+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married...

Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married...

Date post: 25-Apr-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 2 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
40
Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power * Safoura Moeeni March 15, 2016 Abstract In some developing countries, labour force participation (LFP) of women is low and de- creasing, despite an increase in education levels and decline in fertility rates. Such trends are different from those observed in many developed countries. This paper provides an explana- tion for the female labour supply puzzle, by estimating a household bargaining model using data from 2006 to 2013 Iranian Household Income and Expenditure. I build and estimate a structural model of education, marriage, fertility and labour supply in an intra-household collective decision framework, in which bargaining power is an endogenous variable. In the model, women can increase their bargaining power in the household by obtaining education. The estimated model exhibits the features that are consistent with the data; women’s LFP is an inverse U-shaped function of bargaining power. As a woman’s bargaining power increases, she participates more in the labour market. However, over a certain level of bargaining power, women are less likely to work outside the home. Moreover, the data shows bargaining power inequality in Iran has increased, so number of women with very low and very high level of bargaining power has increased. According to the results, these two groups are less likely to participate in labour market. Thus, women’s LFP in Iran has decreased. * I am grateful to Atsuko Tanaka, Assistant Professor at University of Calgary, for her advice and valuable suggestions during the planning and development of this research. I wish to thank my referees B. Curtis Eaton and Daniel Gordon for their helpful feedback. PhD Student, Department of Economics, University of Calgary, 2500 University Drive NW, Calgary, Alberta, Canada, E-mail: [email protected] 1
Transcript
Page 1: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

Married Women’s Labour Supply

and

Intra-Household Bargaining Power∗

Safoura Moeeni†

March 15, 2016

Abstract

In some developing countries, labour force participation (LFP) of women is low and de-

creasing, despite an increase in education levels and decline in fertility rates. Such trends are

different from those observed in many developed countries. This paper provides an explana-

tion for the female labour supply puzzle, by estimating a household bargaining model using

data from 2006 to 2013 Iranian Household Income and Expenditure. I build and estimate

a structural model of education, marriage, fertility and labour supply in an intra-household

collective decision framework, in which bargaining power is an endogenous variable. In the

model, women can increase their bargaining power in the household by obtaining education.

The estimated model exhibits the features that are consistent with the data; women’s LFP is

an inverse U-shaped function of bargaining power. As a woman’s bargaining power increases,

she participates more in the labour market. However, over a certain level of bargaining power,

women are less likely to work outside the home. Moreover, the data shows bargaining power

inequality in Iran has increased, so number of women with very low and very high level of

bargaining power has increased. According to the results, these two groups are less likely to

participate in labour market. Thus, women’s LFP in Iran has decreased.

∗I am grateful to Atsuko Tanaka, Assistant Professor at University of Calgary, for her advice and valuablesuggestions during the planning and development of this research. I wish to thank my referees B. Curtis Eaton andDaniel Gordon for their helpful feedback.

†PhD Student, Department of Economics, University of Calgary, 2500 University Drive NW, Calgary, Alberta,Canada, E-mail: [email protected]

1

Page 2: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

1 Introduction

Aggregated time series data for developed countries reveal a negative relationship between fertility1

and labour force participation (LFP)2 of women, and a positive relationship between LFP of women

and their level of education.3 In contrast, data for Iran reveal a positive relationship between fertility

and LFP of women, and a negative relationship between LFP of women and their level of education.4

Figure 1 shows the low and decreasing rate of LFP of women despite an increase in the education

level and a decline in the fertility rate. While similar trends are observed in some other developing

countries, such as India and Middle Eastern and North African (MENA) countries (Syria, Morocco,

etc.), little is known about the mechanism. 5

In this paper, I develop and estimate a model of education, marriage and the household to

explain the surprising relationship seen in the Iranian data. This model would explain why we

see one pattern in developed countries and another in MENA countries. My proposed explanation

for this apparent anomaly involves changes in the intra-household bargaining power of women.

Bargaining power is the relative capacity of each of the parties to negotiate or dispute to compel

or secure agreements on its own terms. I measure women’s bargaining power by using various

indicators, including the ratio of wife’s education relative to her husband’s, 6 and find that Iranian

women’s bargaining power has been increasing substantially over the past decades. As is often the

case with countries in MENA region, Iranian women historically have had much less bargaining

1 The average number of children that would be born to a woman over her lifetime.

2 The percentage of working-age persons in an economy who are employed or unemployed but looking for a job.

3 For example, in OECD countries female LFP increased from 60 percent to 62 percent, while women averageyears of schooling has increased and fertility rate has declined between 2006 and 2013. Theoretically, education ispositively related to women’s labour force participation because education raises income as well as the opportunitycost of non-market activities. Also, the inverse relationship between fertility and female LFP rate has proven to beempirically significant and robust (Bloom et al. (2009) [11]). The economic conceptualization of the relationshipbetween women’s LFP and fertility emphasizes the opportunity cost of children.

4 According to data published by Statistical Center of Iran (SCI), fertility has declined from six births per womanin the 80’s to two births in recent years, and the number of women who attended university increased 131 percentin the last ten years. At the same time, female LFP fell by five percentage points, from 17 percent to 12 percent.

5 For example, Indian female LFP fell by seven percentage points, from 37 percent to 28 percent and Syrian femaleLFP fell from 16 percent to 14 percent, despite rapidly increasing educational attainment for girls and decliningfertility between 2006 and 2013.

6 One indicator for women’s bargaining power is the ratio of wife’s education relative to her husband’s. Accordingto this indicator, a couple with same education level have equal power in decision making within the household. Aseducation gap with wife and husband increases, the balance of the power will be disrupted.

2

Page 3: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

0

5

10

15

20

25

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

nu

mb

er o

f h

igh

ed

uca

ted

wo

men

(>1

2)

x 1

00

00

0

Women's Education

1.6

1.65

1.7

1.75

1.8

1.85

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

Bir

ths

per

Wo

man

Fertility Rate

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

per

cen

t

Women's LFP

Figure 1: Education, Fertility and LFP

Source: Statistical Center of Iran (SCI)

power within the household than women in developed countries. For example, in many developed

countries there is not much difference between male and female in years of education. 7 While

women in Iran used to attain less education and have more children, women’s bargaining power in

Iran has substantially increased as a result of the recent increase in their education level. Greater

bargaining power allows women to steer allocations in their preferred direction. For instance,

women with larger bargaining power tend to have fewer children and prefer staying at home to

working outside if they find little opportunity in the labor market. Thus, an increase in women’s

household bargaining power can account for a negative education-LFP relationship as well as a

negative education-fertility relationship. 8

The goal of this paper is to investigate my hypothesis by developing a model of intra-household

bargaining power using Iranian household data and to provide an explanation for seemingly incon-

7 Maitra and Ray (2005) [33] showed that the average value of the female share of education is approximately 0.5for Australian household.

8 During this time other factors which affect women’s LFP (e.g. husband’s income, access to and cost of daycareand education cost) didn’t change. Moreover, I control for economic conditions.

3

Page 4: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

gruent labor supply trend observed in some developing countries. This paper develops a general

collective model of household (Chiappori (1992) [18]) by allowing the education, marriage and fer-

tility decisions to be endogenous. Unlike the existing literature of household bargaining, my model

allows women to choose their bargaining power through education. So, in my model not only the

bargaining power is endogenous but also every factor that affects the bargaining power (such as

the husband-wife ratio of education and earnings) is endogenous. Such modification is critical to

model implication since, in real world, education and husband properties are not exogenous for

women. Furthermore, the model captures two counteracting effects of education on labour force

participation. On the one hand, higher education increases the potential wage and thus increases

the probability of participation in the labour market. On the other hand, female’s bargaining power

is positively affected by the woman’s education level. While the first effect of education is well ac-

knowledged, the second effect is not considered as of the foremost importance and is often ignored

in the economic literature. Consistent with this explanation, Figures 2 and 3 show that according

to Iranian data, women with relatively low and relatively high bargaining power, participate less in

the labour market, and if they participate, they work less hours.

1.881.38 1.32

7.25

14.88 14.98

7.67

8.72

3.60 3.60

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

0-0.1 0.1- 0.2 0.2-0.3 0.3- 0.4 0.4- 0.5 0.5- 0.6 0.6- 0.7 0.7- 0.8 0.8- 0.9 0.9- 0.10

Wo

men

's L

FP(p

erce

nt)

Women's Bargaining Power

Figure 2: Women’s LFP

Source: Iranian Household Income and Expenditure

3.10

1.29

4.50

7.71

5.535.30

5.67

4.95

3.43

4.89

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

0-0.1 0.1- 0.2 0.2-0.3 0.3- 0.4 0.4- 0.5 0.5- 0.6 0.6- 0.7 0.7- 0.8 0.8- 0.9 0.9- 0.10

Wo

men

's A

vera

ge D

aily

Ho

urs

Wo

rked

Women's Bargaining Power

Figure 3: Women’s Labour Supply

Source: Iranian Household Income and Expenditure

The model of this study is a four-part static model. Women make decisions for all parts at time

zero. They first independently invest in human capital; their decision is driven by their cost and the

expected returns of education. Education has two roles: first, within a human capital framework,

education augments natural abilities that are sold in the labour market; second, education provides

a way for individuals to sort themselves by ability. Therefore, education acts as a signaling and/or

4

Page 5: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

screening device for unobservable ability in both the labour and the marriage market. In the second

part of the model, women find their mate on the marriage market based on their human capital and

their characteristics. The third part of the model considers the wife and husband’s decision after

marriage regarding the number of children. Finally, in the last part, couples consume private goods,

save and supply labour, subject to household budget and time constraints. Household decisions in

the last two parts depend on the bargaining power of wife and husband, which is determined

by the education level. I assume Pareto efficiency and full commitment in marriage.9 I find that

women’s LFP is an inverse U-shaped function of bargaining power. Women’s LFP initially increases

as bargaining power goes up, but start decreasing after bargaining power reaches a certain level.

Therefore, as a woman’s bargaining power increases, she participates more in the labour market.

However, over a certain level of bargaining power, women are less likely to work outside the home.

Moreover, the data shows bargaining power inequality in Iran has increased, so number of women

with very low and very high level of bargaining power has increased. According to the results, these

two groups are less likely to participate in labour market. Thus, in the case of Iran, women’s LFP

has decreased, despite an increase in education levels and decline in fertility rates.

In the general collective model (Chiappori (1992) [18]) the education level, number of children

and bargaining power are considered exogenous. Thus, the link between the education level, fertility

rate, and bargaining power are missed. With the missing link between the education level and

the bargaining power, Chiappori’s model always predicts that LFP is positively correlated with

education because the sole effect of the education is an increase in the potential wage. Moreover,

due to missing link between the fertility rate and the bargaining power, the general collective model

cannot explain a positive correlation between fertility rate and LFP.

This paper uses data from 2006 to 2013 Iranian Household Income and Expenditure Survey

(HIES) for estimation and testing fitness of the model. The advantage of this survey is that it not

only contains very rich information on individuals’ demographic characteristics (such as age, years

of schooling, relation with the head of family and gender), but also includes detailed information

on individuals’ socioeconomic characteristics (i.e. employment, income, expenditures, etc.). I use

Iran as an example because this rich data is not available for other MENA countries. However,

understanding the case of Iran also has implications for other economies, especially those in the

9 I abstract from issues relating to divorce by full commitment assumption in marriage.

5

Page 6: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

MENA region which have similar labour market conditions.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Theoretical and empirical literature surveys

are presented in Section 2. The theoretical framework of the model is covered in Section 3. Section

4 solves the model. Section 5 provides a description of the sample used. Section 6 and 7 estimate

and simulate the model, respectively. Section 8 solves the puzzle. Finally section 9 concludes.

2 Literature review

In neo-classical family economics, the household is the unit of study. The household’s problem is to

maximize a single utility function subject to a household budget constraint. Allocation is carried

out such that the marginal utility of consumption is equalized across family members. With the

unitary approach, who earns the income should not matter to household consumption patterns. In

other words, income is pooled (Samuelson (1956) [50]) and Becker (1981) [8]).

Although this approach seems to be very convenient in theoretical modeling and empirical

analysis, its application has been strongly criticized in the past decades by Manser and Brown

(1980) [35], Apps and Rees (1988) [2], Chiappori (1992) [18], Bourguignon and Chiappori (1993) [12],

Browning and Chiappori(1998) [15]. First, it is argued that treating the family as the representative

agent violates the individualism principle, which states each individual must be characterized by

own preferences. Second, since the unitary model considers the family as a whole, it does not

allow for raising any intra-household related issues, that might have a significant effect on each

member’s welfare. The family is a place of conflict and cooperation. Third, income pooling imposes

restrictions on the labour supply of individual household members and the unitary model (Slutsky

conditions), which are often rejected by empirical studies for households with more than one member

(Bloemen (2010) [10]).

There are three alternative approaches that address these issues: the Nash cooperative bargain-

ing, the non-cooperative bargaining, and the collective settings. Crucial to the non-unitary model

is the relative power of individual members in the household (Pollak (1994) [42]). All of these

alternative models use a game-theoretic approach. Cooperative Nash bargaining household models

is the earliest attempt to explicitly describe the decision-making process within the household. The

earliest papers that established the Nash bargaining approach to the household include Manser and

6

Page 7: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

Brown (1980) [35] and McElroy and Horney (1981) [37]. This approach consider household members

as agents who try to come to an agreement on how to divide the gain of cooperation while living

together. In this bargaining model, individuals, given their relative bargaining power in the family,

have to reach an efficient allocation of the gain obtained from living together. The generalized Nash

framework has important empirical implications. However, those implications are not immediately

testable with observable data. For instance, there is no reason to assume that the threat point10

of utility functions are observable. If threat points are not observable, no explicit restrictions can

be put on the bargaining power matrix. Another important criticism of this approach is that if its

empirical implications are rejected, then it is impossible to determine whether the particular choice

itself is rejected or the bargaining setting in general causes this rejection (Zeyn Xu (2007) [53]).

Moreover, cooperative bargaining models make the more restrictive assumption of invariant utility

across marital statuses (McElroy (1990) [36]).

The second alternative game theoretic approach is non-cooperative bargaining model. In this

framework, household members are assumed to maximize their utility taking the other’s behavior as

given (Leuthold (1968) [28], Ash worth and Ulph (1981) [3], Browning (2000) [13], Chen and Woolley

(2001) [16] and Lundberg and Pollak (1993) [30]). 11 These models are typically characterized by

a two-stage decision making process with non-cooperative solutions integrated into a generalized

Nash cooperative game. In cooperative models Pareto efficiency can be realized if information is

symmetric and agreement resulting from the game is binding and enforceable. On the contrary,

non-cooperative models have the advantage of focusing on self-enforcing equilibrium, which may

be Pareto optimal (Lundberg and Pollak (1996) [32], Basu (2006) [7] and Ligon (2002) [29]). So,

non-cooperative bargaining models do not always lead to Pareto efficient outcomes.

Chiappori (1988, 1992) [17] [18] and Apps and Rees (1988) [2] initiate an alternative theory

that assumes Pareto efficiency in the intra-household decisions. This approach was extended by

Browning, Bourguignon, Chiappori, and Lechene (1994) [14], Browning and Chiappori (1998) [15].

These types of models are called collective household models or Pareto efficient models, due to the

fact that they only make the minimal assumption that the outcomes of intra-household conflict

and collaboration are Pareto efficient. The collective approach relaxes the restrictive features of

10 Threat point as the reservation utility is one of the key features of the cooperative bargaining model.

11 Cournot Equilibrium

7

Page 8: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

the unitary model by specifying household welfare to be a weighted combination of the individuals’

utilities. These welfare weights turn out to be proxies for the power of each member of the household.

In its general form, the collective model nests cooperative Nash bargaining models as particular

cases, since the latter are based on axioms that include Pareto efficiency. Unlike the cooperative

bargaining models, no household games or decision-making mechanisms are specified. Like the

cooperative bargaining model, the outcomes are efficient. It also nests non-cooperative bargaining

models as long as they lead to Pareto efficient outcomes(Lundberg and Pollak (1994) [31]).

The main drawback of the collective model is that power of each member in the household is

fixed and exogenous. While a household’s balance of power influences its choices, the choices can

in turn affect the household’s balance of power. This feature of households is well recognised in

the descriptive and sociological literature but it has been formally modelled relatively rarely and

usually for special contexts (Basu (2006) [7]). Basu (2001a) [6] is the first attempt at endogenising

the bargaining power in a model of intra-household behaviour. To be more specific, consider a

household with two members, a man and a woman. Following the collective approach, the household

welfare function is a weighted sum of the wife’s and husband’s utility functions in which the weights

capture the balance of power within the household. In the traditional collective model of the

household, variables that determine the intra-household powers typically consists of variables that

are exogenous to the household. Basu(2001a) [6] criticises this assumption and argues that there

are reasons to believe that changes in the household’s choice vector may affect the intra-household

bargaining power. Koolwal and Ray (2002) [43] extended Basu (2001a) [6] in several ways: (i) they

generalised Basu’s framework to allow a simple test of his assumption that the female’s share of

adult wage earnings is a measure of her bargaining power, (ii) they used the relative educational

experience of the woman vis a vis the man, as a measure of her bargaining power (iii) they presented

empirical evidence on the endogenously determined welfare weight, on its variation with female

education, and on its impact on household expenditure patterns. They showed education plays an

effective role in enhancing the power of women inside the household. In their study education is

exogenous. So, their model does not allow women to choose their bargaining power. The current

study is also an attempt to endogenise bargaining power. In my model, every factor that affects the

power of the woman is endogenous and chosen by her. Moreover, this paper consider the possibility

of nonparticipation in the labour market which is neglected in Chiappori model.

8

Page 9: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

I use this framework to explain the observed positive correlation between fertility and married

women’s LFP, and negative correlation between education and married women’s LFP in Iran. There

are two groups of potential alternative explanation in the literature for these stylized facts. The

first group concerns labour supply. In particular, the prevalence of conservative attitudes towards

gender roles, especially among the urban middle classes, seems to be the preferred explanation

among researchers in the field (Salehi Esfahani and Shajari (2010) [20], Hijab (2001) [25], Gunduz-

Hosgor and Smits (2008) [22]). Although, culture and tradition account for some of the reasons

behind low female LFP, they are not the only reason. For example, Malaysia, a country with

comparable fertility and education, and similar culture,12 has twice the female LFP as Iran. 13

Moreover, cultural factors can not explain the decreasing trend of women’s LFP in Iran.

Another probable explanation is related to labour demand. International sanctions against

Iran,14 which intensified in late 2010,15 reduced Iran’s oil income by half and disrupted Iran’s import

of intermediate and capital goods that have caused factories to shut down or work with less than

half their normal capacity (Haidar (2015) [24]). As a result, employment opportunities for many

women decreased. However, international sanctions cannot explain the puzzle completely because

low and decreasing rates of LFP and employment were recorded even before sanctions. Moreover,

as Figure 4 shows in Iran, there is an inverse relationship between real GDP per capita and female

LFP. As real GDP per capita decreases, some women are laid off, but they stay in the the labour

12 Islam is central to and dominant in Iranian and Malay cultures. Muslim women are permitted to work outside thehome, but need to obtain their husbands’ permission for this. Therefore, financial responsibility for the family restssquarely on the husband, and the wife has no duty to contribute to family expenses. So, the society’s norms in thesecountries ensure that non-market activities especially homemaking are assigned to women.

13 Data Source: World Bank / World Development Indicators

14 Following the Iranian Revolution of 1979, the United States imposed sanctions against Iran and expanded themin 1995 to include firms dealing with the Iranian government. In 2006, the UN Security Council passed Resolution1696 and imposed sanctions after Iran refused to suspend its uranium enrichment program. U.S. sanctions initiallytargeted investments in oil, gas and petrochemicals, exports of refined petroleum products, and business dealingswith the Iranian Revolutionary Guard Corps. This encompasses banking and insurance transactions (including withthe Central Bank of Iran), shipping, web-hosting services for commercial endeavors, and domain name registrationservices.

15 United Nations Security Council Resolution 1929 passed in 2010, banned Iran from participating in any activitiesrelated to ballistic missiles, tightened the arms embargo, travel bans on individuals involved with the program, frozethe funds and assets of the Iranian Revolutionary Guard and Islamic Republic of Iran Shipping Lines, and recom-mended that states inspect Iranian cargo, prohibit the servicing of Iranian vessels involved in prohibited activities,prevent the provision of financial services used for sensitive nuclear activities, closely watch Iranian individuals andentities when dealing with them, prohibit the opening of Iranian banks on their territory and prevent Iranian banksfrom entering into relationship with their banks if it might contribute to the nuclear program, and prevent financialinstitutions operating in their territory from opening offices and accounts in Iran.

9

Page 10: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

market and look for jobs. Moreover, in recession some men are laid off or their income decrease,

so the necessity for supplemental income motivates inactive wives to search for a job (Karshenas

(1997) [26], Karshenas and Moghadam (2001) [27], Mirzaie (2014) [41]). This inverse relationship

is consistent with the declining portion of the U-shape relation between female participation and

GDP during the process of economic development.

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014

Rea

l GD

P p

er c

apit

a (R

ial)M

illio

ns

Wo

men

LFP

(p

erce

nt)

Women LFP Real GDP per capita

Figure 4: Real GDP per capita and Women LFP

Source: Central Bank of Iran (CBI), Statistical Center of Iran (SCI)

In addition, there have been a number of attempts to assess the role of education and family

size in women’s LFP and employment in Iran. However, most of these studies are qualitative or use

simple statistical approaches that do not discern and measure the effects of various factors (e.g.,

Alizadeh (2000) [1]; Mehran (2003) [38]; Mehryar, Farjadi, and Tabibian (2004) [39]; Rostami Povey

(2005) [46]; Rezai-Rashti and James (2009) [44]; Bahramitash and Esfahani (2009 and 2011) [5] [4]).

The studies that rely on quantitative methods are quite limited and none of them considers the

effect of intra-household bargaining power. 16

16 Salehi-Isfahani (2005) [48] analyzes the determinants of LFP and paid employment, using a Probit method and asample survey of about 6000 observations in 2001. Salehi-Isfahani and Marku (2008) [49] use a pseudo-panel based onannual household surveys during 1984-2004 to identify the age, cohort, and period effects on female LFP. Majbouri(2010) [34] employs a short panel with about 16000 observations during 1992-1995 to examine the impact of economicstability in that period on LFP.

10

Page 11: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

3 The model

This paper is a direct extension of the collective approach developed by Chiappori (1992) [18].

My model extends his theory by allowing the education, marriage and fertility decisions to be

endogenous. Thus, in this model not only the bargaining power is endogenous but also every factor

that affects the bargaining power is endogenous and chosen by women. The model of this study

is a four-part static model.17 I assume Pareto effciency18. Women make decisions for all parts at

time zero. First, the women independently invest in human capital; their decision is driven by

their ability and their cost. I assume that human capital is equal to years of schooling. When

investing in human capital, women must anticipate the outcome of their investment. This outcome

has two distinct components: (i) education augments and sorts natural abilities that are sold in

the labour market; (ii) a higher educational level has an impact on marital prospects, it affects

the expected income of the future spouse, the total utility generated within the household and the

intra-household allocation of this utility. So, education acts as a signaling and/or screening device

for unobservable ability in both the labour and marriage market. Women choose level of education

to maximize their utility, but it’s costly.

maxEduf

U(Eduf )− cost(Eduf , ability) (1)

where Eduf is female education and U is utility function.

In the second stage, women and men match on the marriage market. They choose their mate

based on their education levels, preferences for marriage and characteristics. A matching is stable

if one cannot find a woman who is currently married but would rather be single, a man who is

currently married but would rather be single, or a woman and a man who are not currently married

together but would both rather be married together than remain in their current situation. Formally,

each woman decides about her mate’s properties (education level, non-labour income and utility

preferences) to maximize gain of marriage subject to her own properties. In addition, her decision

17 Static model is time-invariant and women make decisions for all parts at time zero.

18 Keshavarz Haddad (2015) [23] shows validity of this assumption for Iranian households.

11

Page 12: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

should satisfy her husband.

maxEdum,Ym,αm

U fmarried (2)

st : M(Eduf , Y f , αf , φ) (3)

U fmarried ≥ U f

single (4)

Ummarried ≥ Um

single (5)

where Eduf and Edum are wife and husband’s education levels, Y f and Y m are wife and husband’s

non-labour income, and αf and αm are wife and husband’s preferences.

The two conditions (4) and (5) imply that married women and men would not prefer remaining

single. U fsingle and Um

single are reservation utility levels that a woman and a man require to participate

in any marriage, and U fmarried and Um

married are their utility if they marry. I assume that such

matching is feasible, so women do not need to think about the next-best solution. Moreover, I

assume full commitment assumption in marriage to avoid issues related to divorce.

After marriage, wife and husband make decisions together. In the functioning and decision

making of households, bargaining power has an important role. Bargaining power is the relative

capacity of each of the parties to negotiate or dispute to compel or secure agreements on its own

terms. Since bargaining power is unobservable, it is not possible to actually measure it. So, I need to

find a proxy for women’s bargaining power. Measures that are frequently used to proxy for women’s

bargaining power include income and employment, asset ownership (both current assets and assets

brought to marriage) and education. Koolwal and Ray (2002) [43] showed that a ceteris paribus

increase in the females educational experience leads to a significant increase in her bargaining power

inside the household; and a similar increase in the males educational experience has an opposite

effect. 19 While any woman probably prefers to have a higher-earning partner, a large difference

between their potential income decreases the wife’s bargaining power. So, if a woman can find a

mate who has similar preferences and a lower education level, she has more power in family decisions

but less money to consume. Following them, I use the wife’s share of education in the household

19 Basu (2001a[6]) used the female’s share of adult earnings to measure her bargaining power, but Koolwal and Ray(2002) [43] showed share of potential income is a better proxy for bargaining power. Since the education level isone of the most important factors in determining the income level, they used women share of education to measurebargaining power.

12

Page 13: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

(µ = Eduf

Eduf+Edum) as her bargaining power for two reasons. First, other proxies are exogenous while

there are reasons to believe that a woman’s choices can affect her bargaining power. 20 Second,

I am trying to understand the role of education and marriage in determination of the women’s

bargaining power. Since wife’s share of education in the household can reflect woman’s decision

about her education level and husband’s properties, I use this proxy to measure women’s bargaining

power.

After marriage, wife and husband decide about the number of children. Fertility decision is a

function of wife and husband’s preferences and the costs of children, given an income constraint

(Becker 2009 [9]). Parents receive utility from being mother and father but it is costly for them. 21

Since their utility and cost function are different, the final decision depends on their bargaining

power. So, wife and husband maximize a weighted sum of utility functions minus cost functions:

maxN

µ ∗ [Mom(θf , N)− costf (θf , N)] + (1− µ) ∗ [Dad(θm, N)− costm(θm, N)] (6)

where µ is the wife’s bargaining power and (1− µ) is her husband’s. Mom is wife’s utility of being

the mother that is the function of her preferences θf and the number of children N . Similarly,

Dad is husband’s utility of being the father. These two functions are an inverted-U function of the

number of children (N). The functions costf and costm are cost functions of having children for the

mother and the father. µ is the wife’s bargaining power and (1− µ) is her husband’s.

Finally, in the last part couples and their children consume goods and supply labour subject to

the family budget and time constraints. Following Chiappori (1992) [18], wife and husband behave

as a single decision maker maximizing the weighted sum of the spouses’ utilities:

maxCf ,Cm,Cc,lf ,lm,Lf ,Lm

µ ∗ U f (Cf , lf ) + (1− µ) ∗ Um(Cm, lm) +N ∗ Uk(Ck) (7)

st : p ∗ (Cf + Cm +N ∗ Ck) +W f ∗ lf +Wm ∗ lm < Y +W f ∗ Lf +Wm ∗ Lm (8)

T f = Lf + lf , Tm = Lm + lm (9)

20 Basu(2001a) [6]

21 The costs of children include opportunity costs (the earning loss from reduced labour supply), child-care costs(including the availability of child-care) and time costs of raising and educating a child (including the domesticdivision of labour).

13

Page 14: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

where U f and Um are wife and husband’s utility functions that depend on both consumption C

and leisure l. Also, Uk is child’s utility functions that is a function of consumption Ck. I assume

that all children are homogeneous. Assuming the preferences are rational, monotonic, convex and

continuous, the utility functions are increasing and quasi-concave. It is assumed that spouses know

each other’s and their children’s preferences. Furthermore, I assume that each household member

is endowed with direct preferences on her/his own leisure and consumption. Therefore, household

members have egoistic preferences. However, as Chiappori (1992) [18] showed, “caring” form of

individual preferences would lead to identical results. p is the price of consumption, and Lf and

Lm are labour supply by wife and husband. T is the individual’s total time. Y is the non-labour

income of the family. 22 W f and Wm are wife and husband’s wage that are functions of their

characteristics such as education, age, and economic conditions. I assume wife and husband pool

their labour and non-labour earnings between themselves. Women participate in the labour force if

their market wage exceeds their reservation wage. This decision depends on a vector of explanatory

variables including the personal and family characteristics of the woman such as age, education,

number of children, household income without her wage income, the characteristic of her husband

(status of work and education), and economic conditions. Again, since wife’s and husband’s utility

functions are different, their decision depends on bargaining power. Internal decision processes are

cooperative, in the sense that they systematically lead to Pareto-efficient outcomes. Figure 5 shows

the relationship between all variables of the model.

Figure 5: Schematic Diagram of Whole Model

22 The non-labour income includes financial transferred aids, real estate incomes, subsidies, interest on bank deposits,bounds yield and share dividends, scholarships and cash gifts from others.

14

Page 15: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

I solve the model by working backwards from the last part. So, I start with the labour supply

and consumption decisions. At the third stage they decide about the number of children. Then

I move to the second stage, i.e. the marriage market. The marriage decision is made by women

based on preferences and education levels. However, her decision should satisfy her husband. The

solution of this stage allows me to construct the utility of woman, conditional on her education level

that is chosen at the first part. Table 6 in appendix B shows a list of all variables of the model.

As this table shows, price index (p), non-labour income (y), individuals’ total time (T f&Tm) and

age (agef&agem) are pre-determined variables. The price index (p) and individuals’ total time

(T f&Tm) are normalized to 1. The source of other exogenous variables is HIES. Other variables

of the model including wife and husband’s consumption (Cf&Cm), leisure (lf&lm), labour supply

(Lf&Lm), wage (W f&Wm) and education level (Eduf&Edum) are endogenous. Wife and husband’s

consumption (Cf&Cm) are unobservable, but I can observe total consumption from HIES. Also, I

have wage (W f&Wm), education level (Eduf&Edum) and labour supply (Lf&Lm) from the data

set. By having labour supply, I can calculate leisure (lf = 1 − Lf&lm = 1 − Lm). Moreover,

wife’s intra-household bargaining power is endogenous and is determined by wife and her husband’s

education levels.

4 Solving the model

I solve the model by working backwards from the last stage. Since my focus in this paper is on

LFP not fertility, I solve the model for couples with no children (N = 0). 23 In this framework,

the household consists of two individuals with distinct utility functions and the decision process

leads to Pareto efficient outcomes. I start with the labour supply and consumption decisions and

23 Allowing for children is left for the future work.

15

Page 16: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

consider Cobb-Douglas preferences:

maxCf ,Cm,lf ,lm,Lf ,Lm

µ ∗ Ln[(Cf )αf ∗ (lf )1−αf ] + (1− µ) ∗ Ln[(Cm)αm ∗ (lm)1−αm ] (10)

st : p ∗ (Cf + Cm) +W f ∗ lf +Wm ∗ lm < Y +W f ∗ Lf +Wm ∗ Lm (11)

T f = Lf + lf (12)

Tm = Lm + lm (13)

The price index (p) and individuals’ total time (T f&Tm) are normalized to 1. I assume that

individuals’ preferences (αf and αm), and so the optimal level of consumption and leisure are

different during lifetime. After solving F.O.Cs of this maximization problem, I have four equations

in four unknowns (Cf , Cm, lf , lm):

Cf = αf ∗ µ ∗ (Y +W f +Wm) (14)

Cm = αm ∗ (1− µ) ∗ (Y +W f +Wm) (15)

lf =(1− αf ) ∗ µ ∗ (Y +W f +Wm)

2W f(16)

lm =(1− αm) ∗ µ ∗ (Y +W f +Wm)

2Wm(17)

Cf and Cm are unobservable. In fact, I can only observe total consumption (C = Cf + Cm).

As equation(16) implies the optimal amount of wife’s labour supply (1−lf ) is an inverse function

of her bargaining power (µ) and her non-labour earning 24 (Y +Wm). Another variable that affects

a woman’s labour supply is her wage (W f ). If wage increases, on the one hand, the opportunity

cost of leisure increases. This tends to cause the woman to give up leisure and work more (the

substitution effect). On the other hand, the higher wage increases her income for a given number

of hours. This increase in income tends to cause her to supply less labour in order to spend the

higher income on leisure (the income effect).

I now move to the second stage (the marriage market). Women and men match on the marriage

24 As I mentioned before, I assume wife and husband pool their labour and non-labour earnings between themselves.So, wife’s labour income is W f and her non-labour earning is sum of family non-labour income (Y ) and her husband’swage (Wm).

16

Page 17: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

market and their decision constrained by preferences, non-labour incomes and education levels.

Although, there is the emotional gain from being married relative to remaining single, for simplicity

I assume the gain of marriage is only economics gain. A woman will marry if :

U fmarried ≥ U f

single (18)

⇒ Ln[(Cf )αf ∗ (lf )1−αf ] ≥ Ln[(Cfs )αf ∗ (lfs )1−αf ] (19)

where Cf is her consumption if she marries and Cfs is her consumption if she remains single.

Maximization problem for a single woman is:

maxCf

s ,lfs ,L

fs

U fsingle = Ln[(Cf

s )αf ∗ (lfs )1−αf ] (20)

st : p ∗ Cfs +W f ∗ lfs < Y f +W f ∗ Lfs (21)

T f = Lfs + lfs (22)

By taking F.O.C.s and solving them, I obtain the consumption and leisure in single case (Cfs and

lfs ):

Cfs = αf ∗ (Y f +W f ) (23)

lfs =(1− αf ) ∗ (Y f +W f )

W f(24)

By substitution equations (14), (16), (23) and (24) in (19), I have minimum value of the bargaining

power that a woman require to participate in any marriage:

µ ≥ Y f +W f

Y f +W f + Y m +Wm∗ (2)1−αf (25)

Similarly, a man will prefer to marry if:

Ummarried ≥ Um

single ⇒ Ln[(Cm)αm ∗ (lm)1−αm ] ≥ Ln[(Cms )αm ∗ (lms )1−αm ] (26)

⇒ µ ≤ Y m +Wm

Y f +W f + Y m +Wm∗ (2)1−αm (27)

17

Page 18: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

By combining two conditions (25) and (27), a woman and a man match on the marriage market if:

Y f +W f

Y f +W f + Y m +Wm∗ (2)1−αf ≤ µ ≤ Y m +Wm

Y f +W f + Y m +Wm∗ (2)1−αm (28)

Formally, each woman decides about her mate’s education level to maximize her utility subject

to her own properties. 25 In addition, her decision should satisfy her husband’s reservation utility.

maxEdum

µ ∗ Ln[(Cf )αf ∗ (lf )1−αf ] + (1− µ) ∗ Ln[(Cm)αm ∗ (lm)1−αm ] (29)

st : p ∗ (Cf + Cm) +W f ∗ lf +Wm ∗ lm < Y +W f ∗ Lf +Wm ∗ Lm (30)

Y f +W f

Y f +W f + Y m +Wm∗ (2)1−αf ≤ µ ≤ Y m +Wm

Y f +W f + Y m +Wm∗ (2)1−αm (31)

µ =Eduf

Eduf + Edum(32)

F.O.C:

Edum = F1(Eduf ;αf , αm,W

f ,Wm, Y ) (33)

F.O.C of this problem is nonlinear function of Edum and analytical solution is impossible, so I have

to apply numerical methods in order to find the solution. Edum is a function of parameters (αf , αm),

incomes (wages and non-labour income) and Eduf . Family non-labour income is exogenous and

Eduf is chosen at the first part. In this model, wages are endogenous. Individual’s wage varies

by gender and education. Most papers also use the experience as explanatory variable in the wage

equation, but for the HIES data set I can not observe any variable to calculate the experience.

Since there is negative correlation between experience and education, 26 omitting this variable

would therefore produce a bias to the estimated effect of the education level on the wage (β1f 6= β1f

and β1m 6= β1m ). To solve this omitted variable bias problem, age is commonly used as a proxy

for years of work experience. 27 For simplicity, I consider the wage equation as a linear function of

25 For simplicity, I assume husband’s non-labour income and utility preference are exogenous for women.

26 People who pursue higher education have lower levels of experience.

27 Mincer (1974) [40] uses the transformation experience = age - years of schooling - 6, which assumes that a workerbegins full-time work immediately after completing his education and the age of school completion is years of schooling+ 6.

18

Page 19: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

education, age, square of age and time: 28

W f = β0f + β1f ∗ Eduf + β2f ∗ agef + β3f ∗ (agef )2

+ λf ∗ t (34)

Wm = β0m + β1m ∗ Edum + β2m ∗ agem + β3m ∗ (agem)2 + λm ∗ t (35)

Finally, in the first part women choose the level of education:

maxEduf

µ ∗ Ln[(Cf )αf ∗ (lf )1−αf ] + (1− µ) ∗ Ln[(Cm)αm ∗ (lm)1−αm ]− Cost(eduf ) (36)

st : p ∗ (Cf + Cm) +W f ∗ lf +Wm ∗ lm < Y +W f ∗ Lf +Wm ∗ Lm (37)

T f = Lf + lf (38)

Tm = Lm + lm (39)

F.O.C:

Eduf = F2(αf , αm, β0f , β1f , β2f , β3f , β0m, β1m, β2m, β3m, λf , λm, Y ) (40)

F.O.C of this problem is a nonlinear equation and analytical solution is impossible, so I apply

numerical methods to find Eduf . After solving this problem and finding Eduf , I have W f by using

equation (34). By substitution Eduf in F.O.C of second stage (equation (33)), I have Edum and

then µ (equation(32)) and Wm (equation (35)). Now, I have all variables that I need for computing

Cf , Cm, lf and lm.

28 t is a time trend variable introduced to control for time-varying factors such as economic conditions. I do notinclude the square of education in wage equations because this variable is not significant.

19

Page 20: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

5 Data

This paper uses a pseudo-panel data:29 Iran’s Household Income and Expenditure Survey (HIES)

from 2006 to 2013 for estimation and testing the fitness of the model. 30 The statistical Center of

Iran (SCI) reports this database, which covers near 60000 households every year. For my analysis,

the sample consists of couples in which wives and husbands are aged between 15 and 65 and do not

have children. I also exclude from the sample all students, men who are doing mandatory military

services, those who are physically unable to work, and those who are prohibited by law from working.

Since the behaviour of rural and urban households is different, I only study households who live in

urban regions of the country.

The advantage of this survey is that it not only contains very rich information on individuals’

demographic characteristics (such as age, gender, marital status, relation with the head of fam-

ily and years of education), but also includes detailed information on individuals’ socioeconomic

characteristics (i.e. employment, income, expenditures, etc). Although true panel data for Iranian

families is not available, Deaton (1985) [19] identified four advantages of pseudo panel data. First,

data from different sources can be combined into a single set of pseudo panel data if comparable

cohorts can be defined in each source. Second, attrition problems often found in true panel data are

minimized. Third, the use of cohort means and errors-invariables methods smooth and control the

problem of the individuals’ response errors. Fourth, moving from individual data to larger cohorts

and to one macro cohort can analyze inconsistencies between micro and macro analysis.

However, this data set has some limitations. The HIES does not provide “annual” hours of

work. Instead, individuals are asked to report the “daily” hours of work and the number of days

they worked during the last week. So, I calculate the annual hours of work as (daily hours of work ×

number of work days during the last week × number of weeks in a year). Moreover, HIES does not

provide the wage rate, which is the average hourly earnings. I define the wage rate by dividing total

net yearly labour income including permanent and nonpermanent incomes (over time working) for

29 Individuals and families are not followed over time. However, this data set is constructed by defining cohorts usingindividual characteristics that are stable over (e.g., income, family size, ...) to reduce year to year fluctuations andto make consecutive year samples more similar. So, this database is pooling comparable cross-section data collectedrepeatedly over time. However, this database is not true panel data and it is not possible to apply the normal paneldata techniques on this data set.

30 This data set is available from 1984 but some essential variables for this study such as hours of work were notasked before 2006.

20

Page 21: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

wage earners, and net labour income for employees with private and self employed jobs, over annual

working hours. Another limitation of HIES is that it does not provide the non-labour income, but

it reports detailed composition of individuals’ income. So, I consider the non-labour income as

summation of financial transferred aids, real estate incomes, subsidies, interest on bank deposits,

bonds yield and share dividends, scholarships, and cash gifts from others.

Table 1: Sample Descriptive Statistics for Married Individuals

Variables 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

College educated(percentage)

Wives whole sample 8.88 9.60 10.33 9.11 11.02 10.66 10.61 13.50

employed women 41.13 44.97 48.68 42.86 50.36 51.14 50.04 52.87Husbands whole sample 7.51 7.78 8.05 7.29 8.25 8.12 8.17 11.96

employed men 15.73 16.72 17.09 15.39 17.28 17.19 17.02 26.28Fertility Rate Wives whole sample 2.182 2.118 2.089 2.099 2.003 1.967 1.909 1.746

(1.555) (1.536) (1.441) (1.463) (1.381) (1.353) (1.322) (1.308)College educated 1.448 1.360 1.436 1.396 1.426 1.460 1.431 1.285

(1.071) (1.009) (0.947) (0.986) (0.958) (0.963) (0.972) (0.934)College educated and employed 1.653 1.591 1.647 1.673 1.643 1.694 1.696 1.568

(1.030) (1.029) (0.912) (0.969) (0.928) (0.937) (0.933) (0.942)Participation Rate Wives whole sample 11.2 10.8 10.3 10.2 9.1 8.4 7.9 8.5

College educated 53.1 52.8 49.4 49.1 42.5 41.0 38.4 34.3Husbands whole sample 41.9 42.0 40.9 40.6 39.2 38.4 38.0 38.2

College educated 86.1 88.7 85.8 84.2 81.1 79.6 78.0 82.5Employment Rate Wives whole sample 10.3 9.9 9.6 9.5 8.4 7.9 7.3 7.8

College educated 47.8 46.6 45.4 44.7 38.8 38.0 34.7 30.7Husbands whole sample 40.80 40.90 39.97 39.27 38.28 37.26 36.91 37.06

College educated 85.50 87.88 84.84 82.91 80.22 78.90 76.92 81.45Daily work hours Wives employed women 4.893 4.919 5.078 4.840 4.925 4.999 4.923 4.806

(2.28) (2.27) (2.28) (2.24) (2.15) (2.11) (2.08) (2.00)College educated and employed 4.627 4.824 4.888 4.797 5.023 4.970 4.866 4.807

(1.71) (1.83) (1.76) (1.70) (1.75) (1.68) (1.71) (1.72)Husbands employed men 7.653 7.606 7.573 7.327 7.288 7.267 7.165 6.946

(2.405) (2.392) (2.426) (2.428) (2.350) (2.266) (2.298) (2.226)College educated and employed 6.879 6.826 6.852 6.555 6.762 6.702 6.577 6.546

(2.207) (2.179) (2.217) (2.057) (2.041) (2.032) (1.943) (1.960)

Bargaining Power Wives31 whole sample 0.432 0.437 0.434 0.432 0.436 0.436 0.434 0.446

Eduf

Eduf+Edum (0.201) (0.197) (0.198) (0.203) (0.200) (0.199) (0.202) (0.199)

College educated 0.558 0.560 0.559 0.568 0.565 0.563 0.561 0.554(0.062) (0.059) (0.068) (0.073) (0.069) (0.064) (0.061) (0.055)

College educated and employed 0.542 0.540 0.544 0.558 0.547 0.549 0.549 0.542(0.057) (0.054) (0.063) (0.072) (0.066) (0.063) (0.058) (0.054)

Table 1 reports the descriptive statistics of key variables during the period 2006-2013. As this

table shows, the percentage of college graduates has increased from 9% to 13.5% in the whole

sample, and the same pattern exists in the sample of employed women (Figure 8 in appendix A). At

the same time, fertility has decreased from 2.2 births per woman in 2006 to 1.7 in 2013. Although

there are similar trends for employed women and college educated employed women, it is interesting

to know college educated women who work have more children on average (Figure 9 in appendix A).

Despite the increase in the education level and decline in the fertility rate, females’ participation in

the labour market has decreased from 11% in 2006 to 8.5% in 2013. College educated females have

higher participation rates than the others, but it has seen a sharper downward trend from 53% in

2006 to 34% in 2013 (Figure 10 in appendix A). The same pattern exists for employment rate. It

has decreased from 10% to 7% for the whole sample and from 48% to 31% for college educated

31 Husbands’ Bargaining Power=1-Wives’ Bargaining Power

21

Page 22: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

women (Figure 11 in appendix A). In addition, average of daily work hours has decreased slightly

over time. As previously mentioned, I use wife’s share of education in the household ( Eduf

Eduf+Edum)

as her bargaining power in this paper. Although the values of this indicator for educated women

are greater than the whole sample, the bargaining power for educated women who work is lower

compared to all educated women. For instance, in 2006 the average of bargaining power was 0.56 for

educated women, and 0.54 for employed educated women. 32 Overall, we observe low and decreasing

trend of LFP, employment rate, and daily work hour of married women together with low birth

rate and high education level in Iran.

Prior to using this pseudo panel data set, I address two data issues: (1) cohort stability over

time and (2) differentiation between age, period, and cohort effects.

1. Establishing the stability of cohorts over time

Since it is impossible for this pseudo panel data set to track individual households over time,

Deaton (1985) [19] proposed to track cohorts through such data. A cohort is defined as a group

with fixed membership. So, an individual is a member of exactly one cohort which is the same

for all periods, for instance age cohorts or cohorts based on sex. I defined cohorts using gender

and generation to prevent the movement of individuals between cohorts over time. Moreover,

since this paper only studies households who live in urban regions, I eliminate immigrants to

the urban area from the data to maintain cohort stability.

Construction of a pseudo panel involves a trade-off between the number of cohorts and the

number of observations in each cohort. If the number of cohorts is large, estimations will suf-

fer less from small sample problems. However, if the size of each cohort is not large enough,

average characteristics per cohort will estimate true cohort population means with large sam-

pling error (Deaton (1985) [19]). In this study, the gender characteristic consisted of a male

cohort and a female cohort, and the generation characteristic consisted of six cohorts, which

each cohort representing a ten-year span. The first and sixth generation cohorts contained

individuals born between 1941 and 1950 and between 1991 and 1998, respectively. The gender

(2), and generation (6) cohort definitions describe 12 potential (2*6 = 12) cohorts. Repeated

over the eight census years, there is a potential of 96 cells of cohort mean data. Table 5

32 I check wife’s asset share in the household as another indicator for women’s bargaining power and I observe similartrends.

22

Page 23: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

(in appendix A) lists the number of individuals contained in each cohort.

2. Differentiating between age, period, and cohort (APC) effects

When a data set contains observations on many individuals over an extended period of time,

observed variance can be attributed to three related effects: (a) differences between cohorts,

which are labeled the cohort effects; (b) differences associated with different points in the life

cycle, which are labeled the age effects; and/or (c) differences associated with different periods,

which are labeled the period effects. 33 We cannot identify these three effects simultaneously

because only one time dimension and one individual or cohort dimension exists. More specif-

ically, the functional relationship between all three effects causes perfect collinearity when all

three effects are fully specified (period=age+cohort) (Fienberg and Mason (1985) [21] and

Ryder (1965) [47]). The question of how best to solve this identification problem has gener-

ated controversy, especially among sociologists (Rodgers (1982) [45] and Smith, Mason, and

Fienberg (1982) [51]). Although there is a variety of approaches to solve the APC conundrum,

each has limitations. One common approach is to impose a linear restriction on any pair of

age, period, or cohort variables (e.g., if the membership in the cohort born 1971-1980 is no

different from membership in the 1981-1990 cohort, then I can restrict the cohort effects to be

equal for this pair). For estimating parameters of utility functions, I address the age, period,

and cohort identification problem by using a linear restriction that all age effects are equal

and are included in the constant term. Thus, individuals’ preferences differ across cohorts,

and an individual’s preferences change over time. However, this change is related to time

effect, not age effect.

33 The difference between age effects, period effects and cohort effects is well explicated by this fictional dialogue bySuzuki (2012) [52]:A: I can’t seem to shake off this tired feeling. Guess I’m just getting old. [Age effect]B: Do you think it’s stress? Business is down this year, and you’ve let your fatigue build up.[Period effect]A: Maybe. What about you?B: Actually, I’m exhausted too! My body feels really heavy.A: You’re kidding. You’re still young. I could work all day long when I was your age.B: Oh, really?A: Yeah, young people these days are quick to whine. We were not like that. [Cohort effect]

23

Page 24: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

6 Estimation

In this section, I use the mechanism described in section 4 to estimate the model described in sec-

tion 3. This model has two groups of parameters: utility function parameters (αf , αm), and wage

functions parameters (β0f , β1f , β2f , β3f , λf , β0m, β1m, β2m, β3m, λm). I have six equations ((14) to

(17),(33) and (40)) to estimate these parameters:

Cf = αf ∗ µ ∗ (Y +W f +Wm) (14)

Cm = αm ∗ (1− µ) ∗ (Y +W f +Wm) (15)

lf =(1− αf ) ∗ µ ∗ (Y +W f +Wm)

2W f(16)

lm =(1− αm) ∗ µ ∗ (Y +W f +Wm)

2Wm(17)

Edum = F1(Eduf ;αf , αm,W

f ,Wm, Y ) (33)

Eduf = F2(αf , αm, β0f , β1f , β2f , β3f , β0m, β1m, β2m, β3m, λf , λm, Y ) (40)

Cf and Cm are unobservable. In fact, I can only observe total consumption (C = Cf + Cm). So, I

combine (14) and (15):

C = Cf + Cm = αf ∗ µ ∗ (Y +W f +Wm) + αm ∗ (1− µ) ∗ (Y +W f +Wm) (41)

This system of equations is underdetermined34 because I have five equations ((16), (17),(33),(40)

and (41)) and twelve parameters (αf , αm, β0f , β1f , β2f , β3f , λf , β0m, β1m, β2m, β3m, λm). Therefore,

I have to estimate reduced form of wage functions to estimate the wages parameters, i.e., β0f , β1f ,

β2f , β3f , λf , β0m, β1m, β2m, β3m and λm. Then, taking estimated wages parameters, I estimate

parameters of utility functions (αf and αm) by using F.O.Cs ((16), (17),(33),(40) and (41)).

I estimate parameters of wage equations by Heckman two-stage method. I have access to wage

observations for only those who work. Since people who work are not selected randomly from the

population, estimating the determinants of wages from the subpopulation who work may introduce

bias. The Heckman correction takes place in two stages. Women’s decision to work depends on their

34 There are fewer equations than unknowns.

24

Page 25: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

reservation wage (which depend on education35 and age), bargaining power (her and her husband

education), and economic conditions.36 Moreover, as illustrated before, wages differ according to

gender, education and age:

W fit = β0f + β1f ∗ Edufit + β2f ∗ agefit + β3f ∗ (agefit)

2+ λf ∗ t+ uit regression equation (42)

zct ∗ γf + vct > 0 z = [age, bargaining power, economic conditions] selection equation (43)

where W fit is the female i’s real hourly wage at time t, and similarly for the other variables in the

model. t is a time trend variable introduced to control for time-varying factors such as economic

conditions. Table 2 reports the estimated parameters of these two equations.

Table 2: Estimation results : Wife’s Wage Equation

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)

Equation 1 : Real Wage per hourβ1f : years of schooling 3002.443∗∗ (259.296)β2f : age 11911.328∗∗ (947.624)β3f : age2 -146.615∗∗ (12.884)λf : t -3397.757∗∗ (199.667)

Equation 2 : selection equationage 0.230∗∗ (0.016)age2 -0.003∗∗ (0.000)bargaining power 3.133∗∗ (0.403)bargaining power2 -2.453∗∗ (0.355)t -0.069∗∗ (0.003)

Significance levels † : 10 % ∗ : 5 % ∗∗ : 1 %

The estimated coefficient of the selection equation shows that age has a positive but decreasing

effect on women’s LFP. We expect age to affect participation through two mechanisms: (i) its

impact on an individual’s work-leisure preferences, and (ii) through the impact of experience in

the labour market. Younger women are more likely to be enrolled in full-time education and thus

less likely to participate in the labour market. Middle-aged women will have more experience and

likely more family responsibilities than their younger counterparts and will thus be more inclined to

35 Literacy level is measured by the years of schooling

36 I tried some other variables such as non-labour income (i.e. rent, interest, financial aid, transfers and income ofhomemade products) and family’s income from selling used durable goods. But they are insignificant. Also, I triedhusband’s income, but it has collinearity with bargaining power.

25

Page 26: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

participate in the labour force. Older women are more likely to have significant resources available

for retirement and are less likely to participate as they approach the regular age of retirement.

Regarding the effect of bargaining power on women’s LFP, the estimated results show that

bargaining power has a positive but decreasing effect. As a woman’s bargaining power increases,

she participates more in the labour market. However, over a certain level of bargaining power,

women are less likely to work outside the home. Moreover, the time effect is negative, which means

time-varying factors such as economic conditions make women less likely to participate in the labour

market.

Table 2 also shows the estimated coefficient of the wage equation. Concerning the education

variable, I find that a higher education level increases the hourly wage and the effect is statistically

significant. Moreover, the age has a positive and significant effect on the hourly wage. However,

the effect of the square of the age is negative, which means that over a certain age, the wage does

not increase any more. Furthermore, the time effect is negative, which shows a decreasing trend of

real hourly wage for women over time. Table 7 (in appendix C) provides more details of Heckman’s

method for regression and selection equations.

Since 99% of husbands are employed in my sample, I assume all men participate in the labour

market. Thus, I do not need to estimate the selection equation for them. I estimate the wage

equation for men as a linear function of education, age, square of age and time:

Wmit = β0m + β1m ∗ Edumit + β2m ∗ agemit + β3m ∗ (agemit )

2 + λm ∗ t+ eit (44)

where Wmit is the male i’s real hourly wage at time t, and similarly for the other variables. Again,

I control time-varying factors by t. Table 3 reports the estimated parameters of the men’s wage

equation.

The results suggest that education has a positive effect on men’s hourly wage. Moreover, the

time effect is negative, which means that the trend of real hourly wage is decreasing over time. The

concavity of the wage is captured by the quadratic age terms, age and age2, whose coefficients, β2m

and β3m, are respectively positive and negative. So, the age has a positive on the hourly wage,

but over a certain age, the wage does not increase any more. Table 8 provides more details (in

appendix C).

26

Page 27: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

Table 3: Estimation results : (Husband’s Wage Equation)

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)β1m : years of schooling 2047.275∗∗ (131.658)β2m : age 1184.347∗∗ (261.091)β3m : age2 -7.566∗∗ (2.900)λm : t -1838.469∗∗ (233.961)β0f : Intercept 137507.153∗∗ (20770.722)

Significance levels † : 10 % ∗ : 5 % ∗∗ : 1 %

Taking the wages parameters estimated above, I can estimate parameters of utility functions

based on the generalized method of moments (GMM). I use F.O.Cs of all parts of the model

(equations (16), (17), (33), (40) and (41)) as moment conditions. To estimate these parameters,

as Deaton (1985) [19] suggests, I use the mean-based pseudo-panel approach to track cohorts of

individuals. 37 Mean-based pseudo panels suffer less from problems related to measurement error at

the individual level because they follow cohort means. As mentioned previously, I address the age,

period, and cohort identification problem by using a linear restriction that all age effects are equal.

So, individuals’ preferences differ across cohorts, and an individual’s preferences change over time.

However, this change is related to time effects, not age effects. Tables 9 and 10 (in appendix C)

show estimated parameters of utility functions for each cohort at each year. As these tables show,

preferences are not the same for all cohorts. In all years, the first (born between 1941 and 1950) and

the sixth (born between 1991 and 1998) cohorts have the greatest value of αf , and fourth cohorts

(born between 1971 and 1980) has the smallest value of αf . So, there is a U-shaped relationship

between αf and cohort. The trend for αm is different. This trend is deceasing, i.e. the first cohort

has the greatest value of αm and sixth cohort has the smallest value of αm through all years.

Since the number of moment conditions (five F.O.Cs) is greater than the dimension of the

parameter vector (αf , αm), the model is over-identified. Over-identification allows me to check

whether or not the model’s moment conditions match the data well. The J-test shows that I can

not reject the null hypothesis (H0 : m(αf , αm) = 0), so the validity of the model cannot be rejected.

Table 4 summarizes estimates of parameters and standard errors of the female and male utility

functions and wage equations. Values of αf and αm in this table are average values of all cohorts

over time. Although there is heterogeneity across the various cohorts, on average, values leisure

37 This approach is equivalent to an instrumental variables approach where the grouping variables is the instrument.

27

Page 28: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

are greater for women than for men. So, women are less likely than men to participate in labour

market. Moreover, this table shows that education has positive effect on wage earnings for both

women and men, and their wages are inverse U-shaped functions of age. Also, the trend of real

hourly wage, for both women and men, is decreasing over time.

Table 4: Parameter Estimates

Parameter Value (Std. Err.) Parameter Value (Std. Err.)

Female’s Utility Parameter Male’s Utility Parameter

αf 0.998 (0.0031) αm 0.865 (0.0015)

Female’s Wage Parameters Male’s Wage Parameters

β0m 137507.2 (20770.7)β1f 3002.4 (259.3) β1m 2047.3 (131.6)β2f 11911.3 (947.6) β2m 1184.3 (261.1)β3f -146.6 (12.9) β3m -7.6 (2.9)λf -3397.7 (199.7) λm -1838.5 (234.0)

7 Simulation and Goodness of Fit

This section presents the evidence of the within-sample fit of the model. To measure how well the

model describes the data, I compare the individuals’ actual choices with predicted measures of their

decisions. I use estimated parameters and exogenous variables (age and family non-labour income)

to simulate the model and obtain predicted variables.

A goodness-of-fit test cannot reject the model at the 5% level of significance. Figures ?? to 7

compare some predicted to actual variables. Full lines are for HIES data and the dashed lines

are for model simulations. As shown in these figures, the estimated model fits key features of the

women’s behaviour in the labour market well. As Figures 6 shows, the model is also able to replicate

decreasing trend of women’s LFP that we observe in the actual data.

Figures 7 presents the fit of the model with the women’s participation according to their intra-

household bargaining power. Women’s LFP is an inverse U-shaped function of bargaining power in

data, and the simulations replicate that pattern.

28

Page 29: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................

.......................................................................................................................................................... ........... ........... ........... ........... ...................... ........... ........... ........... ........... ...................... ........... ........... ........... ........... ...................... ........... ........... ........... ........... ...........

........................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................

................................

................................

................................

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.......

.....

................

................

................

................

................

................

810

1214

1618

..............................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................

Women’s LFP

Year

Percent

...................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................

..................................

..................................

..................................

.....................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................

....................................

....................................

....................................

.................................... ............................

........ ....................................

.................................... ............................

........

........................

........................

........................

........................

........................

........................

........................

........................

........................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................

..............................................

........... ........... ......

actualsimulated

Figure 6: Women’s Labour Force Participation

2.20

1.011.68

1.08

9.57

16.45

6.76

9.92

3.57 3.60

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

0-0.1 0.1- 0.2 0.2-0.3 0.3- 0.4 0.4- 0.5 0.5- 0.6 0.6- 0.7 0.7- 0.8 0.8- 0.9 0.9- 0.10

Wo

men

's L

FP(p

erce

nt)

Women's Bargaining Power

Actual LFP

Simulted LFP

Figure 7: Women’s Labour Force Participation fordifferent Bargaining Power

8 Solve The Puzzle

In this section, I provides an explanation for the female labour supply puzzle in Iran. Aggregated

time series data for developed countries reveal a negative relationship between fertility and LFP

of women, and a positive relationship between LFP of women and their level of education. In

contrast, data for Iran reveal a positive relationship between fertility and LFP of women, and a

negative relationship between LFP of women and their level of education.

TotalLFP = (LFPlowBPwomen ∗ percentage of low BP women in population)

+(LFPmidBPwomen ∗ percentage of mid BP women in population)

+(LFPhighBPwomen ∗ percentage of high BP women in population) (45)

29

Page 30: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

9 Conclusion

Why is women’s labour force participation in Iran low and decreasing, despite an increase in educa-

tion levels and decline in fertility rates? This is different from the trend observed in many developed

countries. In such countries, women’s LFP has increased as birth rate has declined and women’s ed-

ucation has increased in the past few decades. Several covariates may create the present situation in

Iran. This study has tried to answer the above question by highlighting the role of intra-household

bargaining power. The main idea is that education has two different effects. On one hand, higher

education increases potential wage and thus increases the probability of participation in the labour

market. On the other hand, when education increases, women’s bargaining power will increase.

Greater bargaining power allows women to steer allocations in their preferred direction. For in-

stance, women with larger bargaining power tend to have fewer children and prefer staying at home

to working outside if they find little opportunity in the labor market. Thus, an increase in women’s

household bargaining power can account for a negative education-LFP relationship as well as a

negative education-fertility relationship.

To be specific, I have presented a structural model of education choice, marriage, fertility and

labour supply. This paper extends the general collective model of the household by allowing bar-

gaining power to be endogenous. This framework allows us to simulate policies that change the

economic environment at any stage of the lifecycle. I used data from 2006 to 2013 Iranian Household

Income and Expenditure Survey (HIES) for estimation and testing the fitness of this model.

I found that women’s labour force participation is an inverse U-shaped function of bargaining

power. Women’s LFP initially increases as bargaining power goes up, but start decreasing after

bargaining power reaches a certain level. Therefore, as a woman’s bargaining power increases, she

participates more in the labour market. However, over a certain level of bargaining power, women

are less likely to work outside the home. Moreover, the data shows bargaining power inequality in

Iran has increased, so number of women with very low and very high level of bargaining power has

increased. According to the results, these two groups are less likely to participate in labour market.

Thus, in the case of Iran, women’s LFP has decreased, despite an increase in education levels and

decline in fertility rates.

There are several limitations to my model that should be addressed in future work. First, my

30

Page 31: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

focus in this paper was on LFP not fertility, so I solved the model for couples with no children. One

generalization is to allow for children. Second, I assumed that human capital is equal to years of

schooling. It would be more precise to add ability to human capital function, but I can not observe

any variable in the HIES to calculate the ability. So, I need to find a proxy or assume a distribution

for ability, that would be left for the future work. Finally, it would be interesting to study the

behaviour of educated women instead of the whole sample.

31

Page 32: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

A Data

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

College educated

whole sample employed women

Figure 8: College Educated Women(percentage)

0.000

0.500

1.000

1.500

2.000

2.500

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

Fertility Rate

whole sample College educated College educated and employed

Figure 9: Fertility Rate

0.0

10.0

20.0

30.0

40.0

50.0

60.0

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

Labor Force Participation

whole sample College educated

Figure 10: Labour Force Participation

5.0

10.0

15.0

20.0

25.0

30.0

35.0

40.0

45.0

50.0

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

employment Rate

whole sample College educated

Figure 11: Employment Rate

32

Page 33: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

Table 5: Total Number of Observations in Each Cohort

Years2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

Female born:1941-1950 29 42 26 30 30 12 17 181951-1960 44 44 73 76 75 83 114 891961-1970 44 42 68 79 70 101 125 981971-1980 207 172 190 159 134 126 103 781981-1990 426 458 458 414 425 364 312 3781991-1998 - 9 20 41 59 88 113 123

Male born:1931-1940 25 24 25 24 21 15 14 141941-1950 30 50 36 52 49 43 61 461951-1960 34 41 81 85 81 102 132 1131961-1970 67 69 78 65 64 82 87 591971-1980 413 366 352 291 246 197 156 1371981-1990 181 217 263 282 331 332 322 399

B Model

Table 6: List of Variables

variable expression source

Endogenous Variables

Cf wife’s consumption unobservableCm husband’s consumption unobservablelf wife’s leisure T f − Lflm husband’s leisure Tm − LmLf wife’s labour supply HIESLm husband’s labour supply HIESW f wife’s wage HIESWm husband’s wage HIES

µ a proxy for wife’s intra-household bargaining power Eduf

Eduf+EdumHIES

Eduf wife’s education level HIESEdum husband’s education level HIES

Exogenous Variables

p price index normalized to 1Y non-labour income (real estate incomes, subsidies, ...) HIEST f&Tm individual’s total time normalized to 1agef wife’s age HIESagem husband’s age HIES

33

Page 34: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

C Estimation

Table 7: Estimation results : Heckman (Wife’s Wage Equation)

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)

Equation 1 : Real Wage per houryears of schooling 3002.443∗∗ (259.296)age 11911.328∗∗ (947.624)age2 -146.615∗∗ (12.884)t -3397.757∗∗ (199.667)

Equation 2 : selectage 0.230∗∗ (0.016)age2 -0.003∗∗ (0.000)bargaining power 3.133∗∗ (0.403)bargaining power2 -2.453∗∗ (0.355)t -0.069∗∗ (0.003)athrho 2.600∗∗ (0.114)lnsigma 10.717∗∗ (0.040)rho .9890176∗∗ (.002)sigma 45130.31∗∗ (1802.932)lambda 44634.67 ∗∗ (1854.182)

N 6283Log-likelihood -8850.752χ2(4) 505.611

LR test of indep. eqns. (rho = 0): chi2(1) = 315.72 Prob > chi2 = 0.0000

34

Page 35: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

Table 8: Estimation results : (Husband’s Wage Equation)

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)years of schooling 2047.275∗∗ (131.658)age 1184.347∗∗ (261.091)age2 -7.566∗∗ (2.900)t -1838.469∗∗ (233.961)Intercept 137507.153∗∗ (20770.722)

N 6283R2 0.053F (4,6222) 86.38

Table 9: Estimation results : αf

YearsCohort 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 20131941-1950 0.9999 0.9999 0.9998 0.9999 0.9996 0.9999 0.9999 0.99951951-1960 0.9996 0.9999 0.9999 0.9995 0.9999 0.9956 0.9983 0.99991961-1970 0.9994 0.9996 0.9997 0.9997 0.9995 0.9992 0.9999 0.99991971-1980 0.9993 0.9908 0.9823 0.9993 0.9995 0.9997 0.9997 0.99231981-1990 0.9998 0.9998 0.9998 0.9997 0.9998 0.9998 0.9950 0.99961991-1998 - 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999

Table 10: Estimation results : αm

YearsCohort 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 20131931-1940 0.9309 0.9974 0.9823 0.9945 0.9962 0.9910 0.9908 0.98051941-1950 0.9975 0.9954 0.9594 0.9904 0.9912 0.9823 0.9823 0.97901951-1960 0.9976 0.8949 0.9748 0.9959 0.9366 0.9785 0.9712 0.99031961-1970 0.9298 0.3668 0.8828 0.9430 0.8969 0.9751 0.9587 0.99371971-1980 0.8625 0.6170 0.8569 0.9161 0.9503 0.9982 0.8847 0.89831981-1990 0.7302 0.1516 0.7589 0.8702 0.8609 0.7796 0.8106 0.93521991-1998 - - - - 0.9654 0.9973 0.9968 0.4478

35

Page 36: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

References

[1] Parvin Alizadeh. The state and the social position of women: Female employment in post-

revolutionary iran. The Economy of Iran: The Dilemmas of an Islamic State. P. Alizadeh.

New York, IB Tauris, 2000.

[2] Patricia F Apps and Ray Rees. Taxation and the household. Journal of Public Economics,

35(3):355–369, 1988.

[3] J Ashworth and D Ulph. Estimating labour supply with piecewise linear budget constraints.

Taxation and labor supply, Allen and Unwin, London, 1981.

[4] Roksana Bahramitash and Hadi Salehi Esfahani. The transformation of female labor market.,

2011.

[5] Roksana Bahramitash and Hadi Salehi Esfahani. Nimble fingers no longer! women’s employ-

ment in iran. Contemporary Iran: Economy, society, policies, pages 77–122, 2009.

[6] Kaushik Basu. Gender and say: A model of household behaviour with endogenously determined

balance of power. CAE Working Paper, 2001a.

[7] Kaushik Basu. Gender and say: a model of household behaviour with endogenously determined

balance of power*. The Economic Journal, 116(511):558–580, 2006.

[8] Gary Stanley Becker and Gary S Becker. A Treatise on the Family. Harvard university press,

1981.

[9] Gary Stanley Becker and Gary S Becker. A Treatise on the Family. Harvard university press,

2009.

[10] Hans G Bloemen. An empirical model of collective household labour supply with non-

participation. The Economic Journal, 120(543):183–214, 2010.

[11] David E Bloom, David Canning, Gunther Fink, and Jocelyn E Finlay. Fertility, female labor

force participation, and the demographic dividend. Journal of Economic Growth, 14(2):79–101,

2009.

36

Page 37: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

[12] Francois Bourguignon, Martin Browning, Pierre-Andre Chiappori, and Valerie Lechene. Intra

household allocation of consumption: A model and some evidence from french data. Annales

d’Economie et de Statistique, pages 137–156, 1993.

[13] Martin Browning. The saving behaviour of a two-person household. The Scandinavian Journal

of Economics, 102(2):235–251, 2000.

[14] Martin Browning, Francois Bourguignon, Pierre-Andre Chiappori, and Valerie Lechene. Income

and outcomes: A structural model of intrahousehold allocation. Journal of political Economy,

pages 1067–1096, 1994.

[15] Martin Browning and Pierre-Andre Chiappori. Efficient intra-household allocations: A general

characterization and empirical tests. Econometrica, pages 1241–1278, 1998.

[16] Zhiqi Chen and Frances Woolley. A cournot–nash model of family decision making. The

Economic Journal, 111(474):722–748, 2001.

[17] Pierre-Andre Chiappori. Rational household labor supply. Econometrica: Journal of the

Econometric Society, pages 63–90, 1988.

[18] Pierre-Andre Chiappori. Collective labor supply and welfare. Journal of political Economy,

pages 437–467, 1992.

[19] Angus Deaton. Panel data from time series of cross-sections. Journal of econometrics,

30(1):109–126, 1985.

[20] Hadi Salehi Esfahani and Parastoo Shajari. Gender, education, family structure, and the

allocation of labor in iran. Middle East Development Journal, 4(02):1250008, 2012.

[21] Stephen E Fienberg and William M Mason. Specification and implementation of age, period

and cohort models. Springer, 1985.

[22] Ayse Gunduz-Hosgor and Jeroen Smits. Variation in labor market participation of married

women in turkey. In Women’s Studies International Forum, volume 31, pages 104–117. Elsevier,

2008.

37

Page 38: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

[23] GholamReza Keshavarz Haddad. Gender ratio, divorce rate, and intra-household collective

decision process: evidence from iranian urban households labor supply with non-participation.

Empirical Economics, 48(4):1365–1394, 2014.

[24] Jamal Ibrahim Haidar. Sanctions and exports deflection: Evidence from iran. 2015.

[25] Nadia Hijab. Women and work in the Arab world. Number 3. MERIP, 1994.

[26] Massoud Karshenas. Economic liberalization, competitiveness and women’s employment in

the middle east and north africa. Economic Research Forum for the Arab Countries, Iran &

Turkey, 1997.

[27] Massoud Karshenas and Valentine M Moghadam. Female labor force participation and eco-

nomic adjustment in the mena region. Economics, 37(38):39, 2001.

[28] Jane H Leuthold. An empirical study of formula income transfers and the work decision of the

poor. Journal of Human Resources, pages 312–323, 1968.

[29] Ethan Ligon. Dynamic intra-household bargaining (with an application to bangladesh). Un-

published manuscript, UC Berkeley, 2003.

[30] Shelly Lundberg and Robert A Pollak. Separate spheres bargaining and the marriage market.

Journal of political Economy, pages 988–1010, 1993.

[31] Shelly Lundberg and Robert A Pollak. Noncooperative bargaining models of marriage. The

American Economic Review, pages 132–137, 1994.

[32] Shelly Lundberg and Robert A Pollak. Bargaining and distribution in marriage. The Journal

of Economic Perspectives, pages 139–158, 1996.

[33] Pushkar Maitra and Ranjan Ray. The impact of intra household balance of power on expen-

diture pattern: the australian evidence. Australian Economic Papers, 44(1):15–29, 2005.

[34] Mehdi Majbouri. Against the wind: labor force participation of women and economic instability

in iran. Manuscript, University of Southern California, 2010.

[35] Marilyn Manser and Murray Brown. Marriage and household decision-making: A bargaining

analysis. International economic review, pages 31–44, 1980.

38

Page 39: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

[36] Marjorie B McElroy. The empirical content of nash-bargained household behavior. Journal of

human resources, pages 559–583, 1990.

[37] Marjorie B McElroy and Mary Jean Horney. Nash-bargained household decisions: Toward a

generalization of the theory of demand. International economic review, pages 333–349, 1981.

[38] Golnar Mehran. The paradox of tradition and modernity in female education in the islamic

republic of iran. Comparative Education Review, 47(3):269–286, 2003.

[39] Gholamali Farjadi Mehryar, Amir H. and Mohammad Tabibian. Labor force participation of

women in the contemporary iran. In Women in Iran from 1800 to Islamic Republic, pages

182–203. Chicago: University of Illinois Press, 2004.

[40] Jacob Mincer and Solomon Polachek. Family investments in human capital: Earnings of

women. In Marriage, family, human capital, and fertility, pages 76–110. Journal of Political

Economy 82 (2), Part II, 1974.

[41] Ida A Mirzaie. Females’ labor force participation and job opportunities in the middle east.

2014.

[42] Robert A Pollak. For better or worse: The roles of power in models of distribution within

marriage. The American Economic Review, pages 148–152, 1994.

[43] Ranjan Ray and Gayatri B Koolwal. Estimating the endogenously determined intrahousehold

balance of power and its impact on expenditure pattern: Evidence from nepal. World Bank

Policy Research Working Paper, (2814), 2002.

[44] Goli M Rezai-Rashti and Susan James. Women and higher education in postrevolutionary iran:

Unsettling policies and unanticipated outcomes. In Race, ethnicity and gender in education,

pages 45–58. Springer, 2009.

[45] Willard L Rodgers. Estimable functions of age, period, and cohort effects. American sociological

review, pages 774–787, 1982.

[46] Elaheh Rostami Povey. Women and work in iran. State of Nature, Online journal,

www.stateofnature.org/womenAndWork.html, (1), 2005.

39

Page 40: Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power · 2016-03-16 · Married Women’s Labour Supply and Intra-Household Bargaining Power Safoura Moeeniy March 15,

[47] Norman B Ryder. The cohort as a concept in the study of social change. American sociological

review, pages 843–861, 1965.

[48] Djavad Salehi-Isfahani. Labor force participation of women in iran, 1987-2001. 2005.

[49] Djavad Salehi-Isfahani and Marenglen Marku. Women and market work in iran: A cohort

approach. 2008.

[50] Paul A Samuelson. Social indifference curves. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, pages

1–22, 1956.

[51] Herbert L Smith, William M Mason, and Stephen E Fienberg. Estimable functions of age,

period, and cohort effects: more chimeras of the age-period-cohort accounting framework:

comment on rodgers. American Sociological Review, pages 787–793, 1982.

[52] Etsuji Suzuki. Time changes, so do people. Social Science & Medicine, 75(3):452–456, 2012.

[53] Zeyu Xu. A survey on intra-household models and evidence. 2007.

40


Recommended