+ All Categories
Home > Documents > The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance......

The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance......

Date post: 23-Jan-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 3 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
20
http://jed.sagepub.com Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 2009; 18; 327 The Journal of Environment Development Harald Fuhr and Markus Lederer Varieties of Carbon Governance in Newly Industrializing Countries http://jed.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/18/4/327 The online version of this article can be found at: Published by: http://www.sagepublications.com at: can be found The Journal of Environment & Development Additional services and information for http://jed.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts Email Alerts: http://jed.sagepub.com/subscriptions Subscriptions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav Permissions: http://jed.sagepub.com/cgi/content/refs/18/4/327 Citations at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.com Downloaded from
Transcript
Page 1: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

http://jed.sagepub.com

Development The Journal of Environment &

DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 2009; 18; 327 The Journal of Environment Development

Harald Fuhr and Markus Lederer Varieties of Carbon Governance in Newly Industrializing Countries

http://jed.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/18/4/327 The online version of this article can be found at:

Published by:

http://www.sagepublications.com

at:can be foundThe Journal of Environment & Development Additional services and information for

http://jed.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts Email Alerts:

http://jed.sagepub.com/subscriptions Subscriptions:

http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navReprints:

http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navPermissions:

http://jed.sagepub.com/cgi/content/refs/18/4/327 Citations

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 2: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

Articles

The Journal of Environment & Development

18(4) 327 –345© SAGE Publications 2009

Reprints and permission: http://www. sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav

DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079http://jed.sagepub.com

Varieties of Carbon Governance in Newly Industrializing Countries

Harald Fuhr1 and Markus Lederer1

Abstract

Recently established carbon governance systems are quite different in Brazil, China, and India. Such divergence is surprising as emerging economies are primarily involved in carbon governance through the clean development mechanism (CDM). One would expect similar institutional and policy outcomes in the major host countries in response to the CDM, as this market instrument is initiated primarily by Western companies and regulated hierarchically by the internationally governed CDM Executive Board. However, from a closer look at the developing features of the CDM markets in Brazil, China, or India and an analysis of dominant actors and their interactions, institutional responses, and the effectiveness of the CDM within each market, there is evidence of a high variance, combined with a strong ownership by the respective governments. Such a variety of carbon governance is interesting from a theoretical point of view as it shows that a good understanding of environmental governance patterns is still lacking in developing and emerging economies. It is also of political importance as the findings may help to diffuse some of the criticism leveled at the CDM.

Keywords

CDM, carbon governance, China, India, Brazil

IntroductionClimate change is a global problem, but the implementation of solutions to the climate crisis and the way in which “carbon issues” are dealt with is very often being done at national and local levels. This is not only true for adaptation, where we would expect

1University of Potsdam, Germany

Corresponding Author:Harald Fuhr and Markus Lederer, University of Potsdam, DFG Research Center 700, Karl-Marx-Straße 67, 14482 Potsdam, GermanyEmail: [email protected]

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 3: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

328 The Journal of Environment & Development 18(4)

this, but also for mitigation, where many would argue that only the global level is of importance. In this special issue, we will analyze the institutional settings currently emerging in newly industrializing countries. We will present case studies of carbon governance from Brazil, China, and India, since these three countries have recently contributed to some of the most important greenhouse gas (GHG) reductions through one particular instrument of carbon governance: the clean development mechanism (CDM). In particular, we are asking whether we see convergence or divergence in regard to carbon governance in Brazil, China, and India.

This question is important for both theoretical and practical reasons. Theoretically, so far most scholarly work using the concept of governance has either focused on member countries of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)—where the monopoly on the legitimate use of force, the rule of law, and a more or less effective implementation of public policies can be regarded as given—or such OECD features are taken as reference points. Nevertheless, there is a high vari-ance among actors who participate in agenda setting, in policy formulation, and in the implementation and monitoring of political decisions (for a good overview of the debate, see Benz, 2004; Schuppert, 2007). One interesting result of the literature that currently deals with such variations in governance in the OECD is that—despite all reconfigurations of the state and “governance by, with and without government”—it is the government that keeps the ultimate political responsibility (Genschel & Zangl, 2007; Leibfried & Zürn, 2006). Although this may, in principle, also hold true for the role governments are playing in the developing world, the state may not be able to fulfill this responsibility in many countries where state institutions are weak. Conse-quently, such shortcomings would need to be taken into account when carbon governance systems in such settings are analyzed.

This debate is also of importance for practical reasons since there is a lot of criticism in using the CDM as an expanded mechanism for the inclusion of the developing world into a post-2012 climate regime. The CDM is often regarded as working just as an offsetting mechanism, which does not contribute to overall emission reductions (Schneider, 2007). Some authors argue that the mechanism diverts attention from domestic reductions in Annex I countries as well as in the South (Luhmann & Sterk, 2008) and that it is has failed so far to initiate carbon reductions in some sectors (in particular the forestry sector) and some regions (sub-Saharan Africa, for example, is completely marginalized in the carbon market). At the local level, various projects have been criticized for their poor or negative environmental impact (International Rivers Network [IRN], 2008; Michaelowa & Purohit, 2007) or for generating high windfall profits. Moreover, most observers agree that one of the key objectives of the CDM—initiating best practices of sustainable development—has not (yet) been achieved. Summarizing such criticism, Wara and Victor (2008) argued that the CDM “rather than draw them [the developing countries] into substantial limits on emissions it has, by contrast, rewarded them for avoiding exactly those commitments” (p. 6). Given such statements, negotiators may often wonder whether the CDM was such a good idea in the first place, and whether it should be abandoned in a post-2012 agreement.

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 4: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

Fuhr and Lederer 329

In the following, we will argue that such conclusion is premature, as it underesti-mates the CDM’s dynamics and its broader effects in the larger host countries. Furthermore, many of the problems mentioned appear to be related to a lack of man-agement as the CDM at all levels is often implemented neither transparently nor professionally (Streck, 2007). The CDM also appears often to generate wrong incen-tives for private companies mandated to validate and ultimately certify individual projects (Schneider, 2007). To address such concerns and to adjust and reform the CDM effectively, we still need a better understanding of local governance issues and the institutional responses triggered by the CDM, especially in those countries where most projects have actually been setup.

In this article, which is based on our findings from empirical research in Brazil, China, and India, we will try to fill these gaps. We will show that the CDM has been managed quite differently in these three cases. At the same time, we recognize some evolving patterns, which help us to explain how the CDM has been integrated success-fully into national environmental policies. This is, to some extent, surprising as one would expect that an internationally initiated and top-down regulated market mecha-nism, such as the CDM, would leave little room for national policy makers to influence implementation. One would expect convergence rather than divergence in practices of implementation. We do, however, see the contrary.

To explore these arguments, we will, in a first step, briefly refer to the debate on governance and highlight some related concepts and how they may be usefully applied to analyzing CDM operations. We will then discuss the inclusion of market instru-ments as one particular governance mechanism and eventually turn to operational aspects of the CDM as a project-based market mechanism, which links developed and developing countries in the climate protection regime. Next, we will present some of the findings and interpretations from our case studies, and explain what we mean when we talk about “varieties of carbon governance.” A short conclusion will sum-marize the results and provide some ideas for further research.

Governance and the Use of Market InstrumentsGovernance refers to institutionalized modes of coordinating societal activities toward collectively binding rules and/or the provision of collective goods for a defined group of people (Risse & Lehmkuhl, 2007). Our understanding of governance presupposes that participating actors intend to bring about such rules or goods for a specific collectivity (Ladwig, Jugov, & Schmelzle, 2007). Contrary to the broader definition of governance by Williamson (1975), we argue that the market itself is not a governance structure. The famous baker of Adam Smith, who bakes bread out of self-interest and thereby contrib-utes to food security, would not, therefore, perform a governance function.

As recent events in the financial system indicate, every economic activity is embed-ded in a broader societal order (Granovetter, 1985; Polanyi, 1944/1957) and can only be carried out within a clearly defined regulatory framework. The setting up of such regulation is an act of governance, whereas the anonymous coordination of demand

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 5: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

330 The Journal of Environment & Development 18(4)

and supply that constitute market mechanisms is not. Therefore, our understanding of governance should not be read as being a synonym to deregulation or a normative call for a retreat of the state. On the contrary, we argue that markets are unlikely to work without a priori governance (see also the recent summary in Dixit, 2009).

For quite some time, economic governance has been neglected by economists. Since the mid-1990s, however, advocates of new public management (NPM) have stressed that market instruments could serve as quite an effective form of “steering” in public policy. Others have been rather skeptical about whether—and to what extent—NPM and market mechanisms could really be employed in the daily practice of public administration and even more so in the developing world where public institutions are often poorly developed and informality is high (Schick, 1998). Markets have also been in the focus of environmental governance (for a rather critical overview, see P. Newell, 2005), although countries with a more state-centric tradition, such as Germany, have initially been quite reluctant to introduce them in environmental practice (Jordan, Wurzel, & Zito, 2007; Wurzel, Jordan, Zito, & Brückner, 2003).

In environmental protection, there are two options for markets to play a role in governance. On one hand, markets can be properly regulated so as to ensure that pro-duction, exchange, or consumption of goods is done more sustainably. This can be achieved either through (a) traditional regulatory measures, (b) cooperation between public and private entities (i.e., public–private partnerships [PPP]), (c) self-regulation of industries, (d) voluntary standards, and (e) certification systems. The latter have been labeled “non-state market driven” governance systems by Cashore and Bernstein (Cashore, 2002; Cashore & Bernstein, 2007). Such private governance rests on the assumption that private actors are not only more efficient than public ones but are also authoritative and thus legitimate regulatory actors (Cutler, Haufler, & Porter, 1999). Examples include the Forest Stewardship Council (Boström & Klintman, 2008; Pattberg, 2005, 2007), the Fairtrade Labelling Organization, the Sustainable Tourism Stewardship Council, or current attempts to certify the production of bioethanol (Delzeit, Bohle, & Holm-Müller, 2007; Friberg, 2008).

On the other hand, markets are being set up directly as an instrument for different environmental issues (for an overview, see Larson, Ambrosi, Dinar, Rahman, & Entler, 2008). They have, for example, successfully been employed in sustainable fishery (Anderson & Sutinen, 2006; R. G. Newell, Sanchirico, & Kerr, 2005). Markets are also perceived as particularly important to reduce GHG emissions efficiently and effectively (Eliasch, 2008; Stern, 2007). Contrary to the simple “greening” of market behavior, market mechanisms now put a price tag on emissions and internalize costs, which otherwise would have to be borne by the public and the environment. The origi-nal concept for setting up tradable permits as an alternative to top-down regulation was introduced by Ronald Coase (1960) and was further developed by the Canadian economist John H. Dales (1968).

In practice, governance systems that use market instruments for the purpose of reducing and trading emissions (i.e., emission trading systems [ETS]) have been known since the early 1970s (for a good overview of the different systems, see

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 6: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

Fuhr and Lederer 331

Schreurs, 2008b). In 1976, the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency introduced the first “offset mechanism,” which allowed the building of new factories under the condi-tion that they provided air pollution reductions in another facility of the same company in the same region. In 1990, the U.S. Acid Rain Program was initiated by the U.S. Clean Air Act to curb sulfur dioxide emissions. Its effect was that “emissions trading left its protected space and stepped out into the wider world of environmental politics” (Voß, 2007, p. 9). Finally, in the 1990s, the use of market instruments moved into the main-stream of climate politics as private actors like Shell or BP—supported by lobby groups like the International Emission Trading Association—and individual countries, such as the United Kingdom and Denmark, set up prototypes of carbon dioxide trading.

At the international level, it was the Montreal Protocol that made use of emission trading for the first time to reduce ozone depleting substances. One of the ironies of the Kyoto process is that the United States favored emission trading initially, whereas the EU was skeptical. Now it is the EU that has ended up championing market instruments through its own emission trading scheme (EU ETS), eventually covering some 11,500 facilities (in 2005) with a total of 6.5 gigatonne of CO2 emissions per year (EU Com-mission, 2005; Skjaerseth & Wettestad, 2008). Other regional or national trading systems are already operating or are being launched in New Zealand, Australia, Switzerland, Canada, and Japan on a national scale, whereas the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (California), the Midwestern Greenhouse Gas Accord, or the Western Cli-mate Initiative all work at subnational level, awaiting a more favorable federal administration in the US (Flachsland, Marschinski, & Edenhofer, 2008; Schreurs, 2008a).

The developing world is linked to these markets as the EU ETS and the Kyoto Protocol’s cap-and-trade systems allow the use of offsets, which encourage emission reductions in transition countries through joint implementation projects or in develop-ing countries through CDM projects. The CDM, however, is not only much more important quantitatively, it is also critical for connecting carbon markets in the devel-oped and the developing world.

Carbon Governance and the CDMThe CDM has two objectives. First, it is an offset mechanism permitting industrialized countries to credit emission reductions on their Kyoto-Protocol obligations from GHG abatement projects in developing countries. As long as GHG emissions are cheaper in the developing, non-Annex I countries, it is possible to lower the cost of Kyoto com-pliance. Second, the CDM should support sustainable development practices in the host countries. The CDM is thus the entry point for developing countries to participate in the burgeoning carbon markets, and today it is the main mechanism for financial transfers for climate protection between the North and the South.1

The CDM has shown to be a rather flexible mechanism that fulfils its objective of providing cost-efficient emission reductions (Benecke, Friberg, Lederer, & Schröder, 2008). It has also been hailed a great success by policy makers as “the CDM is deliver-ing what it was meant to deliver—emission reductions and development. What’s

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 7: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

332 The Journal of Environment & Development 18(4)

more, it has shown that it can evolve, adapt and improve.” (Yvo de Boer, Executive Secretary of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change [UNFCCC]; UNFCCC, 2007). Linking the CDM to the EU ETS, a cap-and-trade system, was not foreseen when the mechanism was designed, but it has increased the general liquid-ity and demand for carbon credits in the market. Furthermore, the CDM has initiated environmental technology transfers (for a good overview, see Benecke, 2009; Dechezlepetre, Yann, & Yann, 2008; Larson et al., 2008). As our case studies will show in more detail, the latter has essentially been achieved through capacity develop-ment, such as skills development and administrative strengthening. The introduction of the CDM has also led to an increase in knowledge about the carbon market in gen-eral and GHG accounting in particular. Also, a general awareness about climate change issues has been initiated. Finally, a substantial transfer of finance has taken place toward emerging economies. For example, in Brazil, revenues from certified emission reductions (CERs) are reaching Rank 20 in terms of external (“export”) revenues. The CDM thus apparently constitutes a rather successful “new mode of governance” that developed from a PPP into a burgeoning market (Fuhr, Lederer, & Schröder, 2007). This has not happened in a uniform manner but rather on different trajectories.

Given the CDM’s overall development, one would expect more convergence than divergence in implementation,2 for four reasons. First, market instruments and pro-cesses of diffusion usually lead to convergence as similar problems result in similar policy responses (Jänicke & Klaus, 2006; Knill, 2005; Simmons & Elkins, 2004). Hence, at least in the OECD, there is an overall trend toward convergence in environ-mental policy making (Busch & Jörgens, 2007). Second, governance arrangements sustaining the CDM are multilevel and most strongly influenced by international actors. This holds for both the Conference of the Parties (COP), which is still its highest authority, and the CDM Executive Board (EB) whose members are appointed by the COP (Benecke, 2008). International regulation thus largely determines the institutional structures in which CDM projects can be developed, verified, and registered. Given such procedures, we should witness a top-down approach that leads to similar patterns in host countries and constrains national modifications. Third, as a market mechanism, the CDM relies heavily on market actors as “change agents” (for a good description of change agents, see Rogers, 2003; Stone, 2004). Initially, these actors were Western consulting companies, project developers, project validators, or development agencies, who all acted as innovators at the local level. One example is Ecosecurities, a company that has been one of the most important project developers in all emerging carbon mar-kets. Another is Det Norske Veritas (DNV), a global certification company that, together with some others, dominates the niche market for validation and verification of CDM projects as designated operational entity (DOE). Again, the involvement of such actors would suggest harmonized practices and emulation in host countries. Fourth, the CDM does not require redistributive practices. On the contrary, the CDM transfers resources from the developed to the developing world and therefore does not face much opposi-tion, neither at national nor at subnational levels. Consequently, we should expect rather similar patterns of development across countries.

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 8: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

Fuhr and Lederer 333

However, contrary to such expectations, there is a rather surprising variety of carbon governance arrangements in Brazil, China, and India. In fact, divergence is visible at the level of policy outcomes and at the level of government programs, indi-cating a strong case of nonconvergence (Holzinger & Knill, 2005). This can be shown by focusing on (a) the features of emerging CDM markets, (b) the role individual actors play and how they interact, and (c) the CDM’s effectiveness.

Features of Emerging CDM MarketsBrazil, China, and India cover the three largest CDM markets in the world, both in terms of the number of projects and the amount of CERs generated. Brazil’s govern-ment first introduced the idea of a clean development fund in the Kyoto negotiations and participated early on in the CDM’s predecessor, the activities implemented jointly. Today, Brazil is the third largest CDM host country but, due to its clean energy matrix, more than 77% of Brazil’s electricity is generated through hydropower. The Brazilian Designated National Authority (DNA) has a reputation for upholding the environmen-tal integrity of the CDM system and does not focus on promoting the CDM. Even if the CDM has so far been too marginal to significantly influence overall energy policy, one sector where the CDM has played an important role is the sugarcane industry. In this sector, CDM projects have helped introduce bagasse cogeneration technology, and the sale of surplus electricity is now seen as a third revenue stream—in addition to the traditional products of sugar and ethanol. Not surprisingly, there are sharp regional disparities in the set up of CDM projects (see Figure 1).

Chinese government officials first appeared reluctant to enter the CDM market, but subsequently the country became a world leader. China now accounts for 39.3% of all CDM projects registered (or in the pipeline) and 55.5% of all CERs generated (United Nations Environment Programme [UNEP], 2009). The country appears to attract investors and CER buyers with favorable conditions for foreign investors and good public management. Interestingly, carbon governance in China follows the traditional top-down approach with command-and-control regulations and a governmental check on foreign companies. The Chinese CDM market is characterized by hard steering and an overall “state capture of the market” as the Chinese government is very apt in utiliz-ing the international market mechanisms for its own political priorities (see Figure 2).

India has the second largest CDM market. The UNFCCC CDM pipeline lists 1,127 projects at various stages of CDM registration, accounting for 25.2% of all CDM projects worldwide (UNEP, 2009). CDM projects generate revenues totaling 423,788 kCERs in 2012, which is 15.3% of the global CDM market. A prominent feature of the CDM in India is its “sweatshop” character. It has led to an exponential increase in CDM project application and a “Project Development Document (PDD) assembly line production.” However, in comparison with China, most projects are small scale and gen-erate little revenue. There are some interesting features of the Indian CDM market. First, the majority of CDM projects concentrate on renewable energy. Second, nowhere else are more CDM projects rejected than in India, and many of the CDM projects currently set

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 9: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

334 The Journal of Environment & Development 18(4)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

Piauí

Maranhão

Alagoas

Paraíba

Ceará

Pará

Pernam

buco

Rio G

rande do Norte

Bahia

Acre

Tocantins

Sergipe

Rondônia

Am

apá

Roraim

a

Goiás

Mato G

rosso do Sul

Minas G

erais

Am

azonas

Mato G

rosso

Paraná

Rio G

rande do Sul

Espírito S

anto

Santa C

atarina

Rio de Janeiro

São P

aulo

Pro

ject

s

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

GD

P/C

AP

R$

Number of CDM Projects GDP/cap

Figure 1. Number of CDM Projects and GDP/capita in Brazilian states (1000 R$)Note: CDM = clean development mechanism.Source: Assembled from United Nations Environment Programme (2009) Risoe Centre CDM Pipeline and Brazilian Institute of Applied Economic Research (IPEA) statistics.

0

10000

20000

30000

40000

50000

60000

70000

Gui

zhou

Gan

suY

unna

nA

nhui

Gua

ngxi

Sic

huan

Jian

gxi

Qin

ghai

N

ingx

iaH

unan

Sha

anxi

C

hong

qing

Hai

nan

Hub

ei

Hen

anS

hanx

iX

injia

ngJi

linH

eilo

ngjia

ngH

ebei

Inne

rF

ujia

nLi

aoni

ngS

hand

ong

Gua

ngdo

ngJi

angs

uZ

hejia

ngT

ianj

inB

eijin

gS

hang

hai

Yu

an/c

ap

020406080100120140160180200

Mill

ion

pro

ject

s/ca

p

Total number of projects Yuan/cap

Figure 2. Total number of projects versus GDP/capita in Chinese provincesSource: United Nations Environment Programme (2009).

up have questionable additionality, particularly in wind energy. Third, only a third of all CDM projects are characterized as bilateral, that is, have signed letters of approval with participants from developed countries. The fact that most of the Indian CDM projects are

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 10: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

Fuhr and Lederer 335

unilateral (with no involvement of Western companies) is subject to critical debates related to issues of foregone technology transfer and foreign investment.

One recurrent feature in all three CDM markets is that CDM projects cluster in the richer parts of each country (Figure 3). This does not come as a surprise as most emis-sions are produced in areas where most industries are located and where the best institutional infrastructure exists.

Overall, the three biggest CDM markets share some features (e.g., regional dispar-ity), but otherwise major differences remain (see summary in Table 1).

Actors and Their InteractionsVarious actors and groups of actors participate in the CDM project cycle. They include project developers, financial institutions, national bureaucracies (in particu-lar the DNAs and the DOEs, which verify and validate projects), and the international authorities (EB).

Project developers and DOEs behave rather similarly in our three country cases. This may be due to the fact that DOEs are almost exclusively Western-based compa-nies. This might change in the future, since (supported by Western donors) some Chinese certification companies have recently applied to become accepted as DOEs by the Executive Board. However, given the widespread concerns in the market whether they will apply the same rigorous standards, there is some reluctance to grant them accreditation offhand. Also project developers are either Western companies or

0

10000

20000

30000

40000

50000

60000

70000

Bih

arU

ttar

Pra

desh

Oris

saJh

arkh

and

Mad

hya

Pra

desh

Ass

amC

hhat

tisga

rhR

ajas

than

Man

ipur

Jam

mu

and

Kas

hmir

Utta

rakh

and

Meg

hala

yaA

runa

chal

Pra

desh

Wes

t Ben

gal

Trip

ura

And

hra

Pra

desh

Kar

nata

kaS

ikki

mN

agal

and

Tam

il N

adu

Miz

oram

Guj

arat

Ker

ala

Him

acha

l Pra

desh

Pun

jab

Har

yana

Mah

aras

htra

D

elhi

Goa

Ru

pee

s/ca

p

020406080100120140160180200

Nu

mb

er o

f p

roje

cts

Total number of projects Rupees/cap

Figure 3. Total number of projects versus GDP/capita in Indian statesSource: United Nations Environment Programme (2009).

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 11: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

336 The Journal of Environment & Development 18(4)

still strongly rely on international consultancies like Ecosecurities. Within this group of actors, we did not find substantial differences among countries in terms of manage-ment practices, but there is no clear cut convergence either.

Nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) did not play a significant role in the CDM discourse in any of our countries. This is possibly the most surprising element of our findings, as one would have expected a highly contentious market mechanism like the CDM to face serious opposition from NGOs in India or Brazil. In the case of Brazil, where we assumed the participation of a lively environmental NGO community, such as the one engaged in the protection of the Amazon rain forest, we found little action toward the CDM. Those NGOs working on climate change issues focused on defores-tation and on the ongoing negotiations for a new international climate agreement. In China, however, with its restrictions to public participation in decision making, we recognized activities by NGOs. NGOs were essentially engaged in campaigns to raise awareness on climate change, but they abstained from critical comments on CDM projects (Schröder, 2008). A position paper on the CDM by 40 Chinese NGOs, which had been drafted with international NGOs and presented at COP/MOP (Meeting of Parties) 13, was basically in line with the Chinese government’s position. In India, civil society actors did not engage much in advocacy or lobbying activities related to the CDM, although many CDM projects are implemented in rural areas where Indian development agencies have a strong presence. If civil society did engage at all in CDM projects, it took place at the federal level. Indian NGOs seem to be more inter-ested in directly participating in the CDM and promoting activities in niche markets,

Table 1. Comparison of Registered CDM Projects in Brazil, China, and India

Brazil

China

India

No. of projects

159

579

438

% share of worldwide total

projects

9

34

26

Volume of CERs up to

2012

131,032

885,215

231,635

% share of worldwide total CER generation

8

54

14

Three most common

project types

Methane avoidance, hydropower, landfill gas

Hydropower, wind power, energy efficiency

Wind power, energy efficiency, hydropower

Three most common project

types world-wide

1. Hydro power

2. Biomass energy

3. Methane avoidance

Note: CDM = clean development mechanism; CER = certified emission reduction.Source: United Nations Environment Programme (2009)

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 12: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

Fuhr and Lederer 337

such as rural electrification. They appeared as partners in CDM development rather than critical watchdogs.

More important than critical civil society groups are national epistemic communi-ties. In Brazil and China, universities and research institutes play an important role in the developing carbon markets. In Brazil, various universities even offer CDM project development courses. In India, by contrast, national epistemic communities working on the CDM hardly exist in academia but rather in the business community, for exam-ple, in chambers of commerce or in the development assistance community.

The most important differences among participating actors, however, can be found within the public sector, in particular regarding the DNAs. In Brazil, we witnessed how the DNA’s initial focus on strong environmental integrity in the CDM was chal-lenged when business interests exerted political pressure for a preferred method of calculating the carbon baseline in the electricity grid. The Chinese government had very clear objectives regarding the CDM. First, it sought to participate in the market

Table 2. Different Roles of CDM Market Actors in Brazil, China, and India

Government

Project developers/consultancies

Buyers/traders

Civil society

Epistemic communities

Brazil

Holds up “environmental integrity” in project development

Heavy competition, but informal cooperation among biggest consultancies

Financial community has large interest in developing carbon market and trading, but so far with limited success

Awareness, but limited engagement in CDM

Strong involvement from key scientists in methodology development and cooperation with DNA

China

Keeps control of market and foreign actors, and also provides capacity development

International and domestic project developers

Banks have no interest in trading, hardly an interest in project financing

Awareness, positive position, no capacity

Involvement of scientists in CDM capacity development and project development

India

Has facilitating role for CDM market development

Many unilateral projects developed by Indian companies

Slowly emerging awareness among national banks

Engagement in project activities but no watchdog

Mostly among development assistance community + business community

Note: CDM = clean development mechanism; DNA = Designated National Authority.

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 13: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

338 The Journal of Environment & Development 18(4)

to gain a substantial amount of market share. Furthermore, foreign investment and the potential of technology transfer were a major motivation. Second, CDM projects were supposed to improve energy efficiency or facilitate the buildup of energy infrastruc-ture in its less developed regions. We therefore found a strong involvement of various state agencies. Third, the Chinese government taxes CDM projects: usually the rate is 2% on the revenues generated, but in some projects, such as industrial gas, taxation may be stepped up to 65%. Profits are channeled into a newly set up “CDM Fund,” which is supposed to finance renewable energy projects. Similar to its regulatory poli-cies vis-à-vis foreign direct investment, the state makes sure that foreigners do not acquire majority control in Chinese projects. Therefore, CDM projects can only be set up in companies that are at least 51% Chinese owned. Finally, the government has set an unofficial floor price for CERs to avoid dumping prices. Overall, the state relies heav-ily on traditional command-and-control and regulates rather top down. Apparently, the Chinese state has captured the carbon market.

In India, a high-level committee on climate change has been set up. The link to the developing carbon market is seen as an overall opportunity to enhance domestic growth and diversify business. Openness toward CDM projects thus very much resembles India’s opening up toward foreign investment. With the maturing of the Indian carbon market, CDM activities are no longer considered exclusively a business issue. State agencies expect individual CDM projects to contribute to investment in public infrastructure, such as the electricity sector. Interestingly, some state govern-ments (e.g., Punjab) are more active in setting up CDM projects than others. India’s regulatory structure, however, has faced serious criticism, as a lot of CDM projects—specifically in wind energy, and significantly more than in other countries—did not satisfy additionality criteria. In the meanwhile, the Indian DNA has responded to such concerns and has taken various steps to improve the quality of its operations without falling back to bureaucratization and overregulation. Overall, the Indian state appears to act as a market facilitator.

The CDM’s EffectivenessBy effectiveness, we essentially mean the achievement of set goals. In the case of the CDM, effectiveness is high when (a) cost-efficient GHG mitigation has been taking place and (b) when CDM projects contribute to sustainable development in a broad(er) sense. As the question of mitigation is verified by the DOEs, we have focused on the CDM’s contribution toward sustainability.

In negotiations on international climate change, the interpretation of whether an individual CDM project is contributing to sustainability was deliberately left to be decided at the national level. Brazil is taking the sustainability aspect seriously and has developed its own criteria on sustainable development. These include, for example, a set procedure for public consultation on all proposed CDM projects. Most projects, however, receive no comments at all. The Chinese government’s main objective seems to be that the CDM should provide foreign investment and help transfer technology

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 14: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

Fuhr and Lederer 339

while the entire process, plus ownership, is under Chinese control. In India, the issue of sustainability takes up less prominence but energy efficiency and distribution are stressed. Thus, the Indian government aims to increase rural electrification through CDM development. Although these results still have a preliminary status, the CDM’s direct contribution toward sustainability appears to be rather low. Again, we have a very diverse picture regarding the CDM’s contribution to sustainable development, and there is no doubt that the overall record is not yet satisfactory.

Nevertheless, the CDM has been effective in various other ways. First, there has been quite a significant output as 1,176 projects have been set up in Brazil, China, and India (out of a total of 1,700 projects registered), amounting to 77.4% of all CER issued. Second, the CDM has led to a significant improvement in national and subnational capacities to deal with climate issues. Within a very short time, a large number of project developers, consultants, and financial experts have evolved in the private sector. Simi-larly, governments have increased the number of professional staff dealing with the climate policy of their country. Although in a country like Brazil the “carbon governance community” is still rather small, the counterfactual that it would hardly be existent with-out the CDM seems fair. Finally and closely related to the second point, the CDM has, according to our observations, also contributed to a repositioning of newly industrializ-ing countries in the international climate negotiations. The more active participation of Brazil, India, and China in the last COP (December 2008), for example, was partially motivated by their wish to influence any change in the international CDM regulation to their advantage. In short, the CDM has had unintended positive consequences in carbon governance that should not be overlooked. These consequences again differ from coun-try to country and no coherent picture has emerged so far (see table 2).

Why Divergence?Our explanation for divergence is the political and economic salience of the CDM in particular and the importance governments have attached to the issue in general. In the more advanced developing countries, carbon governance has become too important for simply doing business as usual. This holds true also for the international level where some of these countries are now major players, questioning the traditional Western hegemony. Carbon governance is, however, also a political issue domesti-cally, and there is substantive “ownership” in all three of our country cases.

In Brazil, the government initially pushed for high integrity to get the CDM off the ground in a proper way. In China, the central government is now actively pushing for a swift development of the CDM, also in its eastern provinces and more remote areas. And India’s public administration has, so far at least, worked much better and more efficiently toward CDM management than in other public policies. Economically, China (in particular) perceives the CDM essentially as a business opportunity and makes every effort to generate as many CDM projects as possible and to gain as much as possible financially. Neither India nor Brazil has made use of the CDM to such an extent, although India’s attempt to boost investment in sectors where public and

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 15: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

340 The Journal of Environment & Development 18(4)

private activities fall behind national development targets (e.g., in rural electrification) indicates that the government is aware of the economic opportunities of carbon gover-nance as well. Therefore, the CDM is a clear example for the state to maintain a decisive role, despite global pressures to the contrary (for a similar conclusion in the field of environment more generally, see Drezner, 2001).

ConclusionWhat are some of the broader lessons from our research? First, our results show that the CDM has not initiated a race to the bottom at the cost of broader sustainable devel-opment objectives. Furthermore, at least in our cases (Brazil, China, and India), there is a high level of ownership of the CDM. This is of importance for policy as there are strong inclinations, in particular within the European Commission, to completely reform and potentially abandon the CDM. China or India will, however, not give up on the CDM that easily. Although these countries could be tempted to opt for sectoral commitments in return for concessions on financial and technological transfers from Annex I countries, there is no reason for them to give up the CDM’s project-based approach until such agreements have been put in place as part of the Kyoto follow-up and the CDM infrastructure integrated into a succession system.

Second, the CDM has had an important impact in newly industrializing countries. Despite the fact that the CDM may be governed differently, the CDM has fostered local businesses to get involved in the global carbon market and has thus contributed step-by-step in establishing appropriate market mechanisms in the environment. Such developments may now also have spillover effects into other environmental markets. Again, this is an important aspect for future policy discussions as it shows that market instruments, just like any other governance instrument, need some time to have an impact and also need continual readjustments.

Third, the CDM has also led to substantial transfers of resources—both technologi-cal and financial—from the North to the South. Although this has not reduced general inequalities within the global system (Roberts & Parks, 2007), transfers have indeed been quite impressive. This supports Biermann’s thesis that in environmental policy making, the South is much more powerful in negotiating international deals than in other sectors (Biermann, 2007).

Fourth, we have just started to analyze (and understand) environmental governance in developing and newly industrializing countries. As our introduction has shown and as the following case studies will highlight, we see more variance than expected but do not know whether this is just a temporary phenomenon or if we need more work to come to a theoretically better informed picture.

Finally, governance arrangements set up to take advantage of the opportunities pro-vided by the CDM have resulted in unintended consequences. The CDM seems to be contributing to a broader debate on sustainable development in all three countries exam-ined. Beyond generating financial resources for technology transfers, CDM operations appear to have played an important role in raising public awareness for climate change

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 16: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

Fuhr and Lederer 341

issues and the need for swift action, that is, for designing adequate policies of mitigation and adaptation, both abroad and at home. This appears on its own to be a significant contribution to advancing the global climate regime during the post-Kyoto phase.

Acknowledgments

The authors thank the editor and three anonymous reviewers of Journal of Environment & Devel-opment for their helpful comments. They are also grateful to the participants of the Workshops “Varieties of Carbon Governance” held in Potsdam in July 2008 and “Politikwissenschaftliche Forschungen zum Klimaschutz: Bilanz und Ausblick” at the Freie Universität Berlin in January 2009 for valuable suggestions on earlier drafts.

Declaration of Conflicting Interests

The authors declared no potential conflicts of interests with respect to the authorship and/or publication of this article.

Funding

Research was funded by the German Research Foundation and carried out as part of the research centre 700 “Governance in Areas of Limited Statehood.” (www.sfb-governance.de).

Notes

1. Of the three Kyoto mechanisms mentioned (International Emission Trading (IES), joint implementation, and clean deve lopment mechanism [CDM]), the CDM is the most impor-tant to date, generating trade of US$12 billion in 2007 (Point Carbon, 2008). Fund-based carbon governance projects, for example through the global environmental facility, of course predate the CDM and still contribute to capacity building and technology transfer, but they have never generated the same amounts of money as the compliance market.

2. Convergence refers to the fact that the aims, instruments, and standards of specific pol-icies resemble each other subsequently across nations, no matter what the cause (Kerr, 1983; Knill, 2005; Lütz, 2007). The underlying transfer can be initiated through hierarchies (coercion), competition, bargaining, deliberation, or lesson drawing (DiMaggio & Powell, 1991; Dolowitz & Marsh, 2000; Lütz, 2007; Rose, 1993).

References

Anderson, C. M., & Sutinen, J. G. (2006). The effect of initial lease periods on price discovery in laboratory tradable fishing allowance markets. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organi-zation, 61, 164-180.

Benecke, G. (2008). The Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) - an Instrument to solve global climate problems? The value added of an analysis of "new forms of governance". In: S. De la Rosa, U. Höppner, & M. Kötter (Eds.), Transdisciplinary governance research. Commonly looking beyond the state. Baden-Baden, Germany: Nomos.

Benecke, G. (2009, January 30). Greening energy politics in India: Assessing contributions from the CDM in the wind energy sector. Paper presented at the Politikwissenschaftliche Forschung zum Klimaschutz: Bilanz und Ausblick, Freie Universität Berlin, Germany.

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 17: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

342 The Journal of Environment & Development 18(4)

Benecke, G., Friberg, L., Lederer, M., & Schröder, M. (2008). From public-private partner-ship to market: The clean development mechanism (CDM) as a new form of governance in climate protection. Berlin, Germany: SFB 700.

Benz. A. (2004). Introduction: Governance--Fashionable term or helpful concept for the social sciences? In A. Benz (Ed.), Governance: Ruling in complex rule-system. An Introduction (pp. 11-28). Wiesbaden, Germany: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.

Biermann, F. (2007). North-South relations in global environmental politics: Global interdepen-dence and institutional innovation. In K. Jacob, P. H. Feindt, P.-O. Busch, & F. Biermann (Eds.), Politics and Society. PVS special edition 39 (pp. 115-132). Wiesbaden, Germany: VS-Verlag.

Boström, M., & Klintman, M. (Eds.). (2008). Eco-standards, product labelling and green con-sumerism. Hampshire, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.

Busch, P.-O., & Jörgens, H. (2007). Political change and convergence in environmental politics, 1950-2000. In K. Jacob, P. H. Feindt, P.-O. Busch, & F. Biermann (Eds.), Politics and Soci-ety. PVS special edition 39 (pp. 200-222). Wiesbaden, Germany: VS-Verlag.

Cashore, B. (2002). Legitimacy and the privatization of environmental governance: How non-state market driven (NSMD) governance systems gain rule-making authority. Governance, 15, 502-529.

Cashore, B., & Bernstein, S. (2007). Can non-state global governance be legitimate? An analyti-cal framework. Regulation & Governance, 1, 1-25.

Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law & Economics, 3, 1-44.Cutler, C. A., Haufler, V., & Porter, T. (Eds.). (1999). Private authority and international affairs.

Albany: State University of New York Press.Dales, J. H. (1968). Pollution, property and prices: An essay in policy-making and economics.

Toronto, Ontario, Canada: Toronto University Press.Dechezlepetre, A. G., Yann, M., & Yann, M. (2008). Technology transfer by CDM projects:

A comparison of Brazil, China, India, Energy. Energy Policy, 37, 703-711.Delzeit, R., Bohle, H.-G., & Holm-Müller, K. (2007). Towards a certification of biomass: Fea-

sibility of a certifications scheme of sustainability standards for trade and production of bioethanol in Brazil (Discussion Paper). Bonn, Germany: Universität Bonn.

DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1991). The iron cage revisited: Institutionalized isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. In W. W. Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 63-82). Chicago: Chicago University Press.

Dixit, A. (2009). Governance institutions and economic activity. American Economic Review, 99, 5-24.

Dolowitz, D. P., & Marsh, D. (2000). Learning from abroad: The role of policy-transfer in con-temporary policy-making. Governance, 13, 5-24.

Drezner, D. W. (2001). Globalization and policy convergence. International Studies Review, 3, 53-78.

Eliasch, J. (2008). Eliasch review: Climate change: Financing global forests. London: Office of the Prime Minister.

EU Commission. (2005, June 20). MEMO/05/84 questions & answers on emissions trading and national allocation plans. Retrieved January 16, 2009, from http://europa.eu/rapid/

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 18: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

Fuhr and Lederer 343

pressReleasesAction.do?reference=MEMO/05/84&format=HTML&aged=1&language=EN&guiLanguage=en

Flachsland, C., Marschinski, R., & Edenhofer, O. (2008). Global trading versus linking: Archi-tectures for international emissions trading. Potsdam, Germany: Potsdam Institute for Cli-mate Impact Research.

Friberg, L. (2008). Certified good? International biofuels certification as a form of non state driven market governance. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the International Stud-ies Association’s 49th Annual Convention, Bridging Multiple Divides, Hilton San Fran-cisco, CA.

Fuhr, H., Lederer, M., & Schröder, M. (2007). Climate protection and development politics: The contribution of private companies. In T. Risse & U. Lehmkuhl (Eds.), Ruling without the state? Governance in areas of limited statehood (pp. 292-308). Baden-Baden, Germany: Nomos.

Genschel, P., & Zangl, B. (2007). The fragmentation of statehood and the centrality of the state. Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte, 20-21, 10-16.

Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91, 481-510.

Holzinger, K., & Knill, C. (2005). Causes and conditions of cross-national policy convergence. Journal of European Public Policy, 12, 775-796.

International Rivers Network. (2008). Bad deal for the planet. Why carbon offsets aren’t work-ing and how to create a fair global climate accord. Berkeley, CA: Author.

Jänicke, M., & Klaus, J. (2006). Lead markets for environmental innovations: A new role for the nation state. In M. Jänicke & J. Klaus (Eds.), Environmental governance in global per-spective. New approaches to ecological and political modernisation: FFU Report 01-2006 (pp. 30-50). Berlin, Germany: Freie Universität Berlin.

Jordan, A., Wurzel, R. K. W., & Zito, A. R. (2007). New modes of environmental governance. In K. Jacob, P. H. Feindt, P.-O. Busch, & F. Biermann (Eds.), Politics and Society. PVS special edition 39 (pp. 283-298). Wiesbaden, Germany: VS-Verlag.

Kerr, C. (1983). The future of industrial societies: Convergence or continuing diversity?Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Knill, C. (2005). Introduction. Journal of European Public Policy, 12, 764-775.Ladwig, B., Jugov, T., & Schmelzle, C. (2007). Governance, Normativität und begrenzte

Staatlichkeit. (SFB-GovernanceWorking Paper Series, No. 4). Berlin, Germany: DFG Sonderforschungsbereich 700.

Larson, D. F., Ambrosi, P., Dinar, A., Rahman, S. M., & Entler, R. (2008). Carbon markets, institutions, policies, and research. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Leibfried, S., & Zürn, M. (Eds.). (2006). Transformation des Staates? Frankfurt/ Main,Germany: Suhrkamp.

Luhmann, H.-J., & Sterk, W. (2008). Climate targets: Should they be met at home or where it is cheapest? Berlin, Germany: Friedrich-Ebert Stiftung.

Lütz, S. (2007). Policy-transfer and policy-diffusion. In A. Benz, S. Lütz, U. Schimank, & G. Simonis (Eds.), Handbook Governance. Theoretical foundations and empirical fields (pp.132-143). Wiesbaden, Germany: VS-Verlag.

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 19: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

344 The Journal of Environment & Development 18(4)

Michaelowa, A., & Purohit, P. (2007). Additionality determination of Indian CDM projects: Can Indian CDM project developers outwit the CDM Executive Board. Zurich, Switzerland: University of Zurich.

Newell, P. (2005). Towards a political economy of global environmental governance. In P. Dauvergne (Ed.), Handbook of global environmental politics (pp. 187-201). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

Newell, R. G., Sanchirico, J. N., & Kerr, S. (2005). Fishing quota markets. Journal of Environ-mental Economics and Management, 49, 437-462.

Pattberg, P. (2005). What role for private rule-making in global environmental governance? Analysing the forest stewardship council (FSC). International Environmental Agreements, 5, 175-189.

Pattberg, P. (2007). Private institutions and global governance: The new politics of environmen-tal sustainability. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

Point Carbon. (2008). Carbon 200: Post-2012 is now. Oslo, Norway: Author.Polanyi, K. (1957). The great transformation. The political and economic origins of our time.

Boston: Beacon Press. (Original work published 1944)Risse, T. & Lehmkuhl, U. (2007). Ruling without the state? Governance in areas of limited

statehood. In T. Risse & U. Lehmkuhl (Eds.), Ruling without the state? Governance in areas of limited statehood (pp. 13-40). Baden-Baden, Germany: Nomos.

Roberts, T. J., & Parks, B. C. (2007). A climate of injustice. Global inequality, north-south poli-tics, and climate policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Rogers, E. M. (2003). Diffusion of Innovations (5th ed.). New York: Free Press.Rose, R. (1993). Lesson-drawing in public policy. Chatham, NJ: Chatham House.Schick, A. (1998). Why most developing countries should not try New Zealand’s reforms.

World Bank Research Observer, 13, 123-131.Schneider, L. (2007). Is the CDM fulfilling its environmental and sustainable development

objectives? An evaluation of the CDM and options for improvement. Report prepared for the WWF. Berlin, Germany: Öko-Institut.

Schreurs, M. A. (2008a). From the bottom Up: Local and subnational climate change politics. Journal of Environment & Development, 17, 343-355.

Schreurs, M. A. (2008b). What the experiences have taught us. In E. Altvater & A. Brunnen-gräber (Eds.), Selling of indulgences against climate change? Market-based instruments in global climate politics and their alternatives (pp. 21-34). Hamburg, Germany: VS Verlag.

Schröder, M. (2008). The construction of China’s climate politics: Transnational NGOs and the spiral model of international relations. Cambridge Review of International Affairs, 21, 505-525.

Schuppert, F.G. (2007). What is governance and what do we need it for? Die Verwaltung, 4, 463-511.

Simmons, B., & Elkins, Z. (2004). The globalization of liberalization: Policy diffusion in the international political economy. American Political Science Review, 98, 171-189.

Skjaerseth, J. B., & Wettestad, J. (2008). EU emissions trading: Initiation, decision-making and implementation. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate.

Stern, N. (2007). The economics of climate change. The stern review. Cambridge, MA:Cambridge University Press.

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Page 20: The Journal of Environment & Developmentenvironmentportal.in/files/Varieties of Carbon Governance... Development The Journal of Environment & DOI: 10.1177/1070496509347079 The Journal

Fuhr and Lederer 345

Stone, D. (2004). Transfer agents and global networks in the “transnationalization” of policy. Journal of European Public Policy, 11, 545-566.

Streck, C. (2007). The governance of the clean development mechanism: The case for strength and stability. Environmental Liability, 2, 91-100.

United Nations Environment Programme. (2009). UNEP risoe CDM/ JI pipeline analysis and database. Available from www.uneprisoe.org

United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. (2007, December 18). Kyoto protocol’s clean development mechanism passes 100 millionth certified emission reduc-tion milestone. Retrieved January 14, 2009, 2009, from http://unfccc.int/files/press/releases/application/pdf/20071218_100_mio_cer_press_release_final.pdf

Voß, J.-P. (2007). Policy instruments as innovation in governance: The case of emission trad-ing. Öko-Institut Working Paper. Freiburg, Germany: Öko Institut.

Wara, M., & Victor, D. G. (2008). A realistic policy on international carbon offsets (Program on Energy and Sustainable Development Working Paper No. 74). Stanford, CA: Program on Energy and Sustainable Development, Stanford University.

Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and anti-trust. New York: Free Press.

Wurzel, R. K. W., Jordan, A., Zito, A. R., & Brückner, L. (2003). From high regulatory state to social and ecological market economy? “New” environmental policy instruments in Ger-many. In A. Jordan, R. K. W. Wurzel, & A. R. Zito (Eds.), New instruments of environmental governance (pp. 115-137). London: Frank Cass.

Bios

Harald Fuhr holds the chair of international politics at the University of Potsdam and is coor-dinating the research project D3 “New Modes of Governance in Climate Protection: Green Companies in Newly Industrialising Countries” of the Collaborative Research Centre SFB 700 “Governance in Areas of Limited Statehood.”

Markus Lederer is an assistant professor at the chair of international politics at the University of Potsdam and assistant project manager of the research project D3 “New Modes of Gover-nance in Climate Protection: Green Companies in Newly Industrialising Countries” of the Collaborative Research Centre SFB 700 “Governance in Areas of Limited Statehood.”

at CNTR SCI AND ENVIRONMENT on February 3, 2010 http://jed.sagepub.comDownloaded from


Recommended