+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple...

Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple...

Date post: 28-Jun-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 5 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
36
Ki-Young Sung / Sookmyung Women’s UniversityABSTRACT This paper aims to provide an adequate theoretical interpretation of the South Korean government’s North Korea policy led by Kim Dae Jung with a particular focus on his attempts to promote inter-Korean trade under political hostility. It finds the so-called ‘Jŏngkyŏng Bulli’ initiative and permission of inter-Korean contact through multiple channels as key elements that facilitated uninterrupted growth of trade between the two Koreas while the military confrontation still prevailed. As a preliminary analytical framework to explain the substantial changes in inter-Korean relations during the Kim Dae Jung presidency, this paper proposes complex interdependence model as an ideal type of relationship. The model reflects a key pattern of changes in international relations, typified by transnational interaction and asymmetrical reciprocity, and these notions also create a backdrop that generated the Kim Dae Jung policy in establishing improved economic exchanges with the DPRK. Key words: Kim Dae Jung, inter-Korean economic exchange, complex interdependence model ※ 논문투고일: 2012. 6. 11. 논문심사일: 2012. 8. 6. 게재확정일: 2012. 8. 13. Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic Exchanges: Complex interdependence model
Transcript
Page 1: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung / Sookmyung Women’s University44)

ABSTRACT

This paper aims to provide an adequate theoretical interpretation of the South

Korean government’s North Korea policy led by Kim Dae Jung with a particular

focus on his attempts to promote inter-Korean trade under political hostility. It finds

the so-called ‘Jŏngkyŏng Bulli’ initiative and permission of inter-Korean contact

through multiple channels as key elements that facilitated uninterrupted growth of

trade between the two Koreas while the military confrontation still prevailed. As a

preliminary analytical framework to explain the substantial changes in inter-Korean

relations during the Kim Dae Jung presidency, this paper proposes complex

interdependence model as an ideal type of relationship. The model reflects a key

pattern of changes in international relations, typified by transnational interaction and

asymmetrical reciprocity, and these notions also create a backdrop that generated

the Kim Dae Jung policy in establishing improved economic exchanges with the DPRK.

Key words: Kim Dae Jung, inter-Korean economic exchange, complex interdependence model

※ 논문투고일: 2012. 6. 11. 논문심사일: 2012. 8. 6. 게재확정일: 2012. 8. 13.

Theorization of Kim Dae Jung’s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic Exchanges:Complex interdependence model

Page 2: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

244 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

Ⅰ. Introduction

Much has been studied to identify an appropriate theoretical construction to

explain the unconventional ‘Sunshine Policy’ led by the ROK president Kim Dae

Jung. But relatively little attention has been paid to how to link (or delink) security

and economic exchange issues in dealing with the provocative regime in the

DPRK. More importantly, the majority of the scholarly works on the security (or

insecurity)-trade relationship under the Kim Dae Jung leadership put an analytical

focus on whether and to what extent the economic exchanges between the two

Koreas contributed to reducing the military tension on the Korean Peninsula.

On the contrary, little attention has been drawn to the reverse causal relationship:

whether and how much the military tension affected the existing level of trade

relationship? In an empirical side of the relevant researches too, scholars and

policymakers faced curious puzzles: how to explain the coexistence of military

insecurity and flourished trade relationship during the Kim Dae Jung presidency and

what to be the adequate theoretical frame to understand this contradictory

phenomenon. This paper is an attempt to answer these questions.

This paper finds complex interdependence model proposed by Keohane and Nye

as a preliminary analytical framework to explain the key changes of inter-Korean

relations accomplished throughout the Kim Dae Jung era.1) At the same time, it

also shed light on the background factors that engendered the complex interdependence

model by focusing on ‘transnational interactions’ and ‘asymmetrical reciprocity’ and

finds similarities of these notions to the Kim Dae Jung policy. By synthesizing

1) Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye published the first edition of ‘Power and Interdependence’ in 1977. Ten years later, they published a fresh article entitled ‘Power and Interdependence revisited’ to respond to the criticisms which had been made by both liberals and realists over the intervening ten years. They reformulated the relationship between military force and economic means as a bargaining tool under complex interdependence in this article. As they published the second edition of ‘Power and Interdependence’ in 1989, they included the revised version of ‘Power and Interdependence revisited’ as an afterword for a fuller discussion. In this paper, the second edition of ‘Power and Interdependence’ will be used as a main text from which the authors’ conceptions will be cited.

Page 3: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 245

these analytical attempts and the empirical findings in the Kim Dae Jung era, this

paper concludes that his ‘Jŏngkyŏung Bulli’ (separation between politics and

economy) initiative combined by the permission of ‘multiple channels’ in

inter-Korean contact paved the way to facilitate inter-Koran trade under the political

confrontation.

This paper is composed of five parts. The following section starts off by

examining the existing theoretical works on how security (or insecurity) affects

trade relationship between states and vice versa. The second part, as an alternative

way to explain Kim Dae Jung’s attempts to broaden a scope of exchange and

diversify actors in inter-Korean relations, explains key features of complex interdependence

model. This section pays intensive attention to a key pattern of changes that engendered

the model by delineating notions of transnational interaction and asymmetrical reciprocity.

The third part reviews the theoretical interpretations on the Kim Dae Jung policy

focusing on security-economy nexus and points out the limitations of those works.

The next part demonstrates applicability of the complex interdependence model in

analyzing the substantial changes. It is followed by concluding remarks and some

suggestions for the future research in the last section.

Ⅱ. Economic interdependence and security

Modern international relations theories intensively explored the questions of

whether and how economic interaction, mainly measured in terms of trade, affects

international security relationship. The theoretical arguments linking economic

interaction and security had as long a tradition as the classical realist-liberalism

debate of international politics. As a result, it showed a similar division mirroring

the contending strands of the classical international relations theory drawn from

liberalism and realism. The earlier version of liberal argument on the significance

of economic interaction to allay the likelihood of military conflict was created by

Richard Cobden in the 1850s. As Cain rightly observed, he simply asserted that

international commerce had a panacea-like power in an industrial world to prevent

and nullify warfare.2) Cobden, as an enthusiastic advocate of free trade, went on to

Page 4: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

246 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

argue that even the colonial attitudes by Western countries in an attempt to acquire

rare resources could be restrained by freer trading relationship. Free trade was not

only morally required but also commercially efficient instrument, in his idealistic

vision, to achieve international peace.

This pacifying effect of trade was reemphasized by Norman Angell before and

even after the First World War.3) He saw a new way of thinking, namely

commercial-basis trade instead of old method of power politics and war, was able

to inhibit likely interstate violence and, as a consequence, to promote peace between

states involved. States retain greater preference of maintaining trade bonds, according

to his formulation, to destruction of the trade partnership in an attempt to pursue a

higher ground in political relations. Although war nevertheless breaks out between

major powers regardless of the anticipated gain from peaceful trade, it was political

leaders’ miscalculation or ignorance on the unprofitable result of war that makes it

extremely likely, Angell argued.

The liberal arguments that had been made by Cobden and Angell were inherited

and more extensively synthesized by Richard Rosecrance.4) Central to his argument

was that states can achieve their goals through trade with other countries than by

trying to conquer and assimilate large tracts of land. His neatly summarized

argument laid a foundation upon which many other liberal theorists could advance

‘trade promotes peace’ thesis in a various fashion. The most compelling of these is

that trade generates mutual benefit but conflict will destroy it. One of the shared

assumptions by the liberals is that political leaders are deterred, before making a

decision on whether or not to take military action against key trading partners, by

the fear of likely loss or reduction of welfare gains from trading with them.5)

2) Peter Cain, “Capitalism, war and internationalism in the thought of Richard Cobden,” British Journal of International Studies 5, no. 3 (October 1979),pp. 229-247.

3) Norman Angell, The Great Illusion, 2nd edition (New York: G.P.Putnam’s Sons, 1933).

4) Richard Rosecrance, The Rise of Trading States: Commerce and Conquest in the Modern World (New York: Basic Books, 1986).

5) John Oneal and Bruce Russet, “The Classical Liberals Were Right,” International Studies Quarterly 41, no. 2 (June 1997), pp. 267-294; Michael Doyle, Ways of War and Peace: Realism, Liberalism, and Socialism (New York: Norton, 1997); and

Page 5: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 247

On the other hand, the modern realist understanding of economic interactions and

conflict finds its roots in mercantilist thinking dating from the seventeenth century.

The mercantilists’ fundamental assumption that states need to secure greater control

over economically essential goods by lessening economic dependence on other

states provides realists with key logic to develop their argument on the relationship

between economic interactions and conflict.6) The realists understand that economic

interactions will deepen and widen the level of mutual dependence between states

and lead to a friction because of the willingness of sates to secure the goods they

lacked. It has been argued particularly true when the states pursued economic

interactions of strategic goods and materials which underpin their security.

For Kenneth Waltz, for example, economic interactions that go with specialization,

in other words international division of labor, bring about high interdependence and

in turn states are worried lest they become more dependent on others.7) For John

Mearsheimer, states may try to extend political control to the source of supply,

giving rise to conflict with the source. High level of economic interdependence,

therefore, will probably lead to greater security competition.8) In the realist arguments,

strategic security concerns are more emphasized in understanding interstate economic

interactions rather than economic short-term benefit. As a result, it is believed that

states have incentives to take coercive or even military action to reduce their

economic vulnerability from increased trade and interdependence and to influence

its adversary’s behavior.9)

Solomon Polachek, “Conflict and Trade,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 24, no. 1 (March 1980), pp. 55-78.

6) Lars Magnusson, Mercantilism: The Shaping of an Economic Language (London: Routledge, 1994); Jacob Viner, “Power versus Plenty as Objectives of Foreign Policy in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries,” World Politics 1, no. 1 (March 1948), pp. 1-29.

7) Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (Reading: Addison-Wesley, 1979), pp. 160-161.

8) John Mearsheimer, “Disorder Restored,” in Graham Allison and Gregory F.Treverton eds., Rethinking America’s Security (New York: W.W.Norton, 1992), p. 223.

9) David Baldwin, Economic Statecraft (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1985); Kal Holsti, “Politics in Command: Foreign Trade as National Security Policy,” International Organization 40, no. 3 (June 1986), pp. 643-671; and Peter Liberman, Does Conquest

Page 6: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

248 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

Despite this prolonged debate between the two contending perspectives, insufficient

attention has been paid to the inverse causal mechanism: whether and to what

extent militarized conflict affects trade between the two countries involved. A

handful of studies that had tackled this question were built on the shared assumption,

whether those works were derived from realist or liberal tradition, that militarized

conflict inhibits, if not destroys, the existing level of economic exchanges.10)

Liberals argue that conflict will disrupt trade or at least adversely affect the

terms of trade. The liberal hypotheses were built on the assumption that conflict

increases the risk of trade disruption and generally implies the increased cost of

doing business. Therefore, they expect that bilateral trade flows will decline as

bilateral political relations become less friendly.11) Realist explanations suggest that

the concern over relative gains will lead at least one of the belligerents to

terminate trade in order to prevent its adversary from using the gains from trade to

increase its relative military power.12) Employing the realist interpretation, Gowa

expects more trade between allied countries than with neutrals or enemies.13) Realist

Pay? The Exploitation of Occupied Industrial Societies (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996). However, the liberal-realist dichotomy does not apply to other scholars who have sought more synthetic approach, For example, Gasiorowski distinguishes simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict whereas the latter leads to increase conflict. Soroos and de Vries find that interdependence increases both cooperation and conflict. See Mark Gasiorowski, “Economic Interdependence and International Conflict: Some Cross-National Evidence,” International Studies Quarterly 30, no. 1 (March 1986), pp. 23-38; Marvin Soroos, “Behavior Between Nations,” Peace Research Review 7, no. 2 (April 1977), pp. 1-107; and Michael de Vries, “Interdependence, Cooperation and Conflict: An Empirical Analysis,” Journal of Peace Research 27, no. 4 (November 1990), pp. 429-444. respectively.

10) Katherine Barbieri and Jack Levy, “Sleeping with the Enemy: The Impact of War on Trade,” Journal of Peace Research 36, no. 4 (July 1999), pp. 463-66.

11) Brian Pollins, “Conflict, Cooperation, and Commerce: The Effect of International Political Interactions on Bilateral Trade Flows,” American Journal of Political Science 33, no. 3 (1989), pp. 737-761; Peter van Bergeijk, Economic Diplomacy, Trade, and Commercial Policy: Positive and Negative Sanctions in a New World Order (Vermont: Edward Elgar, 1994).

12) Joseph Grieco, Cooperation among nations: Europe, America, Non-tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1990); Waltz, Theory of International Politics.

Page 7: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 249

explanation also consolidated the belief that physical confrontation largely hampers

the flow of trade between the two parties.

Unlike these widely accepted arguments in international relations (IR) theories,

trade and investment between the ROK and the DPRK after Kim Dae Jung’s

taking power showed continued growth despite the ongoing political confrontation

between the two countries. For example, inter-Korean trade volume when Kim Dae

Jung came to power in 1998 was around 222 million USD but it became more

than 700 million USD in 2003 when he left office.14) More importantly, the even

higher growth of inter-Korean trade during the second nuclear crisis, which initially

erupted in 2002 and dominated a security climate on the Korean Peninsula, raised

a question that the hitherto hypotheses about influence of militarized conflict on

economic interactions need to be retested.

To elucidate what caused this contradictory move, this study will portray

substantial changes of actors and dynamics that had framed inter-Korean relations,

mostly accomplished throughout the Kim Dae Jung presidency, and attempt to

explain it by the complex interdependence model. The underlying assumption in

this paper is that the major environment which shaped the political climate

surrounding inter-Korean trade, even during the second nuclear crisis, had already

been formed during Kim Dae Jung’s tenure. This paper argues that, in accordance

with this assumption, the evolved pattern of inter-Korean engagement after the

inter-Korean summit in 2000, which is akin to complex interdependence, offers a

useful framework to understand the coexistence of political confrontation and

unflinching trade relationship.

Ⅲ. Complex Interdependence model

Complex interdependence model spawned from the post-war period realism-

13) Joanne Gowa, Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994).

14) Ministry of Unification, Tongil Paeksŏ [Unification White Paper] (Seoul: Ministry of Unification, 2010).

Page 8: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

250 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

dominated IR studies and the challenges by a group of thinkers. After the wars,

classical realist arguments gained undisputable explanatory power in analyzing the

then interstate relationship and predicting how the relationship is going to develop

in the future post-war world by predominantly emphasizing the supremacy of

power, security, self-interest, and conflict. They acknowledged a state as the only

rational actor in international relations and inter-state cooperation is highly unlikely

even by accord or law in anarchical nature of international politics.15)

On the other hand, other group of thinkers suggested that states can cooperate

within commonly agreed economic and political framework for their mutual benefit.

As Mitrany argued, the cooperation between states initially occurs in technical areas

where it was mutually convenient, but once successful it could ‘spill over’ into

other functional areas.16) In this regard, cooperative probability through non-governmental

elites, one of the foundational claims of functionalism, later constituted key notions

in developing interdependence theory.

It should be noted that, as Richard Cooper earlier asserted that all economic

relationships entails costly aspects, the theory of interdependence initially developed

from the need to assess the costs rather than benefits, in other words, the burdens

of adjustment forced upon them.17) However, by demonstrating ‘opportunity costs of

severing the existing relationship’, a group of interdependence theorists successfully

transformed it into an efficient tool to explain a motive for cooperation rather than

a source of conflict.18) Among them, Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye suggested

extensive view to shed light on the cooperative relationship between states without

recourse on military force by formulating a new ideal type of international

15) Hans Morgenthau, Politics among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, 6th edition (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1985).

16) David Mitrany, A Working Peace System (Chicago: Quadrangle Press, 1966), pp. 350-363.

17) Richard Cooper, The Economics of Interdependence: Economic Policy in the Atlantic Community (London and New York: McGraw Hill for the Council on Foreign Relations, 1968). Realist explanations on the interdependence consistently emphasized the vulnerability aspects of interdependence, indicating political weakness coming from dependent relationship with others. See Waltz, Theory of International Politics, p. 138.

18) David Baldwin, “Interdependence and power: a conceptual analysis,” International Organization 34, no. 4 (Autumn 1980), pp. 481-486.

Page 9: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 251

relationship called complex interdependence.

Such an attempt was a challenge to the IR scholars who had paid intensive

attention to the use of economic means such as trade for the purpose of accomplishing

a state’s security objective in a political arena. Since Albert Hirschman had published

his pioneering work on the power and influence of economic means-quotas, exchange

control, and other instruments of economic warfare-in establishing and developing

statecraft, economic interactions between states have largely been studied as part of

national foreign policy to enhance relative gain of the particular state.19)

However, Keohane and Nye showed that two states can be brought together not

only by state to state diplomacy but also by involvement of a variety level of

non-state elites. Under the complex interdependence model they theorized, interstate

interactions are likely to occur outside the realm of statecraft by government,

attracting multiple actors in multiple issue areas through multiple channel among

societies. Further, Keohane and Nye made a contribution to building a comprehensive

theoretical structure to address how the various level of individual actors create a

web of cooperative structure by widening their scope of analysis from simple

bargaining practice to systemic approach to the international politics.20)

Complex interdependence, as a notion to fill the theoretical space that realists

insufficiently explained, has three main characteristics. First, under complex interdependence

in international relations, interstate interaction comes from the informal ties among

non-governmental elites such as businessmen and academics, as well as intergovernmental

dialogues. The non-governmental elites are able to create their own communication

channels by the development of telecommunications without being entirely controlled

by governments. Second, under complex interdependence, the foreign affairs agenda

become increasingly broader and more diversified. The sets of interstate agenda also

lack strict hierarchy among themselves as the distinction between domestic and

19) Albert Hirschman, National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade (Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1945).

20) But it does not rule out the use of complex interdependence model to analyze a dyadic level relationship. One of the major parts of their case studies in ‘Power and Interdependence’ focused on America’s bilateral relationship with Canada and Australia. See Keohane and Nye, Power and Interdependence, chapter 7.

Page 10: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

252 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

foreign issues becomes blurred. Military security that political realists exclusively

emphasized no longer dominates other multiple issues representing the interests of

various domestic groups. Third, complex interdependence causes a decrease in influence

of military force as an instrument to achieve an individual nation’s goals. Military

force shows limited usefulness and loses its prior standing as a dominant source of

power as it was costly and uncertain in the era of complex interdependence.21)

This formulation of the key characteristics of the complex interdependence model

was a product of observation on how actors engage in cooperative endeavour in

international politics. As the proponents spelled out, it was an explanation on the

pattern of change during the 1970s and 1980s.22) Thus it seems useful to go over

this pattern of change prior to tackling empirical cases on inter-Korean relations.

This paper sums up the features upon which the complex interdependence model

has been developed with two notions: asymmetrical reciprocity and transnational

interactions.

Reciprocity was one of the most frequently quoted notions when dealing with

cooperative behavior between states. According to Keohane, the concept of reciprocity

in international politics was characterized by two common features: contingency and

equivalence. He defined it as ‘exchanges of roughly equivalent values in which the

actions of each party are contingent on the prior actions of the others in such a

way that good is returned for good, and bad for bad’. It meant, if two states want

to forge reciprocal relationship in international politics, they ought to respond to

each other’s political actions with equivalent values of reward. One actor’s immediate

response to the other’s actions and affirmative consideration of what the other

desires to gain could be the main factors to strengthen reciprocity in a given

bilateral relation.23)

The notion of reciprocity as one of the conceptual elements that engendered the

complex interdependence model did not necessarily focus on dealing with mutually

beneficial effects of equal weight between actors in terms of their political, economic

21) Keohane and Nye, Power and Interdependence, pp. 24-29.22) Ibid., p. xi.23) Robert Keohane, “Reciprocity in international relations,” International Organization

40, no. 1 (Spring 1986), pp. 5-8.

Page 11: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 253

or military capability. What needs to be more emphasized to explore inter-Korean

relations is an asymmetrical aspect of reciprocity as one of the most influential

elements in shaping one actor’s behavior toward another. The asymmetric nature of

reciprocal relationship is deeply concerned with the widened economic gap between

South and North Korea after the demise of the Cold War.

IGO

G1 G2

S1 S2

G1-G2 : Classic interstate politicsG1-S1 : Domestic politicsG1-S2/G2-S1/S1-IGO/S2-IGO: Transnational interactions

G = GovernmentS = SocietyIGO = Intergovernmental organization

Source: Keohane and Nye (1972) ‘Transnational Relations and World Politics: An Introduction’, p.xiv.

Figure1. Transnational interactions and interstate politics

The notion of transnational interactions constituted another principle source, along

with asymmetrical reciprocity, that led to later formulation of the complex interdependence

model. The notion stressed the changing pattern of international contacts that one

could hardly capture through the conventional diplomatic negotiations between states.

The key point here is cross-border transactions by actors not controlled by central

Page 12: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

254 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

foreign policy organs of government. This engendered the following definition of

transnational interactions: ‘movement of tangible or intangible items across state

boundaries when at least one actor is not an agent of a government or an intergovernmental

organization’.24) The key aspect, in this formulation, was the interactions between

state and non-state actors. Figure 1 provides another way looking at the direct

interactions between a government in state A and a non-state actor in state B.

The interactions between state and non-state actors implied that, for non-state

actors, they could enjoy enhanced autonomy from the government’s political

guidelines or bypass the control of the governments when they tried to make a

new channel with their counterparts.

Ⅳ. Existing theoretical interpretation on Kim Dae Jung policy

Kim Dae Jung acknowledged the likelihood of a simultaneous coexistence of

security crisis and trade partnership in framing his foreign policy. He tried to substantiate

his assumption by dealing with the two issues separately. His policy focus was how

to remove the danger of the likely contradiction between the two issues. Rooted in

functionalists’ separability-priority thesis,25) he pursued the ‘Jŏngkyŏng Bulli’ policy

by involving multiple contact channels with the DPRK to show that military conflict

and economic engagement could coexist on different fronts. He placed greater emphasis

on how to ultimately minimize the influence of political conflicts in order to

continue economic engagement. His policy consequently became a building block to

ensure the continuity of inter-Korean trade under political hostility.

There has been a great deal of research on the nexus between security and

economy. However, the scholarly efforts in the IR discipline to understand security

and economy in an interconnected fashion did not provide an adequate analytical

24) Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye, “Transnational Relations and World Politics: An Introduction,” in Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye, eds., Transnational Relations and World Politics (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1972), pp. ix-xii.

25) Inis Claude, Swords into Plowshares: The Problems and Progress of International Organization (New York: Random House, 1964).

Page 13: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 255

framework to explain the Kim Dae Jung administration’s economic engagement

policy with the DPRK by the ‘Jŏngkyŏng Bulli’ and ‘multiple channel policy’.

The origin of the scholarship that tackled how the economic interactions affect

inter-state conflicts dates back to the notion of Kantian Peace. The key logic of the

Kantian Peace conception was encapsulated in Kant’s assertion that ‘the spirit of

commerce cannot coexist with war’.26) The descendants of the Kantian Peace theory

formulated the role of inter-state economic interactions in building and promoting

peaceful relations between nations. The majority of the earlier theoretical attempts

to explain the relationship were built on one solid hypothesis inspired by the Kantian

Peace School. Their key assumption was that constant compatibility of these two

elements was largely unthinkable. The only possibility that could be substantiated by

the history of foreign policy was when and under what conditions a state employed

either integration or a separation strategy of security and economy in its statecraft.27)

As the reality of international interactions became more complex, scholars turned

their attention to how independent actors with clashing interests made efforts to

enhance individual economic prosperity while avoiding military confrontation. Scholars

paid continued attention to the relationship between trade, among other economic

interactions, and peace building processes. They produced contending arguments reflecting

the dichotomy between realism and liberalism. Liberals argued that heightened

economic exchanges inhibited international conflict and that, as a result, commercial

openness contributed to peace-building.28) One shared conclusion of this set of ideas

among liberals was that a nation whose economic interests are deeply entangled

with the other could not use military force to resolve likely conflicts. Even during

the Cold War, it was evident that the intertwined economic interests rendered

military force unusable.29) However, the liberal view has been criticized by many

26) James Bohman and Matthias Lutz-Bachmann eds., Perpetual Peace: Essays on Kant’s cosmopolitan ideal (Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1997).

27) Michael Mastanduno, “Economics and Security in Statecraft and Scholarship,” International Organization 52, no. 4 (Autumn 1998), pp. 825-854.

28) Richard Rosecrance, The Rise of Trading States: Commerce and Conquest in the Modern World (New York: Basic Books, 1986); Carl Kaysen, “Is War Obsolete?,” International Security 14, no. 4 (Spring 1990), pp. 42-64.

29) Robert Art, “To What Ends Military Power,” International Security 4, no. 4 (Spring

Page 14: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

256 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

realists who insisted that uninhibited economic exchange can undermine national

security.30) Realists rather argued that increased trade flows in the end led states to

take military actions in an attempt to reduce their economic vulnerability.31)

Keohane later inherited liberals’ theoretical tradition by labelling it as commercial

liberalism.32) The fundamental assumption of commercial liberalism was built on the

classical economists’ optimistic view over cross-border economic exchanges and their

welfare effects earlier coined as ‘comparative advantage’ by David Ricardo. It was,

however, institutional aspects of the interstate economic exchanges that Keohane prioritized

by the labelling. It was, in his belief, the regularized patterns of economic exchange

and orderly rules that would bring peace in international politics. In the meantime,

economic analyses employing the quantitative statistical method were also attempted

to measure a relationship between war and trade. There were, for example, positivist

attempts and subsequent debates to substantiate whether a war diminishes trade

volumes between enemies or not.33) It should be noted that what these scholars

tried to find was a causal relationship between trade and military clash directed by

state. However, viewing trade simply as one of many causal variables determining

states’ diplomatic or military behavior lost its analytical effectiveness. The old

approach rather resulted in neglecting, when tackling the influence of trade on

international politics, the role of new actors out of government control as well as

broad spectrum of conflict pattern, ranging from verbal condemnation to full-blown

wars. Thereby, they could not provide an answer to explain economic rationality

which could not be controlled by government dictation. The focus in this subfield

1980), pp. 16-17.30) Barry Buzan, “Economic Structure and International Security: The Limits of the Liberal

Case,” International Organization 38, no. 4 (Autumn 1984), pp. 597-624; Holsti, “Politics in Command: Foreign Trade as National Security Policy,” pp. 643-671.

31) Robert Gilpin, Change and War in World Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981), pp. 140-41.

32) Robert Keohane, “International Liberalism Reconsidered,” in John Dunn ed., Economic Limits to Modern Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 177-179.

33) Barbieri and Levy, “Sleeping with the Enemy: The impact of War on Trade.”; Charles Anderton and John Carter, “The Impact of War on Trade: An Interrupted Times-Series Study,” Journal of Peace Research 38, no. 4 (July 2001), pp. 445-457.

Page 15: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 257

was being shifted to the growing transnational economic relations led by new actors

which had previously been underestimated.34) The growth of economic interdependence

by newly-emerged actors and dynamics thus required a new analytical framework.

The old framework failed to capture the essence of change facilitated by transnational

actors. In this vein, two points should be stressed in evaluating the changed reality

of international politics in general and the Kim Dae Jung policy in particular.

First, the existing literature showed the propensity to analyze the security-economy

nexus within an unchanged framework dealing with ‘war and peace’ primarily conducted

by state actors. The literature focused largely on how to enhance a state’s capability

by pursuing a nexus of the two policy tools against its potential adversaries.35) It

did not pay sufficient attention to how to improve the economic potential of the

national community which could be obtained by actively engaging even with hostile

counterparts. Security concerns still prevailed in viewing interstate relationships in

terms of foreign economic policy as long as they were undertaken under military

tension. It underestimated the role of firms and business organizations as key actors

in the newly-emerged transnational economic relations.

The increased attention to economic interest in the transnational environment

required a different approach from the mercantilist assumptions in the past. Yet it

was hard to deny that the security agenda still subordinated economic issues in

tackling the nexus. It meant that the main research agenda was formed surrounding

political decisions by state actors. One example was to mobilize economic means

such as sanctions against the adversary nation.36) Economic requirements remained

in a secondary concern in dealing with linkage politics between security and trade.

Non-state, economic entities such as firms and business organizations, which actually

engaged in the exchange of resources and goods, as a result, were largely sidelined.

The conventional approach, in turn, failed to provide an adequate tool to explain

the situation on the Korean Peninsula. Above all, as non-aggression became the key

agenda in the inter-Korean dialogues,37) the possibility of an all-out war was

34) Gilpin, Change and War in World Politics.35) Mastanduno, “Economics and Security in Statecraft and Scholarship.”36) Klaus Knorr and Frank Trager, Economic Issues and National Security (Lawrence:

University Press of Kansas, 1977).

Page 16: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

258 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

considerably diminished on the Peninsula. The full-scale mobilization of the retained

military capability in the two parties became highly unlikely from the 1990s.38) The

spirit of mutual accommodation began to burgeon instead at least in a limited

sense. This changed military dynamic on the Peninsula weakened the explanatory

power of the existing security-dominated discourse. The decline of the explanatory

utility of the security-led approach was also valid in explaining Kim Dae Jung’s

policy initiative which pursued a ‘delinking’ of the two issues. Kim Dae Jung

made every effort to diminish the impact of the politically hostile relationship

which was likely to hamper inter-Korean economic exchanges.39) The main vehicle

that helped make the separation sustainable throughout his presidency was what he

called ‘Jŏngkyŏng Bulli’ and the ‘multiple channel policy’.

He particularly emphasized the role of subnational actors in the transnational

economic relations between the two Koreas. His government allowed, for the first

time in the history of inter-Korean relations, South Korean firms and civil society

groups greater room to maneuvre in contacting their North Korean counterparts by

relaxing various types of regulations and simplifying administrative procedures.40)

As a consequence, greater involvement of the South Korean non-state actors in

inter-Korean affairs resulted in forming a more complex pattern of economic engagement

with the North.

Coupled with the rising demand of South Korean small business looking for

37) The mood of the inter-Korean non-aggression culminated when the two Koreas agreed to sign the ‘Basic agreement for reconciliation, non-aggression, exchange, and cooperation’ in 1992. See Ministry of Unification, Tongil Paeksŏ[Unification White Paper] (Seoul: Unification of Ministry, 1992).

38) David Kang, “North Korea’s Military and Security Policy,” in Samuel Kim ed., North Korean Foreign Relations: In the Post Cold War Era (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1998), pp. 165-186.

39) Dae Jung Kim, Ishipil Sekiwa Hanminchok: Kim Dae Jung chon Daet’ongnyong Chuyo Yŏnsŏl Taedam [Twenty-first century and Korean nation: Selection of speech by the former president Kim Dae Jung] (Paju: Dolbekae, 2004).

40) Se Hyun Jeong “Nampukchŏngsanghoedam Ilchunyŏn pyŏngga [The Assessment of One Year after the Inter-Korean Summit],” in Sejong Institute ed., Nampukchŏngsanghoedamkwa Hanpandopyŏnghwa [Inter-Korean Summit and the Peace in the Korean Peninsula] (Seoul: Sejong Institute, 2001), p. 29.

Page 17: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 259

lower cost production in the North Korean territory, the growing level of transnational

interactions in the post-summit inter-Korean relations paved the way for the more

stable development of a comprehensive pattern of interdependence between the two

Koreas. Comprehensive and structural inter-Korean economic relations were supported

by involvement of the South Korean business community that had strong reasons to

press the government not to jeopardize their gains from inter-Korean trade.

Kim Dae Jung made clear, just before his summit with Kim Jong Il, that his

government would aggressively encourage private sector cooperation and exchanges

in inter-Korean relations. What he particularly stressed was the inter-Korea trade

and the Mount Kumkang tourism projects. His emphasis on private sector cooperation

and exchange further broadened and diversified the actors involved in inter-Korean

engagement. He also made an effort to insulate inter-Korean economic exchanges

by private sectors from the anticipated political unrest on the Korean Peninsula by

introducing the principle of ‘Jŏngkyŏng Bulli’ in his North Korea policy.41)

Moreover, as the scope of cooperation expanded, it became essential to involve

many other non-state actors that had previously not been part of inter-Korean

interactions. It included local governments, a variety of quasi-governmental agencies

not necessarily belonging to the Foreign Office / Ministry of Unification, and many

other subnational organizations.

Given those new waves in inter-Korean relations-weakening of security-dominated

agenda formation and diversified actors involved-the existing theoretical interpretations

on the security-economy nexus showed limitations in explaining Kim Dae Jung’s

North Korea policy.

Second, the security-trade nexus literature did not consider, with sufficient care,

the increasing asymmetrical interdependence between states and between actors. The

international politics portrayed by the security-trade nexus literature still reflected

the political climate that required immediate actions and counteractions. The most

viable option for a state to guarantee its sustainable prosperity was to select one of

two choices. They were either to attack its adversarial power or to take defensive

41) Young Yoon Kim, Evaluation of South-North Economic Cooperation and Task for Success (Seoul: Korea Institute for National Unification, 2005).

Page 18: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

260 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

action against a given external threat as immediately as possible. The most

significant task for a state commonly argued in the literature was to create a

driving force to enhance its prosperity, removing the likelihood of military clash.

The key logic of the game theory42) and the prisoner’s dilemma literature43) was

built on the necessity and inevitability of strictly ‘conditional’ application of

positive inducements.44)

As a variety of non-state actors emerged, however, the reality in international

politics began to change. New actors such as multinational corporations (MNCs)

and civil organizations began to take an indispensible role in international politics.

This phenomenon engendered and fostered ‘transnational interactions’45) among

them. It provided a bigger space in which incentives and counterincentives by state

and non-state actors could be interchanged. Changed world politics did not

necessarily require bilateral balancing and strict equivalence between actors at the

same level. Immediate repayment of political and economic debts by state actors in

a strictly bilateral context was becoming less essential. The more realistic pattern of

interactions between actors began to be disputed. It was an ‘overall’ balance

‘within a group’ argued mainly by neoliberal school scholars.46)

One of the closest approximations to the changes of interaction pattern was the

notion of ‘diffuse reciprocity’ conceptualized by Keohane.47) He stressed that the

42) Duncan Snidal, “The Game Theory of International Politics,” World Politics 38, no. 1 (October 1985), pp. 25-57; James Morrow, Game Theory for Political Scientists (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994).

43) Stuart Oskamp, “Effects of Programmed Strategies on Cooperation in the Prisoner’s Dilemma and Other Mixed-Motive Games,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 15, no. 2 (June 1971), pp. 225-259; Warner Wilson, “Reciprocation and other Techniques for Inducing Cooperation in the Prisoner’s Dilemma Game,” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 15, no. 2 (June 1971), pp. 167-195.

44) The concept of conditional action constitutes one of the classical defining characteristics of reciprocity. For discussion, see Alvin Gouldner, “The Norm of Reciprocity: A Preliminary Statement,” American Sociological Review 25, no. 2 (April 1960), pp. 161-178.

45) Keohane and Nye, “Transnational Relations and World Politics: An Introduction.” 46) Robert Keohane, “Reciprocity in international relations,” International Organization

40, no. 1 (December 1986), pp. 15-18.47) Ibid., pp. 19-24. The distinction of ‘balanced reciprocity’ and ‘generalized reciprocity’

Page 19: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 261

asymmetry of reciprocity enabled actors to cooperate with one another without

immediate counterconcession and demonstrated that less strict and less clearly

specified equivalence could safeguard the continuity of cooperation. According to

this formulation, a state’s action can be compensated in a different sequence. The

major factors that made the continued cooperation sustainable were shared commitments

and values and upgraded mutual trust and so on.

Kim Dae Jung’s ‘Sunshine Policy’ apparently had a significant similarity to ‘diffuse

reciprocity’. The ‘Sunshine Policy’ most of all was built on the premise that the

outcome of inter-Korean negotiations does not necessarily have to guarantee ‘equivalent’

value exchanges and ‘immediate’ interactions. His policy is rather understood as a

manifestation of ‘sequential exchange’, a key element of diffuse reciprocity48) in

striving to elicit reactions from the Kim Jong Il regime at any given time rather

than within a strictly finite time frame.

The notion of ‘diffuse reciprocity’, however, could not adequately explain the

inter-Korean engagement led by Kim Dae Jung. His approach toward the DPRK

allowed a more flexible type of reciprocation than what was implied by the

‘diffuse reciprocity’. He was aware that, under the situation where South and North

Korea had asymmetrical issue preferences, the South’s insistence on reciprocity

might be perceived, for the North, as a disguised type of unilateralism.49)

In his inaugural speech, Kim Dae Jung made clear that his government unequivocally

opposed the way of reunification by absorbing weaker DPRK despite the ever-

expanding, overwhelming superiority that the ROK had been enjoying in economic

and military capability.50) The flexibility he accepted overlaid the South’s political

desire to take full advantage of the North’s weakness seeking for its comprehensive

by Sahlins was also useful to understand the asymmetry of reciprocity. See Marshall Sahlins, Stone Age Economics (Chicago: Aldine-Atherton, 1972), p. 194.

48) Ibid., p.22.49) Kun Young Park, “Taepukchŏngch’aekŭi Saeroun Chŏpkun [New approach of North

Korea Policy],” Kukchechongch’inonch’ong [International Politics Studies] 38, no. 2 (1998), p. 103.

50) Kim, Ishipil Sekiwa Hanminchok: Kim Dae Jung chon Daet’ongnyong Chuyo Yŏnsŏl Taedam [Twenty-first century and Korean nation: Selection of speech by the former president Kim Dae Jung].

Page 20: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

262 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

upper-hand.

Kim Dae Jung’s initiative that stressed ‘flexible reciprocity’ constituted a major

factor which could replace the neorealist understanding of inter-Korean relations in

the previous administrations. This political situation reduced the efficiency and

usefulness of the so-called ‘tit-for-tat’ strategy.51)

Put differently, the approach on how to create more flexible reciprocal relations

with Pyongyang was at variance with Kim Dae Jung’s predecessor, who had

remained rigid in insisting on immediate give-and-take style reciprocity.52) Kim Dae

Jung made clear that his government would not stick to the logic of a ‘zero-sum’

game in dealing with the DPRK. This implied the South Korean government would

not oppose relative gains by the DPRK as long as inter-Korean cooperation enhanced

the ROK’s absolute gains in economic interest like trade expansion. This initiative

produced more active engagement by South Korean firms and civil society that

were willing either to invest or to provide humanitarian aid to the DPRK. Kim Dae

Jung’s ‘flexible reciprocity’ consequently broadened the issue areas and diversified the

relevant actors in inter-Korean relations.

Another example of ‘flexible reciprocity’ was the asymmetrical holding of the

two inter-Korean summits talks. After the first summit in 2000, Kim Dae Jung did

not immediately urge Kim Jong Il ‘to offer a quick lunch in return for his formal

dinner’. The next inter-Korean summit plan already agreed in 2000 between the

two leaders was not implemented until 2007. It moreover was not between Kim

Jong Il and Kim Dae Jung but between Kim Jong Il and Roh Moo Hyun, the next

president of the ROK.53)

Kim Dae Jung believed that strengthening the DPRK’s infrastructural capacity

51) Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic, 1984).52) Wan Kyu Choi, “Icarusŭi kyohun: Kim Yongsam Chŏngbŭi Taepukchŏngch’aek Shilp’ae

Yoin Punsŏk [The Sad Fate of Icarus: The Kim Yongsam’s Governments Policy toward North Korea],” Hankukkwa Kukchechŏngch’i [Korea and World Politics] 14, no. 2 (1997), pp. 189-212.

53) The Inter-Korean Joint Declaration announced in June 2000 reads that “Kim Dae Jung cordially invited Kim Jong Il to visit Seoul and Kim Jong Il agreed to visit Seoul at an ‘appropriate’ time” (Chosun Ilbo 16th June 2000). But the second summit talk also took place in Pyongyang.

Page 21: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 263

ought to be a policy focus in dealing with the ailing North Korean economy. He

stressed it would bring a more beneficial trade relationship between the two

Koreas. His approach contrasted sharply with the longstanding perception on which

the previous administrations’ North Korea policy was based. The old perception

was that any efforts by the South to remedy the decay of the North’s economic

institutions would result in strengthening the military capacity of its adversary.

Kim Dae Jung, departing this long-running North Korea guideline of the South

governments, encouraged the participation of the ROK business actors in an effort

to strengthen the DPRK’s infrastructural capacity. Providing those who have prepared

inter-Korean business with more discretion and autonomy made a great contribution

to eliciting the engagement of the ROK firms. This circular process of ROK business

involvement development of inter-Korean economic engagement strengthening

of infrastructural capacity to further support the accomplished engagement suggested

a more productive pattern of bilateral relationship than diffuse reciprocity.

His belief on the positive contribution of business actors in creating politically

cooperative relations was based upon the assumption of many liberals. Classical

liberals demonstrated in many different ways that commercial intercourse increased

cross-border contacts and promoted reciprocal communication between private actors

in different countries as well as between governments. Rising contacts and communications,

in turn, were expected to foster cooperative political relations.54) In other words,

they thought subnational actors such as consumers and firms had vested interests in

commerce that led them to restrain the state when conflict is on the horizon lest

the rising hostilities rupture important economic ties. It was especially the case,

under lack of supranational organization around the country-pair involved, that

subnational actors have influence on security policy through their own commercial

interests.55) Kim Dae Jung’s policy based on more liberal and flexible thinking in

54) Albert Hirschman, The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before its Triumph (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1977), pp. 56-63; Michael Doyle, Ways of War and Peace: Realism, Liberalism, and Socialism (New York: Norton, 1997), pp. 251-300.

55) Edward Mansfield and Brian Pollins, “The Study of Interdependence and Conflict: Recent Advances, Open questions, and Directions for Future Research,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 45, no. 6 (December 2001), pp. 834-859.

Page 22: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

264 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

this sense demonstrated the fact that concessions and counterconcessions toward

each other could take place by a different actor in a different group. This meant

that his policy went beyond Keohane’s assertion on the need for compensation

‘within a group’.

The compensation behavior based on diffuse reciprocity, in addition, is believed

to be understood as the means to promote the production of public goods in international

politics. Keohane stressed the importance to adopt a diffuse reciprocity-style standard of

behavior in creating a more cooperative environment in the international regime.56)

What Kim Dae Jung sought to improve through his ‘Sunshine Policy’ did not lie

only within the realm of public goods, and did not place the state’s material and

realistic interest at the top of the agenda. He aimed to incorporate the private

interests of South Korean firms with the political reconciliation (public goods) of

the two Koreas.

His approach to adopt a different track from his predecessors thus adequately

reflected the key pattern of change that had historically shaped the complex interdependence

model. In turn, the manifestation of asymmetrical reciprocity and transnational

interactions in inter-Korean relations laid a foundation to explain the Kim Dae Jung

policy on inter-Korean trade within the key ideas of the ‘Sunshine Policy’.

To summarize, Figure 2 illustrates how to understand the theoretical origin and

its impact of the Kim Dae Jung policy on inter-Korean trade. In this formulation,

the upper part of the ‘Sunshine Policy’ shows the theoretical elements that

generated the Policy in association with complex interdependence model, while the

lower half explains its impact on the promotion of inter-Korean trade through its

methodological initiatives. The following section further elaborates Kim Dae Jung’s

dealing with inter-Korean non-political relations by projecting the key features of

complex interdependence model onto his policy details.

56) Keohane, “Reciprocity in international relations,”p. 20.

Page 23: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 265

Figure2. Explanatory structure of the ‘Sunshine Policy’ and its influence on inter-Korean trade

Ⅴ. New interpretation: Complex interdependence model

1. No issue hierarchy

Kim Dae Jung abandoned an obsession with the negotiation agenda resulting

from the Cold-War legacy, in dealing with the DPRK, such as legitimacy rivalry,

military build-up, and ideological confrontation. By making a commitment not to

pursue the downfall of the increasingly unstable communist regime, he achieved a

remarkable expansion of inter-Korean economic, political, and cultural ties.57)

He suggested a ‘comprehensive engagement’ as a means to dissuade the DPRK

from taking military action to counter perceived threats from external powers. The

57) Chung-in Moon and David Steinberg, Kim Dae-jung Government and Sunshine Policy (Seoul: Yonsei University Press, 1999); Soon Young Hong, “Thawing Korea’s Cold War: The Path to Peace on the Korean Peninsula,” Foreign Affairs 78, no. 3 (May/June 1999), pp. 8-12.

Page 24: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

266 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

comprehensive engagement was understood as a process mobilizing all possible

means that a status quo power could employ to induce its enemy state to change

its behavior.58) He spelled out in the Inter-Korean Joint Declaration, as a result of

the summit with Kim Jong Il, that he would pursue even more practical steps than

the previous administrations toward enhanced inter-Korean economic, social, and

cultural exchanges and cooperation.59) In the wake of the summit agreement, the

military dynamic, building on ‘zero sum’ logic, no longer exclusively dominated the

negotiation agenda in the inter-Korean political dialogues. Kim Dae Jung instead

paid special attention to the growing necessity for non-political, non-military and

economic exchanges between the two countries in an attempt to expand the scope

and scale of engagement. For example, the ambitious tourism project to develop

Mount Kumkang into an attractive resort park initiated by Hyundai Group, although

the ROK business community was skeptical about the project from the beginning,

was an effective showcase to expose the administration’s determination for comprehensive

engagement.

What was more striking was that these exchange programs were planned and

enforced through not only intergovernmental channels but also various avenues at

the substate level. At the same time, as the sociocultural joint projects came to

receive sustained attention not only by the relevant organizations but also by the

individual government agencies, the need of strict hierarchy in inter-Korean negotiation

agenda setting has diminished. The dividing line between conventional political issues

and newly emerged cooperative agenda was becoming blurred generating ‘desecuritization’60)

or a more structurally entangled cooperative mechanism. The increased exchanges

and cooperation at the sociocultural level showed the diminishing issue hierarchy in

inter-Korean relations.

58) Key-young Son, South Korean Engagement Policies and North Korea: Identities, norms and the Sunshine Policy (London: Routledge, 2006), p. 46.

59) Chosun Ilbo, 16th June 2000. 60) Sung-han Kim and Geun Lee, “When security met politics: desecuritization of North

Korean threats by South Korea’s Kim Dae-jung government,” International Relations of the Asia-Pacific 11, no. 1 (January 2011), pp. 25-55.

Page 25: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 267

2. Multiple channels

The Kim Dae Jung administration allowed and encouraged the ROK firms and

civic group leaders to engage with their counterparts in the DPRK through various

contact channels. This was a great policy reversal from his predecessor Kim Young

Sam who largely prohibited contact with the DPRK entities outside of intergovernmental

channels. This new approach implied that the ROK government was likely to take

a more accommodative attitude toward the DPRK, which had rejected intergovernmental

dialogue with the democratically elected government and aimed to directly reach

the pro-North Korean campaign groups in the South instead.61) It also meant that

the South Korean nonstate actors could enjoy a higher level of autonomy than the

past in getting involved in joint projects with their North Korean counterparts.62)

The consistent implementation of a series of deregulation measures based on the

initiative of ‘multiple channels’ and the ‘Jŏngkyŏng Bulli’ by Kim Dae Jung was

signalled by the key pattern of change-i.e. flexible reciprocity and transnational

actors’ involvement in inter-Korean relations-on which complex interdependence

model was built. More diversified contact channels between the two Koreas showed

the applicability of what Keohane termed transnational relations. This meant

domestic actors in state A could deal politically with their counterparts of state B

in their own issue area without necessarily involving diplomatic negotiation for the

particular project.63)

More direct involvement of business channels in inter-Korean political affairs was

61) Young Kyu Park, Kim Jong Il Chongkwonŭi Anpochongch’aek: Pokwaltchok Anpokaenyŏmŭi chŏkyong [The Security Policy of the Kim Jong Il government: Application of the concept of comprehensive security] (Seoul: Korea Institute for National Unification, 2003), p. 30.

62) A Joint research project on the governance of inter-Korean economic cooperation, led by the Korea Institute for National Unification (KINU), shows how various actors formed a network structure based on autonomous coordination through multiple channels. See Kyu Ryun Kim. et al.“Nampukyŏnghyŏp Governance Hwalssŏnghwa Pangan [How to improve inter-Korean economic cooperation],” (Seoul: Korea Institute for National Unification, 2007), pp. 6-8.

63) Keohane and Nye, “Transnational Relations and World Politics: An Introduction,” pp. xii-xv.

Page 26: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

268 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

shown when Hyundai played a crucial role in engineering the inter-Korean summit

between Kim Dae Jung and Kim Jong Il.64) Such an impact of the business

channel on the interstate political deals showed that nongovernmental elites were

taking over the role of transmission belt between governments. Individual exchanges

by nongovernmental actors could catalyze intergovernmental negotiation for state

actors to achieve political goals. It demonstrated the possibility for concerted

collaboration between state and nonstate actors by making use of multiple channels

in engaging with its potential adversary.

It was not only the business community alone that multiple channels efficiently

worked to establish the implementation strategy the inter-Korean agreements. The

civic group leaders in both Koreas established a ‘Joint Committee for the Implementation

of the inter-Korean Joint Declaration (JCKJD)’. More than twenty individual

organizations from both sides participated in the Committee and they joined and

supported the implementation process of the inter-Korean agreements made through

the government channel.

The DPRK also began to understand how NGOs as well as international

organizations worked to resolve famine and poverty issues in international politics.

Pyongyang made an unprecedented appeal for humanitarian assistance in 1995 after

a series of natural disasters that devastated its economy. It allowed the international

humanitarian agencies and their practitioners’ physical access to over two-thirds of

its geographical area.65) The North Korean authority also decided to accept the

offer of unconditional food assistance from the then Kim Young Sam government

in South Korea.66) Given that there were no such things as NGOs or independent

actors free from governmental control in the DPRK’s language in the 1990s,67) this

64) As to how Hyundai initially got involved in the summit, see Dong Won Lim, Peacemaker (Seoul: Joongang Books, 2008), pp. 25-30.

65) Hazel Smith, “‘Opening up’ by Default: North Korea, the Humanitarian Community and the Crisis,” The Pacific Review 12, no. 3 (1999), pp. 453-478.

66) Woon Keun Kim et al., “Assessing the Food Situation in North Korea,” Economic Development and Cultural Change 46, no. 3 (April 1998), pp. 519-535.

67) Hazel Smith, Hungry for Peace: International Security, Humanitarian Assistance, and Social Change in North Korea (Washington, D.C.: United States Institute of Peace, 2005).

Page 27: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 269

move implied a significant change in terms of how Pyongyang acknowledged the

role of multiple channels in its foreign policy.

With regard to the DPRK’s increased foreign engagement and inter-Korean economic

cooperation after 2000, the Chosun Asia-Pacific Peace Committee (CAPPC), a

quasi-governmental organization, played a crucial role. The CAPPC was in effect

under the control of the Workers’ Party of Korea, although it did not belong to the

Party’s official subunit.68) According to the National Intelligence Service in the

ROK, the CAPPC, established in 1994, had three functions. First, the Committee

was a channel for improving relations with Western countries including the U.S.

and Japan. Second, it planned and coordinated inter-Korean dialogues and overall

exchanges at the sub-state level. Third, the CAPPC acted as an avenue to invite

influential foreign figures to the DPRK.69) The CAPPC, above all, was the main

counterpart of the Hyundai Group that had promoted the largest scale inter-Korean

economic cooperation projects since the end of the Korean War. Business talks at

the corporate level between Hyundai and the CAPPC developed into political

dialogue at the governmental level in the two Koreas.

The coexistence and interaction of state and substate channels such as the JCKJD

and the CAPPC as well as private firms like Hyundai showed the theoretical

adequacy of the complex interdependence model in understanding the transformation

of inter-Korean relations during the Kim Dae Jung presidency. The emergence of

multiple channels was not necessarily to dismiss the role of diplomatic negotiation

and military capability highlighted by the political realists. It was worth noting that

the proponents of the complex interdependence model accepted that state behavior

was dominated by the constant danger of military conflict. They however paid equal

attention to the newly emerged multidimensional economic and social interdependence.70)

68) Keun Shik Kim, “Puk’anshik Minkantanch’eŭi Hyŏnhwangkwa Byŏnhwachŏnmang [Practices and Prospects of the Pseudo NGO in North Korea],” Pyŏnghwa YŏnKu [Peace Study], 11, no. 1 (Winter 2002-2003), pp. 91-114. However, it should be noted that the North Korean main negotiators involved in inter-Korean economic and social exchanges were agencies belonging to mostly government authorities whereas the South Korean counterparts were non-governmental actors in private sector.

69) Son, South Korean Engagement Policies and North Korea: Identities, norms and the Sunshine Policy.

Page 28: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

270 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

Inter-Korean relations after 2000 likewise did not imply the retreat of the state as

the supreme political actor. It rather demonstrated that the state did not monopolize

agenda setting and instead formed a network with alternative actors which had

previously been sidelined. The nongovernmental elites, as one axis of this network,

began to be treated as equally important actors in producing and developing the

agenda and issues of inter-Korean negotiations. It would be misleading to argue

that nongovernmental elites were becoming competitors of the state. Quite to the

contrary, the inter-Korean engagement by nongovernmental actors was largely supported

and consolidated by intergovernmental bargaining.

3. Decreasing role of military

The examples of inter-Korean economic cooperation in the Kim Dae Jung era

showed how politically hostile states could share their self-interest through institutional

agreements. The case of the Kaesong Industrial Complex (KIC) provided a compelling

example of neoliberal thinking on inter-state cooperation through institutional

arrangement.

The sign of reconciliation formed through economic collaboration culminated

when the DPRK military, which formerly had been stationed in the vicinity of

Kaesong, showed no objection to the influx of the ROK government officials and

workers as well as information technology devices. The DPRK military elites in

charge furthermore handed over a part of this strategic point to newly built

industrial facilities.71) Later in 2009 during the renegotiation with South Korea, the

purpose of which was to demand an increase in rent of the KIC, North Korean

negotiators implicitly admitted the military significance of this area by reclaiming

the ‘security value’ of Kaesong they had given up and lost when agreeing to form

the industrial park in this strategic area.72)

70) Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye, “Power and Interdependence Revisited,” International Organization 41, no. 4 (Autumn 1987), p. 727.

71) Il Do Hwang, “Kaesong Kongdan Kaebalo Hyuchŏnsŏn Sashilsang Pukssang [MDL moved northward in effect as a result of the development of the Kaesong Industrial Complex],” Shindonga [New East Asia], 532 (January 2004), pp. 228-234.

72) Jong-Eun Kim, “Puk, Kaesong Kongdan Anposang Oŏk Dollar Kach’i” [Kaesong

Page 29: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 271

According to Rosecrance, growing economic interdependence and the benefit from

it changed the state’s attitude to its territorial control against past adversaries.73)

Similarly, the mutually beneficial KIC project allayed the Korean Peoples’ Army’s

control over its own strategic territory for the first time since the armistice in

1953. The redeployment of the North Korean army out of Kaesong demonstrated

that institutionalized economic collaboration could transform the security environment

that had been dominated by head-to-head military confrontation. This became a

symbolic episode that showed the declining efficacy of military force as a tool

acquiring material benefit in the inter-Korean relationship.

Overall, during the Kim Dae Jung presidency, military issues as the only predominant

negotiation agenda that had defined the post-Korean War relationship between the

two countries began to lose a top priority amid a rising mood of inter-Korean

cooperation. The supreme strategic goal, for both Korean leaderships, was not to

simply entrench military preponderance but to secure material and strategic gains by

mobilizing various policy tools. There was no reason, in this sense, for the DPRK

central leadership to destroy its commercial partners by military force, whose hard

currency influx and capital investment was essential to maintaining its own economy.

The diluted hostility through various exchanges and joint events at the substate

level promoted a national mood of reconciliation and coexistence on the Korean

Peninsula. The reconciliation mood and the strategic utility of inter-Korean economic

exchanges decreased North Korea’s need and desire to replace the South Korean

government with a pro-communist regime. This also illustrated that the complex

interdependence model which paid heed to the relative retreat of military force in

an interdependent relationship could provide the analytical tool in understanding the

changed nature of inter-Korean relations after 2000.

Industrial Complex has half billion dollars security value, North claims], Seoul Shinmun, (20 June 2009).

73) Rosecrance, The Rise of Trading States: Commerce and Conquest in the Modern World.

Page 30: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

272 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

Ⅵ. Conclusion

The changed nature of bilateral relations after the inter-Korean summit illustrated

the decreasing explanatory utility of statecraft discourse approach that emphasized

the security dominance in international relations. The statecraft approach assumes that

a militarily or economically strong state showed a swing of the pendulum between

integrated and separated pursuit of economic and security objectives in dealing with

its weaker counterpart. The strong state’s actions in this formulation normally

depend on how much dominant its power to control the international order is in a

given period. The principle aim of this approach was to understand a stronger

state’s attempts to preserve its preponderance over a weaker state in international

politics.74)

But accentuation of complex interdependence lies not on one dimensional

‘influential’ vis-à-vis ‘being influenced’ relationship between a stronger and a weaker

state. The model thereby calls the dominant role of a state into question and rather

stresses emerging actors and new contact channels between states indicating diversified

engagement routes that undermined traditional diplomatic relationship. In a changing

interstate relationship, complex interdependence model showed a possibility in which

nongovernmental actors can collaborate with each other, resulting in economic and

social transactions among ‘societies’. As a result, the model draws more attention

to the alternative role of economic engagement by multiple actors in various issue

areas. Inter-Korean trade by private firms and many other economic and social

exchanges between the two parties even under the situation of the volatile security

dynamics provides an empirical evidence to support the applicability of complex

interdependence model as a framework of analysis of inter-Korean relations under

the Kim Dae Jung leadership.

Despite the analytical convenience that complex interdependence model provided,

however, it provides by no means a completely pertinent tool kit to analyze the

essence of entire inter-Korean relations. It rather needs to be refined to fully

explain the ROK government’s unchanged capacity in determining the scale and

74) Mastanduno, “Economics and Security in Statecraft and Scholarship”.

Page 31: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 273

pace of inter-Korean economic engagement in consideration with overall security

dynamics on the Korean Peninsula and Northeast Asia. It is also clear that, in the

context of the interrelationship between security and economy, economic considerations

on the Peninsula are not always likely to outweigh security concerns. Improved

reformulation will therefore be needed to embrace these points that the complex

interdependence model did not fully take into account.

It is not the case that the different elements in inter-Korean relations made equal

contributions to framing the relations at all times since the summit in 2000.

Indiscriminately combining all the aspects involved in inter-Korean affairs is another

misleading approach in identifying a key force that has driven the trajectory and

reality of the relations. It is thus important that one acknowledges the military

tension was accepted with different impact and strength according to the level of

interdependence in particular period. But complex interdependence model did not

explain under what conditions rising military tension is either highlighted or overshadowed

by many other interactions that reinforced (or alleviated) interdependence between

states.

This study does not understand complex interdependence model as a constructed

theory through which one can generally define and interpret the static reality of

inter-Korean relations. It means that this relatively short time span case study is not

designed to find a universal theoretical framework to understand entire picture of

inter-Korean relations. Complex interdependence model, in this regard, hints what a

sustainable economic relation between South and North Korea is going to look like

under political confrontation but does not constitute a primary analytical tool to

comprehend the sweeping relationship between the two countries. This study rather

adopts the model as an ideal and desirable type of setting based on which we

could offer a potential key to economic and political stability on the Korean Peninsula.

In that sense, recreating and reinforcing the dynamic reality of inter-Korean relations

to come closer to complex interdependence can play a role of a real cornerstone to

ensure more sustainable future relationship between the ROK and the DPRK.

Page 32: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

274 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Anderton, Charles and John Carter. “The Impact of War on Trade: An Interrupted Times-Series Study.” Journal of Peace Research 38, no. 4 (December 2001).

Angell, Norman. The Great Illusion, 2nd edition. New York: G.P.Putnam’s Sons, 1933.

Art, Robert. “To What Ends Military Power.” International Security 4, no. 4 (December 1980).

Axelrod, Robert. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic, 1984.

Baldwin, David. Economic Statecraft. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press, 1985.

. “Interdependence and power: a conceptual analysis.” International Organization 34, no. 4 (December 1980).

Barbieri, Katherine and Jack Levy. “Sleeping with the Enemy: The impact of War on Trade.” Journal of Peace Research 36, no. 4 (December 1999).

Bergeijk, Peter.A.G. Economic Diplomacy, Trade, and Commercial Policy: Positive and Negative Sanctions in a New World Order. Vermont: Edward Elgar, 1994.

Bohman, James and Matthias Lutz-Bachmann, eds. Perpetual Peace: Essays on Kant’s cosmopolitan ideal. Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1997.

Buzan, Barry. “Economic Structure and International Security: The Limits of the Liberal Case.” International Organization 38, no. 4 (December 1984).

Cain, Peter. “Capitalism, war and internationalism in the thought of Richard Cobden.” British Journal of International Studies 5, no. 3 (October 1979).

Choi, Wan Kyu. “Icarusŭi kyohun: Kim Yongsam Chŏngbŭi Taepukchŏngch’aek Shilp’ae Yoin Punsŏk [The Sad Fate of Icarus: The Kim Yongsam’s Governments Policy toward North Korea].” Hankukkwa Kukchechŏngch’i [Korea and World Politics] 14, no. 2 (1997).

Cooper, Richard. The Economics of Interdependence: Economic Policy in the Atlantic Community. London and New York: McGraw Hill for the Council on Foreign Relations, 1968.

de Vries, Michael. “Interdependence, Cooperation and Conflict: An Empirical Analysis.” Journal of Peace Research 27, no. 4 (November 1990).

Doyle, Michael. Ways of War and Peace: Realism, Liberalism, and Socialism. New York: Norton, 1997.

Gasiorowski, Mark. “Economic Interdependence and International Conflict: Some Cross-National Evidence.” International Studies Quarterly 30, no. 1 (March 1986).

Page 33: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 275

Gilpin, Robert. Change and War in World Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981.

Gouldner, Alvin. “The Norm of Reciprocity: A Preliminary Statement.” American Sociological Review 25, no. 2 (April 1960).

Gowa, Joanne. Allies, Adversaries, and International Trade. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994.

Grieco, Joseph. Cooperation among nations: Europe, America, Non-tariff Barriers to Trade. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1990.

Hirschman, Albert. National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade. Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1945.

. The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before its Triumph. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1977.

Holsti, Kal. “Politics in Command: Foreign Trade as National Security Policy.” International Organization 40, no. 3 (June 1986).

Hong, Soon Young. “Thawing Korea’s Cold War: The Path to Peace on the Korean Peninsula.” Foreign Affairs 78, no. 3 (May/June 1999).

Hwang, Il Do. “Kaesong Kongdan Kaepalo Hyuchŏnsŏn Sashilsang Pukssang [MDL moved northward in effect as a result of the development of the Kaesong Industrial Complex],” Shindonga [New East Asia] 532. (January 2004).

Jeong, Se Hyun. “Nampukchongsanghoedam Ilchunyŏn pyŏngga [The Assessment of One Year after the Inter-Korean Summit],” in Sejong Institute ed., Nampukchongsanghoedamkwa Hanpandopyŏnghwa [Inter-Korean Summit and the Peace in the Korean Peninsula]. Seoul: Sejong Institute, 2001.

Kang, David. “North Korea’s Military and Security Policy,” in Samuel Kim ed., North Korean Foreign Relations: In the Post Cold War Era. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1998.

Kaysen, Carl. “Is War Obsolete?” International Security 14, no. 4 (Spring 1990).

Keohane, Robert. “International Liberalism Reconsidered,” in John Dunn ed., Economic Limits to Modern Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.

. “Reciprocity in international relations.” International Organization 40, no. 1 (Winter 1986).

Keohane, Robert and Joseph Nye. “Power and Interdependence Revisited.” International Organization 41, no. 4 (Autumn 1987).

. Power and Interdependence. New York: Longman, 1989.

. “Transgovernmental Relations and International Organization.” World Politics 27, no. 1

Page 34: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

276 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

(October 1974).

. “Transnational Relations and World Politics: An Introduction,” in Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye, eds., Transnational Relations and World Politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1972.

Kim, Dae Jung. Ishipil Sekiwa Hanminchok: Kim Dae Jung chon Daet’ongnyong Chuyo Yŏnsŏl Taedam [Twenty-first century and Korean nation: Selection of speech by the former president Kim Dae Jung]. Paju: Dolbekae, 2004.

Kim, Jong-Eun. “Puk, Kaesong Kongdan Anposang Oŏk Dollar Kach’i [Kaesong Industrial Complex has half billion dollars security value, North claims].” Seoul Shinmun, 20 June 2009.

Kim, Keun Shik. “Puk’anshik Minkantanch’eui Hyŏnhwangkwa Pyŏnhwachŏnmang [Practices and Prospects of the Pseudo NGO in North Korea].” Pyŏnghwa YŏnKu [Peace Study] 11, no. 1 (Winter 2002-2003).

Kim, Kyu Ryun. et al. Nampukyŏnghyŏp Governance Hwalssŏnghwa Pangan [How to improve inter-Korean economic cooperation]. Seoul: Korea Institute for National Unification, 2007.

Kim, Sung Han and Geun Lee. “When security met politics: desecuritization of North Korean threats by South Korea’s Kim Dae-jung government.” International Relations of the Asia-Pacific 11, no. 1 (January 2011).

Kim, Woon Keun et al. “Assessing the Food Situation in North Korea.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 46, no. 3 (April 1998).

Kim, Young Yoon. Evaluation of South-North Economic Cooperation and Task for Success. Seoul: Korea Institute for National Unification, 2005.

Knorr, Klaus and Frank Trager. Economic Issues and National Security, Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 1977.

Liberman, Peter. Does Conquest Pay? The Exploitation of Occupied Industrial Societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996.

Lim, Dong Won. Peacemaker. Seoul: Joongang Books, 2008.

Magnusson, Lars. Mercantilism: The Shaping of an Economic Language. London: Routledge, 1994.

Mansfield, Edward and Pollins Brian. “The Study of Interdependence and Conflict: Recent Advances, Open questions, and Directions for Future Research.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 45, no. 6 (December 2001).

Mastanduno, Michael. “Economics and Security in Statecraft and Scholarship.” International

Page 35: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

Ki-Young Sung ∥ 277

Organization 52, no. 4 (Autumn 1998).

Mearsheimer, John. “Disorder Restored.” in Graham Allison and Gregory F. Treverton, eds., Rethinking America’s Security. New York: W.W.Norton, 1992.

Ministry of Unification. Nampuk Kiponhabuiso Haesol [Basic Agreement Details]. Seoul: Ministry of Unification, 1992.

. Tongil Paeksŏ [Unification White Paper]. Seoul: Ministry of Unification, 1992-2003.

Mitrany, David. A Working Peace System. Chicago: Quadrangle Press, 1966.

Mogenthau, Hans. Politics among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, 6th edition. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1985.

Moon, Chung-in and Steinberg, David. Kim Dae-jung Government and Sunshine Policy. Seoul: Yonsei University Press, 1999.

Morrow, James. Game Theory for Political Scientists. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994.

Oneal, John and Bruce Russet. “The Classical Liberals Were Right.” International Studies Quarterly 41, no. 2 (June 1997).

Oskamp, Stuart. “Effects of Programmed Strategies on Cooperation in the Prisoner’s Dilemma and Other Mixed-Motive Games.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 15, no. 2 (June 1971).

Park, Kun Young. “Taepukchongch’aekui Saeroun Chŏpkun [New approach of North Korea Policy].” Kukchechongch’inonch’ong [International Politics Studies] 38, no. 2 (1998).

Park, Young Kyu. Kim Jong Il Chŏngkwonui Anpochongch’aek: Pokwaltchok Anpokaenyomui chŏkyong [The Security Policy of the Kim Jong Il government : Application of the concept of comprehensive security]. Seoul: Korea Institute for National Unification, 2003.

Polachek, Solomon. “Conflict and Trade.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 24, no. 1 (March 1980).

Pollins, Brian. “Conflict, Cooperation, and Commerce: The Effect of International Political Interactions on Bilateral Trade Flows.” American Journal of Political Science 33, no. 3 (1989).

Rosecrance, Richard. The Rise of Trading States: Commerce and Conquest in the Modern World. New York: Basic Books, 1986.

Sahlins, Marshall. Stone Age Economics. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton, 1972.

Smith, Hazel. Hungry for Peace: International Security, Humanitarian Assistance, and Social Change in North Korea. Washington, D.C.: United States Institute of Peace, 2005.

. “‘Opening up’ by Default: North Korea, the Humanitarian Community and the Crisis.” The Pacific Review 12, no. 3 (1999).

Page 36: Theorization of Kim Dae Jung s Pursuit of Inter-Korean Economic … · 2012-10-08 · simple economic interconnectedness and interdependence thereby argues the former declines conflict

278 ∥ The Korean Journal of Area Studies Vol. 30, No. 2

Snidal, Duncan. “The Game Theory of International Politics.” World Politics 38, no. 1 (October 1985).

Snyder, Scott. “South Korea’s Squeeze Play.” The Washington Quarterly 28, no. 4 (Autumn 2005).

Son, Key-young. South Korean Engagement Policies and North Korea: Identities, norms and the Sunshine Policy. London: Routledge, 2006.

Soroos, Marvin. “Behavior Between Nations.” Peace Research Review 7, no. 2 (April 1977).

Viner, Jacob. “Power versus Plenty as Objectives of Foreign Policy in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries.” World Politics l, no. 1 (October 1948).

Waltz, Kenneth. Theory of International Politics. Reading: Addison-Wesley, 1979.

Wilson, Warner. “Reciprocation and other Techniques for Inducing Cooperation in the Prisoner’s Dilemma Game.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 15, no. 2 (June 1971).


Recommended