+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State...

Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State...

Date post: 24-Dec-2015
Category:
Upload: richard-carroll
View: 213 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
Popular Tags:
40
Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University
Transcript
Page 1: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development

Can they help?

John M. Crespi

Kansas State University

Page 2: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

The issue is whether producers -- either in a region or using a distinctive production process -- can collectively “brand” themselves to increase profits.

Goal for this session is to discuss what the economic theory says about this type of collective product differentiation.

Page 3: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Handouts (shameless promotion)

Two papers written by myself and Stephan Marette.

Can Quality Certification Lead to Stable Cartels?

Eco-Labelling Economics: Is Public Involvement Necessary?

aside: the answers are, respectively, “Yes” and “Occasionally”.

Page 4: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Appellations

I am being loose with the term. Any mark or label that is used by a

producer association to differentiate a product based upon region and/or regional production process.

A mark of product differentiation that differs from a brand because it is not owned by any one firm.

Page 5: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Protected Geographic Indicators/Protected Designation of Origins

Legally different from “Appellations” (which is used mostly for wines) but same idea.

Very popular in Europe Very contentious for exporters

seeking European markets. This month Colombian coffee

growers became the first non-EU group to seek a protected food name in Europe.

Page 6: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Labels & Appellations

Page 7: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Examples.

Appellation: Medoc

Parma

Page 8: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Do these labels improve profits?

What does economic theory say?

Page 9: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Background: Experience vs. Credence Claims “Tastes” are experience claims. Easily verified

after purchasing. “Sweet & Juicy”, “Tender”, “Spicy”, “An Approachable

Little Pinot with a soupcon of Camembert and Mushroom”, etc.

Credence claims are harder for a consumer to verify either before or after purchasing: “Organically grown”, “Alexander Valley”, “Contains no

GMOs”, “I-80 Beef”, “Highly Regarded Economist”, etc.

Page 10: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Moral Hazard Issue with Credence Labels If consumers cannot check the claim, anyone

can make it: high-quality good will not emerge on the market.

Relatedly with appellations, if consumers are uncertain what the claim means, any firm can try to make a similar claim: Kraft Parmesan vs. true Parmesan cheese.

Premia will dissipate as consumer uncertainty grows.

Page 11: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Appellation Characteristics are often Credence Goods Although there are experience attributes, many claims (Parma’s fresh mountain air) have

to be taken on faith, as such consumers will want some verification

that the product is what it claims to be. The literature on credence goods shows that

these attributes are often tough—but not impossible—to market.

Page 12: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

The reason credence claims are tough to market are:consumers have to believe the appellation

conveys some premia-necessitating quality,and consumers have to believe the

appellation (hence, the claim) is credible.

Page 13: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Issues emanating from cartels exist here, too. Obviously we’re talking about some type of cartel for

producer quality or regional restrictions. Issues... Antitrust issue, though Co-ops, Mktg. Orders, PDI’s etc. provide

legal rationale. Cartel stability: can price be maintained and if not, is deviation a

worry? Relatedly, if the label is profitable what prevents new producers

from entering and eroding premia. If the cartel pays the cost, can free-riding by similar-sounding

appellations or claims erode premia? Worry is over keeping the cartel distinct, stable and profitable.

Page 14: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Quality Signaling and Cartel Stability Much has been written on why cartels break down. Little has been written about cartels formed for purpose

of signaling some quality differentiation. Theory shows that cartels that differentiate themselves

via quality signals can circumvent cartel breakdowns and can also...

Improve overall welfare. Thus cartels for appellations – if consumers truly desire

the good – may be in both producers’ and societies’ best interest. Marette & Crespi

Page 15: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Why don’t more products with appellations exist in the U.S.?Is this a feature of credence goods?

Page 16: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Claim: If it were profitable it would already exist. “The fact that no major supermarket

company has joined the voluntary program... tells you all you need to know about whether this program is a good idea or not.”

Tim Hammonds, President Food Marketing Institute, on country-of-origin labeling.

Page 17: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Claim: If it were profitable it would already exist.In the case of credence characteristics, in my opinion, this claim is mostly a myth for 3 reasons.

Page 18: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Claim: If it were profitable it would already exist. Reason #1 this is a myth. The logistics of modern commodity

agriculture with its commingling and bulk handling are great for cost efficiencies but lousy for relating consumer signals back to producers.

Hayes & Lence Doubly true with respect to consumer demand for credence

attributes. The innovation of the organics movement had to begin outside the

typical ag. marketing channels. Now, that organic is established and profitable the major agbus players

are getting involved and will take it to the next level: ConAgra, General Mills, Gallo Wine*, Heinz, Phillip Morris-Kraft, M&M Mars, Coca-Cola.

see also Barkley

Page 19: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Claim: If it were profitable it would already exist. Reason #2 this is a Myth. Market power affects firm

decisions on both the quality content and the signaling of that quality. Competitive firms address quality desires of “average”

consumers. Monopolies address quality desires of “marginal” consumers. Marginal consumer’s desire for quality could be higher or lower

than average consumer, but are likely not the same. Market power will have an effect on product quality. Market power will have an effect on how firms signal that quality

and, thus, how producer associations signal that quality. Nicholson; Marette & Crespi; Mooman, Du & Mela

Page 20: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Claim: If it were profitable it would already exist. Reason #3 this is a Myth. Market failure occurs

when consumers are uncertain about the attribute. In the case of uncertainty about an attribute,

consumers’ WTP is hedged downward, and will send an inaccurate signal of consumer desires.

Result, firms willing to provide the credence attribute will not be able to adequately signal its presence and attribute may not emerge in the market.

Akerlof; Salop; Stiglitz.

Page 21: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Signaling credence attributes. What does the literature say?The literature shows that the most important feature of profitable credence labeling is an accurate, understandable, and verifiable signal.

Page 22: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Accurate & Understandable Signals

Page 23: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Literature on Appellations’ Effectiveness? Not much, but there is a large literature on

effectiveness and consumer response to other types of voluntary and mandatory labels. Nutrition Facts

Serving Size 1/2 cup (114g) Serving Per Container 4

Amount Per Serving

Calories 90 Calories from Fat 30

Total Fat 3g 5%

Saturated Fat 0g 0%

Cholesterol 0mg 0%

Sodium 300mg 13%

Total Carbohydrate 13g 4%

Dietary Fiber 3g 12%

Sugars 3g

Protein 3g Vitamin A 80% Vitamin C 60%

Calcium 4% Iron 4%

* Percent Daily Values are based on a 2,000 calorie diet. Your daily values may be higher or lower depending on your calorie needs: Calories 2,000 2,500

Total Fat Less Than 65g 80g

Sat Fat Less Than 20g 25g

Cholesterol Less Than 300mg 300mg

Sodium Less Than 2,400mg 2,400mg

Total Carbohydrate 300g 375g

Fiber 25g 30g Calories per gram:

Fat 9 Carbohydrate 4

Protein 4

Page 24: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Issue of effective labeling comes down to Credence Issues. With credence claims, surveys and

literature show that outside verification is a must.

For credence attributes, consumers do not trust the firm itself.Aside, European consumers generally don’t

trust gov’t labels, but U.S. consumers do. Crespi & Marette, Teisl & Roe, Priest et al.

Page 25: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Does the label mean anything?

Credibility is just one issue. Another is whether the attribute itself is more than just fluff: does the label really mean anything? “Sustainable” ~ meaningless “Bird Friendly” ~ meaningless “Shade Grown” ~ meaningful (but few people know what it is). “Organic” ~ meaningful “Cruelty Free” ~ meaningless “Grass Fed” ~ meaningless “Grass Fed Only” ~ meaningful “Natural” ~ ???

Page 26: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Does the label mean anything?

Meaning gets trickier with regional and production appellations.

For regional labels (e.g. Napa, Sonoma, or Calaveras wine), the label’s meaning is only as important as what the producers of that region are able to promote or what outside agents are able to verify.

Exs. To many, Parma is a strong signal for ham; Vidalia for onions, Napa for wine.

But, what about Stockton for asparagus? Iowa for beef?. Big bonus to Iowa beef is that Japanese wholesalers already ask

for “I-80 beef”. So the signal is already there. – See Hayes & Lence

Page 27: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

What makes a label a success?

Common themes emerge in the literature. Label is Standardized Claim is Verifiable Claim is Accurate Meaning is Succinct Label is Legible Consumer Education

Think about the US nutrition label, for example.

Page 28: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Too many labels

Label proliferation is as mind-numbing as too much noise.

Page 29: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Label Proliferation : NOISE.

Label proliferation occurs when a consumer is inundated with too many labels.

Ex. Big problem in Europe with regional appellations on wine. There are so many regional appellations (450!) for

moderately priced French wines, that the appellations have become mostly meaningless to consumers.

Not surprisingly moderately priced French wines are losing market share to Californian, Australian and Chilean brands.

Page 30: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Label Proliferation

“Three quarters of all wine produced in Europe now bears a specific geographic reference. The more this happens, the more devalued it becomes, and the less consumers want to pay for it.... We wanted to use AOC to help differentiate our offering in the New World, but now they have it too.”

Patrick Aigrain, wine economist, April 26, 2005

Page 31: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Conflicting Messages

Label proliferation can also add to confusion when consumers must choose among competing claims.

Ex. The use of “GMOs” can be “Environmentally Sound” and “Sustainable” but in the U.S. cannot be “Organic” which to many consumers means “GMO” must be environmentally unsound leading them to pass on GMO in favor of “Natural” or “Earth Friendly” both of which can sometimes be neither “Environmentally Sound” nor “Sustainable”. HUH?

Confounding messages lead to reduced premia. Loureiro et al.; Tesil & Roe

Page 32: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Beware Eco-Labels!!!

Of all labels studied by economists thus far, eco labels seem most prone to label confusion. Ex. “Shade grown,” “Bird Friendly,” “California Clean.”

Practical impact is that if producers tie their appellation strictly to environmental friendliness, premia may be short lived because such claims are: too easy to duplicate, and too easy to obfuscate.

Page 33: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Piggybacking Helps.

Regional/Producer appellations with little consumer identification are helped if they piggyback on another label that consumers know better

In other words, “Don’t go it alone.” Ex. 1 - Producer groups in France who have added their appellation to

the popular “Label Rouge” program for quality obtain higher premia than those groups who use only the regional appellation label.

Recent INRA study. Ex. 2 - Teisl & Roe find that adding the USDA’s organic logo to and eco-

labeled product significantly increases premium. As the “USDA Organic” or “Certified Angus Beef” labels become

better known for standardized quality, U.S. producer groups with regional appellations may be wise to piggyback on them.

Page 34: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Our Survey Says...

The economic literature on consumer preferences for food attributes shows that surveys can provide guidance on preferences but little guidance on WTP.

Ex. Consumers will say, “Yes, I’d pay a lot more for that...” but when given the chance, pay a lot less... or nothing.

While surveys often show large premia, typical revealed premia are much less: in the neighborhood of 3-5%. See surveys in Crespi & Marette, Lusk et al, Henneberry &

Armbruster.

Page 35: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

How easy is it to duplicate a product? Easy for a Taste/Hard for a Region.

Alexander Valley, Napa Valley, Iowa Beef, Parma Ham, Vidalia Onions, Washington Apples (though Wash Apples, don’t get a premium anymore).

Premia can exist and remain for products that are first in the minds of consumers. Not logical, but often true.

“Why buy ‘the NEXT Taco Bell’ when I can buy ‘Taco Bell’?”-Lynch Premia on products that have generic substitutes shows this to

be true for many brands. Even if substitutes are perfect: Bayer gets a premium over

chemically identical generic aspirin.

Page 36: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Controlling Quality may be Easier than Controlling Production or Number of Producers If profits go up, how will producers keep newcomers out? With regional appellations, this may be possible if there

is a limit on available land. With production methods, this is much harder, though

not impossible (see Dermot’s work on this). Marketing orders?

Can control quality and to some extent production in the short run (but not number of producers).

Survey of marketing order market power in Crespi & Sexton shows that markups from “monopoly” control are small.

Page 37: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Room for optimism

Consumer Incomes are Up. Budget Share for Food is Down.

Those are good things for niche markets.More money available for a food budget of

perceived higher quality foods. Anecdote #1. Organic is fastest growing segment of

retail food market (organic + natural = $48 Billion). Anecdote #2. Whole Foods is building new

supermarkets while Safeway is closing supermarkets.

Page 38: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Grocery-store chains such as Safeway Inc., Albertsons Inc. and Fred Meyer's owner, The Kroger Co., grew into national forces over the past century by marketing to the masses.

But the giants are losing their grip.

Shoppers have locked into new habits, rolling their carts into an ever wider array of food stores at either side of the retailing spectrum. At one end, they steer toward lower prices at big-box discounters: Costco Warehouse, WinCo Foods, Wal-Mart Supercenter, SuperTarget. At the other, they search out upscale and organic offerings at specialty stores, from Portland-based Zupan's Markets and New Seasons Market to national chains --Trader Joe's and Whole Foods Markets.

The Oregonian, June 12, 2005

Page 39: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

Room for optimism...

Don’t need to be Pepsi, just need to have a defensible niche. Whole Foods Market (Mkt. Cap.=$7.7B) and Wild

Oats Market (Mkt. Cap.=$325M) actively source local/regional foods when they open new stores.

Studies of promotion checkoffs (for the most part) show joint producer promotions can raise industry revenues. See Kaiser, Alston, Crespi & Sexton.

Page 40: Regional & Production Appellations for Rural Development Can they help? John M. Crespi Kansas State University.

So, what does the literature suggest about the link between appellations & income?

Does the absence of an appellation mean that a market does not exist? Not necessarily. The key is whether or not the

attribute is a credence one or not. Can an appellation increase profit?

Yes. Will it increase profit?

??? Big issues are quality perception, credibility of the

claim, label proliferation and noise.


Recommended