+ All Categories
Home > Documents > gap in TCE

gap in TCE

Date post: 14-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: divya-kapoor
View: 218 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 14

Transcript
  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    1/14

    *Corresponding author. Tel.:#358-5-6212612; fax:#358-

    5-621-2699.

    E-mail addresses: kirsimarja.blomqvist@lut." (K. Blomqvist),

    kalevi.kylaheiko@lut." (K. KylaKheiko), veli-matti.virolainen@

    lut." (V.M. Virolainen).

    Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14

    Filling a gap in traditional transaction cost economics:Towards transaction bene"ts-based analysis

    K. Blomqvist, K. KylaKheiko, V.-M. Virolainen*

    Telecom Business Research Center, Lappeenranta University of Technology, P.O. Box 20, FIN- 53851 Lappeenranta, Finland

    Department of Business Administration, Lappeenranta University of Technology, P.O. Box 20, FIN-53851 Lappeenranta, Finland

    Received 12 April 2000; accepted 10 August 2000

    Abstract

    This paper analyzes dyadic partnership formation between asymmetric buyers and specialized suppliers. In the "rst

    part of the paper di!erent economics of organization-based approaches are evaluated. Their basic implications

    concerning the rise of partnerships are derived. In the second part a dynamized transaction cost and bene"t model is

    introduced to analyze the most critical elements of a typical partnership decision. The "nal part is based on insights from

    practice and in-depth interviews among 12 specialized suppliers and their four large incumbent partners in the

    Information and Telecommunications Industry. 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Transaction costs and bene"ts; Theory of the "rm; Partnership; Supply management; Trust

    1. Posing the issue

    According to the founders of transaction cost

    economics (TCE), Coase [1] and Williamson [2],

    markets and vertical integration (or hierarchies) are

    the two main governance structures, out of which

    a "rm may choose the most e$cient one. Coase

    did not even mention the intermediate gover-

    nance structure between markets and hierar-chies, called hybrid by Williamson. We call these

    hybrid governance structures partnerships and

    interpret them as individual contracts between

    parties. The aim of the contract is, of course, to

    create the joint surplus through cooperation and

    share it in a way, which bene"ts both (all) the

    parties.

    Rapid changes in business environments are

    increasingly driving the formation of strategic part-

    nerships between companies in the world economy.

    Di!erent types of partnerships are a logical and

    timely response to intense and rapid changes ineconomic activities, technologies, and globalization

    of world markets [3]. Partnerships have gained

    much theoretical interest in strategic literature dur-

    ing the last 10 years. Despite the fact that Coase

    skipped them altogether modern economics of

    organization-related approaches have managed

    to shed light on some factors behind the rise

    of partnership-based governance structures. A

    recent stream of resource-based view, the know-

    ledge-based view, [4}6] analyzes organizational

    0925-5273/02/$- see front matter 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

    PII: S 0 9 2 5 -5 2 7 3 ( 0 0 ) 0 0 0 9 5 - 5

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    2/14

    Table 1

    Typology of di!erent explanations of inter-"rm partnerships [14,17]

    Focus Temporal dimension

    Static Dynamic

    Production & Cognition-based-'

    Transaction & management benexts

    A: Resource-based view based on static capabilities

    and given cognitive frames [15,38] added with [18]

    innovation-related transaction costs

    B: Dynamic capability view based on

    learning and changing cognitive frames

    [8,5]

    Exchange-based-'

    Transaction & managements costs

    C: Static Coasean [1] & Williamsonian [19]

    transaction cost economics

    D: Dynamic transaction cost

    economics (embryos launched by

    [20,9,39]

    capabilities and knowledge as a source for competi-

    tive advantage. The key organizational issue is

    whether to develop the needed competencies, capa-

    bilities and knowledge internally or whether it is

    rational to exploit and integrate external know-

    ledge. Knowledge-based competition leads us to

    the classic questions of the modern theories of the

    "rm concerning the crucial role of organizational

    boundaries. Unfortunately, these explanations are

    typically static and focused primarily on cost-based

    comparisons. Our contribution to this discussion

    will be the explication of the main sources of the

    governance bene"ts, which can be obtainedthrough di!erent kinds of inter-"rm contractual

    arrangements.

    2. On partnership explanations

    We start with a survey of some theoretical results

    obtained so far in economics-based literature. The

    rise of partnerships has been studied at least from

    two di!erent angles. The "rst one can be character-

    ized as the economics of organization-inspired con-tractual or governance approach, which in its

    explanations emphasizes either the Coasean trans-

    action costs or the ownership of non-contractible

    assets (i.e. the property rights school introduced by

    Grossman and Hart [7]). The alternative, more

    evolutionarily inspired perspective is based on the

    dynamic capability or knowledge-based approach

    [8,9], which, in turn, emphasizes the role of

    "rm-speci"c, rare, and hard-to-imitate routines,

    capabilities, learning and socially embedded tacit

    knowledge when creating and sustaining joint

    surpluses through partnerships.

    For those who want to get acquainted well with

    the basic premises and di!erences between these

    two approaches there are many quite recent meta-

    theoretical comparisons available (cf. [10}12]).

    Here we would like to pick up only one important

    position which arised from recent discussions,

    the integrationistic metatheoretical point of view

    strongly propagated by Foss [11] (cf. also [13]).

    According to this view, both the seemingly rival

    approaches can (should) be interpreted as the

    complements but not as substitutes. This view thatwe share has important implications as to the anal-

    ysis of inter-"rm arrangements.

    Following the integrationist research strategy we

    take seriously some parts of the knowledge-based

    criticism of the proponents of the dynamic capabil-

    ity view (e.g. [14}16]). To put it simply, these critics

    maintain that the governance approach at least

    partly neglects the production and cognition-related

    issues, such as genuinely bounded rationality and

    imperfect and disperse knowledge of agents,

    collective tacit know-how, radical uncertainty,and overemphasizes the exchange-related issues,

    such as market (in)e$ciency and incentives.

    We interpret the tone of this critical message

    so that the gap between production and ex-

    change has to be bridged by launching some

    additional explanatory items into the standard

    TCE framework.

    Table 1 outlines the main di!erences between the

    two main approaches mentioned above from the

    explanatory point of view. This typology is based on

    2 K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    3/14

    the insightful ideas introduced "rst by Winter [14]

    and worked out by KylaKheiko and Miettinen [17].

    The distinctions used are between (i) staticness and

    dynamics on the one hand and (ii) production andcognition-based and exchange-based categories on

    the other hand. In terms of these distinctions we

    can characterize the seemingly rival but actually

    complementary domains of theoretical explananda

    (i.e. the set of explained items) of di!erent

    approaches.

    Our main thesis will be that every comprehensive

    explanation of the emergence of various inter-xrm

    relationships has to be based on all the aspects repre-

    sented in Table 1. The largely neglected theoretical

    bridge between the production and the exchange-

    based focal points of Table 1 can be built by intro-

    ducing relevant concepts such as transaction

    benexts or transaction values (cf. [21]).

    3. Towards dynamized and extended governance

    cost minimizing model

    Next, we will introduce some basic concepts of

    the dynamic capability view (cell B in Table 1) in

    order to make sense of our forthcoming analysis

    which can be characterized as an attempt to com-bine all cells A}D and to use them as a common

    explanans set. We begin with learning mechanisms,

    the hallmarks of the dynamic capability view. They

    can best be analyzed in terms ofstatic and dynamic

    routines introduced by Nelson and Winter [22].

    Static routines replicate existing organizational and

    technological competencies. Through partial repli-

    cation there is room for adaptational adjustments

    by learning. Dynamic routines are routines through

    which the "rm can `learn by learninga and di!use

    generic scienti"c and engineering knowledge fromother "rms. The dynamic capability concept rests on

    dynamic routines and can be de"ned as `the capa-

    city of a xrm to renew, augment, and adapt its core

    competencies over timea [23].

    The dynamic capability view regards the "rm as

    an organization, which combines partly tacit and

    cumulative know-how (`technoa) with generic in-

    formation (`logya). Heterogeneity of capabilities im-

    plies that the boundaries of the "rm have to be

    interpreted as strategic devices when outlining

    a "rm's competitive strategy. To put it brie#y, it is

    a question of how to generate more value by using

    internally produced/ externally acquired capabili-

    ties and resources in the most e$cient way. In ouropinion, this message has to be imported into the

    static Coasean framework in order to make it more

    comprehensive for coping with the inter-xrm arrange-

    ment issues.

    Fig. 1 summarizes the basic #ows and determi-

    nants in our extended and dynamized governance

    framework. The "rm is viewed as a value chain

    consisting of many activities. They are all based on

    partly tacit and partly generic routines/capabilities.

    Some internal and external capabilities already

    exist (i.e. they are static), whereas some have to be

    developed through learning or knowledge transfer-

    ring or created through knowledge integration

    (these not yet existing ones are called dynamic).

    Some activities can be bought from other "rms (i.e.

    outsourced capabilities), whereas some are based

    upon internal capabilities. Outsourcing costs are

    called transaction costs (relating to search, planning,

    negotiating, monitoring, and enforcement) and the

    insourcing costs are called management costs (relat-

    ing to administration, control and monitoring as

    well as the costs of using low-powered bureaucratic

    incentives).Following the lead of Coase and Williamson we

    conclude that the main issue in our model is to "nd

    out such a governance structure, i.e. a combination

    of outsourced, networked and insourced transac-

    tions which economizes on the sum of production,

    transaction and management costs at the same time

    when the surplus value obtained through transac-

    tion and management bene"ts is maximizedas well.

    Next, we will launch the main determinants of

    di!erent cost and bene"t categories shown in Fig. 1.

    Williamson [2,19] explicated the followingdeterminants that give rise to (static) transaction

    costs: (i) bounded rationality, (ii) opportunism,

    (iii) information impactedness, (iv) frequency of

    transactions, and (v) asset speci"city. His most

    paradigmatic case was (and is) the so-called ex post

    hold-up problem caused by the dangerous triad of

    uncertainty, frequency and asset speci"city. When

    the assets are very speci"c it means that their value

    is much lower (or even zero), if they cannot be used

    in the joint transaction between the partners [10].

    K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14 3

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    4/14

    Fig. 1. Dynamic transaction and management costs and bene"ts.

    In such a situation there opens up an opportunityfor opportunistic ex post behavior for the non-in-

    vesting partner, who may threaten to stop the co-

    operation, unless he/she/they cannot have a greater

    share of the joint surplus [13]. A paradigmatic

    solution for this case is vertical integration.

    Later, Teece [18] introduced such concepts

    as complementary capabilities and appropriability

    regime. The former consists of external capabilities

    needed to complete a "rm's internal capabilities.

    The complementary external capabilities, which have

    to be outsourced, a!ect the bargaining situation themore, the more ine$cient are their markets. This

    implies higher transaction costs and, consequently,

    more integrated solutions. The appropriability cri-

    terion determines how e!ectively a "rm can protect

    its strategic knowledge from free rider imitators.

    The tightness of this regime depends upon legal

    protection and tacitness. The more tacit knowledge

    is, the lower are transaction costs and vice versa.

    Next, we have to introduce dynamics into the

    framework. The dynamic TC problem can be for-

    mulated as follows: the "rm has to decide, whetherit is more e$cient (i) to generate new and develop

    old internal capabilities through continuous learn-

    ing and R&D investments (`a conglomerate strat-

    egya) or (ii) to acquire external capabilities from the

    market (`a hollow "rm strategya) or (iii) to exploit

    economies of scale and scope through networking

    (`a partnership strategya).

    Henceforward, the costs of transferring capabili-

    ties over the "rm's boundaries are called dynamic

    governance costs. They can further be divided into

    dynamic transaction costs (i.e. persuading, negotiat-ing and teaching with the providers of external

    capabilities) and dynamic management costs, which

    consist of the costs of persuading, negotiating and

    teaching within the "rm of own when trying to

    create/develop a capability internally or persuad-

    ing, negotiating and teaching external partners

    when a "rm-made activity is tried to sell (cf. [20]).

    As an example of how to use these dynamic

    concepts we can take the "rm operating at the

    turbulent emerging phase of a new technological

    4 K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    5/14

    trajectory (e.g. telecommunications) where the role

    of tacit knowledge is high. This means that the

    appropriability regime is tighter than in the case of

    well-established mature trajectory (e.g. the paperand pulp industry). Following this logic, one can

    predict a tendency towards vertically more integ-

    rated inter-"rm arrangements as the technological

    trajectory becomes more stabilized because of de-

    creased technological uncertainty and increased

    standardization.

    Now, it is time to go brie#y into the governance

    benexts problematics (more about this in Section 5).

    A bit paradoxically traditional TCE literature

    totally neglects the issue of transaction, management

    or partnership benexts. This means that they impli-

    citly assume that these bene"ts are somehow inde-

    pendent of governance structures. Of course, this

    argument is not valid. There are always bene"ts,

    which basically depend on the very nature of the

    governance structure. Fig. 1 allows us now to intro-

    duce our "rst characterizations concerning them.

    When the "rm utilizes its own resources and

    capabilities it can e!ectively build on cumulative

    learning and exploit the economies of scope

    through learning. It can also utilize competence-

    enhancing innovations or exploit monopoly power

    over other "rms. They all are benexts related to thevertical integration strategy. We call them manage-

    ment orxrm-internal benexts.

    On the other hand, when the "rm uses the mar-

    ket option it can exploit high-power incentives

    through "erce competition, economies of scale

    through specialization, and utilize #exibility and

    variation generated through many alternative part-

    ners operating in open markets. From the property

    rights perspective this originally evolutionary view

    can be defended by referring to the fact that the

    market-related bene"ts arise basically, since`

    mar-kets are identixed with the right to bargain and, when

    necessary, to exit with the assets owned. This... pro-

    vides entrepreneurial incentivesa [10]. Through the

    market a "rm can also better cope with radical

    uncertainty and competence-destroying innova-

    tions. We call these market-related mechanisms

    transaction benexts. The usual distinction between

    staticness and dynamics is not necessary here, since

    bene"ts typically are generated only through

    dynamic processes. Hence, they are called dynamic.

    In order to clarify all the transaction and manage-

    ment-related categories we extend and modify Die-

    trich's [24] approach, which is based on two crucial

    distinctions. The "rst one is between static transac-tion costs (Cm) and static management costs (Cf),

    where C denotes `costsa and `m, fa denote `marketa

    and `"rm's internal organizationa, respectively. The

    second one deals with the distinction between dy-

    namic transaction benexts (Bm) and dynamic manage-

    ment benexts (Bf). Our own extensions dynamic

    transaction and management costs can be di!erenti-

    ated by using the asterisks (*:s). Our dynamized

    governance cost formulations are as follows:

    (1) Use pro-market option iw

    Bm!Cm!Cm*'Bf!Cf!Cf*or

    Bm!Bf'Cm#Cm*!Cf!Cf*

    (2) Use pro-integration option iw

    Bm!Cm!Cm*(Bf!Cf!Cf*

    or

    Bm!Bf(Cm#Cm*!Cf!Cf*,

    where

    Bm* dynamic transaction benexts, which are posit-

    ively correlated with the ability to exploit

    economies of scale, high-powered incentivesand #exibility. They also allow to generate

    more ideas through the market variation and

    to cope with competence-destroying innova-

    tions.

    Cm static transaction costs, which are positively

    correlated with opportunism, few partners

    available, asset or capability speci"city, in-

    ability to cope with parametric uncertainty,

    dependence on complementary assets

    holders, systemic nature of innovation, low

    appropriability, and organizational inertiaagainst newcomers.

    Cm* dynamic transaction costs related to persua-

    sion and learning costs with the providers of

    outsourced external capabilities.

    Bf* dynamic management bene"ts, which are pos-

    itively correlated with the ability to exploit

    monopoly power, asymmetric knowledge,

    economies of scope, and cumulative tacit

    know-how when facing competence-enhanc-

    ing innovations.

    K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14 5

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    6/14

    Cf static management costs, which are related to

    the costs of monitoring large bureaucracy

    and high sunken R&D costs.

    Cf* dynamic management costs relate to the costsof persuading, negotiating and teaching with-

    in the "rm when a new capability has to be

    generated. It also includes the inability to

    cope with radical uncertainty.

    Now, we are ready to use these implicit equa-

    tions (1) and (2) above when explaining the rise of

    inter-"rm partnerships in light of our approach-

    related explanatory categorization introduced in

    Table 1. The cost types Cm and Cf belong no doubt

    to the domain of the Coasean}Williamsonian basic

    model with some Teecean extras (i.e. cell C#some

    elements of A), Cm* and Cf* belong to the domain

    of until now relatively ill-developed dynamic trans-

    action cost economics (i.e. cell D), whereas, the

    dynamic bene"t functions Bm* and Bf* represent

    our own contribution i.e. they cover a combination

    of cells A and B.

    4. Paradigmatic explanations for emergence of

    partnerships

    In this section we shall put together our explana-

    tory categories (A, B, C, D) and our explanation

    functions (1 and 2) and introduce in terms of them

    some interesting paradigmatic explanations for the

    emergence of inter-"rm partnership relationships.

    First we will take cell C, which combines the

    exchange-based view with static temporal isolation,

    i.e. represents the most paradigmatic Coasean}

    Williamsonian transaction cost case. In this very

    aggregative framework, which is actually built for

    the analysis of the basic choice between the marketsand hierarchies, the rise of di!erent governance

    options can be interpreted as follows.

    Vertical integration is the best option, when

    (i) uncertainty, the danger of opportunism and

    complexity are high, (ii) asset speci"city is high and

    there are only few providers of complementary ca-

    pabilities, and (iii) trust between partners is lacking.

    The market option is preferred when (i) the de-

    grees of uncertainty and complexity are minor and

    the danger of opportunistic behavior is small,

    (ii) there are many potential partners available, and

    (iii) transactions do not need any speci"c investments.

    In this static TCE-oriented interpretation the

    partnership solutions can best be regarded asstrange hybrids between well-de"ned market and

    hierarchies. Intermediate governance structures are

    most preferable when there are determinants,

    which simultaneously speak both for insourcing

    (e.g. uncertainty, danger of opportunism, high asset

    speci"city) and for outsourcing (the need for high-

    powered incentives). A typical precondition for the

    emergence of networks is also the pursuit ofecono-

    mies of scale and scope at the same time, even if this

    dynamic extension can be imported only as an ad

    hoc relaxation into the static framework. These two

    important concepts actually belong to the domain

    of dynamic transaction/management cost, i.e. to

    cell D. In addition, trust and reciprocity among

    partners are badly needed to impede opportunism.

    The next step is to go to cell A, where Teecean

    transaction cost elements can be taken into account

    as well. Main additional elements here are the na-

    ture of innovation (systemic vs. autonomous), the

    role of complementary assets and the tightness of

    the appropriability regime. We can conclude that

    the partnership agreements will be looser (tighter),

    i.e. closer to market (vertical integration) solutions,if (i) innovation launched is autonomous (systemic)

    by nature and requires small (large) speci"c invest-

    ment, (ii) appropriability of new knowledge is tight

    (weak), thus implying no (great) danger of free rider

    imitators, and (iii) the markets of complementary

    capabilities are e$cient (ine$cient), thus fostering

    the pressures towards hold-up problems. Fig. 2

    illustrates the basic governance choice problem

    in terms of a `governance costa indicator or

    pendulum. The higher the management costs and

    the lower the transaction costs are, the more prefer-able is the market option and vice versa. Fig. 2 also

    shows how the boundaries of the "rm change

    subject to governance costs.

    Although all the results derived above grasp

    some important issues as to the rise of inter-"rm

    partnership solutions, they also leave some crucial

    elements out of the explanans (i.e. the set of

    explainers) and, consequently, out of the explanan-

    dum (i.e. the set of explained items) as well. Most of

    these omitted explainers can best be dealt with in

    6 K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    7/14

    Fig. 2. Dynamic transaction and management cost-based choice illustration.

    terms of static and dynamic governance bene"ts

    and their underlying mechanisms, i.e. by taking

    a step towards the union of cells A&B.

    5. On partnership-related bene5ts

    In this section we shall analyze how transac-

    tion and management bene"ts may give rise to

    inter-"rm partnerships. The necessary (but not suf-

    "cient) reason for a partnership is that the aggreg-

    ate level of quasi-rents derived from the joint

    production is higher than would be the sum of

    independent investments done by the parties alone.Let us start with a set-up where we have only two

    parties, say an incumbent buyer (B) and a small

    seller (S). Aggregate quasi-rents (QR) can now be

    measured as QR"

    expected capitalized value of the jointly controlled

    assets obtained in the partnership (i.e. the expected

    value of co-operation) and

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    8/14

    (b) This case, which is not that rare in the R&D

    context, refers to the issue where the joint sur-

    plus can be created only through melting by

    complementary skills, routines and capabilitiesof specialized partners (cf. modern biotech-

    nological "rms).

    (c) In the third case it is possible that the

    cooperative use of an asset x may increase the

    pay-o!generated through another asset y (the

    so-called supermodularity case).

    (d) The fourth case is related to the situation where

    there are cost advantages to be obtained

    through the economies of scope. This fosters the

    tendency towards more vertically integrated,

    tighter partnerships.

    (e) The "fth case is related to the situation where

    there are cost advantages to be obtained

    through the economies of scale or dynamic learn-

    ing-related externalities. They all strengthen the

    tendency towards more market-oriented and

    specialized partnerships.

    (f) The sixth case is related to the situation where

    the "rms can signalize through mutual coopera-

    tion that they trust each other. Trust decreases

    both the static and dynamic transaction costs,

    thus generating more market-oriented partner-

    ships. Trust-generating mechanisms eliminatethe fear for opportunistic behavior, which is the

    factor that compounds all other sources of

    transaction cost. In trustworthy conditions the

    parties can without the threat of getting held up

    to invest in dedicated or relation-speci"c assets.

    This, in turn, lowers production costs, raises pro-

    ductivity, improves quality, and reduces time to

    market. Here we see transaction bene"ts in action.

    The rise of trust-generating mechanisms (i.e. the

    change from non-cooperative to co-operativegame) can most easily be explained in terms of

    a simple game-theoretic exercise. Let us assume

    that there are two players who face the following

    pay-o! matrix: (i) if both the players trust each

    other and ful"ll the contract, they both will have

    EUR 5 million pro year, (ii) if only one partner

    ful"lls the contract, whereas the other breaks it, the

    breaker will have EUR 10 million against EUR

    1 million received by the loser during the "rst year,

    (iii) if both the players break the contract both will

    have EUR 2 million. In a static setting, which is

    typical for the TCE approach, there is an incentive

    to cheat the partner and hope that he ful"lls his

    own part of the contract. If there is no loyalty andtrust between the partners, the equilibrium will be

    the non-cooperative prisoners+ dilemma outcome (2,

    2) where both will face the worse situation than in

    the cooperative equilibrium (5, 5).

    If we now put this extremely simple game into

    the dynamic framework we will see that trust-based

    cooperation is the most rational outcome. Let us

    assume that both the players are playing the tit for

    tat-strategy and no one knows how long the game

    will last. In such a set-up it is easiest to think that

    the game will last forever, which means that you

    can use a simple perpetual discount rate factor

    when calculating the expected net present values of

    non-cooperative and cooperative strategies. If the

    real rate of interest is assumed to be 4%, the ex-

    pected NPV of perpetual non-cooperative strategy

    in the `tit for tata-game is as follows:

    (i) 10#2(1.04)\#2(1.04)\#2(1,04)\#2

    #2(1.04)\L"10#2(0.04)\"EUR 60 million.

    In the cooperative strategy alternative the expectedNPV can be counted as follows:

    (ii) 5#5(1.04)\#5(1.04)\#2#5(1,04)\L

    "5#5(0.04)\"EUR 130 million.

    Since EUR 130 million' EUR 60 million we can

    conclude that in the dynamic set-up of this particu-

    lar model there is a built-in tendency towards

    cooperative games, i.e. trustworthy relations. These

    results can be generalized when taking into accountthe values of cells and the rate of interest. The

    Section 6 will analyze further the role of trust in

    asymmetric partnerships typical in telecommunica-

    tions sector.

    Finally, we can introduce perhaps the most deci-

    sive piece of criticism coming from the dynamic

    capability camp against the contractual gover-

    nance camp. It deals with the inability to treat

    properly the genuine coordination problems, which

    are due to dispersed knowledge, radical uncertainty,

    8 K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    9/14

    Fig. 3. Bene"ts provided with di!erent governance structures.

    and bounded rationality. This criticism clearly goes

    further beyond the traditional issues of mitigating

    the e!ects of incentive con#icts [26].

    The common message of both the property rights

    and principal agency theories is that in the situ-

    ations where the Pareto criterion is too weak to

    bring to the cooperative equilibrium, which maxi-

    mizes the joint surplus, the partners should organ-

    ize the cooperation in a way which gives all the

    players incentives (e.g. bribes) enough to get them

    to the equilibrium with higher joint surplus. This

    simple incentive-alignment game can teach us

    much about di!erent ways to organize some sorts

    of incentive mitigating problems in the dynamic

    set-up, but we can go further. The point of theproponents of dynamic capability view is that this

    paradigmatic contractual game does not take into

    account the real cognitive limitations of players and

    gives therefore quite too naive and simple picture of

    real coordination problems faced by the "rms in

    real-life partnerships negotiations.

    The real issue is that all the players are genuinely

    boundedly rational and relevant knowledge about

    the structure of the game, payo! functions, poten-

    tial economies of scale and scope, etc., is more or

    less imperfect, partly non-existent and necessarilydispersed. Hence, genuine knowledge gaps, such as

    mistakes, accidents and surprises, cannot be ruled

    out ([26]). This again means that one cannot plan

    the rules of the game exactly but one has to rely

    much more on (i) markets as discovery mecha-

    nisms, (ii) alert entrepreneurs as catalysts of new

    combinations, and (iii) trust-generating mecha-

    nisms as vehicles to mitigate unsolvable (due to

    dispersed knowledge and unforeseen contingencies)

    interest con#icts.

    This radical dynamic capability view with empha-

    sis on cognitive limitations has its roots in Austrian

    economics, of course. One cannot help thinking

    when facing this criticism that the recent trend

    towards partnerships may actually be only a reac-

    tion against too centralized (integrated) and too

    planned hierarchies, which cannot cope with rad-

    ical uncertainty when facing turbulent time in not

    yet fully developed industries.

    One interesting answer to this challenge could be

    the evolutionary economics-basedview, which starts

    from the idea that in the situations of radical uncer-

    tainty it is most advisable to build on backward-

    looking routines, which may be changed through

    learning and surprises, and to organize the whole"rm structure on the capabilities based on them.

    We skip this issue now (cf. [13]). In Fig. 3 we

    summarize the list of bene"t-generating factors and

    mechanisms.

    The partnership enables parties to combine the

    bene"ts of economies of scale and scope. At its best

    it may yield many bene"ts of markets and hier-

    archy. The partnership is however challenging gov-

    ernance structure to manage. If parties are able to

    generate coordination mechanisms, e.g. trust they

    may be able to create a most e$cient solution withmajor joint surplus. It is, of course, quite evident

    that all the decisions concerning the choice between

    di!erent governance structure options are based on

    subjective estimates about the e!ects, which main

    transaction and management cost/bene"ts determi-

    nants will give rise to in the future. Since the e!ects

    are often hard or impossible to quantify (at least

    ex ante), the basic decisions have to be based on

    qualitative considerations about the relevance of

    di!erent determinants.

    K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14 9

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    10/14

    6. Role of trust as a mechanism for e7cient solution

    in telecommunications

    In the telecommunications both technologicaland market uncertainty are high. There is little time

    to learn or study the volatile markets or constantly

    emerging new technologies. Considerable rewards

    may be gained, yet the players face considerable

    risks. In such a turbulent business the players are

    forced to constant strategizing. Also, partnerships

    may have to be decided almost `overnighta. Players

    of this challenging game also know, that the

    `shadow-of-the-futurea might be surprisingly short,

    since the various alliances and consortiums are in

    the constant move. Due to the high volatility (un-

    certainty) and the involved great risks the role of

    trust is crucial. Trust is a necessary element in any

    cooperation [27] and an e$cient mechanism to

    manage risks.

    In high-trust relations "rms are better able to

    tolerate the inherent risk. Trust has been identi"ed

    among the key factors in technology partnership

    establishment and management [28]. Previous

    research on trust shows that by nature trust

    develops gradually and common future is a strong

    motivator for a trusting relationship [29]. In tele-

    communications the partnering "rms clearly needtrust, yet they have little chance to commit themsel-

    ves gradually to the relationship or experiment the

    values and goals of the other.

    In telecommunications partnerships between

    a resourceful large incumbent player and a special-

    ized supplier are common. We call these com-

    plementary relationships asymmetric partnerships.

    In this context asymmetry could be de"ned as

    `di!erence in skills, resources and power as well

    as management and culture of actorsa. Role of trust

    may be particularly important in asymmetric part-nerships, where the value addition is generated

    from specialized complementarities resulting in

    dependence and with inherent risks of hold-up and

    opportunism. If the relationship is based on

    co-specialized complementarities, the power bal-

    ance is more equal resulting in mutual dependence,

    which may counterbalance the need for trust.

    Asymmetry in the relationship sets additional chal-

    lenges for the creation of trust due to the dissimilar-

    ity and cultural distance of the parties. In this

    context trust may be de"ned as `an actor's expecta-

    tion of the other party's competence and goodwilla.

    Thus, both the competence (technical capabilities,

    skills and know-how) and the more abstract good-will which implies moral responsibility and positive

    intentions towards the other are included [30].

    Trusting parties are able to relax the various

    safeguarding measures (hostages, reviewing, in-

    formation gathering) and gain increased e$ciency.

    Among others Dodgson [31] notes that perhaps

    the greatest challenge in collaborative relationship

    management is production of trust.

    According to Spekman and Wilson [32] the abil-

    ity to establish and sustain similarvalues and norms

    and to build a set of congruent goals between the

    partners sets a base for a trusting relationship.

    Open communication, commitment and social/char-

    acter similarity are also commonly cited mecha-

    nisms for trust building. Personal trust has been

    seen as a mechanism for promoting organizational

    trustand subsequently enhancing economic perfor-

    mance of organizations [33]. Organizations devel-

    op routines and processes, which unify the behavior

    of their employees and the responses to external

    contacts. Individual members of the organization

    may set the standard for routines and processes by

    their example and by stressing homogeneousorganizational values promoting trust.

    Asymmetric partnerships in the telecommunica-

    tions are especially challenging for trust building.

    Social-psychological processes like trust develop

    slowly as a product of cumulative interactions (see

    e.g. [34]). In highly volatile telecommunications

    there is little time for partnership establishment and

    the asymmetry by nature demands open commun-

    ication, mutual adaptation and commitment for

    trust to emerge.

    7. Illustrations of the bene5ts in the

    telecommunications sector

    Telecommunications is one of the most turbulent

    industries in today's economy. Privatization,

    liberalization, consolidation and emerging new

    technologies re-shape the competitive landscape.

    Telecommunications is a good example of an in-

    dustry where technological discontinuities give rise

    10 K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    11/14

    Fig. 4. The contradictory forces in the development of complex systemic telecommunications software.

    to competence-destroying technological change

    forcing the incumbent large corporations to rethink

    their strategy and underlining assumptions. E.g.

    company core competencies need to be seen as

    dynamic capabilities, which successful companies

    renew and adjust in relation to the environmental

    needs. Incumbent large organizations may utilize

    and preserve their established competencies in, e.g.

    brand, reputation and commercializing services

    and products, but start-ups may be relatively better

    in innovation demanding completely new compet-

    encies (see [37]). In today's telecommunications the

    incumbent large players are looking for specialized

    suppliers to learn from them and to leverage tech-

    nology options provided by technology suppliers.

    Emerging new technologies also enable new busi-ness models, which the start-up ventures may be

    most agile to test and later experiment with more

    resourceful incumbent players.

    In the following, we illustrate the main bene"ts

    provided by di!erent governance structures in the

    telecommunications sector. Insight is based on

    in-depth interviews of 12 small and specialized

    software suppliers and their 4 large counterparts,

    incumbent players in the Information and Com-

    munications Technology industry. Interviews have

    been carried through as a part of the forthcomingPh.D. study on Trust in Asymmetric Technology

    Partnership Formation by one of the authors, Ms.

    Blomqvist. Key decision-makers have been identi-

    "ed and interviewed in lengthy interviews on their

    propensity to establish asymmetric partnerships

    and relevant factors (e.g. bene"ts, costs, com-

    plementarity, opportunism, risk and trust. In

    addition information from expert interviews and

    practical working experience has been bene"cial to

    our insight of empirical reality.

    Market benexts: In the market option the hold-up

    risks of speci"c partnerships are avoided. If the

    products, technologies and services needed are such

    that they can be purchased from the market the

    competition keeps the prices down. E.g. programming

    capacity may be purchased from the market. How-

    ever, it may be di$cult to "nd highly skilled labor

    for some of the most recent technologies, e.g. Java

    used in Mobile Internet, which may become

    a problem. The high boom in the Finnish telecom-

    munications sector has resulted in small "rms with

    good teams which are acquired also for capacity

    reasons. If the company is able to use the market

    option employee costs and costs for establishing

    and managing partnerships are saved. However,

    the demand is usually quite speci"c and theremay be only a small number of suitable suppliers

    available, giving rise to potential transaction

    costs.

    Firm-internal benexts: Coordination, control and

    ewective management should be easier to accom-

    plish within a hierarchy. In the telecommunications

    sector the software is often systemic, i.e. the cus-

    tomer is o!ered a systemic product consisting of

    di!erent layers and components, often provided by

    several specialized suppliers. Development of sys-

    temic software in a partnership is complex anddemands close collaboration. The complexity of

    systemic development would call for vertical gover-

    nance, i.e. hierarchy, yet the need for specialized

    know-how of several technologies calls for co-

    operation Fig. 4.

    Due to the high level of competition and the need

    for innovative and spear-edge product o!ering

    a partnership seems to be an accepted solution

    also in challenging systemic telecommunications

    software development.

    K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14 11

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    12/14

    In a hierarchy it is possible to build on existing

    knowledge and enjoy economies of scale in learn-

    ing. Some of the innovations are competence en-

    hancing making it possible to enter new businessareas. E.g. combining innovations and knowledge in

    mobile technologies, large-scale customer service

    and Internet makes it possible to o!er global servi-

    ces for M-Commerce (mobile electronic commerce).

    On the other hand, some generic innovations, e.g.

    platforms may be used in various business areas.

    Large organizations may also use their monopoly

    power to set standards, e.g. for operating systems or

    new concept development, e.g. mobile portals. They

    may also try to limit competitor access for certain

    business. If the large organization operates e$-

    ciently and focuses its e!orts, it may be able to

    launch new products faster. A quite common `not-

    invented-herea resistance common to technology

    partnerships may be avoided in the hierarchy, even

    if internal politics also play a role. Higher process

    and project quality may be reached without the need

    to adjust and educate external partners. Internal

    communication in a hierarchy may be e$cient yet

    the quality of the communication is dependent on the

    level of organizational trust. If the specialized sup-

    pliers operate alone, they are most probably faster

    to reach and implement decisions. Risk for opportun-istic behavior and unintended disclosure of informa-

    tion is less. Internal management costs of vertical

    hierarchy (e.g. costs for R & D and personnel devel-

    opment, support for the head o$ces, as well as the

    time the management uses to manage and control

    the internal venture) are ignored in the traditional

    transaction cost approach [35,36]. This may result

    in overly optimistic evaluation of the internal net

    bene"ts.

    Benexts from partnering: The partnering "rms are

    able to focus on core competencies and reach higherspecialization and ezciency. Leveraging external

    complementary competencies they are able to

    enjoy the economies of scale and scope at the same

    time. Partnerships may increase the yexibility and

    lower the riskinherent in new technologies and new

    projects by o!ering a technology window to new

    technologies. Asymmetric partnerships with com-

    plementary and diverse "rms may generate new

    innovative practices and processes. Learningis often

    cited as a major positive outcome of partnerships.

    Established partnerships are used in announce-

    ments for signalizing technological and market

    power. They also legitimize new entrants and

    emerging technologies. Partnerships and alliancesare very important tools when newly established

    telecommunication companies try to push their

    new technologies towards dominant design and

    industry standards.

    8. Concluding remarks

    Our study points out that partnership types of

    arrangements (hybrid organizations) emerge in

    businesses characterized by high volatile nature,

    high degree of uncertainty and high degree of asset

    speci"city. High degree of transaction frequency,

    mutual dependency, and a possibility to share risk

    and information encourage inter-organizational

    cooperation.

    It is obvious that a partnership is superior in

    certain conditions when compared with vertical

    integration or to the use of open markets. Positive

    net joint surplus is evident, if there are only a small

    number of players able to provide the needed tech-

    nologies, products and services. High risks inherent

    in technological development and the uncertaindirection of technological development (e.g. which

    technologies will become dominant designs and

    later industry standards) do not favor autonomous

    development. In search of high complementary

    value addition the asymmetric partnerships with

    specialized or co-specialized resources have gained

    popularity. The evolution and management of

    asymmetric technology partnerships is however

    very challenging. Partnership is an e$cient solu-

    tion only if it creates some extra value compared

    with markets and hierarchies. It can be concludedthat partnership is not a panacea, which can be

    transposed into any conditions. Transaction cost

    economics explains why possibly disappointing

    outcomes can arise from a partnership agreement.

    There may be problems with asymmetric in-

    formation and potential opportunism. We believe

    that inter-organizational trust may act as a

    mechanism providing an e$cient solution. Because

    of the extremely high volatility in the converg-

    ing telecommunications partnerships seem to have

    12 K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    13/14

    become increasingly as temporary arrangements.

    This volatility sets great challenges for trust build-

    ing. Trust-building mechanisms in this risky and

    turbulent business will be left for further research.

    References

    [1] R.H. Coase, The nature of the "rm, Economica 4 (1937)

    386}405.

    [2] O.E. Williamson, Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and

    Antitrust Implications, A Study in the Economics of Inter-

    nal Organization, Free Press, New York, 1975.

    [3] Y.L. Doz, G. Hamel, Alliance Advantage, The Art of

    Creating Value through Partnering, Harvard Business

    School Press, Boston, 1998.

    [4] M. Grant Robert, Toward a knowledge-based theory ofthe "rm, Strategic Management Journal 17 (1996)

    109}122.

    [5] D. Teece, Capturing value from knowledge assets: The new

    economy, markets for know-how, and intangible assets,

    California Management Review 40 (1998) 55}79.

    [6] L. Poppo, T. Zenger, Testing alternative theories of the

    "rm: transaction cost, knowledge-based, and measurement

    explanations for make-or-buy decisions, Information Ser-

    vices in Strategic Management Journal 19 (1998) 853}877.

    [7] S. Grossman, O. Hart, The costs and bene"ts of ownership:

    A theory of vertical integration, Journal of Political Econ-

    omy 94 (1986) 691}719.

    [8] D. Teece, G. Pisano, The dynamic capabilities of"rms: An

    introduction, Industrial and Corporate Change 3 (1994)

    537}556.

    [9] R.N. Langlois, N.J. Foss, Knowledge-based and gover-

    nance: The rebirth of production in the theory of organiza-

    tion, KYKLOS 52 (1999) 201}218.

    [10] B. HolmstroKm, J. Roberts, The boundaries of the "rm

    revisited, Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (1998)

    73}94.

    [11] N.J. Foss, Research in the strategic theory of the "rm:

    `Integrationisma and `Isolationisma, Journal of Manage-

    ment Studies 36 (1999) 725}755.

    [12] O.E. Williamson, Strategy research: Governance and com-

    petence perspectives, Strategic Management Journal 20

    (1999) 1087}1108.[13] K. KylaKheiko, Making sense of technology: Towards syn-

    thesis between neoclassical and evolutionary approaches,

    International Journal of Production Economics 56}57

    (1998) 319}332.

    [14] S. Winter, On Coase, competence, and the corporation,

    Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 4 (1988)

    181}197.

    [15] J.B. Barney, Firm resources and sustained competitive

    advantage, Journal of Management 17 (1991) 99}120.

    [16] B. Kogut, U. Zander, Knowledge of the "rm, combinative

    knowledge-based, and the replication of technology,

    Organization Science 3 (1992) 383}397.

    [17] K. KylaKheiko, A. Miettinen, Technology management and

    entrepreneurship, in: S. Birley, I. MacMillan (Eds.), Inter-

    national Entrepreneurship, Routledge, London, 1995,

    pp. 39}58.

    [18] D. Teece, Pro"ting from technological innovation,

    Research Policy 15 (1986) 285}305.

    [19] O.E. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capital-

    ism, Free Press, New York, 1985.

    [20] R.N. Langlois, Transaction-cost economics in real time,

    Industrial and Corporate Change 1 (1992) 99}127.

    [21] A. Madhok, S. Tallman, Resources, transactions, and

    rents: Managing value through inter-"rm collaborative

    relationships, Organization Science 9 (1998) 326}339.

    [22] R.R. Nelson, S.G. Winter, An Evolutionary Theory of

    Economic Change, Harvard University Press, Cambridge,

    MA, 1982.

    [23] D. Teece, G. Pisano, A. Shuen, Dynamic capabilities and

    strategic management, Strategic Management Journal 18(1997) 509}533.

    [24] M. Dietrich, Transaction Cost Economics and Beyond:

    Towards a New Economy of the Firm, Routledge, Lon-

    don, 1994.

    [25] V.-M. Virolainen, Motives, circumstances, and success fac-

    tors in partnership sourcing, Lappeenranta University of

    Technology, Research Papers No. 71, 1998.

    [26] N.J. Foss, The use of knowledge in "rms, Journal of

    Institutional Theoretical Economics 155 (2000) 458}486.

    [27] K.J. Arrow, The Limits of Organization, Norton, New

    York, 1974.

    [28] L. Ha kanson, Managing cooperative research and

    development: Partner selection and contract design,

    R & D Management 23 (4) (1993) 273}285.

    [29] A. Halinen, Exchange Relationships in Professional

    Services, A Study of Relationship Development in the

    Advertising Sector, Series A-6. Publications of the

    Turku School of Economics and Business Administration,

    Turku.

    [30] K. Blomqvist, The many faces of trust, Scandinavian Jour-

    nal of Management 13 (3) (1997) 271}286.

    [31] M. Dodgson, Technological collaboration and innovation,

    In: M. Dodgson, R. Rothwell (Eds.), The Handbook of

    Industrial Innovation, Edward Elgar Publishing, Alder-

    shot, pp. 285}291.

    [32] R.E. Spekman, D.T. Wilson, Managing strategic partner-

    ships: Towards and understanding of control mechanismsand their impact on partnership formation and

    maintenance, in: R. Fiocca, I. Snehota (Eds.), Research

    Developments in Industrial Marketing and Purchasing;

    Proceedings of the sixth IMP Conference, Graduate

    Business School of Bocconi University, Milan, September

    1990, pp. 1000}1015.

    [33] A. Zaheer, B. McEvily, V. Perrone, Does trust matter?

    Exploring the e!ects of interorganizational and interper-

    sonal trust on performance, Organization Science 9 (2)

    (1998) 141}159.

    [34] P.S. Ring, A.H. Van de Ven, Developmental Processes of

    Cooperative Interorganizational Relationships, Strategic

    K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14 13

  • 7/30/2019 gap in TCE

    14/14

    Management Research Center, University of Minnesota,

    Minneapolis, MN, 1993.

    [35] J.B. Quinn, F.G. Hilmer, Strategic outsourcing, Sloan

    Management Review 36 (1994) 43}55.

    [36] E.J. Englander, Technology and Oliver Williamson's

    transaction cost economics, Journal of Economic Behav-

    ior and Organization 10 (1988) 339}353.

    [37] G. Pisano, The R&D boundaries of the "rm, Administra-

    tive Science Quarterly 34 (1990) 153}176.

    [38] B. Wernerfelt, A resource-based view of the "rm, Strategic

    Management Journal 5 (1984) 171}180.

    [39] B. Nooteboom, Innovation and inter-"rm linkages:

    new implications for policy, Research Policy 28 (1999)

    793}805.

    14 K. Blomqvist et al. /Int. J. Production Economics 79 (2002) 1}14


Recommended