+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

Date post: 04-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: quantanglement
View: 220 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 31

Transcript
  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    1/31

    How Urbanization Affects the Inequality in Developing Countries: A Critique of

    Kuznets Curve

    Cem yvat

    According to the Kuznetss U-curve theory, urbanization increases inequality in

    developing countries during the first phase of industrialization. This argument is based

    on to assumptions. !irstly, the increase in productivity is greater for the industrial

    population" secondly, inequality in urban areas is greater than or equal to inequality for

    rural areas. #oever, the Kuznetsian argument could be false for many cases including

    the Tur$ish case, in hich rural inequality as relatively higher due to the social

    structure of the country. Therefore, in many developing countries the relation beteen

    inequality and income may be negative or be only slightly positive for the first phase of

    industrialization.

    This paper aims to prove that% &'( The argument suggested by Kuznets may not

    e)plain real changes in income distribution for many cases including Tur$ey &*( The

    long-run fall in +ini coefficient in Tur$ey may be highly related to the migration process

    ithin the country.

    Intro!uctionIn developing countries, the growth process not only alters the level of output or

    technology, but also changes the economic relations and the social structure. The

    development process involves significant changes in the levels of income of individuals;

    however, a part of the society usually benefits relatively more from the rising incomes.

    Therefore, in many cases the development process changes the income distribution; the

    income of a specific part of the society increases relatively more compared to the rest of

    the society.

    The first stage of the development process is usually associated with

    industrialization. As a country industrializes; individuals in urban areas benefit from

    rising productivities and the gap between per capita incomes of urban and rural areas

    increases. The growing benefits in the urban areas also alter the structure within the

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    2/31

    society. Many individuals in rural areas decide to migrate to urban areas to take

    advantage of the industrialization and rising urban incomes.

    A part of the migration stream may be formed by lowerincome individuals that

    are mostly unskilled and illiterate. These individuals mostly have individual concerns and

    they mostly move to the informal urban sector for earning wages. The higher income

    individuals also migrate for e!ploiting the advantages of urban society; however, these

    individuals concern more about their family re"uirements and aim to generate income,

    education or remittances that could be useful for the whole family #$ipton, %&'(). In any

    case, urbanization preceded by industrialization changes economic structure and gains in

    the society. As the urbanization process alters the incomes of individuals, it will create

    significant changes in the income distribution both in the short and the long run.

    The impact of migration on ine"uality is e!plored by *uznets #%&++) in his A-

    article conomic /rowth and Income Ine"uality0, which forms a basis for *uznets1s

    inverted 2curve theory. In his article, *uznets shows how demographic changes

    followed by industrialization alter income distribution within a country. 3e should notice

    that in his theory, *uznets is only concerned about the one way relation from

    development to ine"uality, he never mentions anything on the impact of ine"uality on

    growth. In fact, *uznets #%&45) says that6 All we can say is that the une"ual distribution

    of income in the earlier decades in the presently developed countries did not prevent

    economic growth. 7ut8we cannot say that a somewhat or less #or more) une"ual size

    distribution might not have contributed to even faster growth.0. Therefore, our focus on

    this study will be on how development and urbanization affect the income distribution.

    The development process can change the overall ine"uality by affecting three

    factors. 9irstly, as the urban share increases, the urban ine"uality starts to make a greater

    contribution to overall ine"uality. :econdly, the industrialization could widen the urban

    rural gap; however, the impact of industrialization would be offset by factors like

    technological spillovers, changes in the terms of trade and rising land per capita. Thirdly,

    the development could change both within rural and urban ine"ualities.

    In *uznetsian framework, development may bring une"ual gains and the first

    phases of industrialization are associated with higher ine"uality. owever, in some cases

    the urbanization followed after the early stage of industrialization may have instant

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    3/31

    positive effects on ine"uality. This instant positive effect may even offset the

    une"ualizing effect of the early industrialization. Thus, the start of industrialization does

    not guarantee a rise in ine"uality.

    Development" urbanization an! the change of inequality in Kuznetsian framewor#

    The *uznetsian approach is considered as one of the most important approaches for

    e!plaining, how development affects ine"uality. According to *uznets #%&++),

    urbanization followed by industrialization is an important factor in the shift of ine"uality.

    *uznets says an invariable accomplishment of growth in developing countries is the

    shift away from agriculture, a process usually referred to as industrialization and

    urbanization0. Thus, *uznets sees industrialization and urbanization as processes that are

    mutually developing at the same time. *uznets claims that urbanization increases

    ine"uality in the first stages of industrialization and he makes two crucial assumptions for

    strengthening his claim6

    a) the average per capita income of the rural population is usually lower than that of the

    urban; b) ine"uality in the percentage shares within the distribution for the rural

    population is somewhat narrower than in that for the urban population

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    4/31

    The *uznetsian framework relies on the $ewis #%&+=) model that was outlined in

    $ewis1s classic article conomic >evelopment with 2nlimited :upplies of $abor0.

    $ewis claims that development is driven by rising profits and accumulation in the

    capitalist sector. The saving rates for the capitalist class are relatively higher compared to

    the working class, since the working class could only save for its essential e!penditures

    like housing, education etc. Therefore, according to $ewis, the amount of savings grows

    as the relative income of the capitalists rises. In his model, savings are realized as the

    ma?or source of capitalist accumulation, so $ewis concludes that the central fact of

    economic development is that the distribution of incomes is altered in favor of the saving

    class0.

    The capitalist group accumulating in $ewis1s conte!t is mainly the capitalist

    industrial class. $ewis argues that merchants use their profits mainly for speculation and

    peasants would prefer to spend his profits for enlarging his land, not his capital. @nly the

    class of industrialists reinvests its profit productively; only the industrialists have

    incentives towards using profits to create a bigger empire of bricks and steel0.

    $ewis argues that the subsistence sector, which is mostly associated with the

    agricultural sector, cannot stimulate development, since the subsistence sector cannot

    produce reproducible capital. >uring the development process, the incomes of capitalist

    industrialists will increase, whereas incomes in the subsistence agricultural sector stay

    relatively stagnant, unless the subsistence sectors start benefiting from the development

    of the capitalist sector. ventually, the emergence of development in the $ewis model is

    associated with higher urban ine"uality and a rising income gap between urban and rural

    areas. The development of the capitalist sector will be supported with the labor supplied

    by the subsistence agriculture sector, which will lead to urbanization as it is claimed by

    *uznets. As a result, the urban population grows and higher ine"uality will be e!pected

    at least in the first stage of $ewisian development.

    $ewis says the subsistence sector could be more productive, if the peasants start

    to imitate capitalist techni"ues by using new seeds and fertilizers or if they start to benefit

    from capitalist investments in irrigation, in transport facilities or in electricity. owever,

    in his statement $ewis does not say whether increase in productivity in the subsistence

    sector will be bigger or less than the increase in productivity in the capitalist sector. Thus,

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    5/31

    he does not imply anything about the changing income gap between the urban and rural

    sectors. e only argues that higher productivity of the subsistence sector will lead to

    higher real wages in the capitalist sector and reduce the capitalist surplus and

    accumulation. ence, $ewis focuses on the relationship between the development of

    subsistence sector and the income distribution within the capitalist sector.

    The *uznets process is depicted in some studies by using modeling. The model

    proposed by -obinson #%&4) claims that the *uznets process holds even if the rural

    ine"uality is greater than the urban ine"uality. owever, he assumes that both within

    rural and urban ine"ualities and ruralurban income gap are constant, while developing

    his model. -obinson1s assumption is not applicable for many cases; the changes that may

    occur in inter and intrasectoral ine"ualities could falsify -obinson1s model.

    Another model that e!plains the *uznets process is developed by Anand and

    *anbur #%&&5). Bonsistent with the *uznetsian approach, Anand and *anbur assume that

    population moves to the urban sector, where ine"uality is larger. The model decomposes

    the ine"uality into withinsector and betweensector component. Anand and *anbur first

    assume that means and the withingroup ine"ualities of the urban and rural sectors are

    constant and the change in ine"uality is occurring only due to population shifts. They

    show that the withinsector component should be increased due to the greater population

    in the more une"ual urban sector and therefore the betweensector ine"uality should be

    reduced for the 2 curve to be formed under their assumptions. owever, empirically they

    show that their assumptions do not hold and the model should allow the sectoral means

    and sectoral ine"ualities to shift over time. The model concludes that ine"uality changes

    not only due to the population shifts, but also due to the changes in sectoral means and

    within sectoral ine"ualities. This result is consistent with the *uznetsian approach that

    e!plains the mechanisms that reduces urban ine"uality. ence, e!plaining the changes in

    ine"uality merely by urbanization is not enough; the results of urbanization on both

    sectoral mean incomes and ine"ualities should also be e!plored.

    Urban$%ural Income &aps

    The urbanization changes the overall ine"uality in a country by raising the impact of

    urban ine"uality on the overall distribution. owever, the industrialization and

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    6/31

    urbanization processes can affect the overall ine"uality not only by shifting the sectoral

    shares, but also by changing the intra and intersectoral ine"ualities. As a country

    develops, the intersectoral ine"uality between the urban and rural sectors changes due to

    first and secondary effects of industrialization.

    According to *uznets #%&++), the early effects of industrialization could raise the

    income gap between the urban and rural sectors. In his A- article, *uznets #%&++)

    claims that6

    The relative difference in per capita income between the rural and urban populations

    does not necessarily drift downward in the process of economic growth6 indeed, there is

    some evidence to suggest that it is stable at best, and tends to widen because per capita

    productivity in urban pursuits increases more rapidly than in agriculture.0

    The intuition behind this argument could come from the $ewis model #%&+=). In

    $ewis model, the development is mainly driven by the industrial sector. owever, $ewis

    also e!amines the secondary effects of development on the subsistence sector #mainly

    agriculture). 9irstly, $ewis mentions that the subsistence sector could also increase its

    productivity by imitating the techni"ues in the capitalist sector. 9or e!ample, peasants

    could get new seeds or they could use fertilizers for raising their productivities. e also

    says that the subsistence sector could benefit from the capitalist investments like

    irrigation works, transport, and electricity.

    $ewis secondly claims that if the capitalist and subsistence sectors specialize in

    different products #like agriculture and industry), the urbanization could lead to greater

    demand and relative shortage of agricultural commodities. As a result, the agricultural

    output will not be enough to feed the industrial workers. The terms of trade will worsen

    for the industrial sector, which would partially close the urbanrural income gap. $ewis

    also mentions that the terms of trade effect might not be seen, if the capitalist sector

    invests on agriculture or the productivity in the subsistence sector increases significantly.

    -anis and 9ei1s #%&4%) arguments in their article The Theory of conomic

    >evelopment0 could be considered as a complement to $ewis model. In their study,

    -anis and 9ei claim that $ewis8has failed to present a satisfactory analysis of the

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    7/31

    subsistence or agricultural sector.0 Thus, they propose a more detailed analysis for

    e!amining the secondary effects of industrialization and urbanization on agriculture.

    In their model, -anis and 9ei #%&4%) claim that the economy could follow a

    balanced growth, in which time to time deviations are seen. As in the $ewis model, in the

    case of overinvestment in the industrial sector, the shortage of food could lead to

    deterioration of the terms of trade in the industrial sector and industrial wages will rise

    due to growing food prices. As a result of this, the industrial investments will be

    discouraged; hence, there will be more incentives to invest on agriculture. Thus, the

    actual growth path could return to the balanced growth path and the urbanrural income

    gaps could narrow down.

    The urbanization could also increase the income in rural areas through the

    remittances. The urban settlers can transfer money to their relatives, which could

    generate an e!tra income for the rural dwellers #$all, :elod and :halizi, (CC4).

    -emittances also create an e!tra economic activity in the rural sector, when the new

    urban settlers spent their income for investments like housing in their origins #>-,

    (CC&). Many studies show that remittances increase the level of education and improve

    health of origin families #7ecker, (CC). Improved human capital could also contribute to

    rural productivity positively.

    There are also studies that show how urbanization can change the ine"uality by

    altering the land per capita. In fact, many studies #:en, %&&4; /riffin, *han and Ickowitz,

    (CC() claim that the land productivity might be lower in small scale farms since family

    farms have advantages in monitoring and effort. owever, the migration of rural

    individuals could still increase the rural income per capita #7ourguignon and Morrisson,

    %&&'), although it might not lead to higher land productivity, as in the case of shift from

    small to large scale farming. In addition, urbanization might not lead to a transformation

    from small to large scale farming. The family farming structure could continue, only the

    family members that cultivate the land could be reduced due to the migration. In this

    case, it is more probable that the rural income per capita will increase with urbanization.

    :tiglitz #%&'() also focuses on increases in agricultural productivity; however, he

    makes an alternative interpretation by using his efficiency wage model. According to

    :tiglitz, the migration of a family member changes the marginal product of the other

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    8/31

    members that stay in the rural sector. If output is proportional to effort, e"ual share of

    output between many family members could reduce output by lowering incentives for

    supplying effort. This might cause a loss of efficiency in agricultural production. In such

    cases, the migration of an individual within the rural family could increase the efficiency

    by bringing better incentives to the peasants for supplying more effort. Therefore,

    migration process could close the urbanrural income gaps by not only increasing average

    rural incomes, but also by raising total productivity in the planted areas.

    'ithin Inequality

    In his article, *uznets #%&++) also claims that the ine"uality will decrease in the later

    stages of development. owever, unlike the studies mentioned above #-anis and 9ei ,

    %&4%; 7ourguignon and Morrisson, %&&'; :tiglitz, %&'(), *uznets focuses on the changes

    in urban ine"uality rather than the narrowing intersectoral income gap. e uses the long

    term effects of urbanization for making his analysis and perceives urbanization as a

    process that would reduce ine"uality in the long run.

    According to *uznets, raising ine"uality will be narrowed, mostly due to the

    declining ine"uality within the urban groups. *uznets claims that, within years the

    economic positions of new urban dwellers and their descendants improve. The social

    mobility e"ualizes economic differences, and hence ine"uality follows a declining path.

    The mechanism behind the social mobility is e!plained by *uznets. 9irstly, as the

    development process continues a larger share of the urban population becomes native0

    urban dweller. Thus, a larger proportion of population benefits from the advantages of the

    city life. :econdly, in democratic societies the growing political power of the lower

    income groups resulted in changing legislation and new policies that counteracts against

    the negative conse"uences of rapid industrialization and urbanization.

    Thirdly, the forces of freedom of individual opportunity0 enable development of

    new fields that bring opportunities for new entrepreneurs. Dew and profitable industries

    will be run by the new entrepreneurs, unless the descendants of upperincome groups do

    not shift to the new industries. owever, *uznets says that the successful great

    entrepreneurs of today are rarely sons of the great and successful entrepreneurs of

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    9/31

    yesterday0. Therefore, *uznets claims that the development of new industries stimulates

    social mobility by creating opportunities for different income groups.

    $astly, the improvement of the service sector reduces income ine"uality. The

    service sector is e!pected to grow as a result of the development process and rising />E.

    In the earlier stages of development, the proportion of workers in industrial sector

    increases as the proportion of workers in agriculture declines. owever, as economic

    growth continues the services sector starts to e!pand, while the agricultural sector

    continues to decline #:yr"uin, %&'').

    According to *uznets, the growth of the service sector decreases ine"uality for

    several reasons. 9irst, *uznets argues that service incomes are mostly earned due to the

    individual e!cellence; thus, the higher levels of service incomes are not necessarily

    pursued by the descendants of the wealthier individuals. *uznets also claims that the

    possibilities of rising income are limited for people who are already in highincome

    occupations. ence, incomes of the lowerincome workers in services are more likely to

    increase. Therefore, incomes are e!pected to be more e"ual within the services sector

    compared to industry.

    In summary, *uznets e!plains the change in income distribution as increasing in

    the first stage of development and declining in the later stages. 3ith this e!planation,

    *uznets describes an inverse 2 curve relation between income and ine"uality.

    2rbanization is pursued together with industrialization; therefore, migration from rural to

    urban areas inherently increases ine"uality by raising the proportion of population of the

    more une"ual part of the country. As the development process continues the income

    ine"uality declines, due to the factors like social mobility and improving service sector.

    There are many e!tensions and criticisms that could made for *uznets1s

    arguments on urban ine"uality. 9irstly, the pace of social mobility is highly related with

    structural factors in the urban sector. Amongst the structural factors, the distinction

    between the urban formal and urban informal sectors could be considered as important.

    9or e!amining the migration process, unlike arris and Todaro #%&C), Bole and

    :anders #%&'+) use a model that distinguishes the urban modern and urban subsistence

    sectors. According to Bole and :anders #%&'+), it is more likely that the new arrivals

    would enter to the urban subsistence sector #mostly informal), in which barriers to

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    10/31

    employment are few and average income is lower compared to the urban modern sector.

    Many other studies #7enar?ee, %&'5; -auch, %&&5) claim that wages in the urban informal

    sector are e"ual to or slightly higher than the rural wages. owever, the many migrants

    shift to the urban informal sector, preserving their hopes for finding a formal ?ob in

    future.

    The shares of informalformal sectors change during the different phases of

    urbanization. According to -auch #%&&5), the share of being underemployed0 in the

    informal sector follows an inverted 2 path as the economy urbanizes. $ikewise the

    Todaro parado!0, the growth of the urban formal sector attracts rural workers and leads

    to a greater growth in the urban informal sector. owever, as urbanization proceeds,

    pressure on the land decreases and the agricultural income rises. The agents become less

    willing to leave the rural sector and be underemployed0 in the informal urban sector.

    Thus, the share of informal urban sector employment will start to decline. :ince, the

    wages are generally lower in the urban informal sector; the inverted 2 curve of the

    informal urban sector share could also form an inverted 2 curve between the level of

    urbanization and within urban ine"uality.

    The migrants could enter to the informal and formal sectors due to several factors.

    A study made for 7olivia #Eradhan and Fan :oest, %&&5) show that the education level is

    an important determinant of entering the formal sector. Eradhan and Fan :oest show that

    factor like ethnicity and unemployment in the region are also important for determining

    the possibility of participating in the formal sector. $ikewise in 7olivia, in India the

    education level is also an important factor for rising migrants1 possibility of being

    employed in the formal sector #7aner?ee, %&'5). The migrants with intermediate and

    higher level of education have a greater chance of getting employed in the formal sector.

    As e!pected, in many countries the return of education is also found to be higher in the

    formal sector #Eradhan and Fan :oest, %&&5; 7aner?ee, %&'5; 9unkhouser, %&&).

    The growth of the informal sector could raise the urban ine"uality; however, the

    ine"uality could be reduced if there is a significant social mobility between the formal

    and informal sectors. Devertheless, the social mobility might not be high for many cases.

    7aner?ee #%&'5) shows that in %&41s >elhi only (=G of those who entered the informal

    sector on arrival was switched to the formal sector. e also shows between the years

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    11/31

    %&4+%&+, only +%+G of the new arrivals were switched to the formal sector in a year.

    In addition, the potential mobility was found to be low; only %+G of the informal sector

    wage employees and %(G of the nonwage workers were actively looking a ?ob in the

    formal sector.

    The network of between the agents is important for enabling the mobility between

    the formal and informal sectors. In India, 4CG of migrants who moved from the informal

    to the formal sector found out their current ?ob with the help of their relatives and friends.

    The level of education is again found to be an important factor of mobility. The informal

    sector employees who have a middle school or intermediate college level education have

    a greater likelihood of shifting to the formal sector.

    In summary, along with the other factors the access to education is an important

    factor for enabling the social mobility and reducing the urban ine"uality. The migrants or

    the children in the migrant families should have an access to an education to secondary or

    tertiary education for the process depicted by *uznets to happen. @ne impediment of that

    is the usage of children as a labor force in the informal sector. Many of the children in the

    migrants1 families work #Acikalin, (CC'), they cannot have an access to higher level of

    education. Also, the "uality of the education that some children get is e!tremely low even

    for the primary school level, since they could not have time to focus on their school,

    while they are working.

    Another e!tension that could be made to the *uznetsian theory is related with the

    services sector. As we mentioned previously, *uznets claims that the growth of services

    sector would reduce ine"uality, since the ine"uality in the services sector is lower

    compared to the industrial sector. The arguments of *uznets on services are mostly

    relevant for the service sectors of %&+C1s. owever, the relations of production are

    significantly changed in many of today1s service sectors; employeremployee type of

    relations improved, whereas the proportion of selfemployed is declining. Also,

    improvements on branding and franchising also created new opportunities for increasing

    the incomes of the wealthier individuals in the service sector. Therefore, the difference

    between the levels of ine"uality within the industrial and service sectors may not be great

    in today1s world, due to the developments in the services sector.

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    12/31

    The property income is another issue that might create a need for the revision of

    *uznets1s theory in today1s world. In fact, in his article Huantitative Aspects of the

    conomic /rowth of Dations0, *uznets #%&45) shows that the shares of property in total

    income are lower in the less developed regions8 they would tend to widen ine"uality

    less in the low income, underdeveloped regions than in the developed regions0 in the

    2nited :tates.

    The current literature on financialization also signs that the situation depicted by

    *uznets might be true for the country wise comparisons. The 2: economy has the

    highest />E per capita compared to other large scale countries%. 9ollowing the economic

    growth, the share of financial income has also risen in the 2: economy #*rippner, (CC+;

    Brotty, (CC&). The share of financial and real estate incomes reached to the level of (5G

    in (CC% and it continued to rise afterwards. In his empirical study, 9razer #(CC4) finds a

    modified inverted 2 curve with ine"uality rising after an income level. This result could

    be partially related with the higher urban ine"uality caused by the rising share of property

    incomes in the high income countries.

    In his %&++ article, *uznets does not focus on the changes in rural ine"uality. e

    e!plains the reduction in ine"uality ma?orly by the changes in the urban ine"uality.

    owever, in his %&45 *uznets develops an argument on the changes in rural ine"uality.

    e claims that6

    The rise in productivity within the A sector, indispensable for modern economic growth,

    may have been associated with technological changes that raised the scale of production

    on farms and introduced a cleavage between the large commercial farms in the

    progressive part of agriculture and the small units lagging behind, which would make for

    wider ine"uality of income within the A sector, at least until the process of modernization

    had been introduced throughout the sector.0

    The technological improvements could increase the rural ine"uality for a period

    of time. As it happened in Ehilippines during the green revolution #7oyce, %&&5), the

    %In fact, the 2nited :tates has the si!th largest />E per capita in the world #IM9, (C%C). owever, the topfive countries Hatar, $u!embourg, :ingapore, Dorway and 7runei have a population smaller than +million; they could be considered as small scale if we use population as a criterion.

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    13/31

    technological improvements0 in agriculture might even lead to the centralization of land

    and would make the higher rural ine"uality permanent. owever, in some cases the small

    scale farms can also compete with the large scale farms that are technologically

    developed. In fact, many recent studies #:en, %&&4; /riffin, *han and Ickowitz, (CC()

    show that the small scale farms could have higher land productivity. It is true that the

    small scale farms could be technologically behind; however, the small scale farms have

    advantages on monitoring and effort. The large scale farms owned by absentee owners

    and cultivated by hired workers under supervision of a manager are often considered as

    inefficient. These farms have high monitoring costs and the effort shown by the workers

    is usually lower compared to the family farms. Also, the proportion of uncultivated land

    is higher in the large scale farms.

    In summary, the small scale farms can compete with the large scale farms; the

    technological improvements followed by growth might or might not lead to a permanent

    rise in the rural ine"uality. $astly, successful land redistribution could play an important

    role on changing the rural ine"uality. The rural ine"uality would be significantly reduced,

    if land is redistributed during the development process #/riffin, *han and Ickowitz,

    (CC()

    (he cases of higher rural inequality

    9or developing his argument, *uznets #%&++) assumes that in any condition ine"uality in

    urban areas is larger than the ine"uality in rural areas. e says that 0It seems most

    plausible to assume that in earlier periods of industrialization, even when the

    nonagricultural population is relatively small in the total, its income distribution was

    more une"ual than that of the agricultural population.0. Therefore, the population shift

    from relatively e"ual rural sector to une"ual urban sector will firstly result in widening

    ine"uality.

    The arguments of *uznets could be challenged within his own conte!t, for the

    cases in which *uznets1s assumptions do not hold. In some countries, the socioeconomic

    structure could create cases that the rural population is more une"ual than the urban

    population. In such cases, urbanization means shift to relatively egalitarian areas. ence,

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    14/31

    urbanization could lead to a reduction in overall ine"uality, before the effects of social

    mobility is observed.

    Table - 1: The Income Inequalities in some countries Rural Gini Urban Gini Total Gini

    Argentina 1953 0.50 0.38 0.41

    Argentina 1961 0.49 0.48 0.43

    Bolivia 1996 0.59 0.51 0.57

    Bolivia 1999 0.63 0.48 0.58

    China 198 0.3 0.1 0.9

    China 1986 0.6 0.16 0.33

    China 1991 0.31 0.18 0.38

    Co!ta Ri"a 1961 0.53 0.47 0.50

    Co!ta Ri"a 1981 0.47 0.43 0.48

    Co!ta Ri"a 1991 0.44 0.43 0.46#or$an 1980 0.38 0.34 0.41

    %igeria 1975 0.43 0.36 &

    'ierra (eone 1968 0.60 0.5 0.60

    Tur)e* 1968 0.57 0.50 0.56

    Tur)e* 1973 0.5 0.46 0.50

    U'A 1957&59 0.4 0.35 &

    U'A 1960&6 0.4 0.35 0.36

    +ene,uela 196 0.45 0.44 0.54

    :ources6Argentina %&+5, %&4%; 2:A %&++&, 2:A %&4C4( < 3eisskoff -.#%&4), ncome distribution andeconomic groth in uerto ico, Argentina and /e)ico

    7olivia %&&4, %&&&; Bosta -ica %&'%, %&&%; Digeria %&+; < 2D23I>- #(CC'), 3orld IncomeIne"uality >atabase F(.CcBhina %&'(, %&'4, %&&%; Bosta -ica %&4%; ordan %&'C; :ierra $eone %&4'; Fenezuela %&4( < >eininger*. and :"uire $. #%&&4), A Dew >ata :et Measuring Income Ine"uality0, 0orld 1an$ 2conomic evieF. %C, Do 5 Ep. +4++&%Turkey %&4' 7ulutay,T., Timur,:.and rsel,.#%&%),TJrkiye1de /elir >aKLlLmL, Ankara6:79.Turkey %&5 :E@ #%&4), /elir >aKLlLmL %&5, Ankara

    @ne ob?ection to this argument could be brought by -obinson #%&4). According

    to -obinson, the 2 curve will be formed even in the condition, where rural ine"uality is

    higher. e shows that the parabolic relation between ine"uality and income will be

    formed in any case as long as the shift of population from rural to urban sector continues.

    owever, in his model -obinson assumes that both within rural and urban ine"ualities

    and income gap between urban and rural sectors are constant. 3e have no rational reason

    to believe that these measures will stay constant during the development process, in fact

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    15/31

    empirically -obinson1s assumption is disproved #Anand and *anbur, %&&5). The within

    ine"ualities or the ruralurban income gap could change as the development process

    continues. In the cases where the within rural ine"uality or the ruralurban income gap

    are consistently declining, the parabolic relation between income and ine"uality might

    not e!ist. In addition to that, there is a greater chance of the 2 curve not to be formed, if

    rural ine"uality minus urban ine"uality is larger.

    Table% shows some cases where the ine"uality is larger for the rural population.

    There could be several reasons of higher rural ine"uality depending on the structural

    conditions of the country. In most of the cases, the high rural ine"ualities are caused by

    une"ual land distribution. 9or e!ample, in the cases of Fenezuela and Bosta -ica where

    higher rural ine"ualities were observed, the /ini coefficients of land concentration for the

    early %&C1s are estimated as C.'( and C.&% respectively #@tsuka, Bhuma and ayami,

    %&&().

    The higher rural ine"uality within the 2nited :tates is realized by *uznets as an

    e!ceptional case. According to *uznets #%&45), the higher ine"uality in rural areas could

    be related with the une"ual distribution of income in the rural :outh and 3est, the

    former because of the cleavage between Degroes and whites, and the latter because of the

    cleavage between largescale, capital intensive farms and smaller units0. Thus, *uznets

    e!plains the high rural ine"uality in the 2:, both with the e!tending effects of slavery

    and the large scale agricultural production.

    (he (ur#ish case

    The high rural ine"uality, which was observed in %&4'1s and %&51s Turkey was an

    inheritance of economic structure in @ttoman mpire. In fact, the traditional relation of

    production in @ttoman mpire is defined as an Asiatic mode of production by many

    scholars #>ivitioKlu, %&4), since most of the surplus was e!propriated by agricultural

    state ta!es. owever, starting from the eighteenth century, a landlord class developed

    from the local ta! collectors and state officers. The formation of this structure led to

    greater land ine"uality and the emergence of semifeudal relations of production.

    The traditional relations of production in @ttoman mpire is e!plained by the

    timarsystem. According to the timarsystem, thesipahis #cavalrymen) had the privilege

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    16/31

    of collecting land surplus in from of ta!es. In e!change, they gave support to the @ttoman

    army #Islamoglu N *eyder, %&'). owever, it must be noted that the timarholders were

    not the owners of the land and the privilege of being timarholder was not surely inherited

    by the other generations. The sultan, in fact, could take the privilege of holding timar

    freely. :ince all of the timars were given by the sultan directly, the timarholders rarely

    transformed into feudal landlords #>ivitioKlu, %&4). Therefore, many scholars like

    >ivitioKlu claims that the timarsystem is a form of Asiatic mode of production rather

    than being a form of feudal mode of production.

    >uring the si!teenth century, as a result of decreasing revenues and increasing

    e!penditures, the @ttoman state faced with a fiscal bottleneck #Islamoglu N *eyder,

    %&'). 9or overcoming the fiscal bottleneck, the @ttoman state leased out the privilege of

    collection of ta!es. The collection of ta!es was issued to the ta! farmers who were mostly

    state officers. This led to a crucial change in the relations of production. The leaseholders

    started to substitute the state and inclined to ma!imize their share of production and

    s"ueeze peasants #reaya) to achieve their goals #Inalcik, %&&%). owever, under a short

    lease, ta! farmers aimed shortterm ma!imization, which resulted in the ruin of the area.

    Therefore, @ttoman state introduced the mali$ane system, in which collection of ta!es is

    issued to ta! farmers on a lifetime basis. The formation of the mali$ane system naturally

    led to the development of semifeudal relations of production within the rural areas.

    In addition to mali$ane, plantationlike large scale farms called 3iftli$s emerged

    during the eighteenth century #Inalcik, %&&%). According to the ciftli$ system, large, waste

    or abandoned lands were issued to the local notables with influence and wealth. The aim

    of this operation was land reclamation; therefore, the beneficiaries had to make necessary

    investments such as irrigation works #Feinstein, %&&%). 3iftli$s became the farms that

    were economically motivated to ma!imize the revenues under the impact of growing

    uropean demand. The labor force was formed by landless peasant, who worked in

    ciftli$ lands as paid agricultural workers or sharecroppers.

    In astern Anatolia, ownership of somesanca$s #administrative unit in @ttoman

    mpire) were given to local tribal leaders called beys, who in e!change paid a certain

    amount of ta! and provided soldiers to the state in the necessary conditions #Aydin,

    %&'4). The lands of beys were inherited by their children, and the state could not dismiss

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    17/31

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    18/31

    :ome scholars like Baglar *eyder #%&'5, %&'&) claim that Turkish agriculture has

    historically characterized by the predominance of independent smallscale peasantry and

    landless peasantry do not constitute a crucial category within the rural society. It is true

    that most of the peasants in Turkey had a land; however, at least until %&Cs, the scale of

    land that peasants owned was very small. According to the agricultural survey of %&C,

    +.%G and ='.(G of farms were smaller than +C and (C decares respectively. *oymen

    #(CC') claims that production level below +C decares insufficient for sustaining a life

    above the poverty level. Therefore, although most peasant owned a land, a large amount

    of peasants were either living below the poverty line or were enrolling in other activities

    #sharecropping, seasonal work, husbandry etc.) for sustaining a reasonable income level.

    %&C agricultural survey also shows that 5.(G of rural households owned =%.G of total

    land, which again e!hibits the e!tent of high rural ine"uality. It might be reasonable to

    assume that many of the unregistered land were not declared in agricultural surveys.

    owever, according to Aydin1s #%&'4) field study, de facto owners of undeclared land

    were mostly large landowners. Thus, we can claim that undeclared lands result in a

    downward bias in the calculations of rural ine"uality.

    @ne of the reasons of high rural ine"uality was the semifeudal structure that even

    still e!ists in :outheast Anatolia. 3ith the acceptance of private property in land in %&(4,

    multezims lost their influence in :outheast Anatolia; however, tribal leaders and big land

    owners #beys) who were the de facto owners of land became the de ?ure owners called

    agas #Aydin, %&'4). Agas are not only the landowners; they have influence over peasants

    beyond their economic power. Eeasants serve as corvee laborer and they have to do all

    kinds of duties issued by aga. If they refuse to do orders, agawould either e!pel them

    from village or mistreat them. Eeasants cultivate agas1 land usually by different forms of

    sharecropping agreements; however, landless agricultural laborers also work in agas1

    lands as wage laborers.

    Another reason for the high rural ine"uality in Turkey could be the privileges,

    which were given to largescale landlords during the early periods of the republic. >uring

    %&(C1s and %&5C1s, mostly large landowners benefited from the credits given by the state

    owned commercial bank Oiraat 7ankasi. $arge landowners1 privileges on reaching

    credits encouraged the usury activities. In many cases, large landowners could get a loan

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    19/31

    with reasonable interest rates and lend this money with interest rates that reached to the

    levels of %(C4CCG. According to 7oratav #%&4&), through the usury activities, the usurer

    e!propriated an important part of smallscale peasant1s surplus. *oymen #%&'%) claims

    that usury activities also changed land distribution significantly. Many of the peasants

    who cannot pay their loans had to sell their land to large landowners.

    After the :econd 3orld 3ar, the Turkish government started to use the Marshall

    Elan aid to finance the importation of agricultural machinery. The number of tractors

    ?umped from (CCC in %&=' to =(CCC at the end of the %&+Cs. The aid was distributed

    through stateowned commercial banks for encouraging tractor purchases; however,

    mostly large landowners benefited from these loans. 7y %&45, poorer 4'.'G of farms

    only had (CG of tractors; whereas, the richest C.+G owned (4G of tractors #*oymen,

    (CC'). The une"ual distribution of tractors was one of the reasons of high rural

    ine"uality, which was observed in %&4' and %&5 surveys.

    A )imple mo!el for e*plaining the Kuznets process

    The *uznets process in Turkey can be e!plored by decomposing ine"uality to its

    components. /ini Inde! is the most commonly used inde! in ine"uality analysis.

    owever, for a decomposition analysis, Theil Inde! could give stronger results compared

    to /ini Inde!. The reason for that is that /ini Inde! cannot be fully decomposed into

    between and within components. Along with between and within components, the

    decomposition of /ini inde! gives an e!tra intensity of transvariation0 term #>agum,

    %&&); whereas Theil inde! can be decomposed into between and within components

    without having a residual term. Therefore, for this analysis Theil Inde! is preferred for

    more accurate decomposition of ine"uality.

    7y using Theil Inde!, the overall ine"uality T can be decomposed into within and

    between sector components T0and T1in the following way6

    #%) 0 1T T T= +

    9or e!ploring the *uznets process, we assume that both within and between

    components are dependent on population share of urban sector, which is defined as !.

    The overall ine"uality can be rewritten by decomposing within component into urban and

    rural components TUand T6

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    20/31

    #()# ) # ) # ) # ) # )

    # ) # ) # )#% # )) # )

    U U . . 1

    U U . U 1

    T T ) . ) T ) . ) T )

    T ) . ) T ) . ) T )

    = + +

    = + - +

    ereUandare respectively production shares of urban and rural sectors in the

    whole economy. It could be reasonable to assume that share of production increases with

    the rise in urban population. 9or analyzing the impact of urbanization on overall

    ine"uality, we calculate first order conditions of Twith respect to urban population share

    #!)6

    #5) P P P#% ) P PU U U U . U . U 1T

    T . T . T . T . T )

    = + + - - +

    :inceU&)(4 - &)(, the e"uation could be written as6

    #=) P# ) # P P ) PU U . U U . . 1T

    . T T T . T . T

    )

    = - + + +

    The e"uation above gives an insight about the development process e!plained by

    *uznets #%&++). *uznets assumes that urban sector has always higher ine"uality

    compared to rural sector. e claims that moving from relatively e"ual urban distribution

    to relatively une"ual rural distribution increases the ine"uality in the early phase of

    development. This argument can be seen in the first and third terms. The first term is

    naturally positive, if urban ine"uality is greater. The between ine"uality component #T1)

    also increases in the first phase of development. Anand and *anbur #%&&5) show that the

    relation between share of urban population #!) and between ine"uality component #T1) is

    inverse 2 shaped even, if the urbanrural mean income gap is constant. The reason for

    that is that the contribution of between ine"uality converges to zero in the economies that

    are totally urban or rural #9igure%). In addition to that, *uznets claims that the

    productivity gap between the rural and urban sector increases in the first phase of

    development. Anand and *anbur show that if *uznets1s assumption is followed the peak

    of 2 curve gets greater and the slopes at the end points become even steeper. Therefore,

    T11#!) Q C assumption is valid for e!plaining *uznets1s theory, when the value of ! is

    smaller. Therefore, assuming that within rural and urban ine"ualities are not declining,

    growth of urban sector surely raises ine"uality in the early stage of development. As the

    development process continues, for higher values of !, both U1 R C and T11#!) R C

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    21/31

    conditions would be satisfied. This would lead to a decline in overall ine"uality and the

    development process would fit to *uznets Burve.

    C %

    7etweengroup

    component #Tb)

    3ithingroup

    component #Tw)

    Ine"uality

    #T)

    2rban share of population #!)

    +igure $,: Change in Inequality in the Kuznets -rocess

    :ource6 Anand, :. and *anbur, :.M.-.#%&&5) The *uznets process and the ine"ualitydevelopment

    relationship0.5ournal of 6evelopment 2conomics, =C, pp. (+

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    22/31

    C %

    3ithingroup

    component #Tw)

    2rban share of population #!)

    Ine"uality

    #T)

    7etweengroup

    component #Tb)

    +igure $.: Change in Inequality in a society with higher rural inequality

    In Turkey, firstly, rural ine"uality was greater than urban ine"uality in the years

    %&4' and %&5. Thus, une"ual urban sector assumption of *uznets does not hold for

    Turkey and there was a movement from une"ual to e"ual sector. ence, the first term of

    e"uation #+) was negative for a period. :econdly, ine"ualities in the urban and rural

    sectors changed. The ine"uality in the urban sector did not rise with urbanization #e!cept

    the year of economic crisis %&&=) and a significant decline was observed for the ruraline"uality. Thus, the second term of e"uation #+) is probably negative. These two

    conditions reduce theT

    )

    and hence

    T

    )

    can be negative even when the urban sector is

    rapidly growing. Thus, the Turkish case shows that *uznets process might not hold if

    *uznets1s assumptions are changed.

    3e can e!plain the changes in longterm Turkish ine"uality by using a simple

    empirical analysis. 9or the empirical analysis, the Theil entropy indices for the years%&4', %&5, %&' and (CC= are calculated #Table < =). The years %&4', %&5 and %&'

    were selected for calculations, since the first three relatively reliable income distribution

    surveys were done for these years. The ine"uality for %&45 was not being estimated by

    household surveys, it was rather calculated by using the land distribution estimated in

    agriculture surveys and the values of income ta!es and social security premiums paid.

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    23/31

    Thus, %&45 income distribution study cannot capture the informal economy. The years

    %&&= and (CC( were not used for calculations, since the ine"uality for these years are

    biased, due to the effects of the economic crises in %&&= and (CC%. I rather used the year

    (CC=, which does not reflect the shortterm effects of economic crises on distribution.

    Theil values for %&4' and %&5 were estimated by using the income distribution data of

    7ulutay, Timur and rsel #%&%) and :tate Elanning @rganization #%&5) respectively.

    9or the years %&' and (CC=, data of Turkish :tatistical Institute :tate Institute of

    :tatisticsas used.

    Table - *: Inequality in Turkey

    ,ini - Total ,ini - %rban ,ini - Rural

    19+* 0.55 & &

    19+ 0.56 0.50 0.5719#* 0.50 0.46 0.5

    19# 0.43 0.44 0.4

    199. 0.49 0.51 0.41

    2!!2 0.44 0.44 0.4

    2!!* 0.4 0.4 0.39

    2!!. 0.40 0.39 0.37

    2!! 0.38 0.38 0.37

    2!!+ 0.43 0.4 0.41

    2!!# 0.41 0.39 0.38

    2!! 0.41 0.40 0.38

    :ources 6

    %&45 SavuoKlu, T., and U. amurdan#%&44), /elir >aKLlLmL AratLrmasL %&45, :E@, Ankara.%&4' 7ulutay,T., Timur,:.and rsel,.#%&%),TJrkiye1de /elir >aKLlLmL, Ankara6:79.%&5 :E@ #%&4), /elir >aKLlLmL %&5, Ankara%&' < :I: #%&&C), %&' anehalkL /elir ve TJketim arcamalarL >aKLlLmL :onularL, Ankara%&&= < :I: #%&&4), %&&= anehalkL >aKLlLmL Anketi :onularL, Ankara(CC((CC' < T2-*:TAT, ousehold Income >istribution :tatistics #www.tuik.gov.tr)

    Table - .: Decom/osition o0 inequality according to urban-rural segmentation

    %rban o/)($ ,iniTheil - Total Theil - %rban Theil - Rural Theil - 3et4een

    19+ 36.8 0.56 0.664 0.519 0.685 0.056

    19#* 40.4 0.50 0.57 0.46 0.557 0.015

    19# 55.3 0.43 0.375 0.39 0.39 0.0092!!. 68.0 0.40 0.93 0.84 0.63 0.014

    Table = e!hibits Theil values for within and between urbanrural ine"ualities in Turkey.

    According to the analysis, the ine"uality between rural and urban areas has only small

    impact on the overall ine"uality. The ine"uality for the given years is mostly e!plained

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    24/31

    by the within ine"ualities in urban and rural areas. Therefore, change in overall ine"uality

    is mostly related with change in within ine"uality.

    The reasons behind the reduction in ine"uality could be predicted by the e"uation

    =6

    #=) P# ) # P P ) PU U . U U . . 1T

    . T T T . T . T)

    = - + + +

    9or estimating impact of the first term # P# )U U . T T- ), which we call *uznets

    effect, we assume that gap between within urban and rural ine"ualities move towards one

    direction between the given years. Thus, we multiply rate of urbanization with the higher

    and lower differences between within urban and rural ine"ualities for the given period.

    7y this method, we find a range showing the possible contribution of *uznets effect on

    overall ine"uality. The second # PU UT ) and third # P. .T ) terms give impact of changes

    in urban and rural ine"ualities on overall ine"uality. 9or calculating the range of second

    and third terms, we again assume that these terms move towards one direction between

    the given years. 3e multiply the rate of urbanization with the larger and smaller values of

    within urban and rural ine"ualities for the given period. $astly, we estimate impact of the

    change in between ine"uality # P1T ) by a simple subtraction.

    Table - : Decom/osition o0 changes in Theil 5alues

    eriod6hange in

    75erall Theil&u8nets '00ect 6hange in %rban 6hange in Rural

    6hange in3et4een

    19+-19#* &0.19 &0.006 &0.003 &0.01 &0.03 &0.081 &0.077 &0.041

    19+-19# &0.89 &0.031 0.01 &0.047 &0.070 &0.5 &0.158 &0.047

    19#*-19# &0.160 &0.014 0.009 &0.08 &0.039 &0.135 &0.101 &0.006

    19#-2!!. &0.08 0.007 0.003 &0.060 &0.073 &0.09 &0.01 &0.014

    Table + e!hibits the decomposition of changes in overall Theil inde! for the given

    periods. The first values for the *uznets effectP# )

    U U .

    T T-and impact of changes in

    within urban # PU UT ) and rural # P. .T . ) ine"ualities are calculated by using the

    conditions of the previous year and the second values are calculated by using the

    conditions of the latter year.

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    25/31

    The results show that the path suggested by *uznets was not followed in the

    Turkish case. The direct effect of urbanization on ine"uality was slightly negative for the

    period %&4'%&5, since the rural ine"uality was higher for this period. 9or the period

    %&5%&', the value of *uznets effect is between C.C%= and C.CC&. The rural ine"uality

    was relatively higher in %&5; however, for %&' the rural ine"uality was lower.

    Therefore, for the period %&5%&', we can say that the urbanization first had direct

    negative and then had direct positive impact on the Theil value. In summary, the shift

    from rural to urban areas did not directly increase the overall ine"uality during the early

    phase of industrialization.

    The estimations also e!hibit that the longrun reduction in ine"uality is highly

    related with the decline in rural ine"uality. The rural ine"uality was significantly reduced

    between %&4'%&'. The decline in rural ine"uality could be e!plained by several

    reasons. 9irstly, a large proportion of migrants came from either smalllandowning or

    landless families(. The migration of landless peasants could immediately have reduced

    the rural ine"uality by logic, since the poorest individuals left the rural distribution

    without transferring any assets to the richer ones. In addition, the benefits like

    remittances accruing to migrants1 families or relatives would probably have pulled the

    level of rural ine"uality down. Thus, urbanization could have an indirect impact on the

    reduction of rural ine"uality.

    :econdly, a spillover in agricultural technology was observed after %&4Cs. In

    %&41s Turkey, there were only +CCC tractors. These tractors were mostly owned by a

    privileged group of large landowners #*epenek N Uenturk, (CC+). owever, the number

    of tractors in Turkey increased to %54CCC in %&( and ?umped to 4++CCC in %&'' and

    '+CCC in %&&. The spillover of agricultural technology could have positive effects on

    rural ine"uality.

    Tables = and + also show that urban ine"uality slightly decreased between %&4'

    %&5 and %&5%&', although urbanization process continued. The decline in urban

    (In a study made for Turkey, *arpat #%&4) shows that most migrants e!plain their decision by pushfactors like low soil productivity, lack of good cultivable land, irrigation, water, division of properties intosmall parcels etc.. G of men and 4+G of women migrants e!plain their behavior by push factors relatedwith poverty, whereas only 'G of men and G of women give search for a better future0 as their reasonfor leaving village. Aydin #%&'4)1s field study also shows that the migrants in :outheast Anatolia weremostly poorer individuals.

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    26/31

    ine"uality for the %&4'%&5 period could easily be e!plained by the rising labor

    movements #7oratav, (CC+). As a result of the labor movements, wage share in

    manufacturing industry increased from (+.(G in %&4' to (.%G in %&5 and 5'.5G in

    %&&.

    owever, the gains of labor movements were mostly lost with the antilabor

    policies followed after the %&'C military coup. Therefore, labor movements cannot

    e!plain the decline in urban ine"uality for the periods %&5%&' and %&'(CC=. The

    decline in urban ine"uality for these periods could be partially e!plained by the social

    mobility0 effects suggested by *uznets #%&++) for the later stages of development. As

    suggested by many scholars #Bole and :anders, %&'+; -auch, %&&5; *arpat, %&4), it is

    reasonable to assume that most of the migrants first moved to the informal sector. Thus,

    ratio of nonagricultural labor with social insurance was only =5.'G in %&4 and =(G in

    %&( #*epenek and Uenturk, (CC+). owever, in time, workers in informal sector moved

    to the formal sector; the nonagricultural labor with social insurance increased to C.&G

    in %&&C and +.&G in (CC=. The raise in the ratio of formal workers could have decreased

    the urban ine"uality.

    $astly, between ine"uality declined during the e!amined periods. The impact of

    decline in between ine"uality is more noticeable for the %&4'%&5 period. This result is

    consistent with >ervis and -obinson #%&'C)1s analysis. >ervis and -obinson show that

    the *uznets -atio in Turkey declined between %&4'%&5, since terms of trade changed

    in favor of the rural sector. 9ollowing $ewis #%&+=)1s argument, we can say that the

    relative growth of the capitalist sector could have shifted the terms of trade in favor of the

    rural sector and reduced the between income ine"uality in Turkey.

    Conclusion

    This study e!plores the effects of urbanization on the changes in income distribution. The

    changes on ine"uality are analyzed within the *uznetsian framework and *uznets1s 2

    curve argument is e!amined in a critical way. The urbanization followed by

    industrialization can change ine"uality by many ways. As urbanization continues, the

    urban share raises; changes are observed both in between and within urban and rural

    ine"ualities. *uznets brings some e!planations on how development changes the

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    27/31

    structure of ine"uality. owever, the path that ine"uality will follow is also related with

    the internal dynamics of a country.

    *uznets claims that the first stage of industrialization increases ine"uality by

    raising the proportion of the population in the une"ual part #urban) of the society.

    owever, there are indeed studies that show that urbanization has counterbalancing effect

    against the income gaps caused by the rapid industrialization. *uznets1s assumption on

    higher urban ine"uality could also be wrong for many cases, which could disprove

    *uznets1s arguments within his own framework. There are in fact cases shown in this

    study, where the ine"uality in the rural areas is greater due to the countries1

    socioeconomic structure.

    In this study, we e!amined the Turkish case in which rural ine"uality was greater

    at the earlier stages of development. 2nlike *uznets1s arguments, urbanization did not

    lead to greater ine"uality during the first stage of Turkey1s development. The direct

    impact of shift from rural to urban sector on ine"uality was not negative for the early

    phase of urbanization. In fact, urbanization reduced the ine"uality in Turkey by

    decreasing the rural ine"uality and closing the urbanrural income gap. The reduction in

    ine"uality pursued during the latter stages of development with the social mobility0

    effects suggested by *uznets.

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    28/31

    %eferences

    Acikalin D. #(CC'), Eoverty and the :ocial Mobility Bhances of Uouth /enerations6 ABase :tudy in Istanbul and /aziantep0#in Turkish), The 5ournal of nternational 7ocialesearch, Folume %V5

    Ahluwalia, M.:.#%&4), Income >istribution and >evelopment% :ome :tylized 9acts0,American 2conomic evie, 44

    Anand, :. and *anbur, :.M.-.#%&&5) The *uznets process and the ine"ualitydevelopment relationship0.5ournal of 6evelopment 2conomics, =C, pp. (+agum, B. #%&&), A Dew Approach to the >ecomposition of the /ini IncomeIne"uality -atio0,2mpirical 2conomics, ((6+%++5%

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    29/31

    >eininger *. and $. :"uire #%&&4), A Dew >ata :et Measuring Income Ine"uality0,0orld 1an$ 2conomic evieF. %C, Do 5 Ep. +4++&%

    >ervis *. and :. -obinson #%&'C), WThe :tructure of Income Ine"uality in Turkey inTurkey, %&+C%&5W, in . Yzbudun and A. 2lusan #eds.), The olitical 2conomy of

    ncome 6istribution in Tur$ey, olmes and Meier, Dew Uork

    >ivitioKlu, :. #%&4),Asya Tipi retim Tarz< ve 9smanl< Toplumu, U*U, Istanbul

    9razer, /. #(CC4), Ine"uality and development across and within countries0, 0orld6evelopment, 5=#&), %=+&@D, 7ogazici2niversitesi6 Istanbul

    *oymen, @. #(CC'),Kapitalizm ve Koylulu$% Agalar, Uretenler, atronlar, Uordam*itap

    *rippner /.#(CC+), The 9inancialization of the American conomy,0 7ocio-2conomicevie, Fol. 5, pp. %5(&'

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    30/31

    *uznets :. #%&++) conomic growth and income ine"uality0,American 2conomicevie, =+, %evelopingBountries6 A :urvey of Theoretical Eredictions and mpirical 9indings0, 3orld 7ankEolicy -esearch 3orking Eaper Do. 5&%+

    $ewis, 3. A. #%&+=), conomic development with unlimited supplies of labour0. The/anchester 7chool.

    $ipton M. #%&'(), Migration from -ural Areas of Eoor Bountries6 The Impact of -uralEroductivity and Income >istribution0 in :abot -.. #ed.),/igration and the labormar$et in developing countries, Bolo. 6 3estview Eress

    @tsuka, *.; Bhuma, and U. ayami #%&&(), $and and $abor Bontracts in Agrarianconomies6 Theories and 9acts0,5ournal of 2conomic Biterature, F. 5C, pp. %&4+(C%'

    Eradhan, M. and A. Fan :oest, #%&&+), 9ormal and Informal :ector mployment in2rban Areas of 7olivia.0,Babor 2conomics, (, (+(&.

    -anis, /. and . B. . 9ei #%&4%). WA Theory of conomic >evelopment,W American2conomic evie, +%6 +55+4+.

    -auch, . . #%&&5). Wconomic >evelopment, 2rban 2nderemployment, and IncomeIne"ualityW, 3anadian 5ournal of 2conomics, vol. (4#=), pages &C%%',

    -avallion, M., Bhen, :. and E. :angraula #(CC), Dew vidence on the 2rbanization of/lobal Eoverty0, 3orld 7ank Eolicy -esearch 3orking Eaper Do. =%&&

    -obinson, :. #%&4), A note on the 2 hypothesis relating income ine"uality andeconomic development.0,American 2conomic evie 44, =5B1s0 in :abot-.. #ed.),/igration and the labor mar$et in developing countries, Bolo. 6 3estviewEress

  • 8/13/2019 Kuznets-NewSchoolUmass

    31/31

    :yr"uin, M. #%&''), Eatterns of :tructural Bhange0 in . Bhenery and T.D. :rinivasan#eds.), andbook of development economics, vol. %, Amsterdam6 Dortholland, (C5(5.

    2nal 9. /. #(CC'), The Impact of $and @wnership Ine"uality on -ural 9actor Markets0,Ehd >issertation6 2niversity of MassachusettsAmherst

    3orld 7ank #(CC&), 0orld 6evelopment eport%eshaping 2conomic +eography

    3eisskoff -.#%&4), Income >istribution and economic growth in Euerto -ico,Argentina and Me!ico0 in A. 9o!ley#ed.),ncome 6istribution in Batin AmericaBambridge 2niversity Eress


Recommended