+ All Categories
Home > Documents > PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

Date post: 11-Dec-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
62
PART IV APPENDICES
Transcript
Page 1: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

PART IV

APPENDICES

Page 2: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-285-

APPENDIX 2A

A Review of Evidence on Allocative Efficiency

Extensive study of allocative efficiency has taken place in

recent years to examine whether farmers use resources efficiently.

This appendix briefly reviews the methodology used and the evidence

available.

The analysis has generally been based on the use of homogeneous I .

production functions estimated from cross-sectional samples of farms.

The estimated function provides the basis for testing whether the

marginal value products of the resources are approximately equal to

the marginal cost of those resources. This test was generally carried

out at the geometric mean level of resource inputs [3]. More recent

studies have carried out the test at input levels other than the geom­

etric mean and on different groups of farms [15].

The only major Australian study in this vein was undertaken by

Duloy [4] and relates to the sheep industry. This study indicated a

substantial range of marginal value products suggesting some inefficiency

in resource use. But the evidence was not so conclusive when considering

the possible gains in gross output from moving to the efficient level.of

resource use, as only relatively small gains in gross output occurred.

He concluded [4, p.163] " ••• that farmers are perhaps rather more rat­

ional in their use of resources than would appear from the wide range

of resource productivities ••• ", but that some farmers may be employing

inferior technologies.

Most studies of allocative efficiency have been undertaken using

data from underdeveloped countries which suggests that allocative effic­

iency is assumed in the developed countries. The objective was to test

1 The unrestricted Cobb-Douglas form has generally been used because of estimational and manipulative ease.

Page 3: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-286-

Schultz's hypothesis that "there are comparatively few significant

inefficiencies in the allocation of the factors of production in trad­

itional agriculture" [9, p.37]. A number of Cobb-Douglas type

studies have tested this hypothesis and generally concluded in its I favour •

From these early studies, methodological developments have

proceeded in two directions. The most developed direction has included

considerations of different types of farms (generally small and large),

and has attempted to "disaggregate" allocative efficiency into price

and technical aspects. Yotopolous, Lau and Somel [15] considered

aspects relating to small and large farms in a Cobb-Douglas framework

and found no evidence that small farms allocated resources more effic­

iently than large farms. They foreshadowed later work which tested

separately for price efficiency when different price regimes are applic­

able to different farms (see Wise and Yotopolous [12]), and then tested

to establish whether some farms are technically more efficient than

others (see Lau and Yotopolous [6]). These studies have concluded that

both small and large farms are price efficient, but tnat small farms

have superior technical efficiency [14, p.222].

The other direction of methodological development, as yet

relatively unexplored. has been the introduction of risk into the

analysis of allocative efficiency. Dillon and Anderson [3] reappraised

some early studies in a statistical decision theory framework. The

results were inconclusive so far as accepting or rejecting the effic­

ient allocation hypothesis of Schultz. However, consideration of risk

in a utility framework may clarify some aspects of allocative efficiency,

but to date Bardham [1] and Srinivasan [10] are among the few who have

specifically considered uncertainty in productivity analysis.

1 Examples of such studies are those of Chennareddy [2], Hopper [5], Sahota [8], Welsch [11] and Yotopolous [13].

Page 4: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-287-

The strength of this evidence depends on the importance

attached to the biases arising from the use of the Cobb-Douglas model.

Acceptance of this model leads to the conclusion that the evidence

generally supports the allocative efficiency hypothesis. But there are

important restrictive assumptions in the Cobb-Douglas model, partic­

ularly constant partial and total elasticities of production and unitary

elasticity of substitution, that mean farmers are unlikely to be,oper­

ating in a Cobb-Douglas world. In this regard the evidence is not con­

clusive.

On the other hand, the Schultz hypothesis has not been disproved

either, although consideration of uncertainty offers strong possibilities

in this regard. For example, in a utility maximising situation where

farmers are risk averse less than optimal resource input levels .may

arise1 • But the case is not conclusively established either way, so

that for this study the efficient allocation of. resources is accepted

as the evidence tends to this view. Furthermore, there are methodolog­

ical advantages from accepting this assumption, particularly as method­

ologies for handling situations of a110cative inefficiency are complex

and less adequately developed.

APPENDIX 2 - References

[1] BARDHAM, P.K., "Size, Productivity, and Returns to Scale: An

Analysis of Farm-Level Data in Indian Agriculture",

J. Pol. Econ., 81(6), 1370-1387, Nov/Dec., 1973.

[2] CHENNAREDDY, V., "Production Efficiency in South Indian Agriculture",

J. Farm Econ., 49(4), 816-820, Nov., 1962.

1 Dillon and MacArthur [71 found that in these circumstances risk aversion . resulted in lower stocking rates than indicated by riskless analysis.

Page 5: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-288-

[3] DILLON, J.L. and J.R. ANDERSON, "A11ocative Efficiency, Tradit­

ional Agriculture and Risk", Am. J. Agric. Econ.,

53(1), 26-32, Feb., 1971.

[4] DULOY, J.H., The Allocation of Resources in the Australian Sheep

Industry, Unpub. Ph.D'. thesis, University of Sydney, 1963.

[5] HOPPER, D.W., "Al1ocative Efficiency in a Traditional Indian Agric­

ulture", J. Farm Econ., 47(3), 611-624, Aug., 1965.

[6] LAU, L.J. and P .A. YOTOPOLOUS, "A Test for Relative Efficiency and

an Application to Indian Agriculture", Am. Econ. Rev.,

61(1), 94-109, March, 1971.

[7] MACARTHUR, I.D. and J .L. DILLON, "Risk, Utility and Stocking Rate",

Aust. J. Agric. Econ., 15(1), 20-35, April, 1971.

[8] SAHOTA, G.S., "Efficiency of Resource Allocation in Indian Agric­

ulture", Am. J. Agric. Econ., 50(3), 584-605, Aug.,

1968.

[9] SCHULTZ, T.W., Transforming Traditional Agriculture, New Haven,

Yale Univ. Press, 1964.

[10] SRINIVASAN, T.N., "Farm Size and Productivity Implications of

Choice Under Uncertainty", Indian J. of Statistics.

Series B, 34(4),409-420, Dec., 1972.

[11] WELSCH, D.E., "Response to Economic Incentive by Abaka1iki Rice

Farmers in Eastern Nigeria", J. Farm Econ., 47(4),

900-914, Nov., 1965.

[12] WISE, J. and P.A. YOTOPOLOUS, "The Empirical Content of Ration­

ality: A Test for a Less Developed Economy, J. Pol.

~., 77(5),976-1004, Nov., 1969.

[13] YOTOPOLOUS, P.A., Al10cative Efficiency in Economic Development:

A Cross Section Analysis of Epirus Farming,. Athens,

Centre of Planning and Economic Research, 1967.

Page 6: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-289-

[14] YOTOPOLOUS, P.A. and L.J. LAU, "A Test for Relative Economic

Efficiency: Some Further Results", Am. Econ. Rev.,

63(1),214-223, March, 1973.

Page 7: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-290-

APPENDIX 3A

Discussion of the A.B.S. Workforce Definitions

The main source of data on the rural workforce used in this

study is the population census [2]. The following extract from the

explanatory notes accompanying the 1966 population census clearly

indicates the definitions used and the changes made for the 1966 census.

"1. At the 1961 and previous Censuses the ,work force was determined as:

"Those who are engaged in an industry, business, profession, trade or service at the time of the Census (including those on long service leave, etc.) ............ "; and

" ........... those·out of a job at time of the Census but who are usually engaged in an industry, busi­ness, profession, trade or service •••••••••• "

2. At the 1966 Census an additional set of ". four. questions was asked in order to obtain information on the,basis of which the work force could be determined more precisely. The questions were as follows:

"Did the person have a job or business of any kind last week (even though he may have been temporarily absent from it)? ANSWER "YES" or "NO"."

"Did the person do any work at all last week for payment or profit? ANSWER "YES" or "NO". Persons working without. pay as a helper in a "family busi­ness" or farm and members of the. clergy and of religious orders (other than purely contemplative orders) should answer "YES" to this question. Persons doing only unpaid housework should answer "NO"."

"Was the person temporarily laid off by his employer without pay for the whole of last week? ' ANSWER ''YES'' or "NO"."

Page 8: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-291-

"Did the person look for work last week? ANSWER "YES" "NO" (N " or , ote. Looking for work" means (i) being registe~ith Commonwealth Employment Service, or (ii) approaching prospective employers, or (iii) placing or answering advertisements, or (iv) writing letters of application, or (v) await­ing the result of recent applications.)"

3. The work force includes all persons for whom the "" i answer yes was g ven to anyone of these four

questions. Except that persons helping but not receiving wages or a salary who usually worked less than 15 hours a week were excluded from the work force , ••

5. The net effect of the new definition is to include approximately 108,000 additional persons in the Australian work force i.e. a proportionate increase in the Australian workforce of approximately 2.3 per cent, The major factor in this change was females working part-time (sometimes for only a few hours a week) some of whom, in 1961, did not, consider them-. selves as " ••• ;. engaged in an industry, business, profession, trade or service" •••••

8. Persons in the workforce were asked to state industry in accordance with the following instructions.

9 •

10.

"State the exact·branch of industry, business or service in which mainly engaged last week, using two or more words where possible. For example, "Dairy Farming", "Coal Mining", "Woollen Mills", "Retail Grocery", "Road Construction", etc. Employees should state the industry of their emp­loyer. For example, a carpenter employed by a coal mining company should state "Coal Mining". ' If employed by a Government Department or other public body, state also its name. For paid house-. keepers and domestic servants in private households, write "P.H."."

From the answers to this question, persons were classified according to the Bureau's "Classification of Industries" which provides for each person to be classified according to the nature of the business in which mainly engaged, regardless of whether operated by a Government authority, corporation or individual.

The precise classification of persons in the workforce according to industry is extremely difficult but subject ~

Page 9: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-292-

to continuing efforts to improve the quality of the data from census to census. Consequently the com­parison of data compiled at the 1966 Census with that obtained at previous censuses is not only in­fluenced by changes in the definition and content of the workforce but by the different responses which may have been evoked by efforts to improve the questions on the Census Schedule, and by some changes in coding rules designed to rectify known deficiencies in the data •. , Classification is difficult mainly because of the problem of conveying through a printed.form the exact nature of the information required (e.g. the conceptual difference between 'occupation' and. 'industry') and the consequential inadequacy of.·many replies."

This lengthy extract indicates that the collection of data is

an evolutionary' process. For example, the attempt to obtain greater

precision in. the estimate of the workforce and the.resultant warning

in par.lO, that over a period of time, particularly as long as the 50

years in this study. the consistency of the estimates may· be more

apparent than real. Many changes are made in the questions and anal­

ysis which can introduce minor changes in the estimates. Over a long

period of time, the accumulation of these small changes can substant­

ially influence the consistency of the estimates.

The most significant change to note is that contained in the

definition of the workforce, and the.resultant effects on the female

component of the workforce (par.5). In this study, an attempt has

been made to achieve consistency in the female workforce estimates by

providing an estimate on the basis of the old workforce definition

(see Section 3.2.4).

In the labour force survey [3], similar definitions to those

used in the 1966 population census are used. The details are:

"The labour force comprises all'persons who, during survey week, were employed or unemployed, as defined below •.

Employed persons comprise all those who, during survey week,

Page 10: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-293-

(a) did any work for pay, profit, commission or payment in kind, in a job or business, or on a farm (includ­ing employees, employers and self-employed persons), or

(b) worked fifteen hours or more without ,pay in a family business (or farm), or

(c) had a job, business or farm, but were not at work because of illness, accident, leave, holiday, prod­uction hold-up due to bad weather, plant breakdown, etc., or because they were on strike.

A person who had a job but was temporarily laid off by his, employer for the whole week without pay is excluded, and is classified in the tables as unemployed. A person who did some,work during the week, however,before he either lost his job or was laid off, is classified as employed. A person who held more than one job is counted only once, in the job at which he worked most hours during survey week."

Despite the similarity in the definitions, the labour force

survey tends to give generally higher estimates than the population

census. Sampling errors, which are higher for the rural sector than

other industries [3J may account· for some of this difference, while

no survey month coincides with the population census date. Other.

differences may arise because the labour force survey uses personal

interviews while the population census does.not •. Finally, in 1971,

the population census was based on the A.S.I.C. classification of

industries [1] while the classification used in the labour force survey,

is not clearly specified in the report ,[3] so differences in rural

workforce estimates could also arise from differing industry classifi-

cations.

The more important comparison, however,

lation census definitions and theA & P census.

in a sample A & P census form for N.S.W. 1972-73

is between the popu­

The labour questions

is set out below.

Page 11: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

PERSONS WORKING ON HOLDING at end of March 1973

EXCLUDE females mainly engaged in domestic duties and children atten­ding schooL

-294-

PERMANENT (FULL-TIME) WORKERS

Owners, Lessees, and Share­farmers actively engaged.in farm or station work

Relatives (of owners, etc.) over IS years of age working permanently full-time on farm but not receiving wages or salary

Employees (including managers and relatives) working perman­ently full-time on farm for wages or' salary

TEMPORARY WORKERS (SEASONAL AND CASUAL) Number of persons working tempor~ arily on holding (on wages or contract) at ,end of March 1973)

Males Females

In this case, the questions are more general and leave some scope for

interpretation. For example, the "end of March" is less precise than

the "last week" used in the population census; the exclusion of

"females mainly engaged in domestic duties and children attending

school" may give different results for unpaid helpers than the.IS

hours a week guideline for the population census; . and there is no

obvious classification for "temporary unpaid family help" or less than

full time "owners, lessees andsharefarmers" so that many of these may

be incorrectly classified as full-time. These are only. some. examples -.

of the problems and it is likely that these and other similar problems

give rise to the A & P census data being less accurate than the data

contained in the population census. For these reasons, the population

census estimates are generally preferred [6].

Page 12: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-295-

APPENDIX 3B

Seasonal Adjustment Factors for Male Employeesa

Year N.S.W. VIC. QLD. S .A. W.A. TAS.

1939 922 939 1063 933 882 885

1943 985 1000 1117 929 882 929

1945 970 1033 1133 892 990 993

1947 915 948 1020 820 990 935

1954 918 850 995 820 1019 900

1961 918 800 1094 800 1000 870

a These factors are those calculated by Keating [6; Appendix 4]. The factors indicate June 30th employment as a ratio of ,the average level of employment during that year. Where the June 30th level equals the average level the ratio.- 1000.

Page 13: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-296-APPENDU 3C

ESTIMATED MALE RURAL WORKFORCE, 1920-21 TO 1970-71a

Working Emp10yeesb Unpaid Year Proprietors

,000 ,000 Helpers Total

,000 ,000

1920-21 220.8 204.3 1921-22 225.8 28.9 454.0 1922-23 229.8

216,0 30.4 472.2 1923-24 233.5

214.3 32.3 476.4 1924-25 236.1

204.4 31.5 469.4 217.2 28.6 481.9

1925-26 236.5 219.0 26.2 1926-27 235.9 218.0 481.7

1927-28 235.7 25.4 479.3 1928-29 235.4

221.7 25.6 483.0 225.6 26.8 487.8 1929-30 236.3 224.4 30.5 491.2

1930-31 240.5 223.1 34.3 497.9 1931-32 246.1 205.3 36.6 488.0 1932-33 252.1 210.8 36.4 499.3 1933-34 254.0 215.1 34.0 503.1 1934-35 252.5 210.7 31.6 494.8 1935-36 251.4 213.4 30.1 494.9 1936-37 248.7 217.7 29.6 496.0 1937-38 247.0 224.8 30.0 501.8 1938-39 245.6 218.3 29.7 493.6 1939-40 243.7 212.4 30.7 486.8 1940-41 241.1 206.0 28.2 475.3 1941-42 236.3 172.7 24.1 433.1 1942-43 225.5 144,1 20,9 390.5 1943-44 230.7 135.6 21.1' 387.5 1944-45 241.2 140,0 23.3 404.5 1945-46 246.4 160.0 23.6 430.0 1946-47 249.9 169.2 22.0 441.1 1947-48 252.0 164.5 20.6 437.1 1948-49 251.7 165.7 18.5 435.9 1949-50 251.3 167.1 17.7 436.1 1950-51 252.4 165.4 17.4 435.2 1951-52 253.7 166.7 17.1 437.5 1952-53 256.0 172.6 16.4 445.0 1953-54 257.7 173.3 15.9 446.9 1954-55 258.3 168.2 15.7 442.2

1955-56 259.6 163.6 15.4 438.6 1956-57 259.5 161.8 14.8 436.1 1957-58 255.5 164.2 14.3 434.0 1958-59 248.2 162.8 13.3 424.3 1959-60 241.8 155.2 11.8 408.8

1960-61 240.3 148.3 11.3 399.9 1961-62 248.1 145.1 10.2 403.4 1962-63 238.5 143.6 9.9 392.0 1963-64 231.1 143.4 8.8 383.3 1964-65 228.8 141.8 8.6 379.2

1965-66 222.0 140.7 7.9 370.6 1966-67 224.3 139.9 8.0 372.2 1967-68 218.0 141.4 7.1 366.5 1968-69 208.2 137.2 7.6 353.0 1969-70 200.1 131.4 6.5 338.0

1970-11c 185.0 120.6 5.2 310.8

a 1920-21 to 1960-61 from Keating [6J, remaining years compiled from the population census [2] and A & P census IS].

b Includes unemployed and adjusted to approximate average employment for that year. c 1970-71 !nc1uded because 1971 was a population census ''benchmark'',

Page 14: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-297-APPENDIX 3D

ESTIMATED FEMALE lWRAL WORKFORCE, 1920-21 TO 1970-71a

Working Employees Unpaid Year Proprietors

,000 ,000 Helpers Total

,000 ,000

1920-21 6.0 2.3 1921-22 6.3 2.5

1.0 9.3 1922-23 6.5 2.6

1.0 9.8 1923-24 6.8 2.8

1.0 10.1 1924-25 7.2 2.9

1.0 10.6 1.0 11.1

1925-26 7.5 3.0 1926-27 7.9

1.0 11.5 3.2

1927-28 8.3 3.3 1.0 12.1

1928-29. 8.8 1.1 12.7

1929-30 9.6 3.3 1.1 13.2 3.4 1.1 14.1

1930-31 11.3 3.4 1.2 1931-32 13.0

15.9

1932-33 3.3 1.3 17.6

14.3 3.2 1.3 18.8 1933-34 15.6 3.4 1.4 20.4 1934-35 16.1 3.6 1.3 21.0 1935-36 16.0 3.8 1.3 21.1 1936-37 15.6 3.8 1.3 20.7 1937-38 15.1 4.0 1.3 20.4 1938-39 14.8 4.1 1.3 20.2 1939-40 14.5 4.7 2.1 21.3 1940-41 14.0 6.0 5.5 25.5 1941-42 13.6 9.7 9.6 32.9 1942-43 12.1 14.7 14.0 40.8 1943-44 13.0 15.4 13.3 41.7 1944-45 15.4 13.8 11.5 40.7 1945-46 16.1 11.3 7.9 35.3 1946-47 14.7 9.8 3.7· 28.2 1947-48 14.2 9.3 2.5 26.0 1948-49 14.7 9.4 2.6 26.7 1949-50 15.7 9.9 3.3 28.9

1950-51 16.8 10.1 3.8 30.7 1951-52 17.3 9.8 3.8 30.9 1962-53 18.0 9.7 4.0 31.7 1953-54 19.2 9.3 4.6 33.1 1954-55 20.0 9.3 4.8 34.1

1955-56 21.1 9.2 4.7 35.0 1956-57 22.6 9.4 4.2 36.2 1957-58 23.8 9.8 4.0 37.6 1958-59 25.1 9.7 4.0 38.8 1959-60 26.3 9.4 3.7 39.4

1960-61 27.4 9.6 3.3 40.3 1961-62 27.7 10.3 3.6 41.6 1962-63 27.9 11.2 3.8 42.9 1963-64 28.2 11.9 4.1 44.2 1964-65 28.4 12.7 4.3 45.4

1965-66 28.7 13.2 4.7 46.6

1966-67 29.1 12.2 4.4 45.7

1967-68 29.4 U.2 4.2 44.8

1968-69 29.8 10.2 3.9 44.0

1969-70 30.1 9.3 3.7 43.1

1970-71b 30.S 8.3 3.4 42.2

a 1920-21 to 1960-61 from Keating [6]. remaining years from the population census [2], labour force survey [3] and the A & P census [5].

b 1970-71 included because 1971 was a population censuS ''benchmark''.

Page 15: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-298-APPENDIX 3E

ESTIMATED UNEMPLOYMENT IN THE MALE RURAL WORKFORCE, 1920-21 TO 1969-70

Year Unemployeda

Employed Male

% ,000

1920-21 3.0 1921-22 2.4

13.6

1922-23 1.8 11.3

1923-24 2.3 8.6

1924-25 2.3 10.8 11.1

1925-26 1.8 8.7 1926-27 1.7 1927-28 2.9

8.1

1928-29 3.0 14.0

1929-30 5.5 14.6 27.0

1930-31 7.9 39.3 1931-32 8.4 41.0 1932-33 7.2 35.9 1933-34 6.0 30.2 1934-35 5.0 24.7 1935-36 3.9 19.3 1936-37 3.1 15.4 1937-38 2.9 14.6 1938-39 3.2 15.8 1939-40 2.8 13.6 1940-41 1.6 7.6 1941-42 1.1 4.8 1942-43 1.0 3.9 1943-44 1.0 3.9 1944-45 1.0 4.0 1945-46 1.1 4.7 1946-41 1.0 4.4 1947-48 1.8 7.9 1948-49 1.6 7.0 1949-50 1.4 6.1

1950-51 1.3 5.7 1951-52 1.1 4.8 1952-53 0.9 4.0 1953-54 0.7 3.1 1954-55 0.3 1.3

1955-56 0.4 1.8 1956-57 1.4 6.1 1957-58 2.4 10.4 1958-59 2.9 12.3 1959-60 2.0 8.2

1960-61 . 2.5 10.0 1961-62 1.9 7.7 1962-63 1.6 6.3 1963-64 1.0 3.8 1964-65 0.8 3.0

1965-66 1.1 4.1 1966-67 1.3 4.8 1967-68 1.2 4.4 1968-69 1.1 3.9 1969-70 1.0 3.4

a The unemployment rate is the percentage of the total male rural workforce unemployed. The series was derived from unemployment rates reported from the population census [2] and from the Labour Report [4].

Workforce ,000

440.4 460.9 467.8 458.6 470.8

473.0 471.2 469.0 473.2 464.2

458.6 447.0 463.4 472.9 470.1

475.6 480.6 487.2 477 .8 473.2

467.7 428.3 386.6 383.6 400.5

425.3 436.7 429.2 428.9 430.0

429.5 432.7 441.0 443.8 440.9

436.8 430.0 423.6 412.0 400.6

389.9 395.7 385.7 379.5 376.2

366.5 367.4 362.1 349.1 334.6

Page 16: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-299-APPENDIX 3F

TOTAL AND ADJUSTED RURAL WORKFORCE, 1920-21 TO 1969-70

Total Adjusted Rural Workforce

Year Rural

Workforce a b Males Females c . 000 .000 ,000

1920-21 463.3 430.3 6.7 1921-22 482.0 450.2 7.1 1922-23 486.2 456.5 7.3 1923-24 480.0 447,6 7.7 1924-25 493.0 460.8 8.1 1925-26 493.2 463.9 8.4 1926-27 491.4 462.3 8.8 1927-28 495.7 460.0 9.2 1928-29 501.0 463.8 9.6 1929-30 505.3 453.5 10.3 1930-31 513.8 446.6 11.6 1931-32 505.6 434.2 12.9 1932-33 518.1 450.6 13.8 1933-34 523.5 461.0 14.9 1934-35 515.8 459.0 15.4 1935-36 516.0 465.1 15.5 1936-37 516.7 470.3 15.2 1937-38 522.2 476.7 15.0 1938-39 513.8 467.4 14.8 1939-40 508.1 462.4 15.4 1940-41 500.8 457.8 17.7 1941-42 466.0 419.9 22.2 1942-43 431.3 379.3 26.9 1943-44 429.2 376.1 27.8 1944-45 445.2 392.3 27.5

1945-46 465.3 417.0 24.4 1946-47 469.3 429.0 20.2 1947-48 463.1 422.0 18.8 1948-49 462.6 422.5 19.3 1949-50 465.0 423.8 20.8

1950-51 465.9 423.5 22.0 1951-52 468.4 426.7 22.2 1952-53 476.7 435.3 22.7 1953-54 480.0 438.2 23.6 1954-55 476.3 435.4 24.3

1955-56 473.6 431.5 25.0 1956-57 472.3 424.8 26.0 1957-58 471.6 418.6 27.2 1958-59 463.1 407.3 28.1 1959_60 448.2 396.5 28.6

1960-61 440,2 385.9 29.4 1961-62 445,0 392.2 30.3 1962-63 434.9 382.3 31.2 1963-64 427,5 376.4 32.1 1964-65 424,6 373.2 32.9

1965-66 417,2 363.8 33.7 1966-67 417.9 364.6 33.1

1967-68 411.3 359.6 32.5 1968..69 397,0 346.5 32.0

1969-70 381.1 332.3 31.4

a Unadjusted sum of males and females in the rural workforce. b Adjusted for unemployment, and helpers· 0.65 adult male. c Female proprietors and employees. 0.75 adult male, female helpers· 0.4875

adult male. d Adjusted sum of males and females in adult male equivalents.

Tota1d

,000

437.0 457.3 463.8 455.3 468.9

472.2 471.1 469.3 473.4 463.8

458.2 447.1 464.4 475.9 474.4

480.5 485.4 491.7 482.2 477.8

475.5 442.1 406.2 403.9 419.8

441.4 449.2 440.9 441.8 444.6

445.5 448.9 458.0 461.8 459.7

456.5 450.9 445.7 435.4 425.1

415.3 422.4 413.4 408.5 406.1

397.5 397.7 392.1 378.4 363.7

Page 17: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-300-

[1]' AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Australian Standard Industrial

Classification, Canberra, 1969.

[2] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Census·of the Commonwealth of

Australia, Canberra, various issues. The Tables used

in this study are those.classifying the population by

Industry and Occupational Status. The detailed data

from the 1971 census is unpublished and was provided

by the A.B.S.

[3J AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, The Labour Force, Canberra,

various issues.

[4] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Labour Report, Canberra, various

issues.

[5] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Rural Industries Bulletin,

Canberra. For details of all issues in this series see

same Reference Chapter 2.

[6] KEATING, M., The Growth and Composition of the Australian Work­

force 1910-11 to 1960-61, Vols,l and 2, unpub. Ph.D.

h i A N U Nov 1967 Subsequently published t es s, "'J .. " •

as KEATING, M., The Australian Workforce 1910-11 to

1960-61, Canberra, Progress Press, 1973.

Page 18: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

Year

1920-21 1921-22 1922-23 1923-24 1924-25

1925-26 1926-27 1927-28 1928-29 1929-30

1930-31 1931-32 1932-33 1933-34 1934-35

1935-36 1936-37 1937-38 1938-39 1939-40

1940-41 1941-42 1942-43 1943-44 1944-45

1945-46 1946-47 1947-48 1948-49 1949-50

1950-51 1951-52 1952-53 1953-54 1954-55

1955-56 1956-57 1957-58 1958-59 1959-60

1960-61 1961-62 1962-63 1963-64 1964-65

1965-66 1966-67 1967-68 1968-69 1969-70

-301-APPENDIX 4A

ESTIMATED TOTAL LABOUR PAYMENTS TO AUS C TRALIAN RURAL EMPLOYEES: a

1920-21 TO 1969-70. $m. CURRENT PRICES

Average Earningsb Award Wage

76 78

96

80 105

77 100

81 97

101 85 88

104

86 111

88 111 115

80 109 68 95 59 80 59 78 60 79 59 80 61 83 66 89 72 96 70 96 71 98 73 100 70 95 72 100 72 101 74 104 81 116 87 126 85 126

101 147 115 165

148 209 183 264 206 295 226 315 232 310

234 308 249 318 262 318 253 315 260 321

262 309 271 320 284 321 298 326 313 344

316 353 336 366 353 383 371 381 380 375

c

jl_ _ _ C

-Includes both male and female employees. females· 0.75 adult male rate.and an imputed ~.payment to unpaid helpers. unpaid helpers· 0.65 adult male rate. b" Based on estimated average earnings of 'rural employees. c Based on the award wage for"rura1industry. for 1920-21 to 1957-58. as shown in

Australian Bureau of Statistics. The Labour Report. Canberra. (various issues) thereaftet' l'!i1u"Ited bv the Bureau of Agricultural Economics. Indices of Prices Paid. Canberra (mimeo). wages item.

Page 19: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-302-APPENDU 4B

ESTIMATED TOTAL LA:BOUR PAYMENTS TO AUSTRALIAN R a URAL PROPRIETORS : 1920-21 to 1969-70, $m, current prices

. '. . -. .

Average Multiplied Award Denison Year Earningsb Average Average Waged Earnings & . EarningsC Method

1% capita1f

1920-21 81 113 102 1921-22 109 99 79 111 107 69 1922-23 82 93 1923-24

115 102 73 99 85 118 106 79 1924-25 103 85 119 108 129 106 1925-26 89 124 110 1926-27 93

80 110 1927-28

129 117 62 114 92 128 1928-29 119 61 115 91 127 120 63 113 1929-30 89 124 121 40 109 1930-31 81 112 113 32 1931-32 79 97

109 107 46 1932-33 76 94 107 ·102 55 90

1933~34 75 104 99 84 1934-35 73 92

102 101 72 89 1935-36 75 104 100 90 1936-37 77

92 107 103 118

1937-38 80 111 97

106 106 98 1938-39' 79 110 110 71 97 1939-40 80 111 111 98 101 1940-41 82 114 112 75 102 1941-42 88 122 120 110 107 1942-43 98 136 136 153 122 1943-44 105 146 149 164 131 1944-45 111 154 157 114 136 1945-46 115 159 164 134 141 1946-47 121 167 175 133 152 1947-48 126 175 186 327 168 1948-49 149 207 216 312 194 1949-50 167 232 239 448 223 1950-51 217 300 306 732 309 1951-52 268 370 387 4B1 343 1952-53 ' 294 407 422 602 377 1953-54 324 448 452 505 408 1954-55 340 470 454 456 422

1955-56 355 490 468 517 437 1956-57 394 543 505 602 488 1957-58 416 573 504 302 503 1958-59 401 552 500 439 486 1959-60 416 572 513 487 511

1960-61 443 609 522 496 543 1961-62 474 651 560 ' 463 575 1962-63 479 658 541 519 586 1963-64 480 659 526 698 601 1964-65 503 690 552 620 623

1965-66 501 686 558 394 630 1966~67 546 749 594 693 683 1967-68 558 765 604 375 698 1968-69 579 792 595 624 726 1969-70, 601 820 593 516 750

a Includes both male and female proprietors, females. 0.75 adult male rate.

b Assumes the payment to proprietors is equal to the average earnings of rural employees.

c Assumes the payment to proprietors is equal to 1.4 times the average earnings of rurs1 employees.

d Assumes the payment to proprietors is equal to the award wsge of rural employees.

e Assumes the payment to proprietors is equal to rural factor output x (total wages paid in Australia/gross national product)-Estimsted actual wage payments to employees.

f Assumes the payment to proprietors is equal to the average earnings of rural employees plus a management allowance of I per cent of the capital stock value.

Page 20: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-303-

APPENDIX 4C

ESTIMATED TOTAL LABOUR PAYMENTS TO AUSTRALIAN RURAL WORKFORCE;a

1920-21 TO 1969-70, $m, CURRENT PRICES.

Year Award Wageb Average Multiplied Denison Average EarningsC Average d Methode Earnings and Earnings 1% Capital f

1920-21 198 157 189 1921-22 212 157 185 174

1922-23 202 162 189 147 170

1923-24 203 195 153 177

162 195 1924-25 209 156 179

166 200 210 185 1925-26 214 174 209 165 1926-27 229 194

181 217 149 1927-28 230 178 200

1928-29 236 214 148 199

179 215 150 200 1929-30 230 169 204 120 187 1930-31 208 149 180 100 1931-32 186 163

138 168 105 1932-33 181

151 136 166 114 148

1933-34 178 135 164 143 150 1934-35 181 132 161 131 145 1935-36 183 136 165 152 152 1936-37 191 143 173 184 162 1937':'38 201 152 183 178 168 1938-39 206 149 180 141 165 1939-40 209 151 182 168 169 1940-41 212 155 187 148 173 1941-42 215 158 192 180 177 1942-43 236 170 208 225 192 1943-44 250 177 218 235 200 1944-45 260 185 228 187 208 1945-46 280 196 240 215 221 1946-47 301 208 254 220 237 1947-48 313 211 260 412' 250 1948-49 363 250 308 413 292 1949-50 404 282 347 563 335

1950-51 515 365 448 880 452 1951-52 651 451 553 664 521 1952-53 717 500 613 808 578 1953-54 768 550 674 731 628 1954-55 764 572 702 688 647

1955-56 775 589 724 750 664 1956-57 823 643 792 851 728 1957-58 822 678 835 564 756 1958-59 816 654 805 692 728 1959-60 833 676 832 747 761

1960-61 831 705 871 758 792 1961-62 880 745 922 734 833 1962-63 862 763 942 803 857 1963-64 851 771J 957 996 885 1964-65 897 816 1,003 934 922

1965-66 910 817 1,002 710 931 1966-67 960 882 1,085 1,029 1,002

1967-68 987 911 1,118 729 1,034

1968-69 976 950 1,163 995 1,079

1969-70 968 981 1,200 896 1,109

a Females _ 0.75 adult male rate, unpaid helpers. 0.65 adult male rate.

b All receive payment based on adult male award wage.

c All receive payment based on adult male average earnings.

d Employees as in c, proprietors receive 1.4 times adult male average earnings.

e Employees as in c, proprietors receive aufficient to equate rural total labour payments/factor output ratio to total wages in the economy/gross national product ratio.

f Employees as in c, proprietors receive average earnings plus 1 per cent of capital stock value.

Page 21: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-304-

APPENDIX 5A

Land Values and Capitalised Value of the Residual

Return to Land

Two broad., groups of, factors influence, the value of agricultural

land. First, there is level of returns obtained from using that land

in agricultural production. This return can be considered a residual

or balance after all other payment claims by inputs have been met. "

That is, all purchased inputs have been paid for and all labour and

capital that is not fixed to the land have been rewarded prior to any,

return accruing to the land and attached improvements. The size of.

this residual return to land will be an important· determinant of the

value of~that land.

The second main influence on land prices is a group of factors

which Clark [5] usefully termed "amenity andexpectat;ion" factors.

These include personal benefits of owning the land such as: the pros­

pect of capital gains, it's effectiveness as. a hedge against inflation,

being King of one's own mini Kingdom, etc., as well as expectations

about the future level of the residual returnto·land. Thefollowing

is designed to indicate (a) the relative magnitudes of the two factors,

(b) that the relative importance of the two factors varies over time,

and (c) the timing of major changes in the relative importance of the

two factors.

There is no way of estimating directly, the importance of the

amenity and expectation factors. But, with so~e assumptions, it,is

possible to assess the importance of the residual· return to land. To

do this, it.is necessary to estimate the payment to all inputs used in

production other than land and attached improvements. The analysis

begins with factor outputl which represents the 'return to.labour and

1 This term was introduced in Chapter 2, and.elaborated and estimated in Chapter 8.

Page 22: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-305-

capital including land. Labour payments consisting of actual wage

payments to employees, and 1.4 times the actual wage rate for prop-1

rietors have been deducted. The remaining deduction is a return on 2 livestock and plant and machinery capital, The residual return is

attributed to land and in a world of no uncertainty and no lags, can

be considered to be one year of an expected continuous stream of such

returns i.e. an annuity. The value of,landattributed to this flow

of returns should therefore be the present value lump sum equivalent of that annuity.

The procedure outlined above has been carried out using data

contained in this study. A range of discount rates and time periods

were tried, but only the present value of 20 year annuities discounted

at 5 per cent are reported here. This example is sufficient to fulfil

the purposes outlined earlier. The analysis is simplistic, and attrib­

utes all other influences to the amenity and expectation factors, The

quantitative estimate of these amenity and expectation factors is

derived as the difference between actual land va1ues3 and the capital­

ised annuity, These values are shown in Table SA.1, while Figure SA,l

shows the relationship between actual land values, and the capitalised

annuity value. In inteFpreting the diagram, where the actual land

value exceeds the capitalised ann~ity value, ,the amenity and expect­

ation factors. are exerting a positive influence .on actual land prices

(and vice-versa). This would be expected in periods such as the early

1930's depression when farming was so unprofitab1e~ Land prices were

well above the capitalised value, and some suggested reasons for this

1

2

3

See Chapter 4.

These capital values are· estimated in Chapters 6 and 7 respectively. The rate of return is assumed to be identical to. that, discount ,rate used in converting the residual return from an annuity to a present value lump sum.

The derivation of these values is described in Section. 5.2, ,

Page 23: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

$

15,000

12,500

10,000

7,500

5,000

2,500

o ~ ."L

1920/21 1930/31

Capitalised Return to Land

1940/41 1950/51

FIGURE 5A.1

Y

Actual Land Value

. 1960/61

Land Value and Capitalised Return to Land, 1920-21 to 1969-70: $m current prices.

Year

1969/70

I W o 01 I

Page 24: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-307-TABLE 5A.1

ESTIMATED "AMENITY AND EXPECTATION" VALUE IN LAND PRICES 1920-21 TO 1969-70

(current prices)

Year

1920-21 1921-22 1922-23 1923-24 1924-25

1925-26 1926-27 1927-28 1928-29 1929-30

1930-31 1931-32 1932-33 1933-34 1934-35

1935-36 1936-37 1937-38 1938-39 1939-40

1940-41 1941-42 1942-43 1943-44 1944-45

1945-46 1946-47 1947-48 1948-49 1949-50

1950-51 1951-52 1952-53 1953-54 1954-55

1955-56 1956-57 1957-58 1958-59 1959-60

1960-61 1961-62 1962-63 1963-64 1964-65

1965-66 1966-67 1967-68 1968-69 1969-70

Value of Land and

Improvementsa

$m

1.783 1.888 1.999 2.101 2.207

2.339 2.435 2.520 2.670 2.733

2.712 2.614 2.497 2.465 2.444

2,408 2,432 2,396 2,579 2,634

2,525 2,676 2,699 2,693 2.715

2,757 2,815 2,888 3.015 3.207

3,626 3,847 4,412 4,861 5,533

5,693 6,424 6,667 6,908 7,438

7,913 8,516 9,081 9,563

10,087

11,232 11,983 13,602 14,811 15,224

a Derived from Scott [10] and Gutman [6]'

Capitalised Retu~to

Land $m

1.313 576 587 636

1.704

634 213

. 194 270

-207

-291 -21 214 831 609

972 1,542 1,318

583 1.379

600 975

1,553 1.603

457

989 1,175 6,004 4,592 7,674

14,533 5,198 8,298 6,189 4,470

5.277 6,765 -118

3.486 4,063

3,572 2,376 3,963 8,255 5,943

471 6,412 -796

4,509 1.580

"Amenity and Expectations"

. Valuee $m

470 1.312 1.412 1.465

502

1.705 2.222 2.326 2.400 2.940

3.003 2.635 2,283 1.634 1,835

1,436 890

1,078 1,996 1,255

1,925 1,701 1,146 1,090 2,258

1,768 1,640

-3,116 -1,577 -4,467

-10,907 -1.351 -3.886 -1.328 1,063

416 -341

6,785 3,422 3,375

4,341 6,140 5,118 1,308 4,144

10,761 5,571

14,398 10,302 13,644

b id 1 eturn to land to be a 20 year annuity, Calculated by considering the res ua dr i discount rate of 5 per cent. from which the present value is derive us ng a

c Value of Land and Improvements less capitalised return to land.

Page 25: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-308 ...

are contained in Section 5.3, By way of contrast, the marked pros­

perity of the early 1950's wool boom was not generally expected to

last at that level, so that the amenity and expectation factors

exerted a strong negative influence.

Any comparison of these results with those of 'Clark for U.K.

IS, Table 37; facing p,94] should be made carefully because of major

differences between the,agricu1tura1 structures in the two countries.

These include the much greater importance of production for export in

Australia, and the more important renting ~actor in the U.K. Despite

these cautionary thoughts, the,trends'are surprisingly simiiar.

Briefly, in both countries, the amenity and expectation factors ,are

strong positive influences to about 1932-33, then they begin to

diminish in their positive influence to eventually become strongly

negative in the 1950's. Finally, they regain a strong positive

influence again from the l,ate 1950's. The only major difference is

that ,Clark finds the amenity and expectation factors to be negative

from 1933-34, while in Australia the negative period coincides with

the post-war boom.

The main implication of this analysis lies in the ,varying

importance of the amenity and expectation factors ove~ time, particularly

in periods ,of major disturbances such as the.early 1930's and 1950's.

Considering this in the context of land va1ues,.it means that ,the

efficiency with which land values reflect the productivity of.1and·

will also vary, particularly in times of major disturban~es. As a

result, it will be very difficult to obtain a satisfactory means of

deflating current price land values to constant price value.s,. In the'

absence of a land.· price index pre-war, some' price proxy, is . needed. and

agricultural product prices,are an obvious. choice because they are a

major determinant of tbe size of the residual return to land. However,·

the use of these inethods,will not produce satisfactorY'resu1t$ due,to

the changing role of amenity' and expectation factors in determining

land·prices.

Page 26: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-309-

A second implication may appear contradictory but is not.

Although there are all kinds of disturbance factors operating to

produce the oscillations in the capitalised values as indicated in

Figure 5A.l, there is some tendency for the trend in actual land­

values and the capitalised annuity value to move together. While

this is not pursued in detail here, the evidence is sufficient to

provide a warning about using land value as a measure of land input

as it will entail an element of circular reasoning. ariefly, this

means a tendency to try ,to explain rising output by rising land input

which in itself is partly determined by rising output. Th~s offers

further support for the use of a non-price based measure of land

input such as that outlined in Section 5,3,2.

Page 27: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-310-

APPENDIX 5B

IMPROVED AND UNIMPROVED RURAL LAND VALUES IN AUSTRALIA 1920-21 TO 1969-70a

Year Improvedb Un1m.provedb Value of Values Values Improvements C

$m $m $111

1920-21 1.783 974 809 1921-22 1.888 1.016 872 1922-23 1.999 1.069 930 1923-24 2,101 1,105 996 1924-25 2,207 1,131 1.076 1925-26 2,339 1.179 1,160 1926-27 2.435 1.198 1,237 1927-28 2,520 1,226 1,294 1928-29 2.670 1.249 1,421 1929-30 2.733 '1.255 1.478 1930-31 2.712 1,182 1,530 1931-32 2.614 1.153 1.461 1932-33 2,497 1,097 1.400 1933-34 2.465 1.093 1,372 1934-35 2,444 1.089 1,355 1935-36 2.408 1.072 1,336 1936-37 2.432 1.070 1.362 1937-38 2.396 1,053 1,343 1938-39 2,579 1.097 1.482 1939-40 2.634 1.106 1,528 1940-41 2.525 1.067 1,458 1941-42 2,676 1,103 1,573 1942-43 2,699 1.108 1,591 1943-44 2,693 1,100 1.593 1944-45 2,715 1.104 1.611 1945-46 2,757 1.102 1,655 1946-47 2.815 1.111 1.704 1947-48 2,888 1,131 1.757 1948-49 3.015 1.115 1.900 1949-50 3,207 1,145 2,062

1950-51 3,626 1,232 2,394 1951-52 3.847 1.291 2.556 1952-53 4,412 1.460 2.952 1953-54 4,861 1,554 3,307 1954-55 5.533 1.718 3.815

1955-56 5,693 1.774 3,919 1956-57 6.424 2,013 4.411 1957-58 6.667 2.066 4,601 1958-59 6,908 2,145 4.763 1959-60 7,438 2,266 5,172

1960'-61 7,913 2.531 5.382 1961-62 8,516 2,552 5,964 1962-63 9.081 2,648 6.433 1963-64 9.563 2.854 6,709 1964-65 10,087 2,882 7,205

1965-66 11.232 3,253 7.979 3,417 8.566 1966-67 11,983

9,842 1967-68 13,602 3,760 10.652 4.159 1968-69 14.811

4,274 d 10,950 d 1969-70 15,224 d

a All current prices. b Derived from Scott [10] and Gutman [6]. c Improved value less unimproved value. d

Interpolated.

Page 28: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-311-APPENDIX 5C

PRICE INDEX DEFLATED UNIMPROVED LAND ESTIMATES 1920-21 TO 1969-70

Year

1920-21 1921-22 1922-23 1923-24 1924-25

1925-26 1926-27 1927-28 1928-29 1929-30

1930-31 1931-32 1932-33 1933-34 1934-35

1935-36 1936-37 1937-38 1938-39 1939-40

1940-41 1941-42 1942-43 1943-44 1944-45

1945-46 1946-47 1947-48 1948-49 1949-50

1950-51 1951-52 1952-53 1953-54 1954-55

1955-56 1956-57 1957-58 1958-59 1959-60

1960-61 1961-62 1962-63 1963-64 1964-65

1965-66 1966-67 1967-68 1968-69 1969-70

Unimproved Values a

$m

974 1,016 1,069 1,105 1,131

1,179 1,198 1,226 1,249 1,255

1,182 1,153 1,097 1,093 1,089

1,072 1,070 1,053 1,097 1,106

1,067 1,103 1,108 1,100 1,104

1,102 1,111 1,131 1,115 1,145

1,232 1,291 1,460 1,554 1,718

1,774 2,013 2,066 2,145 2,266

2,531 2,552 2,648 2,854 2,882

3,253 3,417 3,760 4,159 4,274 c

Land Pric;, Index

63 65 67 69 69

66 66 66 66 67

65 63 61 59 57

56 56 59 58 59

61 64 67 69 71

74 76 78 80 85

91 100 100 121 133

144 154 163 170 176 180 184 189 195 203

213 226 240 251 n.a.

Index Deflated UnilJlproved Land

Value $m

1,546 1,563 1,596 1,601 1,639

1,786 1,815 1,858 1,892 1,873

1,818 1,830 1,798 1,853 1,910

1,914 1,911 1,785 1,891 1,875

1,749 1,723 1,654 1,594 1,555

1,489 1,462 1,450 1,394 1,347

1,354 1,291 1,327 1,284 1,292

1,232 1,307 1,267 1,262 1,288

1,406 1,387 1,401 1,464 1,420

1,527 1,512 1,567 1,657 n.a.

a Current prices derived from Scott [10J and Gutman 16J. b 1920 .. 21 to 1943...44, consumer price index 12J, 19.44-45 to 1969-70, Macph1l1amy [7,81,

base 1949-50 • 100. The two series have been spliced, and a six year lagged moving average calculated.

c Interpolated.

Page 29: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-312-

APPENDIX 5D

Compilation of an Index of Rural Public Capital

Total public capital expenditure estimates excluding defence

are available since 1860 in But1in [4]. His estimates are-generally

comparable to the official estimates in the.A,N,A, [1] which are avail­

able from 1938~39, These estimates for th~ 50 years.beginning in 1920-21

are shown in Table 5D,l, column (1) and are derived·from But1in [4]

1920-2lto 1937-38, official national- income.estimates 1938-39 to 1947-48

reported in Butlin [4], and-A.N,A. [1] estimates since 1948-49. While

there is a detailed breakdown of some of this expenditure by purpose

such as land settlement and·irrigation, this only allocates a small­

proportion of public expenditure to the.rural sector, ManYcexpenditures

such as those in the.transport. communications'and power generation

categories provide benefits to all sectors and are not allocated by

industry. Mathews [9] in his study of. public investment discusses

many aspects of particular rural investments, but does ,not include

any estimates or basis for estimating the proportiOn of total public

capital expenditure that has.a sign1ficantimpact on.the rural sector.

For the purposes of this study, an allocation has ,been based

on the proportion of rural output in Gross ,National Product (G,N.P,).

The basis for this allocation lies in -the assumption that public' capital

expenditure is likely.to be.directed.to-areas or industries in a way

which corresponds to the importance of these areas or industries as

sources of national output, This procedure is notable to indicate­

minor changes in emphasis in public capital expenditure programs-but

merely to distill the main trends, In this,regard, the allocated

proportions shown in Table 5D,1, column (2) appear appropriate for

this purpose, and were derived from Butlin [4] for the years 1920-21

to 1937~8, official estimates .reported,in Butlin [4] for 1939-40 to

1947-48 and the A.N.A. [1] since 1948-49. . ,

Page 30: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-313-

TABLE SD.1

COMPILATION OF THE RURAL PUBLIC CAPITAL STOCK INDEX 1920-21 TO 1969-70a

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Public Rural Rural Deflated Rural Rural

Year Investment Allocation Allocation Rural Public Public $m Allocation Capital Capital

% $m $m $m Index

1920-21 135 28.3 38 68 891 64.6 1921-22 127 23.3 30 61 925 67.8 1922-23 126 22.5 28 59 956 70.4 1923-24 134 22.7 30 65 992 72.8 1924-25 149 26.5 40 84 1.046 75.5 1925-26 154 22.5 35 72 1.087 79.7 1926-27 167 21.4 36 75 1.129 82.8 1927-28 171 20.4 35 72 1.167 86.0 1928-29 161 21.4 34 71 1.203 88.9 1929-30 141 20.0 28 58 1.225 91.6 1930-31 104 20.6 22 46 1.234 93.3 1931-32 69 23.0 16 35 1.233 94.0 1932-33 73 23.4 17 38 1.234 93.9 1933-34 77 25.9 20 45 1.242 94.0 1934-35 97 22.3 22 49 1.254 94.6 1935-36 103 23.5 24 56 1.272 95.5 1936-37 120 25.1 30 61 1.295 96.9 1937-38 137 22.8 31 64 1.319 98.6 1938-39 124 19.7 24 49 1.329 100.5 1939-40 116 22.0 26 46 1.335 101.2 1940-41 100 20.0 20 34 1.328 101.6 1941-42 76 19.0 14 23 1.311 101.1 1942-43 60 20.0 12 18 1.289 99.9 1943-44 64 20.0 13 19 1.269 98.2 1944-45 70 20.0 14 20 1.252' 96.7

1945-46 90 21.0 19 27 1.241 95.3 1946-47 182 21.0 38 53 1,257 94.5 1947-48 236 24.0 57 68 1.287 95.7 1948-49 283 21.2 60 65 1.313 98.0 1949-50 399 24.4 97 97 1.371 ·100.0

1950-51 575 28.9 166 126 1.456 104.4 1951-52 792 18.9 150 89 1.502 110.9 1952-53 774 21.0 163 96 1.552 114.3 1953-54 799 18.6 149 88 1.594 118.2 1954-55 849 16.4 139 79 1.625 121.4

1955-56 903 15.9 144 77 1.653 123.7 1956-57 934 16.6 155 80 1.683 125.8 1957-58 977 13.0 127 67 1,700 128.2 1958-59 1.075 14.4 155 83 1.732 129.5 1959-60 1.214 13.6 165 88 1.768 131.9

1960-61 1.256 13.1 165 85 1.799 134.6 . 1961-62 1.402 12.3 172 88 1.834 137.0

1962-63 1.451 12.6 183 94 1.872 139.6

1963-64 1.602 13.7 220 111 1.927 142.6

1964-65 1.854 12.4 230 111 1.980 146.8

1965-66 2.058 10.4 214 100 2.021 150.8

1966-67 2.168 11.6 252 115 2.076 153.9

1967-68 2.372 8.6 204 92 2.105 158.1 246 106 2.148 160.3

1968-69 2.536 4.7 226 92 2.175 163.5

1969-70 2.755 8.2

a For a description of these items and sources. !efer to the text of this Appendix.

Page 31: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-314-

The ratio of rural output to G.N,P, is then applied to the

estimate of total public capital expenditure to obtain an estimate

of the proportion which benefits the rural sector. This amount is

shown in Table 50,1, column (3), The next step was to convert these

expenditures to 1949~50 base year prices. An.index was compiled (but

not shown, in Table 50,1) using items on which price information was.

available and which were important components in public capital invest­

ment. Three items, metals and coal, building materials and·wages were

used and combined on an equal weights basis to form an index, From

1920-21 to 1958-59, this price information was derived from the

Melbourne Wholesale Price Index, and since 1959-60 from the.Wholesale

Price (Basic Materials and Foodstuffs) Index [2]. The resultant

deflated rural public capital expenditure estimate is shown ,in Table

50,1, column (4).

These annual gross public capital expenditures were used to

compile a stock series using a stock model

where Kt - public capital .stock in year t·

It - public capital expenditure in year t

d - diminishing balance rate'of depreciation of public

capital,

For these estimates, 'a rate of depreciation of 3 per cent was selected.

This is an arbitrary judgement made in the·absence of evidence on the.

real.rate of depreciation of public capital, ·and designed to reflect

the generally long-life of most public capital. The opening stock for

19~O-2lwas derived from But1in's [4] estimates extending back to 1860,

and processed in the same way as described above. For example, a

portion of the 1860 level of public capital expenditure is allocated to

rural use. in accord,with the ratio of rural production to G,N,P.,

deflated to,1949-50 prices, and then depreciated ,at a 3 per cent

Page 32: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-315-

diminishing balance rate, Repeating this process for all years from

1860 to 1919-20 and aggregating all years, resulted in a beginning

capital stock estimate for 1920-21 of $89lm. Stock estimates for

the remaining years were then derived via the stock model and are

shown in Table 5D.l, column (5). Finally, this stock series was

represented in index form with 1949-50 - 100, and is shown.,in column

(6), The index forms the .basis for estimating movements in the public

capital component of unimproved land as indicated in Appendix 5E,

Page 33: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-316-APPENDIX 5E

LAND AREA AND PUBLIC CAPITAL UNIMPROVED LAND ESTIMATES 1920-21 TO 1969-70a

Year Lan<1, x.a;:l~eac Public Total

Area Capitald Unimprovede mac. $m Value Land Value $m $m

1920-21 1.051 893 149 1.042 1921-22 1.041 885 157 1.042 1922-23 1.029 87S 163 1.038 1923-24 1.040 884 168 1.052 1924-25 1.006 855 174 1.029 1925-26 1.017 864 184 1.048 1926-27 1.020 867 191 1,058 1927-28 1,060 901 199 1,100 1928-29 1,047 890 205 1,095 1929-30 1,048 891 212 1,103 1930-31 1,022 869 216 1,085 1931-32 1,062 903 217 1,120 1932-33 1,066 906 217 1,123 1933-34 1,066 ·906 217 1,123 1934-35 1,065 905 219 1,124 1935-36 1.031 876 221 1,097 1936-37 1,000 884 224 1,108 1937-38 1,070 910 228 1.129 1938-39 1,079 917 232 1.149 1939-40 1.080 918 234 1,152 1940-41 1.055 897 235 1.132 1941-42 1.047 890 234 1.124 1942-43 1.055 897 231 1.128 1943-44 1.067 907 227 1.134 1944-45 1.074 913 223 1.136 1945-46 1.070 910 220 1.130 1946-47 1.080 918 218 1,136 1947-48 1.090 927 221 1,148 1948-49 1,083 921 226 1.147 1949-50 1.087 924 231 1.155

1950-51 1.091 927 241 1.168 1951-52 1.110 944 256 1,200 1952-53 1,116 949 264 1.213 1953-54 1.120 952 273 1.225 1954-55 1.127 958 280 1.238

1955-56 1.136 966 286 1.252 1956-S7 1,147 975 291 1,266 1957-S8 1.145 973 296 1.269 1958-59 1.150 978 299 1.277 1959-60 1.153 980 305 1.285

1960-61 1,168 993 311 1.304 1961-62 1,174 998 316 1,314 1962-63 1.180 1.003 322 1.325 1963-64 1.191 1.012 329 1.341 1964-6S 1.210 1.029 339 1.368

1965-66 1,211 1.029 .348 1.377 1966-67 1.216 1.034 356 1.390

365 1.409 1967-68 1.228 1.044 370 1.413 1968-69 1.227 1.043 378 1.421

1969-70 1.227 1.043

a All in 1949-50 prices. b Derived from Scott [10J. c Land area valued at $0.85 per acre. d

20 per cent of 1949-50 unimproved land value ($23lm), adjusted by the index of rural public capital from Appendix 5D.

e Sum of Land Area Value and Public Capital Value.

Page 34: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-317-

APPENDIX SF

Compilation of a Price Index for Improvements, to Land

The current price valuation of improvements is assumed to

approximate the depreciated replacement cost of effecting those,

improvements. This permits the deflation of that series to constant'

prices using an index based on the cost of effecting those improve­

ments. Such an index is compiled taking into ,account the availability

of price information, and the relevance of items in effecting improve­

ments. Throughout, equal weights have been allocated ,in the absence of

data on the importance of various components such as labour, materials,

chemicals, etc. in effecting improvements. This is a major deficiency

as it is likely that there has been substantial movements in the,

relative importance of input components. For example, in the ,1930's

and 1940's, the economic circumstances ,of low farm incomes and·1ater

wartime shortages of basic materials, would lead to the creation of

relatively more improvements with lower material requirements and,higher

on-farm labour content. Further, in the. 1950's and 1960's with heavy,

emphasis on pasture improvement, the ,mix of input·components,is likely

to be different to that of the 1930's and 1940's. To overcome·these

problems there is a need for detailed information on expenditures and

the use of labour ,and plant which is not available for recent years

let alone the ,whole 50 years. Hence, the equal weights procedure has

been invoked in the.absence of a feasible alternative.

Two sources have been used to derive the index of the cost of

improvements. The main source is theB.A.E. Prices Paid Indices [3]

which are available in disaggregatedcomponents from 1945~6 on, This

source is preferred because these indices specifically re1ate·to the

rural sector. From those indices, the following components were

Selected: seed fertilizer chemicals, fuel, machinery, fencing " , 1 .

materials, building mater,ia1s, wages. and contracts,. Prior to 1945-46,

1 This component i80n1y available from 1960-61 on.

Page 35: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-318-

data is more limited, and components were selected from the.Melbourne

Wholesale Price Index [2] which were comparable to items used from the'

B.A.E. indices and of relevance to the creation of improvements. The

selected components were chemicals, building materials, and metals and!

coal. The latter is included to represent items such as fencing wire,

machinery, waterpiping, etc. Wages was also included for this period:

and was derived from the award wage data discussed in Chapter 4. This!

wage series was compiled in an index form with the'same base year as

the Melbourne Wholesale Price Index.

The component indices were then used to.compile a single index . .

using equal weights. The years 1920-21 to 1944-45 which were built up

from the Melbourne Wholesale Price Index referred to a.base year of 1911.

The years 1945-46 to 1969-70 which drew on the B.A.E. Prices Paid Indices

relate to a base period of the.three years ended June 1963. Thus the

final calculation involved adjusting the index to a 1949-50 base. The

resultant index is shown in Table 5F.l.

Page 36: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-319-

TABLE 5F.1

Price Index for Improvements to Landa 1920.-21 to 1969-70.

(1949-50. - 100)

Year Index Year Index

1920.-21 56 1945-46 73 1921-22 50. 1946-47 75 1922-23 47 1947-48 81 1923-24 46 1948-49 90. 1924-25 46 1949-50. 10.0

1925-26 46 1950.-51 126 1926-27 48 1951-52. 159 1927-28 48 1952-:-53 160. 1928-29 48 1953-54 159 1929-30. 50. 1954-55 160

1930.-31 50. 1955-56 164 1931-32 47 1956-57 173 1932-33 47 1957-58 176 1933-34 46 1958-59 175

1934-35 46 1959-60. 177

1935-36 46 1960.-61 180.

1936-37 48 1961-62 180

1937-38 48 1962-63 179

1938-39 '49 1963 .. 64 179

1939-40. 55 1964-65 179

1940.-41 58 1965-66 187

1941-42 61 1966-67 195

1942-43 66 1967-68. 20.0.

1943-44 67 1968-69 20.3

1944-45 68 1969-70 20.1

a For the years 1920-21 to 1944-45, based on components selected from the Melbourne Wholesale Price Index [2], for 1945-46 to 1969-70., based on,components selected ,from the B.A.E. Prices Paid Indices [31; base'1949-5D - 10.0..

Page 37: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-320-

APPENDIX 5G

PRICE INDEX DEFLATED IMPROVEMENTS ESTIMATES 1920-21 TO 1969-70

Value of Price Index Constant Price

Year Improvementsa of Improve- Value of Estimated

Depreciation c $m menta b Improvements

$m $m

1920-21 809 59 1921-22 872 60

1,371 24 1922-23 930 59

1,453 26

1923-24 996 55 1,576 28

1924-25 1,076 52 1,811 30 2,069 32

1925-26 1,160 49 1926-27 1,237 47

2,367 35

1927-28 1,294 47 2,632 37

1928-29 1,421 47 2,753 39

1929-30 1,478 48 3,023 43 3,079 44

1930-31 1,530 48 3,188 1931-32 1,461

46

1932-33 49 2,982 44

1.400 48 1933-34 1,372

2,917 42

1934-35 48 2,858 41

1,355 48 2,823 41 1935-36 1.336 47 2.843 1936-37

40 1.362 47 2.898 41

1937-38 1.343 1938-39

47 2.857 40 1.482 47 3.153 45

1939-40 1.528 49 3.118 46 1940-41 1.458 51 2.859 44 1941-42 1.573 53 2.968 47 1942-43 1.591 56 2.841 48 1943-44 1.593 59 2.700 49 1944-45 1.611 63 2.557 48

1945-46 1.655 66 2.508 50 1946-47 1.704 68 2.506 51 1947-48 1.757 72 2.440 53 1948-49 1.900 76 2.500 57 1949-50 2.062 81 2.546 62

1950-51 2.394 91 2.631 72 1951-52 2,556 105 2.434 77 1952-53 2.952 119 2.481 89 1953-54 3.307 132 2.505 99 1954-55 3.815 144 2.649 115

1955-56 3.919 155 2.528 118 1956-57 4.411 163 2,706 132 1957-58 4,601 165 2.788 138 1958-59 4.763 168 2.835 143 1959-60 5.172 171 3.025 155

1960-61 5.382 174 3.093 162 1961-62 5.964 177 3,369 179 1962-63 6.433 178 3,614 193 1963-64 6.709 178 3.769 201

1964-65 7.205 179 4,025 216

1965-66 7.979 181 4.408 239

1966-67 8.566 113 4,681 257

1967-68 9.842 187 5,263 295

1968-69 10,652 191 5,577 320

1969-70 10,950 d 194 5,644 329

a Current prices derived from Scott [10] and Gutman [6].

b This series is a six year lagged moving average of the index discussed in Appendix SF.

c Depreciation estimated using 3 per cent diminishing balance, and in current prices.

d Interpolated.

Page 38: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-321-

APPENDIX 5 - References

[1] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Australian National Accounts,

Canberra, (various issues),

[2] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF "STATISTICS, Labour Report, Canberra, (various"

issues).

[3] BUREAU OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS, Indices of Prices Paid, Canberra,""

(mimeo), "

[4] BUTLIN, N.G., Australian Domestic Product, Investment and Foreign

Borrowing, 1861-1938/39. Cambridge Univ. Press, 1962.

[5] CLARK, C., The Value of Agricultural Land, Oxford, Pergamon Press,

1973.

[6] GUTMAN, G.O., "Investment and Production in Australian Agriculture",

Rev. Mktg Agric. Econ" 23(4), 237-310, Dec" 1955.

[7] MACPHILLAMY, C.H., "Movements in Rural Land "Prices and Factors

Affecting These Movements", Unpublished' (mimeo), Sydney,

1968.

[8] MACPHILLAMY, C,H., "Rural" Land Prices - New South Wales Current

Situation and Prospects"; The Valuer, 22(1), 18-23,

Jan., 1972.

[9] MATHEWS, R., Public Investment in Australia, Melbourne, Cheshires,

1967.

[10] SCOTT, R.H., The Value of Land in Australia, Unpublished manu-"

script, Sydney, 1973.

Page 39: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-322-APPENDIX 6A

ESTIMATED NUMBER OF LIVESTOCK IN AUSTRALIA:

1920-21 TO 1969-70, milliona

Year Sheep Beef Dairy Cattle Cattle Pigs Poultry Horses

1920-21 81.8 10.4 3.1 0.8 1921-22 86.1 11.0 2.4

10.9 3.5 1.0 11.7 1922-23 82.7 2.4 10.7 3.7 1.0 12.0 1923-24 84.0 2.4

9.9 3.5 0.9 12.3 1924-25 93.2 2.3 9.6 3.7 1.0 13.0 2.3

1925-26 103.6 9.6 3.7 1.1 1926-27 104.3

13.2 2.3 8.5 3.5 1.0 13.4 2.1 1927-28 100.8 8.2 3.5 0.9 13.6 2.0 1928-29 103.4 7.8 3.5 0.9 13.7

1929-30 104.6 7.6 1.9

3.6 1.0 13.9 1.8 1930-31 110.6 7.9 3.8 1.1 14.7 1931-32 110.6

1.8 8.1 4.2 1.2 15.6

1932-33 112.9 1.8

8.3 4.5 1.2 15.9 1933-34 109.9 8.8 4.7

1.8 1.0 16.5 1.8

1934-35 113.0 9.1 4.9 1.2 17.0 1.8 1935-36 108.9 8.9 5.0 1.3 17.0 1.8 1936-37 110.2 8.6 4.9 1.2 16.7 1.8 1937-38 113.4 8.2 4.9 1.1 16.5 1.7 1938-39 111.1 8.0 4.9 1.2 16.7 1.7 1939-40 119.3 8.2 4.9 1.5 17.4 1.7 1940-41 122.7 8.3 4.9 1.8 17.7 1.7 1941-42 125.2 8.6 4.9 1.4 17.6 1.6 1942-43 124.6 9.0 5.0 1.6 18.1 1.5 1943-44 123.2 9.3 4.9 1.7 19.0 1.4 1944-45 105.4 9.3 4.8 1.6 19.4 1.4 1945-46 96.4 9.3 4.6 1.4 18.5 1.3 1946-47 95.7 8.8 4.6 1.3 18.7 1.2 1947-48 102.6 9.0 4.8 1.3 18.5 1.2 1948-49 108.7 9.2 4.9 1.2 18.3 1.1 1949-50 112.9 9.7 4.9 1.1 18.5 1.1

1950-51 115.6 10.4 4.9 1.1 18.5 1.0 1951-52 117.6 10.3 4.6 1.0 lS.2 0.9 1952-53 123.1 10.5 4.S ·1.0 17.9 0.9 1953-54 126.9 10.7 4.9 1.2 18.1 O.S 1954-55 130.8 10.9 4.9 1.3 17.9 0.8

1955-56 139.1 11.4 5.1 1.2 18.2 0.8 1956-57 149.8 12.1 5.1 1.3 21.7 0.7 1957-58 149.3 11.9 5.0 1.4 18.1 0.7 1958-59 152.7 11.4 4.8 . 1.3 18.8 0.7 -1959-60 155.2 11.6 4.9 1.4 20.0 0.6

1960-61 152.7 12.4 4.9 1.6 21.6 0.6 1961-62 157.7 13.0 5.0 1.7 22.4 0.6 1962-63 158.6 13.5 5.1 1.4 22.8 0.5 1963-64 165.0 14.2 4.8 1.5 25.5 0.5 1964-65 170.6 14.1 4.7 1.7 27.6 0.5

1965-66 157.6 13.3 4.6 1.7 28.9 0.5

1966-67 164.2 13.7 4.5 1.8 31.7 0.5

1967-68 166.9 14.8 4.4 2.1 33.8 0.5

1968-69 174.6 16.3 4.3 2.3 35.5 0.5

1969-70 180.1 18.0 4.2 2.4 38.9 0.5

a Except for poultry, derived from Australian Bureau of Statistics, Rural Industries Bulletin, Canberra. For details. see same reference. Chapter 2. Poultry e~timates from Angliss. D.B. and R.A. Powell. "Estimates of Poultry Numbers by States • unpublished U.N.E. paper. 1974 (mimeo).

Page 40: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-323-

APPENDIX 6B

ESTIMATED VALUE OF LIVESTOCK IN AUSTRALIA:

1920-21 TO 1969-70. $m. 1949-50 pricesa

Year Sheep Beef Dairy Cattle Cattle Pigs Poultry Horses Total

1920-21 409 364 140 8 11 97 1.028 1921-22 431 382 159 10 12 98 1.090 1922-23 414 374 165 10 12 95 1.068 1923-24 420 346 157 9 12 93 1.037 1924-25 466 337 166 10 13 92 1 •. 083 1925-26 518 336 166 11 13 90 1.134 1926-27 521 277 157 10 13 85 1.083 1927-28 504 286 155 9 14 82 1.049 1928-29 517 272 159 9 14 78 1.049 1929-30 523 267 160 10 14 74 1.048 1930-31 553 277 171 11 15 72 1.098 1931-32 553 283 189 12 16 71 1.122 1932-33 565 289 204 12 16 71 1.155 1933-34 550 309 211 11 17 71 1.167 1934-35 565 320 221 12 17 71 1.205 1935-36 544 313 224 13 17 71 1.182 1936-37 551 302 219 12 17 71 1.171 1937-38 567 288 219 11 17 70 1.170 1938-39 555 280 218 12 17 69 1.151 1939-40 597 286 220 15 18 68 1.203 1940-41 614 292 221 18 18 67 1.229 1941-42 626 303 221 14 18 64 1.246 1942-43 623 315 225 16 18 61 1.258 1943-44 616 324 221 18 19 58 1?256 1944-45 527 326 217 16 19 54 1.160 1945-46 482 324 207 14 19 51 1.097 1946-47 479 308 209 13 19 48 1.074 1947-48 513 315 216 13 19 47 1.121 1948-49 544 322 221 12 18 45 1.162 1949-50 565 339 222 11 19 42 1.198

1950-51 578 363 218 11 19 40 1.229 1951-52 588 360 208 10 18 37 1.222 1952-53 615 366 216 10 18 36 1.261 1953-54 635 375 220 12 18 34 1.294 1954-55 654 382 222 13 18 32 1.321

1955-56 696 399 228 12 18 31 1.383 1956-57 749 425 230 13 22 29 1.469 1957-58 747 416 225 14 18 28. 1.448 1958-59 764 399 218 13 19 27 1.439 1959-60 776 407 220 14 20 26 1.462

1960-61 763 435 221 16 22 24 1.481 1961-62 789 455 227 17 23 22 1.531 1962-63 793 472 228 14 23 22 1.552 1963-64 825 498 218 15 26 21 1.602 1964-65 853 492 214 17 28 21 1.624

1965-66 788 467 207 18 29 20 1.528 1966-67 821 481 204 18 32 19 1.575 1967-68 835 518 198 21 34 19 1.624

1968-69 873 572 192 23 36 18 1.713

1969-70 900 630 187 24 39 18 1.799

a Derived from the number of livestock using values as follows: sheep $5. beef cattle $35. dairy cattle $45. pigs $10. poultry $1 and horses $40.

Page 41: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

~324~

APPENDIX 7A

Depreciation of Farm Machinery, 1920-21 to 1940-41

With information on both the stock and gross investment in

plant and machinery, an estimate of depreciation may be obtained.

Depreciation represents the difference between gross investment and

net investment, that is

Dt = GI t - (Kt+l - Kt )

where Dt = depreciation in period t

GI t = gross investment in period t

Kt +l - Kt = net investment in period t, that is the net addition

to the stock value (K) in period t.

Published data on the depreciated historic cost of plant and

machinery on farms spaned the period 1920-21 to 1940-41, as detailed

in Section 7.3.1. Gross investment in plant and machinery can be

estimated from data on imports and Australian production of plant and

machinery as discussed in Section 7.3.2. These data are used in

Table 7A.l to estimate the rate of depreciation of plant and machinery

on Australian farms.

The main difficulty with these estimated depreciation rates

is the effect of changing prices. The extent of the price changes can

be gauged from the plant and machinery price index. The problem lies

in the difficulty of deflating a stock valued at depreciated historic

cost in the absence of information on the age distribution of items

in that stockl • Thus, Table 7A.l is compiled in current price terms

which biases the estimated depreciation rates.· The bias will be upwards

when period t prices are lower than the prices in period t-l to

t-n when the stock was acquired. In these circumstances, an amount

of expenditure in period t equivalent to the amount of depreciation

1 The constant price stock estimates contained in Section 7.4 are not suitable for this purpose either because the inventory model from which they were derived, already incorporates a specified depreciation rate.

Page 42: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-325-

on the stock acquired in earlier periods, will add more to the real

stock of plant and machinery than is being subtracted via depreciation.

Thus, the estimated replacement component of expenditure (GI - NI ) t t

will be overestimated. As this is assumed to be equivalent to the

amount of depreciation on the stock of plant and machinery, this too

will be overestimated. The converse will apply when plant and

machinery prices are rising.

Throughout most of the period plant and machinery prices

were declining, rapidly through the 1920's then marginally to

1936-37 when they began to rise. This would partly explain the

relatively high estimated rates of depreciation in the late 1920's

and early 1930's, when prices were fairly stable, but significantly

lower than prices before the mid 1920's. Average depreciation over

the whole period was 9.13 per cent. Allowing for the price change

effect to be biasing the estimate upwards the real rate of deprec­

iation on a straight line basis would seem to,. have been 9 per cent

or less.

Page 43: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-326-

TABLE 7A.1

Estimated Rate of Depreciation of Plant and Machinery, 1920-21 to 1940-41

(current prices)

Value of Net b Gross Depreciation Machinery f Year Stocka Investment InvestmentC Price Index d Ratee Amount

$m $m $m $m r.

1920-21 62.0 6.6 10.2 3.6 5.8 75 1921-22 68.6 6.7 10.8 4.1 6.1 69 1922-23 75.3 3.6 9.6 6.0 7.8 62 1923-24 78.9 8.1 13.4 5.3 6.8 61 1924-25 87.0 3.9 14.5 10.6 12.2 59 1925-26 90.9 6.8 14.1 7.3 8.1 58 1926-27 97.6 7.7 16.7 9.0 9.3 56 1927-28 105.3 3.0 15.0 12.0 11.4 55 1928-29 108.3 1.1 14.6 13.5 12.5 56 :1929-30 109.4 -3.3 11.6 14.9 13.7 56 1930-31 106.1 -7.2 5.9 13.1 12.3 54 1931-32 98.9 -3.8 3.8 7.6 7.7 52 1932-33 95.1 -1.9 5.6 7.5 7.9 51 1933-34 93.2 -2.2 5.9 8.1 8.8 49 1934-35 91.0 3.4 7.3 3.9 4.3 49

1935-36 94.4 1.5 10.7 9.2 9.8 49 1936-37 95.9 6.1 14.5 8.4 8.7 49 1937-38 102.0 9.0 20.0 11.0 10.8 54 1938-39 111.0 3.1 13.7 10.6 9.5 54 1939-40 114.1 2.2 12.6 10.4 9.5 58

1940-41 116.3

a Derived from Rural Industries Bulletin [3].

b Stock t+l - Stockt •

c Derived from Imports and Australian production of plant and machinery, Appendix 7C.

d'Gross Investment less Net Investment.

e Depreciation as per cent of the value of stock.

f Appendix 7E.

Page 44: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-327-

APPENDIX 7B

INVESTMENT, DEPRECIATION AND STOCKS OF PLANT AN;) MAr.H!NERY, 1920-21 TO 1969-70

STOCK BASED ESTIMATES. $m 1969-70 prices a

Year Stockb Depreciation Gross Investment

1920-21 117.0 11.7 20.5 1921-22 125.8 12.5 22.1 1922-23 135.4 13.5 19.6 1923-24 141.5 14.2 27.3 1924-25 154.7 15.5 22.1 1925-26 161.3 16.1 27.8 1926-27 173.0 17.3 31.0 1927-28 186.7 18.7 24.3 1928-29 192.3 19.2 21.2 1929-30 194.3 19.4 13.4 1930-31 188.2 18.8 5.6 1931-32 175.0 17.5 10.1 1932-33 167.7 16.8 13.1 1933-34 164.0 16.4 11.8 1934-35 159.4 15.9 22.9 1935-36 166.3 16.6 19.7 1936-37 169.4 16.9 29.5

·1937-38 182.0 18.2 34.8 1938-39 198.6 19.9 25.6 1939-40 204.3 20.4 24.1 1940-41 208.0 20.8 30.6 1941-42 217.9 21.8 31.2 1942-43 227.2 22.7 31.7 1943-44 236.5 23.6 36.6 1944-45 249.0 24.9 39.9 1945-46 263.8 26.4 36.4 1946-47 274.2 27.4 34.4 1947-48 286.9 28.7 51. 7 1948-49 310.4 31.0 66:0 1949-50 345.3 34.5 77.5

1950-51 388.1 38.8 80.8 1951-52 429.6 43.0 75.0 1952-53 462.0 46.2 75.2 1953-54 490.7 49.1 83.1 1954-55 524.5 52.4 83.5

1955-56 555.9 55.6 77.6 1956-57 577.7 57.8 86.8 1957-58 597.0 59.7 75.7 1958-59 612.9 61.3 83.3 1959-60 634.7 63.5 82.5

1960-61 653.7 65.4 88.4 1961-62 677.1 67.7 80.7

69.0 90.0 1962-63 690.3 71.1 95.1 1963-64 710.6 72.1 83.5 1964-65 720.6

744.8 74.5 100.5 1965-66 77.1 95.1 1966-67 770.7

77.9 1967-68 189.0 78.9 83.8 ~87.6 78.8 1968-69

79.2 68.9 1969-70 792.5

1 hi 1 Compilation described in Section a These estimates do not include commercia ve c es. 7.4, and data from Gutman [8] and A.B.S. [3].

b Stock • Stock - Depreciationt + Gross Investmentt • t+1 t

Page 45: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-328-APPENDIX 7C

PLANT AND MACHINERY SUPPLY IMPORTS AND DOMESTIC PRODUCTION : 1920-21 TO 1969-70 $m, current pricesa

Year Importsb Domestic Proportion to Estimated c Production Agriculture Supply Value

1920-21 2.68 4.58 1.00 10.2 1921-22 2.03 5.73 1.00 10.8 1922-23 1.55 5.37 1.00 9.6 1923-24 3.32 6.26 1.00 13.4 1924-25 3.74 6.57 1.00 14.5 1925-26 3.61 6.46 1.00 14.1 1926-27 4.27 7.64 1.00 16.7 1927-28 4.03 6.61 1.00 15.0 1928-29 4.01 6.33 1.00 14.6 1929-30 3.40 4.80 1.00 11.6 1930-31 1.30 2.95 1.00 5.9 1931-32 0.45 2.29 1.00 3.8 1932-33 0.68 3.40 1.00 5.6 1933-34 0.73 3.53 1.00 5.9 1934-35 1.30 3.94 1.00 7.3 1935-36 2.56 5.06 1.00 10.7 1936-37 4.01 6.30 0.99 14.5 1937-38 5.71 8.45 1.00 20.0 1938-39 2.98 6.81 1.00 13.7 1939-40 2.29 6.84 0.97 12.6 1940-41 1.63 8.60 0.95 13.9 1941-42 1.62 12.85 0.90 19.5 1942-43 3.30 13.46 0.85 22.4 1943-44 7.02 13.21 0.55 23.6 1944-45 14.62 13.18 0.65 32.0 1945-46 8.69 13.40 0.76 28.0 1946-47 6.92 13.43 0.83 26.7 1947-48 10.04 16.80 0.92 36.5 1948-49 20.19 20.77 0.84 53.5 1949-50 40.71 28.37 0.89 92.6

1950-51 50.19 40.48 0.79 114.1 1951-52 62.07 54.25 0.73 141.2 1952-53 32.87 46.85 0.94 109.6 1953-54 45.53 59.16 0.87 139:3 1954-55 52.24 61.11 0.82 146.8

1955-56 47.69 56.80 0.79 133.2 1956-57 39.94 51.41 0.89 122.7 1957-58 46.83 59.35 0.90 146.0 1958-59 40.79 60.52 0.89 136.2 1959-60 53.29 70.35 0.87 164.5

1960-61 57.32 69.86 0.86 168.3 1961-62 38.16 74.35 0.87 150.2 1962-63 54.33 80.18 0.87 170.1 1963-64 88.40 103.08 0.86 253.2 1964-65 106.44 117.37 0.83 291.0

1965-66 71.60 105.08 0.82 229.7 1966-67 63.38 126.93 0.85 252.2 1967-68 72.34 131.81 0.79 263.7 1968-69 54.79 161.48 0.79 282.9 1969-70 44.62 137.04 0.72 233.2

a Excludes vehicles

b Derived from Overseas Trade [2]

c Derived from Commonwealth Year Book [5].

d Assumed equal to 1.00 for years 1920-21 to 1935-36, thereafter estimated from information in Crawford, et.al. [7], Saxon [9,10] and the Rural Industries Bulletin [3].

Page 46: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-329-

APPENDIX 7D

INVESTMENT , DEPRECIATION AND STOCKS OF PLANT AND MACHINERY; 1920-21 TO 1969-70

SUPPLY BASED ESTIMATES, $m 1949-50 pricesa

Year Stockb Depreciation Gross Investment

1920-21 117.0 11. 7 1921-22 13.6

118.9 11.9 15.6 1922-23 122.6 12.3 15.4 1923-24 125.8 12.6 22.0 1924-25 135.2 13.5 24.5 1925-26 146.3 14.6 24.4 1926-27 156.0 15.6 29.9 1927-28 170.3 17.0 27.2 1928-29 180.5 18.0 26.0 1929-30 188.4 18.8 20.7 1930-31 190.2 19.0 11.0 1931-32 182.2 18.2 7.2 1932-33 171.2 17.1 11.0 1933-34 165.1 16.5 12.0 1934-35 160.6 16.1 14.8 1935-36 159.3 15.9 21.8 1936-37 165.2 16.5 29.5 1937-38 178.2 17.8 37.0 1938-39 197.3 19.7 25.3 1939-40 202.9 20.3 21.7 1940-41 204.3 20.4 22.8 1941-42 206.7 20.7 30.5 1942-43 216.5 21.6 32.4 1943-44 227.3 22.7 34.2 1944-45 238.8 23.9 46.4 1945-46 261.4 26.1 40.6 1946-47 275.8 27.6 36.6 1947-48 284.9 28.5 44.0 1948-49 300.4 30.0 58.1 1949-50 328.5 32.8 92.6

1950-51 388.3 38.8 95.9 1951-52 445.4 44.5 99.4 1952-53 500.3 50.0 71.2 1953-54 521.4 52.1 89.3 1954-55 558.5 55.9 91. 7

1955-56 594.4 59.4 80.7 1956-57 615.7 61.6 71.8 1957-58 625.9 62.6 79.8 1958-59 643.1 64.3 69.5 1959-60 648.3 64.8 82.3

1960-61 665.7 66.6 82.5 1961-62 681.6 68.2 72.2 1962-63 685.6 68.6 84.9 1963-64 702.0 70.2 118.9 1964-65 750.6 75.1 133.5

196~66 809.1 80.9 102.5 1966-67 830.7 83.1 109.2 1967-68 856.8 85.7 110.3 1968-69 881.4 88.1 113.2 1969-70 906.4 90.6 91.4

a These estimates do not include commercial vehicles. Compilation described in Section 7.4, and opening stock estimate from Gutman [8) and gross investment from Appendix 7C.

b Stockt+

1 - Stockt - Depreciationt + Gross Investmentt •

Page 47: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-330-

APPENDIX 7E

INVESTMENT. DEPRECIATION AND STOCKS OF PLANT AND MACHINERY. 1920-21 TO 1969-70

COMBINED STOCK AND SUPPLY BASED ESTIMATE. Sm. a

Year Stockb Depreciation Gross Investment Machinery Stockd

Price Indexc

1920-21 124.0 12.4 21.3 75 93 1921-22 132.8 13.3 26.3 69 92 1922-23 145.8 14.6 27.7 62 91 1923-24 158.9 15.9 32.5 61 97 1924-25 175.4 17.5 31.1 59 103 1925-26 189.0 18.9 37.4 58 110 1926-27 207.5 20.7 41.3 56 116 1927-28 228.1 22.8 31.9 55 125 1928-29 237.2 23.7 25.7 56 133 1929-30 239.1 ·23.9 11.0 56 134 1930-31 226.2 22.6 12.8 54 122 1931-32 216.4 21.6 14.3 52 112 1932-33 209.1 20.9 20.7 51 107 1933-34 208.8 20.9 16.3 49 102 1934-35 204.2 20.4 34.3 49 100 1935-36 218.0 21.8 35.2 49 107 1936-37 231.4 23.1 42.6 49 113 1937-38 250.9 25.1 45.2 54 136 1938-39 271.0 27.1 36.3 54 146 1939-40 280.2 28.0 31. 7 58 162 1940-41 283.9 28.4 34.8 61 173 1941-42 290.3 29.0 38.4 64 186 1942-43 299.6 30.0 39.8 69 207 1943-44 309.4 30.9 46.7 69 213 1944-45 325.2 32.5 58.3 69 224 1945-46 350.9 35.1 49.3 69 242 1946-47 365.1 36.5 52.5 73 266 1947-48 381.1 38.1 59.0 83 316 1948-49 402.0 40.2 74.4 92 370 1949-50 436.2 43.6 111.1 100 436

1950-51 503.7 50.4 118.3 119 600 1951-52 571.6 57.2 139.2 142 • 812 1952-53 653.7 65.4 99.5 154 1,007 1953-54 687.8 68.8 125.0 156 1,073 1954-55 744.0 74.4 128.5 160 1,190

1955-56 798.1 79.8 113.1 165 1.317 1956-57 831.4 83.1 100.4 171 1,421 1957-58 848.7 84.9 111.6 183 1.554 1958-59 875.4 87.5 97.3 196 1.715 1959-60 885.2 88.5 115.2 200 1,770

1960-61 911.8 91.2 115.5 204 1.860 1961-62 936.2 93.6 101.1 208 1,947 1962-63 943.6 94.4 118.7 211 1.992 1963-64 968.0 96.8 166.5 213 2,062 1964-65 1,037.7 103.8 186.9 218 2,263

1965-66 1,120.8 112.1 143.6 224 2,511 1966-67 1,152.3 115.2 152.7 231 2.661 1967-68 1,189.8 119.0 154.3 239 2,844 1968-69 1.225.1 122.5 158.3 250 3,063 1969-70 1.260.9 126.1 127.9 255 3,216

a These estimates include commercial vehicles. Estimates in 1949-50 prices unless indicated. Compilation described in Section 7.4, and data from Appendices 7B, 7D and Gutman [8].

b Stock • Stock - Depreciation + Gross Investmentt • t+1 t t

c 1920-21 to 1944-45 from Gutman [8], since 1945-46 from B.A.E. [6].

d Stock valued in current prices.

Page 48: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-331-

APPENDIX 7F

The Farm Stock of Commercial Vehicles under 10

and 15 per cent Depreciation

The ABS published data of commercial vehicles on farms

only covers the 1943 to 1951 period [3]. Since then, an estimate

of commercial vehicles on farms can be obtained from the 1963

Survey of Motor Vehicle Usage [4]. This survey indicates that

315,730 vehicles, about 38 per cent of all such commercial vehicles,

are used in the rural sector.

As described in Section 7.4.3, expenditure on commercial

vehicles has been estimated at 40 per cent of estimated expenditure

on plant and machinery other than commercial vehicles. Using this

estimate of expenditure on commercial vehicles deflated to base

prices, the inventory model can be used,to estimate the constant

price stock value. Dividing this value by the estimated vehicle

price, yields on estimate of the number of vehicles on farms. Similar

estimates can be derived for the number of vehicles scrapped and the

number of vehicles added in each year.

The inventory model requires the rate of depreciation

(or scrappage) to be specified. Only two rates have been considered,

10 and 15 per cent. The results for the stock of vehicles are shown

in Table 7F.l. This'shows that the 10 per cent depreciation rate

gives an estimate of 307,413 vehicles in 1962-63 which is close to

the Commercial Vehicle Survey estimate of 315,730. Furthermore, .

the trends appear reasonable; rapidly increasing numbers following

the early 1950's wool boom, slow increases in the late 1950's, until

after the 1961 credit squeeze; then rapid increases corresponding to

the rapid expansion in crop area in the middle 1960's; and a slowing

down in 1969-70 with the advent of wheat quotas and falling wool prices.

Page 49: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-332-

These results should be treated cautiously. Errors could

arise due to:

(i) errors in estimated expenditure on commercial vehicles,

(if) changing real value of commercial vehicles over time, and

(iii) varying rates of vehicle scrappage over time.

However, in the absence of additional data to validate the estimate

for years other than 1951 and 1963, the estimates are plausible

in indicating 1.63 such vehicles per holding in 1969-70, or 2.07

vehicles per commercial farm in 1968-691 / Further, the~e results

would lend support to a depreciation rate of approximately 10 per

cent rather than the more conventionally used depreciation rate of

15 per cent.

1 1968-69 is used because the number of commercial farms is available for that year [1] but not for 1969-70.

Page 50: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

a Year

1950-51 1951-52 1952-53 1953-54 1954-55

1955-56 1956-57 1957-58 1958-59 1959-60

1960-61 1961-62 1962-63 1963-64 1964-65

1965-66 1966-67 1967-68 1968-69 1969-70

a

-333-

TABLE 7F.1

Estimated Stock of Vehicles on Farms

10%

142,200b

174,084 189,571 212,100 233,538

247,773 256,265 267,517 273,028 283,968

293,852 297,970 307,413 331,972 360,800

372,401 385,708 398,202 410,800 412,053

Depreciation Rate

As at March 31st in the second year.

b A.B.S. [3] estimate for March 31st 1951.

15%

142,200b

166,346 174,200 189,559 203,770

210,798 212,424 217,448 217 ,088 222,773

227,645 226,995 232.184 273~086 294,142

297~691 303~573 309,084

.315,128 310,186

Page 51: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-334-

APPENDIX 7 - References

[1] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Classification of Rural

Holdings by Size and Type of Activity, Canberra,

various issues.

[2] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Overseas Trade, Canberra,

various issues.

[3] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Rural Industries Bulletin,

Canberra. For details of all issues in this series

see same Reference, Chapter 2. ""-",-

[4] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Survey of Motor Vehicle Usage,

1963, Canberra, 1965.

[5] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Year Book of the Commonwealth

of Australia, Canberra, various issues.

[6] BUREAU OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS, Indices of Prices Paid,

Canberra, (mimeo).

[7] CRAWFORD, J.G., et.al., Wartime Agriculture in Australia and

New Zealand 1939-50, Stanford University Press,

1954.

[8] GUTMAN, G.O., "Investment and Production in Australian Agriculture",

Rev. Mkgt Agric. Econ., 23(4), 237-310, Dec., 1955. < "

[9] SAXON, E.A., "Tractors on Australian Farms: pas\ and Probable

Future Australian Requirements", Qtly Rev. Agric. Econ.,

6(1), 11-13, Jan., 1953.

[10] SAXON, E.A, "Tractors on Australian Farms", Qt1y Rev. Agric.Econ.,

12(2), 81-86, April, 1959.

Page 52: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-335-

APPENDIX 8A

GROSS OUTPUT OF AUSTRALIAN AGRICULTUllE, 1920-21 TO 1969-70

Year Output Components Grosa Agricultural Gross

Value of Fa? Livestock Output Pricec Output

Production lnventobY current Index 1949-50

$m pricee Pricee Changes $m $m $m

1920-21 463 17 480 49 980 1921-22 379 22 401 35 1,146 1922-23 434 -9 425 41 1,137 1923-24 447 -14 433 44 984 1924-25 535 21 556 45 1,235

1925-26 465 21 486 42 1,158 1926-27 492 -20 472 40 1,179 1927-28 489 -15 474 43 1,103 1928-29 491 0 491 39 1,258 1929-30 402 0 402 34 1,182

1930-31 341 13 354 26 1,362 1931-32 340 6 346 25 1,384 1932-33 352 .8 360 23 1,563 1933-34 405 3 408 28 1,458 1934-35 368 10 378 26 1,453

1935-36 429 -7 422 30 1,406 1936-37 495 -4 492 35 1,404 1937-38 499 0 499 31 1,609 1938-39 444 . -6 438 29 1,512 1939-40 493 17 510 33 . 1,546

1940-41 451 9 460 34 1,352 1941-42 507 6 513 35 1,466 1942-43 597 5 602 41 1,468 1943-44 631 -1 630 44 1,432 1944-45 600 -43 557 45 1,237

1945-46 662 -32 631 50 1,261 1946-47 743 -14 729 59 1,236 1947-48 1,168 37 1,205 78 1,544 1948-49 l,2ll 34 1,245 82 r 1,518 1949-50 1,571 36 1,607 100 1,607

1950-51 2,375 50 2,425 160 1,515 1951-52 1,920 -10 1,910 130 1,469 1952-53 2,326 54 2,380 139 1,712 1953-54 2,301 45 2,346 136 1,725 1954-55 2,209 34 2,243 127 1,766

1955-56 2,315 78 2,393 126 1,899 1956-57 2,549 ll8 2,667 137 1,947 1957-58 2,258 -26 2,232 123 . 1,815

1958-59 2,523 -ll 2,512 117 2,147 1959-60 2,656 29 2,685 128 2,098

1960-61 2,745 25 2,770 129 2,147 1961-62. 2,734 63 2,797 124 2,256 1962-63 2,990 27 3,017 127 2,375

1963-64 3,399 70 3,469 139 2,495

1964-65 3,422 29 3,451 132 2,614

1965-66 3,316 -131 3,185 136 2,342

1966-67 3,825 64 3,889 137 2,839

1967-68 3,342 64 3,406 130 2,620

1968-69 ·3,947 116 4,063 130 3,125

1969-70 3,790 109 3,899 121 ·3,070

a The series for 1920-21 to 1938-39 is derived from Butlin [4], for 1939-40 to 1947-48 from the Value of Production. Bulletin [2l and for 1948-49 to 1969-70 from the A.N.A. [1].

b From Appendix 6B. c Derived from the Value of Production Bulletin [2].

Page 53: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-336-APPEmlU 8B

NON-FACTOR EXPENSES IN AUSTRALIAN AGRICULTURE 1920-21 TO 1969-70

Gross Non-Factorb Ratio N.F.E. Non-Factor

Year Outputa Expenses N.F.E./G.O. Price Expenses (G.O.) (N.F.E.) Index c 1949-50 prices $m $m $m

1920-21 463 .124 0.27 55 225 1921-22 379 109 0.29 49 222 1922-23 434 120 0.28 47 255 1923-24 447 121 0.27 46 263

.1924-25 535 148 0.28 46 322 1925-26 465 153 0.33 46 333 1926-27 492 163 0.33 48 340 1927-28 489 166 0.34 48 346 1928-29 491 173 0.35 48 360 1929-30 402 135 0.34 50 270 1930-31 341 122 0.36 50 244 1931-32 340 108 0.32 47 230 1932-33 352 108 0.31 47 230 1933-34 405 107 0.26 46 233 1934-35 368 99 0.27 46 215. 1935-36 429 107 0.25 46 233 1936-37 495 118 0.24 48 246 1937-38 499 134 0.27 48 279 1938-39 444 132 0.30 49 269 1939-40 493 131 0.27 55 238

1940-41 451 138 0.31 58 238 1941-42 507 150 0~30 61 246 1942-43 597 169 0.28 66 256 1943-44 631 180 0.29 67 269 1944-45 600 188 0.31 68 276

1945-46 662 201 0.30 72 279 1946-47 743 261 0.35 74 353 1947-48 1,168 320 0.27 80 400 1948-49 1,211 410 0.34 90 456 1949-50 1,571 457 0.29 100 457

1950-51 2,375 540 0.23 122 443 1951-52 1.920 665 0.35 158 421 1952-53 2,326 779 0.33 166 469 1953-54 2,301 834 0.36 168 496 1954-55 2,209 818 0.37 170 481

1955-56 2,315 859 0.37 172 499 1956-57 2,549 900 0.35 182 495 1957-58 2,258 972 0.43 190 512 1958-59 2,523 978 0.39 188 520 1959-60 2,656 1,045 0.39 192 544

1960-61 2,745 1,110 0.40 198 561 1961-62 2,734 1,158 0.42 200 579 1962-63 2,990 1,206 0.40 202 597 1963-64 3,399 1,263 0.37 202 625 1964-65 3,422 1,353 0.40 208 650

1965-66 3,316 1,475 0.44 218 677 1966-67 3,825 1,580 0.41 228 693 1967-68 3,342 1,589 0.48 236 673 1968-69 3,947 1,721 0.44 240 717 1969-70 3,790 1,728 0.46 242 714

a Gross Output excluding livestock inventory change in current prices - see Appendix 8A.

b Series for 1920-21 to 1938-39 from But1in [4], 1939-40 to 1947-48 interpolated, 1948-49 to 1969-70 from the A.N.A. [1]. The A.N.A. estimates for 1948-49 to 1958-59 adjusted by deducting net rent, interest and royalties paid by primary industry.

c For 1920-21 to 1943-44, this is the index of improvements from Appendix SF, and for 1944-45 to 1969-70, B.A.E. Prices Paid Index [3].

Page 54: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-337-APPENDIX 8C

FACTOR OUTPUT OF AUSTRALIAN AGRICULTURE 1920-21 TO 1969-70a

Year Grossb Non-Factor Depreciation d Factor Output Expenses c Output

$m $m $m $m

1920-21 980 253 69 658 1921-22 1,146 311 101 733 1922-23 1,037 295 90 651 1923-24 984 275 90 619 1924-25 1,235 329 95 811

1925-26 1,158 364 109 685 1926-27 1,179 408 122 650 1927-28 1,103 386 119 598 1928-29 1,258 444 143 671 1929-30 1,182 397 170 616

1930-31 1,362 469 223 668 1931-32 1,384 432 220 732 1932-33 1,563 470 229 865 1933-34 1,458 382 184 893 1934-35 1,453 381 195 878

1935-36 1,406 357 169 880 1936-37 1,404 337 149 918 1937-38 1,609 432 174 1,003 1938-39 1,512 455 204 853 1939-40 1,546 397 188 961

1940-41 1,352 406 179 767 1941-42 1,466 429 188 849 1942-43 1,468 412 167 889 1943-44 1,432 409 157 866 1944-45 1,237 418 157 662

1945-46 1,261 402 148 711 1946-47 1,236 442 132 662 1947-48 1,544 410 108 1,026 1948-49 1,518 500 115 903 1949-50 1,607 457 106 1,045

1950-51 1,515 338 82 1,096 1951-52 1,469 512 121 836 1952-53 1,712 560 136 1,016 1953-54 1,725 613 152 960 1954-55 1,766 644 184 938

1955-56 1,899 682 198 1,020 1956-57 1,947 657 200 1,089 1957-58 1,815 790 239 786 1958-59 2,147 836 269 1,043 1959-60 2,098 816 260 1,022

1960-61 2,147 860 269 1,017 1961-62 2,256 934 301 1,021 1962-63 2,375 950 309 1,117 1963-64 2,495 909 293 1,294 1964-65 2,614 1,025 335 1,254

1965-66 2,342 1,085 361 897 1966-67 2,839 1,153 382 1,304 1967-68 2,620 1,222 446 952 1968-69 3,125 1,324 481 1,320 1969-70 3,070 1,361 512 1,198

a All series deflated by the Agricultural Price Index (see Appendix 8A) to 1949-50 prices.

b From Appendix 8A. c Fro~ Appendix 8B. d From Appendices 5G and 7E.

Page 55: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-338-

APPENDIX 8 - References

[1] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Australian National Accounts,

Canberra, (various issue~).

[2] AUSTRALIAN BUREAU OF STATISTICS, Value of Production Bulletin,

Canberra. For details of all issues in this series,

see same Reference, Chapter 2.

[3] BUREAU OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS, Indices of Prices Paid,

Canberra, (mimeo).

[4] BUTLIN, N.G., Australian Domestic Product, Investment and

Foreign Borrowing, 1861-1938/39. Cambridge Univ. Press,

1962.

Page 56: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-339-APPENDIX 9A

CAPITAL IN AUSTRALIAN AGRICULTURE. 1920-21 TO 1969-70

(stock values. 1949-50 prices)

Year Landa Improvements a Livestockb Plant andc Total

$m $m $m Mach1nery Capital $m $m

1920-21 1.042 1.371 1.028 124 3.565 1921-22 1.042 1.453 1.090 133 3.718 1922-23 11'038 1.576 1.068 146 3.828 1923-24 1,052 1.811 1.037 159 4.059 1924-25 1,029 2.069 1.083 175 4.356

1925-26 1.048 2,367 1,134 189 4,738 1926-27 1,058 2,632 1,083 208 4,981 1927-28 1,100 2,753 1,049 228 5,130 1928-29 1,095 3,023 1,049 237 5,404 1929-30 1,103 3,079 1,048 239 5,469

1930-31 1,085 3,188 1,098 226 5,597 1931-32 1,120 2.982 1,122 216 5,440 1932-33 1,123 2,917 1,155 209 5,404 1933-34 1,123 2,858 1.167 209 5,357 1934-35 1,124 2,823 1.205 204 5.356

1935-36 1,097 2,843 1,182 218 5,340 1936-37 1,108 2,898 1,171 231 5,408 1937-38 1,129 2,857 1,170 251 5,407 1938-39 1,149 3,153 1,151 271 5,724 1939-40 1,152 3,118 1,203 280 5,753

1940-41 1,132 2,859 1,229 284 5,504 1941-42 1,124 2,968 1,246 290 5,628 1942-43 1,128 2,841 1.258 300 5.527 1943-44 1,134 2,700 1,256 309 5,399 1944-45 1,136 2,557 1,160 325 5.178

1945-46 1,130 2,508 1,097 351 5,086 1946-47 1,136 2,506 1,074 365 5,081 1947-48 1,148 2,440 1,121 381 5,090 1948-49 1,147 2,500 1,162 402 5,211 1949-50 1,155 2,546 1,198 436 '5,335

1950-51 1,168 2,631 1,229 504 5,532 1951-52 1,200 2,434 1,222 572 5,428 1952-53 1,213 2,481 1,261 654 5,609 1953-54 1,225 2,505 1,294 688 5,712 1954-55 1,238 2,649 1,321 744 5,952

1955-56 1,252 2,528 1,383 798 5,961 1956-57 1,266 2,706 1,469 831 6.272 1957-58 1,269 2,788 1,448 849 6,354 1958-59 1,277 2,835 1,439 875 6,426 1959-60 1,285 3,025 1,462 885 6,657

1960-61 1,304 3,093 1,481 912 6.790 1961-62 1,314 3,369 1,531 936 7,150 1962-63 1,325 3,614 1,552 944 7,435 1963-64 1,341 3,769 1,602 968 7,680 1964-65 1,368 4,025 1,624 1,038 8,055

1965-66 1,377 4,408 1,528 1,121 8,434 1966-67 1,390 4,681 1,575 1,152 8,798 1967-68 1,409 5,263 1,624 1,190 9.486 1968-69 1,413 5,577 1,713 1,225 9,928 1969-70 1,421 5,644 1,799 1,261 10,125

a From Chapter 5. b From Chapter 6. c From Chapter 7.

Page 57: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

Year

1920-21 1921-22 1922-23 1923-24 1924-25

1925-26 1926-27 1927-28 1928-29 1929-30

1930-31 1931-32 1932-33 1933-34 1934-35

1935-36 1936-37 1937-38 1938-39 1939-40

1940-41 1941-42 1942-43 1943-44 1944-45

1945-46 1946-47 1947-48 1948-49 1949-50

1950-51 1951-52 1952-53 1953-54 '1954-55

1955-56 1956-57 1957-58 1958-59 1959-60

1960-61 1961-62 1962-63 1963-64 1964-65

1965-66 1966-67 1967-68 1968-69 1969-70

-340-

APPENDIX 9B

CAPITAL IN AUSTRALIAN AGRICULTURE, 1920-21 TO 1969-70,

(current prices.)

Unimproved Improvements Livestock Plant Land to Land and

$m $m $m Machinery $m

974 809 504 93 1,016 872 382 92 1,069 930 438 91 1,105 996 456 97 1,131 1,076 487 103

1,179 1,160 476 110 1,198 1,237 433 116 1,226 1,294 451 125 1,249 1,421 409 133 1,255 1,478 356 134

1.182 1,530 285 122 1.153 1.461 281 112 1.097 1.400 266 107 1,093 1,372 327 102 1.089 1.355 313 100

1.072 1,336 355 107 1.070 1,362 410 113 1.053 1,343 363 136 1.097 1.482 334 146 1,106 1.528 397 162

1.067 1.458 418 173 1.103 1.573 436 186 1.108 1.591 516 207 1.100 1.593 553 213 1.104 1,611 522 224

1.102 1.655 549 242 1.111 1.704 634 266 1.131 1.757 874 316 1.115 1.900 953 370 1.145 2.062 1.198 436

1.232 2.394 1.966 600 1.291 2,556 1.589 812 1.460 2.952 1.753 1.007 1.554 3.307 1.760 1.073 1.718 3.815 1.678 1.190

1.774 3.919 1.743 1.317 2.013 4.411 2.013 1.421 2.066 4,601 1.781 1.554 2.145 4.763 1.684 1,715 2.266 5.172 1.871 1.770

2.531 5,382 1.910 1.860 2.552 5.964 1.898 1.947 2.648 6.433 1.971 1.992 2.854 6.709 2.227 2.062 2.882 7.205 2.144 2.263

3.253 7.979 2.078 2.511 3.417 8.566 2.158 2.661 3.760 9.842 2.111 2.844 4.159 10.652 2.227 3.063 4.274 10.950 2.285 3.216

Total

$m

2,380 2,362 2,528 2,654 2,797

2,925 2,984 3,096 3,212 3,223

3,119 3.007 2.870 2.894 2.857

2.870 2.955 2.895 3.059 3.193

3.116 3.298 3.422 3.459 3.461

3.548 3,715 4.078 4.338 4.405

6.192 6.248 7.172 7.694 8.401

8.753 9,858

10,002 10.307 11.079

11.683 12.361 13.044 13.852 14.494

15.821 16.802 18.557 20.101 20.725

Page 58: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-341-

APPENDIX 9C

NET INVESTMENT IN THE AUSTRALIAN RURAL SECTOR,

1920-21 to 1969-70, $m, 1949-50 prices

Land - Land- Improve- Plant Total Year Area Public ment to Livestock and Total Excluding

Capital Land Machinery Land

1920-21 -8 8 82 35 9 126 126 1921-22 -10 6 123 63 13 195 199 1922-23 9 5 235 -22 13 240 226 1923-24 -29 6 258 -32 16 219 242 1924-25 9 10 298 46 14 377 358

1925-26 3 7 265 51 19 345 335 1926-27 34 8 121 -51 20 132 90 1927-28 -11 6 270 -34 9 240 245 1928-29 1 7 56 -1 2 65 57 1929-30 -22 4 108 0 -13 77 95

1930-31 34 1 -206 5Q -10 -131 -166 1931-32 3 0 -65 24 -7 -45 -48 1932-33 0 0 -58 33 0 -25 -25 1933-34 -1 2 -35 12 -5 -27 -28 1934-35 -29 2 20 38 14 45 72

1935-36 8 3 55 -24 13 55 44 1936-37 26 4 -41 -10 20 -1 -31 1937-38 7 4 296 -1 20 326 315 1938-39 1 2 -35 -19 9 -42 -45 1939-40 -21 1 -260 52 4 -224 -204

1940-41 -7 -1 109 26 6 133 141 1941-42 7 -3 -127 17 10 -96 -100 1942-43 10 -4 -141 12 9 -114 -120 1943-44 6 -4 -143 -2 16 -127 -129 1944-45 -3 -3 -50 -96 26 -126 -120

1945-46 8 -2 -2 -63 14 -45 -51 1946-47 9 3 -66 -23 16 -61 -73 1947-48 -6 5 60 47 21 127 128 1948-49 3 5 46 41 34 129 121 1949-50 3 10 84 36 68 201 188

19.50-.51 17 1,5 -197 31 68 -66 -98 1951-52 5 8 47 -8 82 134 121 1952-53 3 9 25 39 34 110 98 1953-54 6 7 144 33 56 246 233 1954-55 8 6 -121 27 54 -26 -40

1955-56 9 5 178 62 33 287 273 1956-57 -2 5 82 86 18 189 186 1957-58 5 3 47 -21 26 60 52 1958-59 2 6 189 -9 10 198 190 1959-60 13 6 69 23 27 138 119

1960-61 5 5 276 19 24 329- 319 1961-62 5 6 245 51 8 315 304 1962-63 9 7 155 21 24 216 200 1963-64 17 10 256 50 70 403 376 1964-65 0 9 383 22 8~ 497 488

1965-66 5 8 273 -96 31 221 208 1966-67 10 9 582 47 3R 686 667 1967-68 -1 5 314 49 3.5 402 398 1968-69 0 8 67 89 36 200 192 1969-70 n.a. n.a. n.a. 86 D.a. D.a. D.a.

Page 59: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-342-

APPENDIX 9D

NET INVESTMENT IN THE AUS'IRALIAN RURAL SECTOR,

1920-21 to 1969-70. Sm. current prices

Land - Land - Improve- Plant Total Year Area Public: ments to Livestock and Total Excluding

Capital Land Machinery Land

1920-21 -4 4 46 17 7 70 70 1921-22 -5 3 62. 22 9 91 93 1922-23 4 2 110 -9 8 115 109 1923-24 -13 3 119 -14 10 105 115 1924-25 4 5 137 21 8 175 166

1925-26 1 3 122 21 11 158 154 1926-27 16 4 58 -20 11 69 49 1927-28 -5 3 130 -15 5 118 120 1928-29 0 3 27 0 1 31 28 1929-30 -11 2 54 0 -7 38 47

1930-31 17 1 -103 13 -5 -77 -95 1931-32 1 0 -31 6 -4 -28 -29 1932-33 0 0 -27 8 0 -19 -19 1933-34 0 1 -16 3 -2 -14 -15 1934-35 -13 1 9 10 7 14 26

1935-36 4 • 1 25 -7 6 29 24 1936-37 12 2 -20 -4 10 0 -14 1937-38 3 2 142 0 11 158 153 1938-39 0 1 -17 -6 5 -17 -18 1939-40 -12 1 -143 17 2 -135 -124

1940-41 -4 -1 63 9 4 71 76 1941-42 4 -2 -77 6 6 -63 -65 1942-43 7 -3 -93 5 6 -78 -82 1943-44 4 -3 -96 -1 11 -85 -86 1944-45 -2 -2 -34 -43 18 -63 -59

1945-46 6 -1 -1 -32 10 -18 -:23 1946-47 7 2 -50 -14 12 -43 -52 1947-48 -5 4 49 37 17 102 103 1948-49 3 5 41 34 31 114 106 1949-50 3 10 84 36 68 201 188

1950-51 21 19 -248 50 81 -77 -117 1951-52 8 13 75 -10 116 202 181 1952-53 5 14 40 54 52 165 146 1953-54 10 11 229 45 87 382 361 1954-55 13 10 -194 34 86 -51 -74

1955-56 15 8 292 78 54 447 424 1956-57 -3 9 142 118 31 297 291 1957-58 9 5 83 -26 48 119 105 1958-59 4 11 331 -11 20 355 340 1959-60 23 11 122 29 54 239 205

1960-61 9 9 497 25 49 589 571 1961-62 9 11 441 63 17 541 521 1962-63 16 13 277 27 51 384 355 1963-64 30 18 458 70 149 725 677

1964-65 0 16 686 29 181 912 896

1965-66 9 15 511 -131 69 473 4&9

1966-67 20 18 1.135 64 88 1.32.5 1.287 1967-68 -2 10 628 64 84 784 776

1968-69 0 16 136 116 9(1 358 342

1969-70 n.a. n.a. n.a. 109 n.a. n.a. n.a.

Page 60: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-343-APPENDIX 9E

GROSS INVESTMENT IN THE AUSTRALIAN RURAL SECTOR

1920-21 to 1969-70, $m, 1949-50 prices

Year Unimproved Improvements Livestock Plant Total Improvements Land to Land and and Plant

Machinery

1920-21 0 123 35 21 179 144 1921-22 -4 167 63 26 252 193 1922-23 14 282 -22 28 302 310 1923-24 -23 312 -32 32 289 344 1924-25 19 360 46 31 456 391

1925-26 10 336 51 38 435 374 1926-27 42 200 -51 41 232 241 1927-28 -5 353 -34 33 347 386 1928-29 8 147 -1 25 179 172 1929-30 -18 200 0 10 292 210

1930-31 35 -110 50 12 -13 -98 1931-32 3 24 24 14 65 38 1932-33 0 29 33 22 84 51 1933-34 1 51 12 15 79 66 1934-35 -27 105 38 34 150 139

1935-36 11 140 -24 35 152 175 1936-37 21 46 -10 42 99 88 1937-38 20 382 -1 46 447 428 1938-39 3 60 -19 37 81 97 1939-40 -20 -166 52 32 230 198

1940-41 -8 195 26 34 247 229 1941-42 4 -38 17 40 23 2 1942-43 6 -56 12 39 ~ 1 -17 1943-44 2 -62 -2 46 -16 -16 1944-45 -6 27 -96 48 -25 75

1945-46 6 73 -63 49 65 122 1946-47 12 9 -23 53 51 62 1947-48 -1 133 47 60 229 193 1948-49 8 121 41 74 244 195 1949-50 13 160 36 112 321 272

1950-51 32 -118 31 118 63 0 1951-52 13 120 -8 139 264 259 1952-53 12 99 39 100 250 199 1953-54 13 219 33 125 390 344 1954-55 14 -42 27 128 127 86

1955-56 14 254 62 113 443 367 1956-57 3 163 86 101 356 264 1957-58 8 131 -21 III 229 242 1958-59 8 274 -9 97 370 371 1959-60 19 159 23 116 317 275

1960-61 10 369 19 115 513 484 1961-62 11 346 51 102 510 448 1962-63 16 263 21 118 418 381 1963-64 27 369 50 167 613 536 1964-65 9 504 22 187 722 691

1965-66 13 405 -96 143 465 548 1966-67 19 722 47 153 941 875 1967-68 4 472 49 154 679 626 1968-69 8 234 89 158 489 392 1969-70 na ne 86 na na na

Page 61: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-344-APPENDIX 91

GROSS INVESTMENT IN THE AUSTRALIAN RURAL SECTOR

1920-21 to 1969-70, $m, current prices

Year Unimproved Improvements Livestock Plant Total Improvements Land to Land and and Plant

Machinery

1920-21 0 70 17 16 103 86 1921-22 -2 88 22 18 126 106 1922-23 7 138 -9 17 153 155 1923-24 -11 149 -14 20 144 169 1924-25 9 169 21 18 217 187 1925-26 5 157 21 22 205 179 1926-27 20 95 -20 23 118 118 1927-28 2 169 -15 18 174 187 1928-29 4 70 0 14 88 84 1929-30 -9 98 0 6 95 104

1930-31 18 -57 13 7 -19 -50 1931-32 2 13 6 7 28 20 1932-33 0 15 8 11 34 26 1933-34 1 25 3 8 37 33 1934-35 -12 50 10 17 65 67

1935-36 5 65 -7 17 80 82 1936-37 10 21 -4 21 48 42 1937-38 10 182 0 25 217 207 1938-39 2 28 -6 20 44 48 1939-40 -11 -97 17 18 -73 -79

1940-41 -5 107 9 21 132 128 1941-42 2 -30 6 25 3 -5 1942-43 4 -45 5 27 -9 -18 1943-44 1 -48 -1 32 -16 -16 1944-45 -4 14 -43 40 7 54

1945-46 4 49 -32 34 55 83 1946-47 9 1 -14 39 35 40 1947-48 -1 102 37 49 187 151 1948-49 7 98 34 68 207 166 1949-50 13 146 36 112 307 258

1950-51 40 -176 50 141 55 -35 1951-52 21 152 -10 197 360 349 1952-53 19 129 54 153 355 282 1953-54 21 328 45 194 588 522 1954-55 22 -79 34 205 182 126

1955-56 23 410 78 186 697 596 1956-57 5 274 118 173 570 447 1957-58 14 221 -26 203 412 424 1958-59 14 474 -11 191 668 665 1959-60 33 271 29 231 570 508

1960-61 18 659 25 235 937 894 1961-62 20 620 63 212 915 832 1962-63 29 470 27 250 716 720 1963-64 48 659 70 355 1,132 1,014 1964-65 16 902 29 407 1,354 1,309

1965-66 24 750 -131 320 963 1,070 1966-67 37 1,392 64 354 1,847 1,746 1967-68 8 923 64 368 1,363 1,291 1968-69 16 456 116 396 984 852 1969-70 na na 109 na na na

Page 62: PART IV - rune.une.edu.au

-345-

APPENDU 9G

ON-FARM CAPITAL PBODUCTION. 1920-21 TO 1969-70. $m.

Year Gross Capital On-Farm Produc~ion Investmenta b Expenditure of capital

(1) (2)

1920-21 86 27 59 105 1921-22 106 30 76 152 1922-23 155 28 127 270 1923-24 169 33 136 296 1924-25 187 30 157 341

1925-26 179 37 142 309 1926-27 118 38 80 167 1927-28 187 30 157 327 1928-29 84 23 61 127 1929-30 104 10 94 188

1930-31 -50 12 -62 -124 1931-32 20 12 8 17 1932-33 26 18 8 17 1933-34 33 13 20 43 1934-35 67 28 39 85

1935-36 82 28 54 117 1936-37 42 35 7 15 1937-38 207 42 165 344 1938-39 48 33 15 31 1939-40 -79 30 -109 -198

1940-41 128 35 93 160 1941-42 -5 42 -47 -77 1942-43 -18 45 -63 -95 1943-44 -16 53 -69 -103 1944-45 54 67 -13 -19

1945-46 83 57 26 36 1946-47 40 65 -25 -33 1947-48 151 82 69 85 1948-49 166 117 49 54 1949-50 258 176 82 82

1950-51 -35 241 -276 -219 1951-52 349 303 46 29 1952-53 282 254 28 18 1953-54 522 299 223 140 1954-55 126 304 -178 -Ill

1955-56 596 303 293 179 1956-57 447 317 130 75 1957-58 424 322 102 58 1958-59 665 316 349 199 1959-60 508 348 160 90

1960-61 894 369 525 292

1961-62 832 346 486 270

1962-63 720 395 325 182

1963-64 1.014 516 498 278

1964-65 1.309 517 792 442

1965-66 1.070 469 601 321

1966-67 1.746 560 1.186 608

1967-68 1,291 541 750 375

1968-69 852 583 269 133

1969-70 n.a. Sl1 n.a. n.a.

a In current prices, from Appendilt 9F, excluding land and livestock.

b In current prices, for years 1920-21 to 1947-48, gross investment in plant and machinery / 0.6, 1948-49 to 1969-70, gross fixed capital expenditure by primary industry, from A.B.S., Australian National Accounts, canberra.

c GroSs Investment less Capital Expenditure, (ll in current prices, (2) in 1949-50 prices, deflated by improvements price index.


Recommended