)

Model 2

Fair Model with new measures of GROWTH and INFLATION

(1916-2000)

Model 3

Fair Model with new measures of GROWTH and INFLATION,

no GOODNEWS (1916-2000)

Model 4

Fair Model with new measures of GROWTH and INFLATION,

no GOODNEWS (1916-2004)

Model 5

Fair Model with new measures of GROWTH and INFLATION,

no GOODNEWS (1824-1912)

Model 6

Fair Model with new measures of GROWTH and INFLATION,

no GOODNEWS (1824-2004)

Page 15: Economics and Electing the President

Table Three Various Estimates of Fair’s Model

Dependent Variable is VOTE White Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Standard Errors & Covariance

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Sample: 1916-2000 1916-2000 1916-2000 1916-2004 1824-1912 1824-2004 GROWTH 0.691* 0.457* 0.409** 0.413** -0.135 0.342 (6.169) (3.526) (2.569) (2.649) (-0.560) (1.577) INFLATION -0.775* -0.808* -0.988* -0.943* 0.438 -0.191 (3.915) (4.132) (5.405) (5.051) (0.511) (0.731) PARTY -2.713* -2.054** -1.644*** -1.252 0.647 -0.594 (5.434) (2.644) (1.946) (1.363) (0.344) (0.580) PERSON 3.251*** 2.145 1.701 1.578 -0.372 1.705 (1.837) (1.007) (0.698) (0.663) (0.083) (0.625) DURATION -3.628** -4.238** -5.216** -4.519*** 1.414 -0.448 (2.517) (2.410) (2.315) (1.968) (0.611) (0.208) WAR 3.855 5.268 2.905 2.262 -1.881 -0.835 (1.213) (1.369) (1.102) (0.832) (0.102) (0.214) GOODNEWS 0.837** 0.539 (2.932) (1.238) INTERCEPT 49.607* 52.871* 57.769* 56.892 48.458 50.889 (19.550) (15.512) (18.169) (17.736) (10.618) (15.184) R-Square 0.923 0.845 0.828 0.769 0.093 0.116 Adjusted R-Square 0.885 0.767 0.759 0.683 -0.248 -0.020 F-Statistic 24.000* 10.888* 12.015* 8.883* 0.272 0.850 Observation 22 22 22 23 23 46

t-statistics in parenthesis below each coefficient. * - Significant at the 1% level ** - Significant at the 5% level *** - Significant at the 10% level

Page 16: Economics and Electing the President

Table Four The Accuracy of the Fair Model

1824-1912 Forecast Based on Model 3

Year Incumbent Party

Candidate Challenger

Actual VOTE received by incumbent

Predicted VOTE received by incumbent Error

Actual Winner

Predicted Winner

1824 Jackson J.Q. Adams 57.2 39.8 17.4 J.Q. Adams* J.Q. Adams 1828 J.Q. Adams Jackson 43.8 56.9 13.1 Jackson J.Q. Adams 1832 Jackson Clay 59.2 58.0 1.2 Jackson Jackson 1836 Van Buren W. Harrison 58.1 43.7 14.4 Van Buren W. Harrison 1840 Van Buren W. Harrison 47.0 51.4 4.4 W. Harrison Van Buren 1844 Clay Polk 49.3 58.6 9.4 Polk Clay 1848 Cass Taylor 47.3 53.5 6.2 Taylor Cass 1852 Scott Pierce 46.3 62.0 15.7 Pierce Scott 1856 Buchanan Fremont 57.8 55.2 2.6 Buchanan Buchanan 1860 Breckinridge Lincoln 31.2 56.4 25.2 Lincoln Breckinridge 1864 Lincoln McClellan 55.0 42.9 12.1 Lincoln McClellan 1868 Grant Seymour 52.7 48.5 4.2 Grant Seymour 1872 Grant Greeley 55.9 55.9 0.0 Grant Grant 1876 Hayes Tilden 48.5 50.3 1.8 Hayes* Hayes 1880 Garfield Hancock 50.0 50.0 0.2 Garfield Hancock 1884 Blaine Cleveland 49.9 45.1 4.8 Cleveland Cleveland 1888 Cleveland B. Harrison 50.4 59.1 8.7 B.Harrison* Cleveland 1892 B. Harrison Cleveland 48.3 61.2 13.0 Cleveland B. Harrison 1896 Bryan McKinley 47.8 53.7 5.9 McKinley Bryan 1900 McKinley Bryan 53.2 59.5 6.3 McKinley McKinley 1904 T. Roosevelt Parker 60.0 49.9 10.1 T. Roosevelt Parker 1908 Taft Bryan 54.5 46.8 7.6 Taft Bryan 1912 Taft/Roosevelt Wilson 54.7 50.6 4.1 Wilson* Taft-Roosevelt

* - did not win popular vote

Page 17: Economics and Electing the President

WHY DOES THE FAIR MODEL FAIR POORLY BEFORE 1916?

Economic data did not exist. U.S. economy not integrated. Federal government was not held responsible for the macroeconomy.

Non-economic issues were more important in the 19th century.

Page 18: Economics and Electing the President

Econometrics and Presidential Elections

Larry M. Bartels

Page 19: Economics and Electing the President

OVERVIEW OF THE FAIR MODEL One of the most interesting aspects of Fair's essay is

the unusually frank and detailed description it provides of the enormous amount of exploratory research underlying published analyses of aggregate election outcomes. What is the relevant sample period? Which economic variables matter? Measured over what time span? What does one do with third party votes, war years, or an unelected incumbent? In fewer than a dozen pages, Fair raises and resolves many such questions, as any data analyst must. In the process, he makes clear how much of what Leamer (1978) has referred to as “specification uncertainty” plagues this (or any other) statistical analysis of presidential election outcomes.

Page 20: Economics and Electing the President

CHOOSING A MODEL ….(Fair’s) choice of model specification

seems to have been guided by goodness-of-fit considerations rather than by a priori political or economic considerations. His data set begins in 1916 because “some experimentation . . . using observations prior to 1916" produced results that “were not as good.” Gerald Ford is sometimes counted as an incumbent and sometimes not, depending upon which treatment “improves the fit of the equation.” Revised economic data produced significant changes in several key coefficients, prompting renewed searching “to see which set of economic variables led to the best fit,” and so on.

Page 21: Economics and Electing the President

WHAT HAVE WE LEARNED? What most electoral scholars really care about is what the

relationship between economic conditions and election outcomes tells us about voting behavior and democratic accountability.

On that score, what have we learned, and what have we yet to learn?

The clearest and most significant implication of aggregate election analyses is that objective economic conditions -- not clever television ads, debate performances, or the other ephemera of day-to-day campaigning -- are the single most important influence upon an incumbent president's prospects for reelection.

Despite a good deal of uncertainty regarding the exact form of the relationship, the relevant time horizon, and the relative importance of specific economic indicators, there can be no doubt that presidential elections are, in significant part, referenda on the state of the economy.

Page 22: Economics and Electing the President

THREE KINDS OF VOTERS…

Page 23: Economics and Electing the President

My own thoughts…

Three voters in the election… Republicans (vote Republican) Democrates (vote Democrat) Independents

The only free agents are independents. These are voters who care so little, they don’t join a party. And these are the voters that matter.

Why the economy? It is the one issue that matters to the independent.

Page 24: Economics and Electing the President

Politics and football…

Some football coaches believe the run sets up the pass. Others think the pass sets up the run. Fans, though, don’t care. You win, you keep your job. You lose, you lose your job.

Applied to politics… some people believe in smaller government and low taxes. Others believe in more government to solve problems.

Independents, though, don’t care. The economy does well, you keep your job. If not, your fired. What the politician believes is simply not relevant.


Recommended