+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to...

Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to...

Date post: 19-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
39
DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage Mandates Using New Public and Administrative Data: Evidence for New York City IZA DP No. 7113 December 2012 David Neumark Matthew Thompson Francesco Brindisi Leslie Koyle Clayton Reck
Transcript
Page 1: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

DI

SC

US

SI

ON

P

AP

ER

S

ER

IE

S

Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Study of Labor

Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage Mandates Using New Public and Administrative Data: Evidence for New York City

IZA DP No. 7113

December 2012

David NeumarkMatthew ThompsonFrancesco Brindisi

Leslie KoyleClayton Reck

Page 2: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage Mandates Using

New Public and Administrative Data: Evidence for New York City

David Neumark UCI, NBER and IZA

Matthew Thompson

Charles River Associates

Francesco Brindisi New York City Office of

Management and Budget

Leslie Koyle Charles River Associates

Clayton Reck

Charles River Associates

Discussion Paper No. 7113 December 2012

IZA

P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn

Germany

Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180

E-mail: [email protected]

Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.

Page 3: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

IZA Discussion Paper No. 7113 December 2012

ABSTRACT

Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage Mandates Using New Public and Administrative Data: Evidence for New York City*

Policy researchers often have to estimate the future effect of imposing a policy in a particular location. There is often evidence on the effects of similar policies in other jurisdictions, but no information on the effects of the policy in the jurisdiction in question. And the policy may have specific features not reflected in the experiences of other areas. It is then necessary to combine the evidence from other locations with detailed information and data specific to the jurisdiction in question, with which to simulate the effects of the policy in the new jurisdiction. We illustrate and use this approach in estimating the impact of a proposed living wage mandate for New York City, emphasizing how our ex ante simulations make use of detailed location-specific information on workers, families, and employers using administrative data and other new public data sources. JEL Classification: J23, J38, R51 Keywords: living wage, employment, poverty Corresponding author: David Neumark Department of Economics 3151 Social Science Plaza University of California, Irvine Irvine, CA 92697 USA E-mail: [email protected]

* This paper is drawn from a larger study conducted by Charles River Associates, funded by the New York City Economic Development Corporation (Charles River Associates, 2011). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not reflect the views of Charles River Associates, the City of New York, its Office of Management and Budget, or the New York City Economic Development Corporation. We are grateful to Daniel Hamermesh for many helpful comments and to Marsha Courchane, Timothy Riddiough, and Anthony Yezer for collaboration on the larger project.

Page 4: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

1

I. Introduction

With the advent of the living wage movement in the early 1990s, labor economists and

other policy analysts have often been asked to estimate the future effects of imposing a local

wage mandate in a city. Lacking an historical record, studies for the cities that implemented

living wages early relied on ex ante simulations using some existing data and survey evidence,

coupled with assumptions about the effects of the mandates (e.g., Pollin & Luce, 1998). As

more local governments adopted living wage laws, “before-and-after” (longitudinal) evidence

became available (e.g., Neumark & Adams, 2003), although the experience of other cities may

not capture specific features of a given city’s economic landscape or specifics of a proposed law.

In 2010, a proposal (Intro. 251) was introduced to significantly expand New York City’s

existing very narrow contractor-only living wage law to a broad “business assistance” living

wage law intended to cover firms and real property receiving financial assistance from the City

for economic development. The law would have covered employees, contractors, and sub-

contractors hired by the direct recipients of financial assistance, and tenants and sub-tenants,

establishing a wage floor of $10 per hour, or $11.50 if health insurance was not provided.1

The New York City Economic Development Corporation (NYCEDC) commissioned a

comprehensive study to estimate the effects that Intro. 251 would have on labor and real estate

markets (Charles River Associates, 2011). The estimates are derived from ex ante simulations

specific to New York City, but the parameters used are informed by new longitudinal estimates

for other cities. The longitudinal estimates of the effects of living wages in other cities provide

the best information we have on the actual effects of living wage laws that have been

implemented. At the same time, there are limits to what we can learn about the potential effects

of a living wage law in New York City from studying the experiences of other cities, because the

law proposed for New York City had unique features, and the evidence from before-and-after

Page 5: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

2

analyses for other cities may be less applicable to New York City because it is such a large,

complex, and, in many ways, unique labor market.

Thus, we conducted detailed simulations of the effects of the proposed living wage law

mandate in New York City, using highly detailed data for New York City that captures features

of the labor market and the proposed law in a realistic way. Nonetheless, one needs to make

assumptions about behavioral responses to do the simulation – in particular, for the employment

effect of a living wage mandate – and it seems best to rest such assumptions, where possible, on

estimates from observed changes in behavior.

The simulation analysis presents a number of innovations relative to the earlier ex ante

simulations, based on new data and sources of information, including extensive historical data on

recipients of financial assistance from the city, employer-level data for New York City from the

Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages, and data on place of work and residence, and other

information, from the relatively new American Community Survey. This paper highlights the

simulation analysis and the role these innovations play in the analysis.

Living wages have been and remain a contentious and politically charged topic, and the

reception of this study was no exception.2 Much of the debate focuses on the estimation of the

wage and employment effects of living wages that are central inputs into the simulations. The

purpose of this paper is not to revisit this debate, although many of the estimates presented rely

on the methods that have been subject to debate. Our new longitudinal estimates based on other

cities are not the focus of the paper; readers are referred to Neumark, Thomson, Brindisi, Koyle,

and Reck (2012) for details and an extensive discussion of the debate over these methods.3 The

methods used in the simulations can be applied to other cities, whether using our longitudinal

methods and estimates, or other estimates or assumptions regarding behavioral responses.

Nor is the goal of this paper to argue about the actual effects of proposed legislation that

Page 6: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

3

has been substantially revised and, though subject to ongoing litigation, went into effect at the

end of September 2012. From a research perspective, this would be of little relevance, and

confirmation or rejection of our simulation results ultimately requires ex post observations on the

outcomes we simulate. Rather, the goal of this paper is to present to researchers and

practitioners the comprehensive methods and data sources that, in our view, can and should be

used to evaluate the prospective effects of living wage policies.4 We describe the results of our

analysis along the way, to illustrate and explain our methods, while recognizing that other

researchers, even following our approach, might do things differently and reach different

answers. Regardless, we believe the methods and data we use provide a template for more

thorough and compelling predictions of the effects of living wage mandates, and of related

policies for which the data and methods are appropriate.

II. Simulating the Effects of the Living Wage in New York City

Evaluating the likely effects of New York City’s living wage law required elements of an

ex ante analysis to account for the uniqueness of the city and the proposed legislation. At the

same time, evidence on the effects of living wages in other cities provides the best information

on the actual effects of laws that have been implemented. Thus, we conducted an updated

longitudinal analysis of living wages laws in U.S. cities to estimate the behavioral responses, and

coupled this with rich, new data sources to try to capture as accurately as possible the specific

features of New York City’s labor market. In the next subsection we briefly describe the results

of the longitudinal analysis of other cities, before turning in detail to simulations for New York

City.

Estimated Effects on Low-Wage Workers and Low-Income Families

The estimation of the effects of living wage laws in other cities relies on monthly Current

Population Survey (CPS) files to study workers, and the annual March CPS files to study

Page 7: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

4

families. We use the methods from Adams and Neumark (2005b), updated as far as 2009. There

were a number of complications stemming from changes in the classification of geographic areas

in the CPS. Details are provided in Neumark et al. (2012). That same paper also presents a

lengthy discussion of earlier criticisms of the research using the CPS data to estimate the effects

of living wage laws, concluding that the CPS data and the methods used give valid results.

Regardless, the emphasis in this paper is on how these estimated effects get used in the

simulation study, so researchers or policy analysts can easily substitute their own preferred

estimates, or a range of estimates or assumptions.

The analysis also required information on living wage laws. Cities are the political units

that adopt most living wage laws. We characterized the living wage laws prevailing in a

metropolitan area based on the living wages passed by the major cities in the MSA, which was

also complicated by the changes in geographic classification. We engaged in extensive research

to recover the needed historical information on living wage laws. Using this information, we

coded the wage levels for the major cities in our analysis sample with living wages, for each year

and month from January 1995 through December 2009.5 We also coded whether or not the

living wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors.

This analysis leads to elasticities of wages and employment of low-skilled workers and

individuals with respect to living wages, which we use in the simulation analysis that follows.

The elasticity estimates we use come from the evidence on living wage laws in other cities that

cover employers who receive financial or business assistance from the city, paralleling the

proposed New York City living wage law.6 Our preferred estimated wage elasticity 0.051 (not

statistically significant, but the positive finding is robust across many specifications and samples,

and significant in some). This elasticity applies to workers in the bottom decile of the wage

distribution. However, as explained below, we do not rely explicitly on this wage elasticity in

Page 8: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

5

the simulation, because we have detailed wage data and information on employers targeted by

the proposal, so we can directly estimate the effect of topping covered workers up to the living

wage. The estimated employment elasticity, in contrast, is a key input into the simulation. The

estimated employment elasticity with respect to business assistance living wages that we prefer

based on our analysis is −0.055 (statistically significant at the 5% level). This is estimated for

those in the bottom decile of the predicted wage distribution. Our analysis indicated that the

wage and employment effects of living wages fall on these lowest-skilled workers, and hence

that their effects on the distribution of family incomes stem mainly from the effects of living

wages on the lowest-wage and lowest-skilled workers. As a result, in the simulations for New

York City below, we focus only on effects on the lowest-wage, lowest-skilled workers.7

Past research on living wages in other cities has also studied the effects of living wages

on family income, and in particular the probability that a family is poor. These estimated effects

capture the distribution of wage and employment (and hours) effects on families at different

points of the income distribution. Again, the methods follow Adams and Neumark (2005b), and

details are provided in Neumark et al. (2012). This analysis arrives at a preferred estimated

effect of −0.035, which implies, for example, that a 100% increase in a business assistance living

wage reduces the poverty rate by 3.5 percentage points (again not statistically significant, but

positive across many specifications and samples, and significant in some). However, in the

simulation study we do not apply this elasticity directly, preferring to use the rich information we

have on wages in New York City, coupled with our estimated employment elasticity, to directly

simulate the effects on the family income distribution. Nonetheless, this estimate is useful as a

comparison to our simulation results.

Simulation Study

We establish a baseline for our simulation by providing a detailed description of workers

Page 9: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

6

and families that could be affected by the proposed living wage law, and then project how they

would be affected. We use multiple inputs, including data on New York City workers, families,

and business establishments, estimates of effects of living wage laws that are broadly applicable

to New York City, and information on income-support and other programs available to New

York City residents and how eligibility and benefit levels are determined. The estimates of

behavioral responses to living wage laws, where appropriate, come from the analyses described

briefly above. The other inputs – including the data used for New York City – are described

next.

Data and Measurement

The American Community Survey (ACS) contains detailed information on where people

live and work, and can therefore be used to construct a detailed portrait of the New York City

workforce and the population affected by the proposed living wage law. We also use the ACS to

identify workers based on their wage levels, their industry and borough of employment, their

place of residence, and the characteristics of other members of their families; the latter is used

for simulating the effects on the distribution of family incomes. We use the three-year ACS

sample covering 2006-2008, which collects yearly data re-weighted to yield average values over

the sample period.

To identify workers directly affected by the proposed living wage, we had to identify

covered work sites and obtain information about workers and earnings at these sites. Typically,

tax expenditures for economic development in New York City are tied to construction or

renovation of real estate. Various programs in place exempt the taxation of changes in

properties’ assessed values for a number of years (New York City Department of Finance, 2011;

New York City Economic Development Corporation, 2012). The New York City Department of

Finance provided us with longitudinal data on commercial and residential properties receiving

Page 10: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

7

tax exemptions for Fiscal Years (FY) 1984-2011.8 The living wage proposal included a

minimum financial assistance threshold of $100,000 for mandating living wages. However, it

was not specified how to calculate the threshold (net present value, yearly assistance, etc.); the

analysis was conducted based on buildings that received real property tax exemptions of

$100,000 or more in at least one fiscal year.9 The proposal also required that, once the threshold

was met, the mandates would apply for the life of the financial assistance or 30 years, whichever

was longer.

The information on properties receiving tax exemptions was matched to business

establishments in the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages (QCEW) data for 2006-2008

– confidential data provided to NYCEDC for the analysis.10 The QCEW has information on

average quarterly earnings and number of jobs, by establishment, and on the address of each

establishment, which was geocoded to real properties;11 we matched to sites that ever received

assistance through FY 2011, to provide the most representative snapshot of what kinds of

businesses locate in properties receiving financial assistance. We use the data to estimate the

share of workers potentially affected by the living wage law and the increases in wages that

would be experienced by affected workers, by borough and by industry. We use data on all for-

profit employers at covered sites, since many non-profits were exempted from the proposed law.

We want to estimate how many of the workers at sites that received real property tax

assistance at some point in the period FY 1984-FY 2011 (“covered sites”) would be affected by

the proposed living wage law, and by how much. However, because we have no information

about the distribution of wages within a QCEW establishment, we have to estimate this wage

distribution and hence the share of workers paid less than $10 per hour.12 We first estimate the

percentiles of the wage distribution by industry and borough of employment using the ACS. We

cannot just assume that the ACS wage distribution holds equally at all establishments in the

Page 11: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

8

industry and borough, because wage levels may vary across employers. We therefore use the

QCEW, for each industry and borough, to estimate the wage level for covered establishments.

This, in turn, requires an estimate of average hours worked at establishments, because the

QCEW counts positions (including part-time). We use the ACS data to estimate average hours

by industry and borough of employment and apply this to the QCEW data, by industry and

borough, to estimate average wages. Finally, we compute the percentage difference between the

average ACS hourly wage and the average QCEW wage in the industry and borough, and then

adjust the percentiles of the ACS wage distribution by this amount to arrive at an estimated wage

distribution for employees at covered establishments in each industry and borough.13 We can

then calculate the wage increases needed to bring wages up to $10, and the implied average

percentage wage increase for affected workers and for all workers. This calculation

approximates the change in wages that would actually occur in New York City if those earning

less than $10 at covered sites were brought to that level.

Finally, we incorporated information on a wide range of income-support and other

assistance programs that are provided through federal, state, and city resources to New York City

residents. Many of these programs have eligibility requirements or determinants of benefit levels

based on household characteristics that are not reported in the ACS data, and others provide

benefits that cannot directly be measured in dollar terms (e.g., Home Energy Assistance Program

and NYC Housing Authority Resident Employment Services). Thus, we limited our analysis to

three larger programs – SNAP (formerly food stamps), the EITC (federal, state, and New York

City’s), and Medicaid – for which eligibility and benefit levels can be determined or estimated

from the ACS data. SNAP and EITC benefits can be measured in dollar terms, whereas the

dollar benefits of Medicaid depend on the family’s usage of medical services. We therefore

measure the effect of the proposed living wage in terms of dollars for the SNAP and EITC

Page 12: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

9

programs and in terms of participation for the Medicaid program. Because the ACS data do not

provide detailed information on assistance program participation or with which to predict

participation well, we assume all families that are eligible to participate in a particular program

based on simulated family earnings do participate.

Living Wage Coverage

Our calculations of the percent of employees who would be subject to the living wage

law, and the simulations that follow from them, are based on sites that received real property tax

assistance of $100,000 or more in at least one year. This threshold also happens to be fairly

consistent with living wage laws in other locations, and hence the CPS estimates of the

employment elasticity (and the other CPS estimates we which we compare some of our

simulation results) are roughly speaking applicable to a definition of coverage based on this

criterion. Based on workers employed at sites that received $100,000 in assistance, the estimated

percentage of workers earning less than $10 per hour who would have been subject to the living

wage laws ranges from 9.9% in Brooklyn to 31.3% in Staten Island, and is 12.9% across all

boroughs. There is also considerable variation across industries, from 4% in construction to

24.4% in retail trade. The potential impact of the living wage legislation depends on the

percentage of low-wage workers employed at sites receiving assistance, the number of low-wage

workers in the industry, and wages in the industry.

Simulation Methods

We begin with wages. The QCEW data provide estimates of the share of employment in

each borough and industry at covered sites. For each borough (b, based on place of work) and

industry (i) we denote the share of workers earning less than $10 per hour who are employed at

sites that received assistance in that borough and industry as CEbi, which is the number of

workers earning less than $10 per hour employed at sites receiving assistance in a borough and

Page 13: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

10

industry divided by the total number of workers earning less than $10 per hour in the same

borough and industry.

To simulate the effects of the living wage, we have to assign wage increases to some

workers who earn less than $10 per hour. In the ACS data, we can identify workers employed in

any borough b and industry i who earn less than $10 per hour. Using the estimates of CEbi from

the QCEW data, we apply the living wage to the borough and industry using the following

method. For all workers employed in borough b and industry i, we take those who earn less than

$10 per hour and give them a wage of $10 per hour with probability CEbi, while leaving their

wage unchanged with probability (1 − CEbi). For those who are assigned the living wage rate,

we assume no change in hours or weeks worked. For the purposes of calculating how the living

wage would affect the wage distribution, this “random assignment” is better than just giving

everyone the “expected” increase. Giving everyone the expected increase would lead to badly

estimated distributional effects. This is particularly important when we examine whether a

family is pushed above an income threshold, which can be very different depending on how the

benefits are distributed.

Some individuals in the ACS data have wages below the minimum wage (either due to

measurement error, non-compliance with local minimum wage laws, or inapplicability of the

minimum wage). We assume most individuals who would be subject to the law have an hourly

pay rate at or above the minimum wage, and therefore in the simulations restrict the population

eligible for a wage increase to those who report a wage that is at or above the 2006 minimum

wage that is applicable to New York City workers – $6.75 per hour.14 These restrictions also

reduce measurement error from individuals reporting unusual hours, earnings, and weeks worked

in the ACS. We also exclude self-employed earners.

The ACS data are reported at the individual level, but the individuals are representative

Page 14: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

11

individuals with specific weights based on the number of actual persons in New York City that

they represent. In order to apply wage changes randomly to individuals working in New York

City, we expand the ACS data by creating duplicate records for each individual based on their

household weight. Using this expanded file, we randomly assign the living wage to individuals

earning less than $10 per hour by borough and industry based on the above method. The

household weight was used so that we could aggregate individuals back to a complete household

level (each person in the household receives the same household weight).

The QCEW data capture those who work in New York City without regard to where they

live. However, the ACS data capture place of residence and place of work. Since we are

primarily interested in the effects on residents of New York City, we report the wage and

employment effects for New York City residents. Nonetheless, some of the effects of the living

wage would fall on residents of other cities and states who work in New York City. Below,

these “outflows” are reported separately from the results pertaining to New York City residents

and are labeled “Outside New York City.”

Given that our estimates from the CPS data indicate some probability of job loss, we also

assign job loss to simulate the effects of the proposed living wage law. We tie our projected

employment effects explicitly to the CPS evidence, using the elasticity of −0.055 discussed

earlier, although we do not do this for wages because the CPS results on wages were less precise,

and for New York City the QCEW and ACS data enable us to estimate the wage distribution at

affected firms – something that could not be done with the CPS data. This reflects the tradeoffs

between relying on longitudinal studies of other cities versus ex ante simulations; with regard to

wages, we have more specific information about likely effects on wages in New York City, and

hence use that information.

For most boroughs and industries, a $10 per hour living wage rate is above the 10th

Page 15: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

12

percentile of the wage distribution, implying that the estimated CPS employment effects would

apply only to workers earning less than the living wage. However, we assume that our CPS

employment elasticity to mandated wage increases above the minimum wage for the lower decile

would approximately fall on the workers who, according to the QCEW data, would have their

wages affected by the living wage, hence applying the earlier estimates for workers in each

borough and industry that have wages below $10.15

We calculate the predicted decline in employment among those workers earning below

$10 per hour, given the proposed living wage increase and the estimated employment elasticity.

This yields, overall for the city, a predicted probability of job loss, denoted p. We use the −0.055

employment elasticity described earlier. This elasticity comes from the longitudinal evidence

from other cities, and estimates the effect of increasing the living wage conditional on the other

controls in the regression model. It therefore provides an estimate of what would happen in a

single city where, as mimicked by the regression model, everything else (including possible

underlying trends) remains the same. Applying this elasticity to the increase in the wage floor

from the New York state minimum wage of $6.75 to the $10 living wage that the law would

entail, a 48.1% increase implies an employment decline of 2.65% (0.055 × 0.481 × 100) among

those earning less than $10 per hour.

The job loss presumably occurs among those at covered sites, although we simply apply

this to workers in the ACS earning less than $10 per hour – distributed by industry and borough

based on their estimated wage distributions – because we cannot identify which workers in the

ACS work at covered sites. For each industry and borough we have an estimate of the share of

workers earning less than $10 per hour working at covered sites (CEbi). We want to assign job

loss with higher probability to those who are more likely to be working at a covered site, based

on their industry and borough of employment. To do this, we construct the probability that a

Page 16: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

13

worker earning less than $10 per hour working in borough b and industry i is at a covered site

relative to the probability that any worker earning less than $10 per hour working in the city is at

a covered site (CEcity). We then use a probability of job loss for a worker earning less than $10

per hour in borough b and industry i of p ×{CEbi/CEcity}.

The simulations give us new wages for some workers and different employment statuses

for others. Using these wage and employment changes for individuals, we simulate the effects of

the living wage law on families by calculating how the distribution of family income changes, in

particular relative to the poverty line and one-half the poverty line (“extreme poverty”), using the

poverty threshold for New York City from the New York Center for Economic Opportunity

(2011); we refer to these as “CEO thresholds.”16 One limitation of this kind of simulation study

of the effects of the living wage on family incomes is that we do not know the actual distribution

of those who get wage gains and those who lose jobs across families with different levels of

income (or differences in other characteristics). In contrast, we simulate effects assuming that

these gains and losses from living wages are randomly distributed across potentially affected

workers in proportion to their representation in the data by industry and borough.17

The living wage proposal we studied would apply to new recipients of financial

assistance and to existing recipients in case of renewal or amendment of the original agreements.

We do not know when or if current sites receiving financial assistance would, in the future, be

new recipients as a result of assistance renewal, or when new developments will qualify for and

receive assistance in the future. As a consequence, we know of no reliable way to, for example,

isolate some sites that would be recipients of new financial assistance in the next year, the next

two years, etc. Instead, we assume the effects apply to all covered workers. As a result, the

results should be thought of as long-run effects. Given that most other cities also apply business

assistance provisions of living wage laws to new projects only, and have been implemented at

Page 17: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

14

different times, it is likely that the estimates from the CPS data that we use for the employment

response is intermediate between short-run or long-run effects.

Wage and Employment Effects

The dark bars in Figure 1 show the baseline wage distribution (up to $13.50) for those

living and working in New York City. The vertical distance measures the percentage in each

range relative to all workers living and working in the city. The chart includes all those with

positive wages, but in our simulation only those earning between $6.75 and $10.00 could have

their wages changed by the living wage. The second set of bars (labeled “Implementation of

Living Wage”) shows the wage distribution after simulating the wage effects, with no

employment effects. This bar is below each of the baseline bars less than $10 and then spikes at

$10, with no changes above the proposed living wage, because those who are assigned wage

changes have their wages increased to $10. The last and lightest bars show the distribution of

individuals after simulating the employment effects as well, where those who become

disemployed are assigned a wage of zero. In each instance the third bar is slightly below the

second bar for wages of $10 or less, and these reductions cumulatively add to the small mass in

the $0 wage column, reflecting job loss.

[Figure 1 about here]

To provide some information on the variation in these effects across boroughs, and in an

industry that would likely be strongly affected, Figure 2 reports results for retail by borough.

The figure is limited to those who either received a wage increase (to $10) or experienced a job

loss. The largest impacts appear in Staten Island and the smallest impacts in Manhattan. And of

course the impacts are bigger than those in Figure 1.18

[Figure 2 about here]

Table 1 provides more information on these wage and employment effects. Looking

Page 18: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

15

citywide, the table shows that about 13% of the workforce at covered sites are estimated to earn

less than $10 per hour, and hence would have their wage increased by the living wage. Our

estimates indicate that roughly 33,600 workers would receive wage increases. The average

increase for those who receive the living wage is substantial ($1.67).19 Our simulations imply

that just fewer than 6,000 would lose their jobs.

Relative to the entire workforce, the proposed living wage would impact a little more

than 1.2% of the entire workforce. But this percentage is more than twice as high in the Bronx

(1.6%) than in Manhattan (0.7%), owing to differences in both industry composition and wage

levels. The living wage would have a small impact on average wages of the entire workforce

(0.1% increase), and on overall employment (a 0.2% decrease). These effects vary in a similar

way by borough. Finally, we see that some (approximately 8%) of those receiving the benefit of

the living wage mandate reside outside of New York City, suggesting that “leakage” to non-

residents is not very large.

[Table 1 about here]

Effects on Poverty and Family Income

Table 2 reports on the results of the simulation for whether families are moved over the

thresholds for poverty or extreme poverty. The first column reports the baseline percentages of

families in extreme poverty (top panel) or poverty (bottom panel) for the city overall and each of

the boroughs, and the second column shows the percentages after we simulate the effects of

living wages, assigning the wage increases and employment losses reported in the previous table.

A comparison of these columns shows that the simulated changes in the income distribution in

terms of these two thresholds are small, and they are mixed in terms of direction. As the top

panel of the table shows, overall the percentage of all families classified as “extreme poor”

would slightly increase, by 0.05 percentage point, or 0.5%; this would certainly be viewed as an

Page 19: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

16

unintended adverse consequence of the living wage. However, as the bottom panel shows, the

percent of families below poverty would slightly decrease by 0.02 percentage points, or 0.08%.

The numbers of affected families are correspondingly fairly small. The simulations

indicate that an additional 1,200 families would enter extreme poverty, while about 400 families

would be lifted out of poverty. In other words, some families below the poverty line would be

lifted above it, while others below the poverty line would sink further beneath it, in what is a

rather stark illustration of the fact that a higher living wage, given disemployment effects, creates

both winners – those who get higher wages – and losers – those who lose their jobs. Overall, the

results show that while the number of workers receiving wage increases is considerably higher

than the number of workers experiencing job losses, the aggregate effect on the distribution of

income is negligible. In other words, the simulations suggest that the living wage mandate would

mainly redistribute income from some low-skill workers who lose jobs to other low-skill workers

who earn higher wages.

These simulated impacts on poverty are lower than those experienced on average for

other cities imposing living wage laws, as discussed above with respect to the CPS estimates.

However, the findings are not inconsistent. The poverty thresholds used in the simulations are

those reported by the New York City Center for Economic Opportunity (2011), which are higher

than the federally poverty thresholds used in the CPS estimates. In addition, when we redid the

the simulations without restricting affected workers to those earning at least the 2006 minimum

wage rate, the impacts on poverty look more comparable to those estimated using the CPS data,

even when we apply the NYC CEO poverty thresholds.

[Table 2 about here]

Income-Support and Other Programs

Given that many income-support programs require low family income to qualify, or tie

Page 20: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

17

benefits to income, we might expect the beneficial effects of living wages to be more limited

than the increase in earnings, because rising earnings reduce eligibility for benefits or affect the

amounts for which workers are eligible from social programs such as Medicaid, S-CHIP, Food

Stamps, housing assistance, and the Earned Income Tax Credit decline. The implication is that

families that see earnings rise because of a living wage law would also receive fewer government

benefits. Of course, the effects of job loss go in the opposite direction.

These changes might be of interest to local policymakers. If benefits decline, then to the

extent that these benefits come from the federal (or state) government, there would be less

money coming into a city. As a prime example, the federal Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC)

has grown into the largest program for providing income support to lower-income families

(Blank, 2002). As a consequence, when a worker’s earnings rise, the inflow of federal dollars

via the EITC can decline. On the other hand, the expenses for some benefits paid by the local

government would fall.

Our simulation goes into more detail on how the proposed living wage law would affect

local, state, and federal expenditures on income-support and other programs in New York City.

Program participation and benefit levels are estimated based on the current rules and award

levels. The specific eligibility guidelines and charts showing benefit levels were obtained

through state and federal government websites providing program details.20 Medicaid and EITC

eligibility and benefits are determined based on family income and number of family members.

SNAP eligibility and benefits were also determined based on family size and income and applied

the standard household and shelter deductions. Estimated EITC eligibility and benefit levels are

based solely on family income, family size, and family structure (age of family members), and

implicitly assume families pass the other eligibility requirements for which we have no data. We

calculate family eligibility and benefit levels prior to assigning wage and employment effects,

Page 21: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

18

and then after assigning the simulated effects that we project would result from the living wage

law, to determine how assistance would be impacted.

For Medicaid and SNAP, there is a clear predicted relationship whereby eligibility or

benefits decrease as earnings increase. However, for the EITC, benefits initially rise as earnings

increase over some range, then remain flat, and eventually decrease. So, for families affected by

the living wage EITC benefits may decline or increase depending on family income and the

effects of the living wage.

Table 3 shows the aggregate impacts on eligibility and potential benefit levels for New

York City families when the effects of the proposed living wage are simulated. The simulations

show declines in EITC payments, and in eligibility for and benefits from SNAP, but an increase

in the percentage eligible for Medicaid.21 The changes range from approximately a 0.5%

decrease to a 0.2% increase. Not surprisingly, boroughs with a higher percentage of low-wage

workers covered (e.g., Staten Island) are projected to experience greater changes in eligibility

and benefit levels, and boroughs with a lower percentage of low-wage workers covered (e.g.,

Manhattan) are expected to have smaller changes. With respect to the EITC and SNAP, these

conclusions imply that where a living wage law has the potential to deliver the most benefit

because wages are lower, the earnings gains are likely to be more strongly offset because of

declines in income from or eligibility for government assistance.

[Table 3 about here]

Finally, Table 3 also reports the changes in aggregate earnings and benefit amounts that

are implied by simulating the impact of the living wage. Based on the simulated effects, family

earnings would increase by approximately $11.6 million. Referring back to Table 2, these

increases come from the approximately 34,000 workers who experience a wage increase, while

approximately 6,000 workers experience reduced earnings due to disemployment. SNAP

Page 22: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

19

benefits decline only slightly, while EITC benefits would decline by approximately $4.6 million,

offsetting over one third of the income gains.

III. Conclusions

We project the effects of a prospective living wage law in New York City, a type of

exercise that has been fairly common in recent years and shares many features with prospective

evaluations of other proposed policies. Longitudinal estimation of living wages implemented in

some cities can be used to estimate effects based on historical experience, but may fail to capture

unique features of a specific labor market or policy proposal. Nonetheless, ex ante simulations

require some evidence from this historical experience to obtain magnitudes of behavioral

responses used in the simulations. We therefore combine the two methods. In addition, newly-

available administrative data on the labor market and covered employers, as well as detailed

information on where people live and work in the ACS, increase the scope for basing these kinds

of studies on a very accurate and complete empirical description of the relevant labor market.

This paper demonstrates how we use these methods and data to study the proposed living wage

law, and argues that these kinds of prospective evaluations should use these mixed methods and

new data sources.

The key point of the paper is its demonstration of methods and uses of data, rather than

the specific conclusions, both because research on the actual effects of laws is ultimately how

social science evaluates policy, and because the actual law implemented could end up differing

from the one we studied, as it in fact did (as discussed below). For the record, nonetheless, the

longitudinal evidence points to living wages generating both winners and losers – the former

those who get higher wages, and the latter those who become jobless. This evidence to some

extent updates earlier research, although changes in geographic classifications in the CPS data

pose challenges in updating the evidence to the present.

Page 23: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

20

These estimated wage and employment effects, along with the administrative and ACS

data, are used in the simulations for New York City, in large part to assess the likely

distributional effects of the proposed living wage. The predicted distributional effects are quite

modest, with poverty or extreme poverty rates changing little – although the extreme poverty rate

actually increases. Thus, the results suggest that the effect of living wages is primarily to shift

earnings from some low-wage, low-skill workers to others. There is a net earnings gain to

affected workers, but a sizable share of it (more than one-third) would likely be offset by lower

EITC benefits.

Insofar as this paper is intended to outline how the effects of proposed living wage laws

can be simulated, the methods, in our view, can be extended to other legislative proposals, while

considerable caution should be exercised in generalizing the conclusions. The methods we have

used take very explicit account of the likely effects of an actual living wage law, specifically by

incorporating both the historical data on covered employers, and the administrative labor market

data on workers’ earnings at covered employers. These are very rich data, but once analysts have

them in hand, a similar type of analysis can be done for other cities. Of course the ability of

analysts to get access to these data – especially the establishment-level QCEW – may be limited,

and may be less likely to be granted in small cities. And we should point out that only one

member of our research team employed by the NYC Economic Development Corporation was

able to work with these data directly; outside researchers working in isolation would face greater

challenges.

The ACS data, in contrast, are publicly available, and can therefore be used for many

other cities. However, for considerably smaller cities these data become less useful. The

geographic designation in the ACS that identifies cities is the Public Use Microdata Area

(PUMA). PUMAs are areas within a state with at least 100,000 residents. But they are generally

Page 24: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

21

constructed using counties as building blocks.22 Thus, for smaller cities that have larger portions

of the counties they occupy outside city boundaries, the identification of city residents or

workers is not as clean.

Generalizability of results is much trickier. First, the actual measurement of the number

of affected firms, and the number and earnings of workers at those affected firms, can be quite

different across cities. This depends on both the economic structure and economic conditions in

different cities, and the structure of any proposed living wage law. We are of course aware that

the economic structure of New York City is unique. New York City’s proposed law is what we

have termed a business assistance living wage mandate. Thus, the results are more generalizable

to other laws that would cover recipients of assistance from cities. In contrast, expected results

for the type of narrower contractor-only law would probably be quite different (and, based on the

work in Adams and Neumark, 2005b, much more modest).

It is true that the legislative proposal that we studied would have been among the most

aggressive business assistance living wage laws in the nation, in part because of the extensive

proposed coverage, and in part because of steep penalties for non-compliance.23 In particular,

the living wage ordinance proposed for New York City differed from that in other cities in terms

of its transference of liability to developers, landlords, or owners of the building, as they are the

financial assistance “recipients,” rather than the normal practice of placing liability primarily on

employers only. However, this feature of the living wage law did not really enter into our labor

market calculations, as the employment elasticity – which is a key driver of the simulations –

was based on evidence from other cities. Thus, the results may be somewhat generalizable, and

hence provide a benchmark, for business assistance living wage laws in other cities where the

living wage falls at a similar percentile of the wage distribution at covered sites and there is a

similar share of workers covered by the law – at least for large cities that share some features

Page 25: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

22

with New York City.

Indeed, given these features of the proposed living wage law, it is likely that because this

key elasticity comes from other cities, we have understated the effects of the proposed law in

New York City. Moreover, the larger report (Charles River Associates, 2011), of which our

labor market research was one component, also studied how the real estate market in New York

City was likely to be affected by the proposed living wage law. The real estate analysis

suggested potentially quite adverse effects on real estate development in New York City owing

to the coverage of the living wage law, who liability would have been extended to, and the

penalties for non-compliance, which include repayment of the financial assistance received.

Because labor markets and real estate markets are closely related, were these adverse effects on

real estate development to occur, the labor market impacts could be worse than the relatively

modest impacts suggested by our labor market analysis.

Finally, by way of emphasizing that any simulation exercise like the one we present in

this paper must be attuned to the details of the specific living wage law under consideration, it

turns out that New York City ended up adopting a considerably weaker living wage law (Local

Law 37, in June, 2012).24 This law reduces coverage in a number of ways. It applies only to

recipients of “discretionary” assistance rather than the broader category in the proposed law we

were asked to study, which included “as-of-right” assistance recipients. It exempted tenants and

sub-tenants of recipients of assistance, unless they have a majority stake, and also exempted non-

profits (largely exempted as well under the original proposal), manufacturing firms, some other

affordable housing, retail, and commercial development projects, and business with annual gross

revenues less than $5 million. Finally, it raised the threshold for coverage to at least $1 million

of assistance in present value. The estimates presented in our paper are based on a much larger

employment base that included nearly all of the now-exempted businesses. There is little doubt

Page 26: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

23

then, that the far narrower coverage of Local Law 37 would imply much smaller effects than

those we report in this paper. Nonetheless, the methods we use could be readily applied to

simulate the effects of the new law, using the data sources we have brought to bear on the

problem that allow identification of covered employers and which permit estimation of the

distribution of earnings at those employers.

Page 27: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

References

Adams, S., & Neumark, D. (2005a). When do living wages bite? Industrial Relations,

44(1), 164-192.

Adams, S., & Neumark, D. (2005b). Living wage effects: New and improved evidence.

Economic Development Quarterly, 19(1), 80-102.

Blank, R. M. (2002). Evaluating welfare reform in the United States. Journal of

Economic Literature, 40(4), 1105-1166.

Charles River Associates. (2011). The economic impacts on New York City of the

proposed living wage mandate. Retrieved December 13, 2011, from

http://www.nycedc.com/NewsPublications/Studies/Documents/CombinedReportLivingWageImp

acts.pdf.

Citro, Constance F. and Robert T. Michael, eds. (1995). Measuring poverty: A new

approach. Washington, DC: National Academy Press, 1995

Groshen, E. L. (1991). The structure of the female/male wage differential: Is it who you

are, what you do, or where you work? Journal of Human Resources, 26(3), 457-472.

Holzer, H. J. (2008). Living wage laws: How much do (can) they matter? Discussion

Paper, Brookings Institution Metropolitan Policy Program, Washington, DC, December.

Neumark, D., & Adams, S. 2003. Do living wage ordinances help reduce urban poverty?

38(3), 490-521.

Neumark, D., Schweitzer, M., & Wascher, W. (2005). The effects of minimum wages on

the distribution of family incomes: A nonparametric analysis. Journal of Human Resources,

40(4), 867-894.

Neumark, D., Thompson, M., Brindisi, F., Koyle, L., & Reck, C. (2012). Estimating the

economic impacts of living wage mandates using ex ante simulations, longitudinal estimates, and

Page 28: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

new public and administrative data: Evidence for New York City. Working Paper No. 18055.

Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

New York Center for Economic Opportunity. (2011). Policy affects poverty: The CEO

poverty measure, 2005-2009. Retrieved September 29, 2012, from

http://www.nyc.gov/html/ceo/downloads/pdf/poverty_measure_2011.pdf.

New York City Department of Finance. (2011, February). Annual report on tax

expenditures fiscal year 2011. Retrieved February 15, 2012, from

http://www.nyc.gov/html/dof/html/pdf/11pdf/ter_2011_final.pdf.

New York City Economic Development Corporation. (2012, January). Annual investment

projects report fiscal year 2011. Retrieved February 15, 2012, from

http://www.nycedc.com/about-nycedc/financial-public-documents.

Pollin, R., & Luce, S. (1998). The living wage: Building a fair economy. New York: The

New Press.

Page 29: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

FigurLa

Source:

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

% o

f w

age

earn

ers

livi

ng

and

wor

kin

g in

New

Yor

k

re 1: Distribaw (based o

Authors’ si

%

%

%

%

%

%

%

$0.00

B

bution of Won sites rec

imulations.

$7.00- $7.50

$8.0$8

Baseline

Wages Beforceiving $100

00 -.50

$9.00 -$9.25

Implementati

re and Afte0,000 or mo

- $9.50 - $9.75

on of Living W

er Implemeore of assist

$10.00 -$10.25

$10$1

Wage Di

ntation of atance in at

0.50 -10.75

$11.00$11.5

isemployment

a $10 Livinleast one ye

0 -50

$12.00 -$12.50

t Effects

ng Wage ear)

$13.00 -$13.50

Page 30: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

Figure 2: Distribution of Wages Before and After Implementation of a $10 Living Wage Law, Retail Trade Industry, by Borough (based on sites receiving $100,000 or more of

assistance in at least one year)

Source: Authors’ simulations.

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

$0.00 $10.00 -$10.25

$0.00 $10.00 -$10.25

$0.00 $10.00 -$10.25

$0.00 $10.00 -$10.25

$0.00 $10.00 -$10.25

$0.00 $10.00 -$10.25

Bronx Brooklyn(Kings County)

Manhattan(New York County)

Queens Staten Island(Richmond County)

New York(All Boroughs)

%t

of w

age

earn

ers

livi

ng

and

wor

kin

g in

ret

ail i

n N

ew Y

ork

Retail Trade Only

Baseline Implementation of Living Wage Disemployment Effects

Page 31: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

Table 1: Wage and Employment Changes, Overall, by Borough, and Outside New York City (based on sites receiving $100,000 or more of assistance in at least one year)

% of workers earning < $10 per hour

employed at covered sites (“affected”)

Number of affected

workers with wage increases

Average wage increase, affected workers who get

wage increase

Number of affected workers

losing jobs

% affected relative to

entire workforce

Average % wage increase,

entire workforce

% of entire workforce losing jobs

New York City 12.9% 33,561 $1.67 5,896 1.2% 0.1% 0.2%

Bronx 12.9% 6,017 $1.70 1,067 1.6% 0.1% 0.3%

Brooklyn 9.9% 9,749 $1.64 1,734 1.1% 0.1% 0.2%

Manhattan 12.5% 4,437 $1.68 778 0.7% 0.0% 0.1%

Queens 13.5% 10,815 $1.66 1,845 1.4% 0.1% 0.2%

Staten Island 31.3% 2,543 $1.65 472 1.5% 0.1% 0.3%

Outside New York City

2,820 $1.50 490

Source: Authors’ simulations.

Page 32: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

Table 2: Changes in Family Poverty Status, by Borough (based on sites receiving $100,000 or more of assistance in at least one year, and CEO poverty thresholds)

% of all families, baseline

% of families, after living wage

implemented

Percentage point

difference %

change Families, baseline

Families, after living

wage implemented

Change in number of

families Families in extreme poverty

New York City 9.55% 9.60% 0.05% 0.50% 245,600 246,816 1,216 Bronx 14.27% 14.32% 0.05% 0.34% 54,170 54,352 182 Brooklyn 9.28% 9.34% 0.05% 0.59% 66,858 67,252 394 Manhattan 10.03% 10.07% 0.03% 0.32% 65,182 65,388 206 Queens 7.17% 7.24% 0.07% 0.99% 48,764 49,248 484 Staten Island 7.51% 7.47% -0.04% -0.47% 10,626 10,576 -50

Families below poverty New York City 20.70% 20.69% -0.02% -0.08% 532,333 531,910 -423 Bronx 29.49% 29.48% -0.01% -0.02% 111,923 111,896 -27 Brooklyn 22.07% 22.06% -0.01% -0.05% 158,980 158,899 -81 Manhattan 17.78% 17.76% -0.02% -0.09% 115,466 115,360 -106 Queens 18.21% 18.19% -0.02% -0.09% 123,864 123,753 -111 Staten Island 15.62% 15.55% -0.07% -0.44% 22,100 22,002 -98

Source: Authors’ simulations.

Page 33: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

Table 3: Changes in Support Programs (based on sites receiving $100,000 or more of assistance in at least one year)

Percent

change in EITC

amount

Percent change in number

Medicaid eligible

Percent change in number SNAP eligible

Percent change in

total amount of

SNAP New York City -0.45% 0.21% -0.18% -0.11% Bronx -0.49% 0.12% -0.11% -0.07% Brooklyn (Kings County) -0.44% 0.20% -0.16% -0.10% Manhattan (New York County) -0.45% 0.16% -0.12% -0.08% Queens -0.47% 0.39% -0.29% -0.16% Staten Island (Richmond County) -0.28% 0.06% -0.45% -0.14%

Change in

total earnings

Change in EITC

amount

Change in number

Medicaid eligible

Change in number SNAP eligible

Change in total

amount of SNAP

New York City $11,614,097 -$4,639,732 784 -945 -$198,478 Bronx $2,525,020 -$1,196,001 100 -114 -$27,741 Brooklyn (Kings County) $2,818,007 -$1,517,036 226 -249 -$63,228 New York (Manhattan) $1,567,378 -$613,921 132 -140 -$28,573 Queens $4,679,903 -$1,204,460 316 -346 -$68,554 Staten Island (Richmond County) $23,789 -$108,314 10 -96 -$10,383 Source: Authors’ simulations.

Page 34: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

Endnotes

1 See http://legistar.council.nyc.gov/LegislationDetail.aspx?ID=664291&GUID=A83A5A5B-

9589-4589-AAD7-5B2C6884610F&Options=ID|Text|&Search=251 (viewed November 2,

2011).

2 For example, see http://nelp.3cdn.net/67dcccd3fc93450105_l4m6ibn7g.pdf (viewed December

13, 2011).

3 For a relatively recent review of research on living wages prior to our study see Holzer (2008).

4 We would argue that the detailed data and information we use would also enable better before-

and-after studies, and that they could be used in the evaluation of other labor market policies.

5 Our analysis sample includes 79 MSAs/PMSAs, in which 23 major cities had living wage laws.

Some cities passed laws that were never implemented, for instance because of a subsequent court

decisions (see Adams and Neumark, 2005a). Only living wage laws that were actually

implemented are included.

6 We collected extensive information on other characteristics of living wage laws, with the goal

of estimating effects of particular living wage laws most similar to the one proposed for New

York City. However, as detailed in Charles River Associates (2011), no city had the panoply of

penalties and costs proposed for New York City, including putting the burden of monitoring

costs on the developer or owner of a building, or repayment of subsidies for violations. More

generally, it turned out to be fruitless to estimate the effects of other features of living wage laws

that have parallels to the proposed law in New York City, because there simply are not that many

cities with living wage laws, and once we look for specific features of the laws, there is at most a

handful of them. To some extent, this parallels the findings from Adams and Neumark (2005a)

that were unable to pin down strong evidence of differences in effects of different types of living

wage laws. As a consequence, the longitudinal analysis could not be used to learn about the

Page 35: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

experiences of other cities with living wages very similar to that proposed for New York City;

rather, the best we could do was to focus on business assistance living wage laws. This problem

highlights why ex ante simulations that capture the unique features of a city’s law are important.

7 As noted earlier, there is some debate about these findings. Holzer’s (2008) review can perhaps

be viewed as providing a “third-party” view of the original Neumark and Adams studies, as well

as of the criticisms of these studies and of city-specific studies of the effects of living wages by

other authors. Regarding the criticisms, Holzer concludes, “Though I find their [Neumark and

Adams’] arguments more compelling than those of their critics on many of these issues, some

concerns over sample sizes and representativeness both within and across their cities remain” (p.

17, brackets added). Regarding the larger set of studies, Holzer concludes that “[T]here is some

consensus across most of them that wages rise among the least-paid workers, while their

employment levels modestly decline (at the covered firms and maybe more broadly), as a result

of these laws” (p. 20).

8 New York City fiscal years run from July 1 of a calendar year to June 30 of the following year,

and are referenced by the calendar year on June 30. Based on the proposed legislation, the types

of exemptions considered were: Industrial and Commercial Incentive Program (ICIP), 421-a,

NYC Industrial Development Agency, and NYC Economic Development Corporation.

9 There are relatively few investments entering the real estate exemption programs after FY 2008

because of the economic downturn. Furthermore, employment concentrates in commercial

properties and the largest program for commercial properties (ICIP) was reformed and only

applications submitted by the end of FY 2008 could qualify for it. ICIP was replaced by the

Industrial and Commercial Abatement Program (ICAP) but our data do not contain information

on abatements.

Page 36: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

10 There are confidentiality restrictions on the QCEW data. The analysis reported here was based

on aggregated information satisfying the following two restrictions: each industry-borough cell

includes no less than three employers; and each employer accounts for less than 80% of the total.

In the case of single-establishment employers, the QCEW data always refer to that

establishment. For multi-establishment firms, the data reported by the employer are generally

broken out by establishment. We always use the data at the establishment level except when we

know the firm has multiple establishments but the data are not reported by establishment, in

which case we treat the firm as an establishment and assign employment to the address reported

in the QCEW.

11 Because the geocoding is time intensive, we only geocoded data for one quarter from each of

the three years covered by the ACS data, and then matched the data for this quarter to the QCEW

data for other quarters and averaged employment and earnings over the calendar year. We used

data from the third quarter because the data indicated a disproportionate share of births in the

first quarter of the year and a disproportionate share of deaths in the fourth quarter.

12 The $10 per hour floor is wage rate in the proposed living wage legislation when health

benefits are provided by the employer. We use this rate in the simulations to be consistent with

the estimates using the CPS data – both the earlier estimates and the updated estimates described

briefly in this paper. If we were to assume that health benefits were not provided, the hourly rate

associated with the proposed living wage law would increase to $11.50 per hour, which, on its

own, would imply somewhat larger effects.

13 We do the adjustment proportionally to avoid getting negative adjusted wage percentiles. The

proportional adjustment parallels the standard wage equation specifications in the labor

economics literature in which log wages are regressed on industry, occupation, or – when

Page 37: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

available – establishment dummy variables (e.g., Groshen, 1991). Our original intention was to

do this establishment by establishment. However, it turned out that the average establishment

wages in the QCEW data estimated this way have lots of outliers in both the positive and

negative direction (i.e., very high and very low estimated hourly wages), which would have

implied massive numbers of workers affected by the proposed living wage. The reason

measurement errors of this type creates bias is because the artificially low wages that are

estimated are not “offset” by the artificially high wages that are also estimated because it is only

the artificially low wages that contribute to estimating wages that are below $10 per hour. That

is, the measurement error puts too many observations in both the lower and upper tails of the

wage distribution, but it is only the former that matter. We are quite sure that the outliers are

generated by the inapplicability of the average hours estimate to the specific establishments. If

the hours estimate is too high, then the estimated hourly wage will be too low and vice versa.

14 The applicable minimum wage is $6.75 in 2006 and $7.15 in 2007 and 2008. In an effort to

reduce the number of individuals excluded due to timing or reporting issues, we use the 2006

level in all years.

15 By applying the probability of job loss to more than those in the bottom decile, the resulting

simulated job loss estimates may be slightly higher than those suggested by the CPS estimates

for the lowest 10% of wage earners.

16 The CEO thresholds use the methods from the National Academy of Science study by Citro

and Michael (1995), which includes more expenditures but also more resources, such as in-kind

benefits, and incorporates geographic differences in living costs. This results in higher

thresholds for New York City than the federal poverty threshold. For example, for a two-adult,

two-child family the CEO threshold for 2009 was $29,477, compared with a federal threshold of

Page 38: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

$21,756 (CEO, 2011).

17 In contrast, the longitudinal analysis of data from cities where living wages have been

implemented captures differences in effects on family income owing to the distribution of

workers – and how they were affected – across families. For a lengthier discussion of this issue

in the context of the effects of minimum wages on family incomes see Neumark, Schweitzer, and

Wascher (2005).

18 Note that the vertical scale is different.

19 The predicted wage increase of $1.67 for those earning less than $10 an hour who keep their

jobs is a 20% increase. Table 1 shows that 12.9% of workers at covered sites earn less than

$10. Thus, the average wage increase for those earning less than $10 is 2.6%. Given that the

proposed living wage increase is 48.1% more than the 2006 minimum wage, the implication of

the 0.051 wage elasticity we estimate from the CPS is that wages of those in the bottom decile

should rise by 2.5%. Thus, although there is not an exact match between the bottom decile and

those earning less than $10 an hour, the simulation results match the CPS estimate quite well.

20 See http://www.health.state.ny.us/health_care/medicaid/ (viewed February 8, 2011);

http://www.irs.gov/individuals/article/0,,id=96406,00.html (viewed April 5, 2011);

http://otda.ny.gov/main/programs/tax-credits (viewed February 8, 2011); and

http://www.fns.usda.gov/snap (viewed April 5, 2011).

21 Because the simulations assume that individuals who continue employment at the living wage

will receive an hourly wage of $10, we implicitly assume that health benefits are provided. If we

were to assume that wages would increase to $11.50 per hour because health benefits were not

provided, the percent of families eligible for Medicaid benefits would decrease. Offsetting this is

the possibility that some employers would stop offering health insurance as a result of the wage

Page 39: Simulating the Economic Impacts of Living Wage …ftp.iza.org/dp7113.pdfliving wage law applies to business assistance recipients, or only to contractors. This analysis leads to elasticities

floor. Note that the Medicaid income thresholds are higher than those for the other programs,

especially for families with infants and young children. This may be one explanation for why we

see a slight increase in Medicaid eligibility and small decreases in the other programs.

22 Details are provided at https://www.census.gov/geo/puma/2010_puma_guidelines.pdf (viewed

October 2, 2012).

23 Details and comparisons with living wage laws in other cities are provided in Charles River

Associates (2011).

24 And even this law is still being litigated at the time of writing.


Recommended