+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Gosnell Lecture Series Rochester Institute of Technology Dwindling U.S. Internal Migration: Evidence...

Gosnell Lecture Series Rochester Institute of Technology Dwindling U.S. Internal Migration: Evidence...

Date post: 26-Dec-2015
Category:
Upload: gwenda-murphy
View: 214 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
Popular Tags:
44
Dwindling U.S. Internal Migration: Evidence of a Spatial Equilibrium? prepared for presentation at the Gosnell Lecture Series Rochester Institute of Technology Department of Economics Rochester, NY 27 October, 2011 by Mark D. Partridge The Ohio State University Co-authors: Dan S. Rickman, Oklahoma State University M. Rose Olfert, University of Saskatchewan Kamar Ali, University of Lethbridge. 1
Transcript

1

Dwindling U.S. Internal Migration: Evidence of a Spatial Equilibrium?

prepared for presentation at theGosnell Lecture Series

Rochester Institute of TechnologyDepartment of Economics

Rochester, NY27 October, 2011

by

Mark D. Partridge The Ohio State University

Co-authors:Dan S. Rickman, Oklahoma State UniversityM. Rose Olfert, University of Saskatchewan

Kamar Ali, University of Lethbridge.

2

Introduction

• Long-standing high internal migration rates in US– Such migration reallocates labor to areas with high

productivity. • The pre 20th settlement of the U.S. and the industrialization pre WW II are

the most vivid examples.• Rural-urban migration related to farm/manufacturing realignment.

– Smoothes out regional shocks to labor demand (e.g., from differences in industry composition).

– Such ‘disequilibrium’ migration is often hailed as why US labor markets are flexible in responding to economic shocks compared to Europe (Obstfeld and Peri, 1998).

3

Intro—cont.• Demands shocks should be random, but US migration is very

persistent (Blanchard and Katz, 1992; Partridge and Rickman, 2003).

• The US also has a long history of ‘equilibrium’ migration that originates on the supply or household side—climate and landscape being the largest factors (Graves) – Relates to major debate on jobs vs. people (Greenwood et al., 1991)– e.g., amenity demand related to higher income & pop. aging,

technological innovations such as air conditioning (Rappaport, 2007; Chen and Rosenthal JUE (2008).

– Rappaport (2004) shows how equilibrium migration can persist for decades.

– Could be man-made amenities—e.g., Florida, 2002; Glaeser et al., 2001; and Adamson et al., 2004.

4

Introduction—cont.• Modeling takes place in a spatial equilibrium context.

In equilibrium, utility and profits are equalized across space.– Migration flows are a positive function of utility differentials

• The question is why does the U.S. has such persistent flows to ‘nice’ places? Would not forward-looking agents and markets eventually capitalize the effects of nice climate, income changes, and demographic shifts in wages & housing prices (Evans 1990)?– The US has experienced a long-term downward trend

in internal migration – Began in late 1980s and really accelerated post-2000. We do

not believe this is a housing bubble phenomenon.

5

Annual Gross Migration Rates, U.S. 1947-2008

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

5.0

6.0

7.0

Percent

Moved to diff county Moved to diff county diff state

Source: U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey.

6

19911992

19931994

19951996

19971998

19992001

20022003

20042005

20062007

20082009

0

0.002

0.004

0.006

0.008

0.01

0.012

Net Migration (Standard Deviation)

Figure 2: Standard Deviation of Annual State Net Migration as a Share of Initial Population

Source: U.S. Census Bureau Intercensal Population Estimates (http://www.census.gov/popest/estimates.html)

7

Intro—cont.

• Does diminished migration imply the U.S. has achieved a spatial equilibrium of roughly equal profits and utility across space?– There is still economic migration in the ‘flexible’ U.S

labor market, but site-specific factors such as amenities or distance to cities would have a much smaller influence—i.e., the decline of equilibrium migration with capitalization of their effects into wages and housing.

8

Intro Continued

• An alternative explanation is that there has been a decline in economic migration (only a slight decline in the standard deviation of economic shocks). – Superficially, the US labor market would be less flexible.– Take on a European flavor of less geographic mobility with

local labor demand shocks being satisfied by changes in local labor force participation and unemployment rates.

• Implications for policy interventions: place-based vs. people-based

9

Theoretical framework• In spatial equilibrium, indirect utility of residence (V)

should be equal to some level V across locations k (Partridge and Rickman, 1997; Glaeser 2007):

• V = V(.)k-Mk for all k,

• V is a function of wages, housing costs, and quality of life. • The overall net migration rate from location i to j (Net

Migij) during the adjustment in any time period depends on the differences in V over all time pds:

• Net Migij(t) = f(∑(Vj-Vi - Mij), – Net Mig is a positive function of utility differentials (Douglas,

1997)

10

Theoretical framework• In equilibrium, firm profits are also equalized across space

for every region j.

• Π = ΠJ

• Like movement of households, net movement of firms and establishments from region i to j are a positive function of the respective profit differential

• NET FIRMij = g(Πj- Πi)

• We assume this is roughly equalized over the long-run with the exception of responses to economic demand shocks.

• Bringing labor demand and supply together:Migkt = f(LDSHOCKk0, INDUSTRYko, AMENITYk0, URBANk0, DEMOGk0, .),

11

Empirical ImplementationBase Model Population Growth at the county level:

Population growth is measured more accurately than net migration and it includes immigrants who also would be affected by the spatial equilibrium.

α, φ, θ, ψ, and γ are coefficient vectors

Explanatory variables are generally measured in the initial period. Most key variables should be predetermined such as natural amenities.

σs represents the state fixed effects; so coefficient vectors reflect average county variation within states;

ε - the residual, assumed to be spatially correlated within BEA areas but not between them.

isi0i0i0i00)-i(t DEMOG ECON AMENITY GEOG Pop%

12

Explanatory Variables

•DEMAND SHOCK/ECON: using total employment growth would be endogenous.

•Most studies on say ‘jobs versus people’ would need to instrument for total employment using industry mix. In our case, we are not interested in the effects of employment growth per se, but the impact of a demand shock. Industry mix is a demand shock.

•We use Industry mix employment growth, calculated by multiplying each industry's national job growth (1990-2000 and 2000-2007) by the initial period industry shares in each county (Bartik, 1991; Blanchard and Katz, 1992; Bound and Holzer, 2000);

•∑i(ei/E)*gni,

•ei represents county employment in industry i, E is total county employment, and gni is the national growth rate in industry i.

13

Explanatory Variables• AMENITIES: a natural amenity scale constructed by U.S.

Department of Agriculture ERS: 1 = Low level of amenities, 4 = above average, 7 = High;

• proximity to Great Lakes, Oceans• GEOG variables: Distance to nearest Urban Center, Incremental

dist. to an MA, Incr. dist. MA> 250K, Incr. dist. to MA> 500K, Incr. dist. to MA>1.5m (representing distances to urban hierarchy)

• population of actual, surrounding counties & county area • DEMOG incl. 5 ethnicity vars, 4 education vars, % female, %

married, and % with a work disability, all measured in 1990 (2000).– Migration specialists have long pointed to the importance of

demographics—human capital and life cycle. However sorting of the young, in particular, causes us to be very cautious with these variables (especially the age distribution).

14

Data and Methodology• County level data dating back to 1980/90 to

assess the sources of population growth over two periods, 1990-2000 and 2000-2007 (pre-recession)

• Four samples, Non-metro, Rural, Small Metro (<250,000) and Large Metro (>250,000)

• Extensive sensitivity analysis and staged estimations to mitigate estimation problems associated with multicollinearity or the housing bubble.

15

Non-metro Small MA Large MA1990-2000

2000-2007

1990-2000

2000-2007

1990-2000

2000-2007

Industry Mix Empl. Growth Amenity2 dummy  Amenity3 dummy  Amenity4 dummy  Amenity5 dummy  Amenity6 dummy  Amenity7 dummy  County pop 1990/2000  Pop of nearest or actual UC 1990/2000

4.502***(3.26)0.176(0.90)0.268(1.33)

0.489**(2.34)

0.915***(3.89)

1.146***(3.63)

1.499***(4.40)

-1.7E-06(-1.10)4.1E-07(1.15)

-2.161**(-2.19)0.266(1.18)

0.446**(2.00)

0.520**(2.29)

0.764***(3.12)

0.835***(2.79)0.293(0.90)

6.0E-06***(4.31)

4.3E-07***(2.95)

6.881**(2.11)

0.745***(3.50)

0.789***(3.29)

0.715***(2.62)

1.062**(2.42)0.915*(1.91)0.644(1.02)

3.0E-10(0.00)

1.3E-06(1.34)

0.377(0.12)

0.570***(2.95)

0.487**(2.03)0.210(0.75)0.135(0.32)0.034(0.05)

-1.547**(-2.11)

-1.1E-07(-0.12)

2.7E-06***(3.28)

8.050***(2.69)

0.778**(2.56)

0.634**(2.32)

0.567**(2.15)0.417*(1.81)

0.561***(4.72)

(dropped)

-8.5E-08(-1.46)

4.2E-08*(1.65)

1.523(0.47)

1.528***(3.35)

1.235***(2.73)

1.030**(2.48)

1.223***(2.99)0.589*(1.67)

(dropped)

-1.1E-07(-1.13)2.5E-08(0.81)

Table 1: Dep. Variable: Population growth (%/year) U.S. counties

Notes: Robust t-statistics from STATA cluster command ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10%.

16

Non-metro Small MA Large MA1990-2000

2000-2007

1990-2000

2000-2007

1990-2000

2000-2007

Dist. nearest UC

Incr. dist. to a MA

Incr. dist. MA> 250K

Incr. dist. to MA> 500K

Incr. dist. to MA>1.5m

AmenitiesState fixed effectsDemog. vars 1990/2000

-0.010***(-8.22)

-0.004***(-5.60)

-0.003***(-5.60)

-0.002***(-2.85)

-0.001**(-2.56)

YYY

-0.008***(-8.40)

-0.003***(-5.73)

-0.002***(-4.62)

-0.002***(-3.83)

-0.001**(-2.31)

YYY

-0.0002(-0.08)

n.a.

-0.004***(-5.70)

-0.002**(-2.04)

-0.002*(-1.83)

YYY

-0.001(-0.22)

n.a. 

-0.003***(-3.02)

-0.003***(-2.62)-0.002*(-1.95)

YYY

0.007**(2.36)n.a.

 n.a.

 -0.002(-1.54)

0.00008(0.16)

YYY

0.001(0.24)n.a.

 n.a.

 -0.004**(-2.41)-0.002*(-1.66)

YYY

NR-squared

1,9700.522

1,9700.523

4160.604

4160.516

6410.642

6410.483

F-stats: All dist=0Inc dist to MA=0Amenity vars= 0

17.92***12.55***8.17***

18.04***11.48***8.76***

8.63***11.43***2.39**

3.27***4.36***5.67***

4.79***1.78

5.46***

4.33***5.61***3.49***

Table 1: Dep. Variable: Population growth (%/year) U.S. counties

Notes: Robust t-statistics from STATA cluster command ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10%.

17

Interpretation

• Industry Mix Employment growth effect (local growth potential based on industry composition, relative to sources of national growth)—a priori expectation positive, i.e., demand driven migration evident in the 1990-00 period.

• This effect is not statistically significant in the latter period for all FOUR subsamples!

• This appears to be a structural change in economic migration.

Table 2: Pop. Growth in U.S. counties: Impact at Mean ValuesNon-Metro Small MA Large MA

1990-2000

2000-2007

1990-2000

2000-2007

1990-2000

2000-2007

Average pop growth (%/year) 0.595 -0.092 1.266 0.747 1.544 1.094 Ind mix emp gr 1990-00/2000-07 Distance to nearest or actual UC Incremental dist to a metro Inc. dist to metro > 250,000 pop Inc. dist to metro > 500,000 pop Inc. dist to metro > 1.5 mil. pop County pop 1990/2000 Pop of nearest or actual MA1990/2000 County area (sq miles) Amenity2 dummy Amenity3 dummy Amenity4 dummy Amenity5 dummy Amenity6 dummy Amenity7 dummy Great lakes Pacific ocean Atlantic ocean

0.934-0.410-0.225-0.218-0.073-0.079-0.0380.0270.0430.0280.1090.1510.0760.0350.013-0.001-0.007-0.001

-0.127-0.326-0.182-0.133-0.074-0.0640.1470.0310.0380.0420.1820.1610.0640.0250.003-0.007-0.0010.007

1.445-0.004

n.a.-0.389-0.074-0.1200.0000.1800.0380.1130.2830.2530.0690.0400.008-0.007-0.0070.023

0.021-0.016

n.a.-0.235-0.108-0.141-0.0090.4200.0230.0860.1740.0740.0090.001-0.019-0.006-0.007-0.032

1.7300.198n.a.n.a.

-0.0580.009-0.0230.071-0.0140.0700.2680.1890.0330.030n.a.

-0.009-0.005-0.126

0.0850.029n.a.n.a.

-0.127-0.177-0.0330.048-0.0490.1380.5220.3440.0950.031n.a.

-0.017-0.022-0.134

N 1970 1970 416 416 641 641Notes: The table reports the regression coefficient reported in Table 1 multiplied by the variable mean.

19

Further Investigation: LF Part

Dep. Var.: (Empl/Pop18+)00/07 - (Empl/Pop18+)90/00

• Does positive (negative) local demand shocks (decline) generate a higher (lower) employment rate?– The industry mix variable and emp/pop are measured in the same

units.

– Industry Mix Growth variable is positive significant in both periods for all samples, i.e., we observe the expected supply response; But MUCH larger in latter period

• Since this supply response did not come from in-migration, we infer it must have been in the form of increased local (internal) labor force participation response

20

Non-metro Small MA Large MA1990-2000

2000-2007

1990-2000

2000-2007

1990-2000

2000-2007

Industry Mix Empl. Growth 

0.200***(4.41)

0.725***(9.65)

0.222***(3.03)

0.547***(5.10)

0.269***(2.95)

0.513***(4.00)

Table 3: Dep. Var.: Diff. in employment-pop (18+year) ratio U.S. counties

Notes: Robust t-statistics from STATA cluster command ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10%.

21

What about slack labor markets post-2000?

• Perhaps in slack labor markets, more of the labor demand shock could be satisfied by local labor supply.

• The 1990s had strong labor markets, but weaker post 2000. Does this explain our employment/pop results—i.e., it is a cyclical phenomenon when measured at the mean.

• We estimate a series of pop growth quartile regressions at 10, 25, 75, 90th percentiles. In both decades, the slack labor market hypothesis suggests industry mix would have a stronger impact in areas that are growing faster. – We show 75/25 difference in quantile regression results.

22

Non-metro Small MA Large MA

1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007

Ind mix emp growth rt. 1990-00/2000-07

.522(0.38)

1.22(1.05)

5.73(1.29)

0.92(0.15)

5.78(1.37)

7.70*(1.69)

N 1972 1972 416 416 641 641 .75 Pseudo R2 0.3471 0.3441 0.4506 0.4118 0.4663 0.4067 .25 Pseudo R2 0.3215 0.3560 0.3917 0.3267 0.4132 0.2719

Notes: The coefficients are the difference between the industry mix regression coefficients in a 75th percentile quantile regression model and the corresponding coefficient in the 25th percentile regression model. In parentheses are the bootstrapped t-statistics for the statistical significance between the two estimates using 250 repetitions.

Table 4: Diff. in 75-25 interquantile regression results

23

Other hypotheses• Demographics and super reduced form.

– Due to possible self-sorting we remove the demog variables.– Not shown, the results are basically the same.

• Home ownership and housing bubble. In the bubble, home ownership rates rose. Did this impede migration? – Partridge and Rickman (1997) and Oswald (1997) argue that home

ownership reduces out-migration due to selling ‘costs’. We also argue that it reduces in-migration due to a lower housing supply.

• When adding home ownership share to the model, it supports these migration expectations, though our key results are unchanged.

24

Other hypotheses• Armed forces. Pingle (2007) argues that a decline

in the size of the military and resulting decline in transfers reduced gross migration. Did this affect net migration?– We add the armed forces employment share variable

to the model.– While it has the expected negative coefficient, the

industry mix results are basically unchanged.

25

Table 5: Selected sensitivity analysis regression results

Panel A

Non-metro Small MA Large MA

1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007

Ind mix emp growth rt. 1990-00/2000-07

4.89***(3.58)

-2.08**(-2.11)

8.06***(2.60)

2.27(0.72)

8.89***(3.13)

3.90(1.24)

Armed Forces Emp Share 1990/2000

-0.045***(-2.72)

-0.024(-1.51)

-0.072***(-3.84)

-0.073***(-2.93)

-0.086***(-5.95)

-0.121***(-5.01)

N 1970 1970 416 416 641 641R2 0.526 0.524 0.630 0.536 0.668 0.520

26

Other hypotheses• Initial housing and labor market disequilibrium.

– Housing bubble.

• Regress for the initial period 1990 and 2000 log median housing price and median wage on quality and other site-specific characteristics (Clark et al., 2003; Partridge et al., 2010).

• Ln(median housing price) = βhXh + eh

• Ln(median wage) = βwXw + ew

• Use the residuals eh & ew as measures of initial ‘disequilibrium’ and place them in the base regression model. This allows us to assess if a frothy housing market affects our results.– We find that our results are unchanged for industry mix and that a initial

local housing bubble is positively associated with net migration. (also controlling for 1980 wages and housing prices)

27

Panel B

Non-metro Small MA Large MA

1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007

Ind mix emp growth rt. 1990-00/2000-07

5.28***(3.47)

-2.48**(-2.24)

7.72**(2.18)

0.61(0.18)

9.28***(2.88)

1.79(0.46)

Resids from log(avg. wage) 1990/2000

-0.078(-0.25)

0.40(1.19)

-0.17(-0.18)

1.22(1.08)

0.55(0.94)

1.88**(2.29)

Resids from log(avg. rent) 1990/2000

1.40***(4.55)

1.61***(5.49)

1.51**(2.55)

1.16(1.22)

1.08**(2.38)

0.32(0.36)

N 1970 1970 416 416 641 641R2 0.5326 0.5367 0.6107 0.5215 0.6470 0.4899

Table 5: Selected sensitivity analysis regression results

28

Other hypotheses

• Demographics– An aging population may alter migration patterns

• Yet, this is in the constant term and in the state fixed effects. Moreover, in terms of life cycle effects, it would alter how the amenity variables affect migration.

• Directly controlling for the age composition has endogeneity issues—i.e., the young move to growing places.

• When we control for age composition, the results are fairly similar. We take the results cautiously because of the self-sorting makes age composition endogenous.

29

Panel C

Non-metro Small MA Large MA

1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007Ind mix emp growth rt. 1990-00/2000-07

6.86***(5.38)

-0.77(-0.66)

8.37***(3.08)

2.35(0.77)

11.44***(4.40)

8.16**(2.34)

Pop share 7-17 -0.163***(-4.62)

-0.16***(-4.78)

-0.206*(-1.85)

-0.30***(-2.69)

-0.103(-0.96)

-0.50***(-4.00)

Pop share 18-24 -0.070**(-2.28)

-0.09***(-3.05)

-0.092(-1.14)

-0.117(-1.34)

0.017(0.25)

-0.296***(-3.17)

Pop share 25-54 -0.034(-1.12)

-0.12***(-3.95)

-0.102(-1.18)

-0.1448(-1.46)

0.093(1.29)

-0.240**(-2.06)

Pop share 55-59 -0.060(-1.19)

-0.08*(-1.82)

-0.292**(-2.04)

-0.308**(-2.02)

-0.41***(-3.57)

-0.583***(-5.70)

Pop share 60-64 0.071(1.40)

-0.054(-1.19)

-0.041(0.29)

-0.2051*(-1.65)

-0.177(-1.12)

-0.485***(-3.80)

Pop share 65+

-0.141***(-4.82)

-0.184***

(-6.86)-0.190**(-2.13)

-0.24**(-2.60)

-0.028(-0.40)

-0.354***(-3.62)

N 1970 1970 416 416 641 641R2 0.5636 0.5739 0.6402 0.5876 0.7014 0.5625

Table 5: Selected sensitivity analysis regression results

30

Further Investigation• Add occupation mix variable to assess whether mobility became

more linked with skill/occupation shocks, implying increased mobility across industries while staying in the same occupation.

– Statistically significant results suggest weak evidence of this being true post-2000, but not during the 1990s.

• Net-Migration—much like Pop. Chg.

– Industry Mix variable strongly positive in initial period, insignificant in the latter period all samples

– Modest reduction in Amenity influence between periods for Small and Large Metros

• Net migration models with international migration are also not qualitatively different

• Using in- and out-migration flows do not alter our conclusions.

31

Summary and Conclusions• Preliminary results suggest that one culprit of the decline in

migration may be a modest decline in amenity migration. Rural/urban migration trends continue as well.

• The major factor, however, appears to be a decline in economic migration due to differential local economic growth

• Until this decade, a major factor underlying migration was job related, but local labor force demand appears to be increasingly satisfied with local and nearby workers rather than new migrants

• We conclude that diminishing migration is not reflective of the U.S. reaching a spatial equilibrium. Rather there is a structural change in economic migration.

32

Conclusions• U.S. labor markets took on more of a European flavor with local

labor demand being satisfied with local labor supply.• Does this imply that the U.S. labor market is less flexible due to

less geographic mobility?• Perhaps not….• Technological change facilitates more information about other labor

markets but it also helps one find out about information about local job opportunities (much like unexpected NEG and transport results or internet is a complement to face-to-face interaction).

• There is evidence of more industry mobility (Kambourov and Manovskii, 2008).

• There is also more temporary and contingent workers.• Together, it may be less necessary to relocate for economic reasons.

Geographical mobility is being replaced with industry mobility. This needs to be addressed with micro data.

33

Thank-you

34

Appendix slides

Annual Gross Migration Rates, U.S. 1947-2008

-

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

12.0

14.0

16.0

18.0

20.0

22.0

Percent

Total moved Moved to diff county Moved to diff county diff state

Source: U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey.

36

1990-2000 period 2000-2007 periodNon-metro Rural Sm. MA Lg. MA Non-metro Rural Sm. MA Lg. MA

Pop growth 1990-00 and 2000-07

0.5950(1.08)

0.4776(1.10)

1.2661(1.12)

1.5442(1.36)

-0.0919(0.96)

-0.2795(0.95)

0.7472(1.07)

1.0945(1.52)

Chg in emp/pop. (18+) ratio 1990-00/2000-07

0.0165(0.05)

0.0173(0.05)

0.0191(0.03)

0.0153(0.03)

-0.0027(0.05)

-0.0003(0.06)

-0.0121(0.03)

-0.0257(0.03)

Ind mix emp gr 1990-00/2000-07

0.2075(0.04)

0.2095(0.04)

0.2100(0.03)

0.2149(0.02)

0.0588(0.03)

0.0617(0.03)

0.0564(0.03)

0.0561(0.02)

Distance to nearest or actual UC

41.07(36.52)

59.91(30.56)

16.85(17.00)

26.27(16.77)

41.07(36.52)

59.91(30.56)

16.85(17.00)

26.27(16.77)

Incremental dist to a metro 55.40(51.67)

43.47(49.93)

0.00(0.00)

2.33(7.37)

55.40(51.67)

43.47(49.93)

0.00(0.00)

2.33(7.37)

Inc. dist to metro > 250,000 pop

66.80(106.20)

76.02(115.19)

93.23(93.26)

0.00(0.00)

66.80(106.20)

76.02(115.19)

93.23(93.26)

0.00(0.00)

Inc. dist to metro > 500,000 pop

42.89(66.07)

45.32(68.95)

36.89(59.07)

36.29(73.34)

42.89(66.07)

45.32(68.95)

36.89(59.07)

36.29(73.34)

Inc. dist to metro > 1,500,000 pop

89.03(111.10)

83.45(106.24)

78.54(115.44)

99.37(139.88)

89.03(111.10)

83.45(106.24)

78.54(115.44)

99.37(139.88)

County pop 1990/2000 22442(20585)

13770(10401)

72161(64892)

270700(539956)

24441(22808)

14832(11427)

82750(76200)

308194(595249)

Pop of nearest or actual MA 1990/2000

65459(93944)

73970(113164)

133332(49192)

1486906(2726624)

72664(110160)

82460(132956)

151186(59500)

1681592(2997111)

% 1990(00) Pop. African American

7.7560(14.74)

7.1534(14.77)

8.9211(12.25)

11.0011(13.98)

7.8995(14.89)

7.3009(14.87)

8.8893(12.24)

11.2831(14.18)

% 1990(00) Pop. Native America

1.8192(6.72)

2.0982(7.66)

0.8659(2.67)

0.6514(1.64)

1.9445(7.06)

2.2666(8.09)

0.8963(2.63)

0.6623(1.49)

% 1990(00) Pop. Hispanic 4.3354(11.64)

4.2174(11.46)

3.7863(9.17)

4.8435(9.82)

5.9260(12.55)

5.5656(12.21)

5.7645(10.66)

7.0098(11.25)

% 1990(00) Pop. Asian 0.3159(0.43)

0.2164(0.27)

0.7911(1.16)

1.3257(2.30)

0.4241(0.46)

0.3173(0.31)

1.0180(1.28)

1.8556(2.93)

% 1990(00) Pop. Other origin 1.7779(4.84)

1.7162(4.85)

1.6347(3.95)

1.9858(4.06)

2.4443(4.88)

2.2584(4.71)

2.5950(4.98)

2.9430(4.72)

% 1990(00) High School Grad. 35.00(5.96)

35.25(5.82)

34.26(6.32)

32.47(6.07)

35.97(5.89)

36.40(5.59)

34.27(6.76)

31.49(7.00)

% 1990(00) Pop. 25+ Some College

15.65(4.38)

15.28(4.32)

17.10(4.41)

18.19(4.34)

20.04(4.52)

19.98(4.62)

20.86(3.99)

21.22(3.82)

% 1990(00) Pop. 25+ Assoc. Degree

5.15(2.20)

5.01(2.26)

5.56(1.96)

5.79(1.77)

5.47(2.05)

5.29(2.02)

5.97(1.86)

6.23(1.68)

% 1990(00) Pop. 25+ College Degr

11.75(4.73)

10.98(4.12)

14.83(6.98)

17.68(8.27)

14.32(5.64)

13.51(4.99)

18.01(8.04)

21.90(9.64)

% 1990(00) Pop. that is female 51.02(1.63)

50.95(1.65)

50.97(1.52)

51.05(1.60)

50.37(2.07)

50.25(2.18)

50.63(1.55)

50.80(1.45)

% 1990(00) Pop. married 59.92(5.91)

60.79(5.77)

58.03(5.91)

57.36(6.89)

58.14(5.15)

58.83(5.05)

56.95(5.29)

56.83(6.09)

% 1990(00) Pop. with a disability

10.05(3.05)

10.29(3.28)

9.11(2.30)

8.28(2.20)

12.25(3.33)

12.39(3.43)

11.50(3.01)

11.33(2.75)

N 1972 1300 416 641 1972 1300 416 641

Appendix Table 1: Descriptive Statistics, Mean and (Standard Deviation) for U.S. Counties, Selected Variables

37

Impact at one std. dev. Pop. Change ModelNon-metro Rural

1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007Average pop growth (%/year) 0.595 -0.092 0.478 -0.279Ind mix emp gr 1990-00/2000-07Distance to nearest or actual UCIncremental dist to a metroInc. dist to metro > 250,000 popInc. dist to metro > 500,000 popInc. dist to metro > 1,500,000 popCounty pop 1990/2000Pop of nearest or actual UC 1990/2000County area (sq miles)Amenity2 dummyAmenity3 dummyAmenity4 dummyAmenity5 dummyAmenity6 dummyAmenity7 dummyGreat lakesPacific oceanAtlantic ocean

0.159-0.365-0.210-0.346-0.112-0.099-0.0350.0380.0540.0640.1320.2260.2530.1970.139-0.009-0.074-0.004

-0.069-0.290-0.170-0.211-0.114-0.0790.1370.0470.0470.0970.2190.2400.2110.1430.027-0.040-0.0080.036

0.869-0.523-0.178-0.247-0.084-0.0960.1030.012-0.0260.0000.0170.0860.0790.0260.0090.000-0.004-0.002

-0.148-0.410-0.131-0.174-0.081-0.0760.3060.020-0.005-0.0060.0570.0620.0510.0140.002-0.002-0.0010.003

N 1970 1970 1300 1300

38

Impact at one std. dev. Pop. Change ModelSmall MA Large MA

1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007Average pop growth (%/year) 1.266 0.747 1.544 1.094Ind mix emp gr 1990-00/2000-07Distance to nearest or actual UCIncremental dist to a metroInc. dist to metro > 250,000 popInc. dist to metro > 500,000 popInc. dist to metro > 1,500,000 popCounty pop 1990/2000Pop of nearest or actual UC 1990/2000County area (sq miles)Amenity2 dummyAmenity3 dummyAmenity4 dummyAmenity5 dummyAmenity6 dummyAmenity7 dummyGreat lakesPacific oceanAtlantic ocean

0.190-0.004

n.a.-0.389-0.118-0.1760.0000.0590.0520.2670.3790.3420.2620.1860.070-0.033-0.0480.070

0.010-0.016

n.a.-0.235-0.173-0.208-0.0080.1470.0320.2040.2340.1000.0330.007-0.169-0.026-0.044-0.096

1.7300.198n.a.n.a.

-0.0580.009-0.0230.071-0.0140.0700.2680.1890.0330.030n.a.

-0.009-0.005-0.126

0.0850.029n.a.n.a.

-0.127-0.177-0.0330.048-0.0490.1380.5220.3440.0950.031n.a.

-0.017-0.022-0.134

N 416 416 641 641

39

Background cont’d.“Slump Creates Lack of Mobility for Americans,”

New York Times by Sam Roberts, April 23, 2009

“the number of people who changed residences declined to 35.2 million from March 2007 to March 2008, the lowest number since 1962, when the nation had 120 million fewer people.”

Refers to concern that “if job-related moves are getting suppressed and workers are not getting re-sorted to the jobs that best use their skills,” long term negative consequences.

Reasons for greater immobility: greater home ownership, two earner households, ageing (LF).

40

Theoretical Model cont’d.• Households in region i derive utility from

consumption (X), housing (H), and site-specific amenities (S).

• HH provide labour to the market for which they receive wages (w) with some probability of employment (e), and pay rents (r) for housing

• HHs in region i are located in a spatial environment such that they can access employment opportunities, built amenities and consumption goods in n other regions j by traversing Distance (Dij)

41

Theoretical Model cont’d.• HH and Firm expected conditions location i

– Indirect Utility Function:

Vi(wi, riH, ei, Si

H, DISTij, ·)

– Indirect profit function:

Πi(wi, rFi, mi, Si

F DISTij, ·)

• LR equilibrium requires HH and Firm re-locations, at rate α, to equalize expected utility and profits– HHNMi=αH

i(Vj-Vi) for any j; HH net migration

– FNMi= αFi(COSTj-COSTi) for any j; firm net migration

• Pop. Chg.i = f(initial conditions in i incl. DISTij)

42

Descriptive Statistics Average Annual

Population Growth (%)Average Chg in Empl/Pop

18+ ratio

1990-2000 2000-2007 1990-2000 2000-2007

Non-Metro 0.595 -0.092 0.0165 -0.0027

Rural 0.478 -0.279 0.0173 -0.0003

Small Metro 1.266 0.747 0.0191 -0.0121

Large Metro 1.544 1.094 0.0153 -0.0257

Phoenix

Salt Lake City

Provo-Orem

Cedar City

St. George

88 km

88 km58 km

146 km

132 km

278 km

43 km

321 km

156 km

ARIZONA

UTAH

Garfield county,Utah

Garfield County, a rural Utah county, ≈ 4,000 residents (1990). The nearest urban area is Cedar City (a MICRO) located 88kms away. The nearest MA is St. George (≈ 90,000 pop.), 146kms away, an incremental distance of 58kms (146-88). Nearest larger MA > 250K, which is Provo-Orem, UT (pop. of 377,000), is 278kms from Garfield County, incremental distance versus St. George is 132kms (278-146). The nearest MA > 500K, the next higher tier, Salt Lake City, UT (969,000 people). Salt Lake is 321kms from Garfield County, incremental distance of 43kms (321-278). Nearest MA > 1.5 million people, the next higher tier above Salt Lake, is Phoenix, AZ (3.25 million 1990 pop.). Phoenix is 477kms away from Garfield County, an incremental distance of 156kms (477-321).

Distance calculations

43

44

Casper

Laramie

Fort Collins

Denver-Aurora

Carboncounty

129km

129km

14km

143km

67km210km

72km

WYOMING

COLORADO

Representing the Urban HierarchyFor Carbon County, a rural Wyoming county (pop. 8,500) nearest urban area is Albany County (a MICRO), containing the city of Laramie, 129kms away. The nearest MA is Casper (67,000pop.), located 143kms away, an incremental distance of 14kms (143-129). Because Casper is a small MA, Carbon County will also be influenced by its remoteness from larger MA of at least 250K. Nearest of >250 is Ft. Collins, Colorado, (pop. 250,000) 210kms from Carbon County, but the incremental distance beyond Casper is 67kms (210-143). The nearest MA of at least 500K, the next tier, is Denver, Colorado (2.5 pop). Denver is 282kms away from Carbon County, an incremental distance of 72kms (282-210). Because Denver is already over 1.5 million population, no incremental distance to reach a MA of at least 1.5 million.


Recommended