+ All Categories
Home > Documents > WHAT ARE THE SOURCES OF DEMOCRATIC …paperroom.ipsa.org/app/webroot/papers/paper_5452.pdf ·...

WHAT ARE THE SOURCES OF DEMOCRATIC …paperroom.ipsa.org/app/webroot/papers/paper_5452.pdf ·...

Date post: 06-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: doannhan
View: 214 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
32
WHAT ARE THE SOURCES OF DEMOCRATIC ENDURANCE IN NEW REGIMES? COLLECTIVE LEARNING AND THE BUILDING OF DEMOCRATIC LEGITIMACY IN LATIN AMERICA ENRIQUE PERUZZOTTI Department of Political Science and International Relations Universidad Torcuato Di Tella [email protected] Paper prepared for Session “Why and How do Democratic Regimes Endure?” (327) of the 20 th IPSA World Congress, Fukuoka, Japan, July 9-13, 2006
Transcript

WHAT ARE THE SOURCES OF DEMOCRATIC ENDURANCE IN NEW

REGIMES? COLLECTIVE LEARNING AND THE BUILDING OF DEMOCRATIC LEGITIMACY IN LATIN AMERICA

ENRIQUE PERUZZOTTI Department of Political Science and International Relations

Universidad Torcuato Di Tella [email protected]

Paper prepared for Session “Why and How do Democratic Regimes Endure?” (327) of the 20th IPSA World Congress, Fukuoka, Japan, July 9-13, 2006

In the past decades, Latin American countries have made a crucial transition to

democracy. Democratic regimes in the region were able to endure severe military,

political, economic, and social crises. What are the sources of democratic stability in

Latin America? How to account for the unusual strength exhibited by democracy in a

region that had been historically marked by recurrent military intervention and chronic

institutional instability? The questioning about the variables that might contribute to the

institutionalization of democratic regimes in the region has produced a large corpus of

studies and arguments. The academic production about political institutionalization in

Latin America can be divided into two halves: a) the works produced before the last

continental democratizing wave, a period where most of the academic production hoped

to account for the chronic problem of institutional instability and authoritarianism that

affected most of the region, b) the constitution after the transitions from authoritarianism

of a field of democratization studies interested in the analysis of the recently consolidated

democracies and their chances for survival.

The first group of studies attempted to explain the reasons behind the historical

inability exhibited by the region at stabilizing a democratic-representative regime. The

agenda of the second group focused, instead, on the specific challenges, obstacles and

problems that the current process of building, strengthening and perfecting democratic-

representatives regimes poses for the different countries of the region. Both periods

generated important works and arguments that contribute to the building of a significant

body of work about the factors that are behind democratic institutionalization. The early

Enrique Peruzzotti 1 IPSA

works of modernization theory inaugurated a rich debate about the correlations between

economic development and democracy. The more recent literature on transitions and

democratic consolidation rapidly built an impressive corpus of studies of different aspects

of the institutional and political dynamics of the new regimes. Yet, none of them

provided a plausible explanation that could fully account for the processes that contribute

to generate democratic endurance.

In this article I hope to contribute to such debate by developing a theory of collective

learning that might help to account for the major novelty of this last democratizing wave:

the emergence of a normative consensus on democracy. It is my argument that the

surprising endurance that democracy has displayed in the region, despite poor economic

performance and the presence of serious institutional and political crisis is related to that

novel commitment to democracy values in significant sectors of the population. To fully

understand the reasons behind democratic endurance, it is necessary to develop a theory

of collective learning that will account for such cultural and normative shift. The article

divides as follows: section I review the different arguments that tried to explain the

challenges that were preventing the stabilization of a representative type of democracy in

Latin America. Sections II and III analyze the production of democratization theory,

arguing that while contributing to shed light into many aspects of democratic life, it failed

to provide a convincing answer to the question of democratic endurance. Section III

attempts to develop an answer to the former question.

Enrique Peruzzotti 2 IPSA

I. Explaining Institutional Instability: Modernization Theory

The debates of the first period were initially framed in the language and models of

classical modernization theory. Modernization theory postulated certain correlation

between socioeconomic development and political institutionalization. In this literature, it

was assumed that the problems of political instability and of authoritarianism that

affected Latin American societies lay in the socioeconomic backwardness of those

societies. Rapid development was seen as the cure to most of the ills affecting the region.

Authors such as Seymour Martin Lipset and Daniel Lerner, for example, postulated a

linear correlation between economic development and democracy. The process of

economic development, they argued, would eventually create the appropriate cultural and

social environment for the consolidation of a representative democratic regime similar to

the ones in Western societies.1

More sophisticated modernization theorists already posed some doubts about the

inevitability of a representative form of democracy in developing societies. The

assumption of early theories of modernization that the final stage of the developmental

process would be the consolidation of a Western type of democracy was challenged by

the works of Gino Germani, Samuel Huntington and Guillermo O’Donnell. Taking as

their point of departure those Latin American countries that had already attained a

considerable degree of socioeconomic development and the political incorporation of the

citizenship into the political system, their analyses argued that the modernizing process

far from generating institutional stability and representative government, tended to

generate novel and disquieting forms of political instability and/or authoritarianism.

Rapid socioeconomic modernization produced problems and challenges that were absent

Enrique Peruzzotti 3 IPSA

at lower levels of development: “transitional” modernizing societies were subject to new

strains and problems that posed serious threats to their polities, producing political

phenomena that openly challenged the optimistic correlation between modernization and

democratic political institutionalization of classical modernization theory.

Gino Germani, for example, analyzed the completion of the process of political

incorporation in Argentina. Under Peronism, he argued, Argentina attained the full

incorporation of the masses into the political system. Such accomplishment, however, did

not result in the consolidation of a representative form of democracy but rather on the

establishment of an authoritarian version of populist democracy2. Samuel P. Huntington,

instead, called attention on the notorious inability of most societies of the region at

developing a stable structure of political mediations. In Political Order in Changing

Societies, Huntington considered such shortage of mediating representative structures the

main bottleneck to institutional modernization. In his view, the process of modernization

resulted in the mobilization of new social groups without the simultaneous building of

political institutions that could articulate and aggregate their demands. In the absence of

mediating institutional mechanisms, social and political forces confronted each other

'nakedly', i.e., their politicization is not channeled through institutional mechanisms of

political aggregation and intermediation but consists on unmediated war of all against

all3. For Huntington, mass praetorianism and political ungobernability --not democracy--

is the most likely future scenario of developing societies.

Guillermo O’Donnell’s influential book Modernization and Bureaucratic-

Authoritarianism represents the final chapter of the debate opened by classical

modernization theory. In his view, the most advanced countries of the region had already

Enrique Peruzzotti 4 IPSA

completed the easy stage of import-substitution industrialization. The demands of the

new stage of industrialization made the survival of democracy in the region unlikely.

O’Donnell postulated an elective affinity between the new economic period and a novel

form of military intervention in politics: the bureaucratic-authoritarian state. The aim of

the authoritarian state was to carry out the particular demands that the exhaustion of the

easy face of the import-substitution process of industrialization posed to policy-makers,

mainly, the demobilization of a politically activated popular sector4. The theory about

bureaucratic-authoritarianism reverses Lerner and Lipset’s linear correlation between

socioeconomic and political modernization. In O’Donnell’s opinion, military

authoritarianism, not democracy, is “the more likely concomitant of the highest levels of

modernization.5”

II. Democratization Theory and Democratic Endurance

The breakdown of authoritarian regimes and the subsequent establishment and

consolidation of democratic regimes throughout the region posed a theoretical challenge

to previous theories and diagnoses. The fact that the transitions resulted in the

consolidation of stable democracies without the region experiencing any significant

transformation of its socioeconomic variables redirected academic attention away from

structural approaches to the analysis of short term political interactions. The literature

about transitions to democracy stressed the uncertainty and disorder that characterized

such extraordinary moments and the determining influence that the short-term strategic

dynamics and choices of democratizing and authoritarian elites had on the political

Enrique Peruzzotti 5 IPSA

outcome of the process6. Political democracy, Guillermo O’Donnell and Philippe

Schmitter concluded in their influential four volume study of transitions from

authoritarianism, emerges from a “nonlinear, highly uncertain and imminently reversible

process” that takes place in a context “which encourages strategic interaction among

wary and weary actors.7”

As time passed by and the democratic regimes move towards consolidation, new

questions arose concerning the nature and challenges that the former confronted. A

copious literature on institutional issues rapidly developed. The latter imported the

institutional methods that were applied to the study of consolidated Western democracies

to the analysis of the new Latin American regimes. An important body of studies

developed in a relatively short time span that dealt with manifold aspects of institutional

analysis: from constitutional design to the specific dynamics of the different institutions

of representative government. The relationship between executive, legislative and

judicial powers8, the peculiarities of Latin American presidentialism9, the various

configurations of party systems that were found in the region10, the strength or weakness

of accountability mechanisms11, the problems of federalism12, were some of the central

questions that caught the attention of institutional analysis. Those analyses represented a

significant contribution to the understanding of the new democracies and served to shed

important light over different aspects of the institutional structure of the novel regimes.

In general, the institutionalist approach tended to converge on a similar diagnosis:

that democracy in the region was assuming characteristics and dynamics that set it apart

from the established model of representative government that predominates in Western

societies. The Latin American regimes seem to combine the formal structure of

Enrique Peruzzotti 6 IPSA

representative democracy with authoritarian or discretional behaviors on the part of

political elites. Such peculiar combination resulted in a political hybrid that the literature

categorized with adjectives such as delegative, illiberal, unconsolidated, fragile or

unstable democracy.

While the political science approach served to specify the institutional distinctiveness

of current democracies, it was unable to provide a plausible explanation to two crucial

questions: a) what were the reasons for such a peculiar outcome? and b) what explained

the unusual endurance of democracy in the region? The search for answers to the first

question led to a focus on the role of cultural and political legacies while the attempt to

provide a plausible explanation to the question of democratic endurance reopened some

of the debates of the modernization studies period.

The outcome of the transitions being different than the model of representative

democracy (that served as the comparative yardstick) triggered a historically-informed

search about the ways past legacies are shaping the actual process of political

institutionalization. The debate centered on the weight of different “legacies” and the

imprint they are leaving on current political life.13 In this debate, political culture

appears as a crucial variable of the institutionalizing equation. Guillermo O’Donnell’s

delegative democracy argument, for example, focuses on the problematic legacy of

populist traditions in Argentina, Brazil and Peru. In his view, the endurance of

problematic features of the political culture of populism is negatively shaping the

political and institutional dynamics of present democracies14. The whole debate about

neopopulism follows a similar line of argument.15 Finally, other authors concentrate on

the more immediate legacies of military authoritarianism, such as the devastating effects

Enrique Peruzzotti 7 IPSA

on civil society of the culture of fear and repressive legacy of the military dictatorships16,

or on the endurance of traditional oligarchic power structures and their disruptive effects

on democratic governability and political representation17.

The literature on authoritarian legacies stresses the incompatibility of the region's

political culture and traditions with democratic institutionalization. What for these

authors seems to be preventing representative democracy from taking roots in the

continent is the survival of an authoritarian political culture, be it populist, military or of

a more traditional-oligarchic type. The strength and endurance of such problematic

heritage conspires against the actualization of formal representative institutions. The

focus on cultural legacies, while might serve to partially answer the question about the

distinctiveness exhibited by current democratic regimes, can not provide, however, a

convincing response to the issue of democratic endurance. If the last democratizing wave

has been characterized by cultural continuity rather than rupture, how to account for the

stabilization of democratic regimes in the region? If there is continuity at the cultural

level, where is the source of innovation?

In their search for an adequate answer to the question of endurance, many authors

returned to the question initially raised by modernization theory: whether there is a

correlation between socioeconomic development and democracy. Such debate was

recently reopened by Adam Przeworski, et al. who wondered about the factors that are

behind the endurance of democratic regimes18. The authors not only reopened the debate

about modernization and democracy but returned to some of the earlier postulates of

classical modernization theory. According to these authors, Seymour Martin Lipset was

right in asserting that

Enrique Peruzzotti 8 IPSA

“…`the more well-to-do a nation, the greater the chances that it will sustain democracy’. Once established in a developed country, --Przeworski et al. argue-- democracy endures regardless of how it performs and regardless of all the exogenous conditions to which it is exposed.19” In their view, affluence is a sufficient condition for democratic survival. In this way, the

modernization debate comes into full circle. This last reformulation of the problem

returns to the initial argument of classical modernization theorists: it is modernization

what breeds democracy. What about non affluent countries? Democracy, Przeworski et

al. argue, might be able to survive in a non-affluent country as long as there is

governmental effectiveness concerning economic and social policies: “…the secret of

democratic durability seems to lie in economic development”20. Economic performance

appears as the crucial variable in explaining the endurance of certain democratic regime.

The authors recognize that theirs is not an optimistic conclusion considering the poor

economic performance of many third wave democracies.

The problem with the previous statements is that they are inadequate to explain the

recent experience of most Latin American democratizing countries where democracy was

stabilized in a hostile socioeconomic environment and by administrations characterized

by a dreadful economic performance21. A quick look at the landscape in which the new

democracies developed raises serious doubts about any correlation between economic

performance or development and democratization. Poor economic performance,

extensive poverty, and high rates of inequality are established features of the region. In

fact, the process of democratization coincided with a period of economic stagnation and

in some individual cases, with some of the most dramatic economic crisis of those

countries´ histories. Yet, and in spite of distressing socioeconomic conditions, the region

has achieved its longest period of democratic stability, putting an end to the praetorian

Enrique Peruzzotti 9 IPSA

period that for decades marked the political history of several countries of the continent.

The puzzle, as Karen Remmer argues, is how to account for such an unexpected outcome,

“Despite the persistence of dismal economic conditions, the process of political transformation that began in Latin America during the late 1970s maintained its momentum through the early 1990s, producing the broadest, longest, and deepest wave of democratization in the region’s history”22

In her view, rather than reviving previous debates about whether there is a correlation or

not between socioeconomic development and democracy, it is necessary to pay attention

to issues such as the legitimacy of political power. For Remmer, what explains the

resilience of democracy in the region independently of economic performance is the

development of a normative commitment to the principles and procedures of democracy.

Legitimacy insulates democracy from performance failures for it detaches support for

democracy from substantive outcomes23. What makes democracy endure in the region

even under hostile socioeconomic conditions, Remmer argues, is the emergence of a

novel belief in the legitimacy of democratic arrangements. Such thesis seems to indicate

that the legacy arguments about cultural continuity need to be tempered with the

recognition that the region has experienced some significant processes of political

learning as well.

III. The Building of Democratic Legitimacy in Latin America: How to Account for Political Change?

If what makes democracy endure even in the midst of a hostile socioeconomic

environment is a novel belief in the value of democratic procedures and institutions, then

it is necessary to explain what generated such process of cultural change. How does

Enrique Peruzzotti 10 IPSA

collective learning take place? How to account for cultural change? Surprisingly, given

the pessimistic diagnosis about the cultural and political heritage of the region that

informed great part of the debate about the dilemmas of democratic consolidation, the

issue of collective learning did not received much attention. The argument about the role

of legacies views political culture as the crucial variable of the institutionalizing equation:

what seems to be preventing democratic institutionalization in the region is the

uncoupling between the formal structures of constitutional democracy and the

predominant political culture of each society. Assuming that such diagnosis is right, then

cultural innovation emerges as a crucial precondition for institutional strengthening. In

societies where authoritarian legacies are alive, only the reshaping of collective identities

in a democratic direction can guarantee the success of current efforts at democratic

consolidation. While tacitly suggesting the need for cultural change, democratization

literature has seldom engaged in a serious and systematic effort to analyze the dynamics

of cultural innovation.

Democracy requires for its institutionalization of the development of certain values,

attitudes and behaviors from its citizens. How such political culture comes about? It was

generally assumed that democratic practices and values would be the product of a gradual

political development that would unfold over a long period of time. Robert Dahl’s classic

description of the British path to democracy serve as a paradigmatic example of the way

a democratic political culture develops over time. For Dahl, the success of the British

model lies in the incremental way that characterized the process of institutionalization of

a culture of competitive politics. Attitudes amenable to democracy, the author argue,

Enrique Peruzzotti 11 IPSA

initially develop within elite circles and only after a long period of habituation the former

are extended to a broader constituency24.

Gradualism and elitism is usually coupled with a naturalistic theory of cultural

change. The consolidation of collective identities and of democratic forms of self-

understanding does not appear as a conscious undertaking but is described in terms of an

uncritical naturalization of practices that initially derives out of strategic considerations.

For instance, Dahl argues that the choice for democracy is frequently the product of a

contingent and instrumental decision of elites that is largely based on strategic choices25.

There is a change of strategies, not necessarily of forms of political self-understanding.

Only after a long period of habituation, do the new practices became incorporated into

the political culture of society at large. The process of learning therefore does not

consist on a reflexive appropriation (and transformation) of certain values and practices

but is described as the routinization of strategic equilibriums: political culture is not the

product of a reflexive undertaking but is the outcome of a long and uncritical process of

naturalization of social identities26.

Such gradualist approach is unfit to account for processes of regime change that take

place in a relatively short span such as the ones that are the focus of the literature on

democratization. A major emphasis of the transitions literature was on the

unpredictability that characterizes such extraordinary moments of political change. As

O’Donnell and Schmitter stated, in transitional periods major transformations occur in a

context where “there are insufficient structural or behavioral parameters to guide and

predict the outcome.27” Analysts of processes of democratic transition and consolidation

Enrique Peruzzotti 12 IPSA

were thus forced to adapt the previous theory of cultural change to a context were radical

political and institutional changes occur in a compressed time frame.

Severe crisis and traumatic experiences, some authors argue, provide a unique

opportunity for sudden political change, forcing political elites to reevaluate their tactics

and goals28. Political transitions are a fruitful terrain for a redefinition of strategic

equilibriums that might be conducive to democratization. The previous gradualist

approach is replaced by an understanding of learning that places great emphasis on the

presence of crisis or traumas as triggers of political change. Learning is thus associated

with exceptional and foundational moments. It does not seem to be a regular feature of

political life29. It appears more as a reactive process spawn by unexpected developments

than a conscious deliberate process that takes place both in normal as well as in

exceptional times.

The conception of political learning that informs democratization literature rests on

two assumptions. On the one hand, political learning is fundamentally understood as

strategic learning. Political learning does not necessarily entail the development of a

normative commitment to democratic principles; it rather refers to a process of tactical

reorientation30. The open and unpredictable nature of transitions provides a rich ground

for the development of new strategic games and coalitions: during transitions, new

coalitions might develop that could lead to a new strategic equilibrium conducive to the

establishment of a democratic political compromise. Such compromise is not seen as a

substantive one but is merely based in strategic considerations31. Laurence Whitehead,

for instance, described the regimes that emerged as a result of the last democratizing

wave as democracies by default. In his view, the new democracies are a product of a

Enrique Peruzzotti 13 IPSA

situation of political stalemate based on the failure of the alternative political and

institutional options that dominated the Latin American political scenario for decades

(populism, desarrollismo, bureaucratic-authoritarianism, socialism, etc.). Unable to

advance their normatively preferred alternatives, Latin American elites agreed upon

democracy as a 'second-best' outcome32.

On the other hand, political learning is narrowly understood as learning by political

actors and other related elites33. While some authors acknowledge the role that a

mobilized civil society plays at destabilizing authoritarian rule34, the stabilization and

consolidation of a democratic regime is seen fundamentally as the product of elite

bargaining and accords. As Nancy Bermeo argues,

“…for better or for worse, the construction of democracy is an occasion where ‘the beliefs of some are more important than those of others’… the design of formal democratic institutions is, of necessity, the work of a political elite35”

Adam Przeworski will attempt to turn the premises of the democracy by default

argument into a more general theory about regime legitimacy. “What matters for the

stability of any regime, he argues, is not the legitimacy of this particular system of

domination but the presence or absence of preferable alternatives.36” Przeworski

proceeds to strip Max Weber’s conception of legitimacy of its normative content: a

regime might be viewed as illegitimate for most groups, he continues, yet, if there is no

visible alternative, it will remain stable.

For Weber, always at the core of any legitimate structure of domination there is some

sort of normative consensus between rulers and ruled. The hallmark of a legitimate authority

relationship is the recognition by the ruled of the normative claim of validity made by the

rulers37. This feature endows legitimate regimes with a stability that is absent in other

Enrique Peruzzotti 14 IPSA

forms of power relationships. Weber acknowledges that while any system of domination

presupposes the presence to a relevant degree such normative attitude, there might also be

persons who relate to the political order on purely opportunistic grounds38. Adam

Przeworski generalizes this last observation into a conception of legitimacy that lacks any

reference about a normative content. “Acquiescing behavior, he argues, do not

necessarily originate from beliefs in the legitimacy of a system of domination” but might

be hypocritically simulated on purely opportunistic grounds or for reasons of self-interest.

In this way, Przeworski attempts to build a theory of institutionalization organized around

the notion of democratization by default: democratic endurance does not require, in his

opinion, legitimacy in the strong Weberian sense but only acquiescent behavior on the

part of self-interest actors39.

The previously reviewed approach to collective learning rests a very “thin” theory of

institutions. “Custom, personal advantage, purely affectual or ideal motives of solidarity

–Max Weber argues-- do not form a sufficiently reliable basis for a given domination. In

addition there is normally a further element, the belief in legitimacy.40” An order that is

purely based on reasons of expediency such as the one envisioned by Przeworski and the

democratization by default argument is much less stable than one that has develop a

normative commitment to its legitimating principles. Democratization’s theory of

political institutionalization leaves aside the fundamental question of how a regime’s

validity principles are anchored in the political culture of a society. To argue that the

recent process of democratic institutionalization in Latin America largely rests on

strategic equilibriums born out of purely tactical considerations is to assume that the

whole edifice of democracy in the region is built upon very precarious foundations. The

Enrique Peruzzotti 15 IPSA

severity of the military, social, political and economic crises that many Latin American

polities encountered in recent years without those societies reverting into authoritarianism

suggest that there has been more than merely strategic learning on behalf of elites.

Irrespectively of its policy failures and persistent socioeconomic inequalities, public

support for democracy has shown surprising resilience: citizens support democracy as a

regime despite being dissatisfied with the performance of democratic administrations41.

Democratic endurance seems to be rooted on a normative commitment to democratic

values on behalf of significant sectors of society. The task is how to account for the

processes that have allowed such a significant shift of values to take place. It is necessary

to go beyond the argument of democratization by default to develop a more solid

approach to collective learning and cultural change that could account for the conditions

under which democratic normative orientations and validity principles are embedded into

a particular political culture.

IV. Towards an Alternative Theory of Cultural Innovation: Democracy, Collective Learning and the Development of a Public Sphere

A first step toward the building of a theory of collective learning that could

explain the surprising resilience that democracy has exhibited in the region is to see

learning processes as a reflexive undertaking that is rooted in discursive communication.

“Cultural change in modern society, Klaus Eder argues, is produced by a collective

learning process whose logic is defined by the logic of discursive communication.”42

Modern civic associations organized around the principles of equal and discursive

Enrique Peruzzotti 16 IPSA

handling of disputes are the main locus of collective learning processes. The discursive

practices of civic associations, social movements and independent publics are crucial

sites for the developing of collective learning processes. Through the emergence of actors

who have become self-reflective regarding social processes of identity formation,

existing norms and values are challenged43. In this theoretical approach, learning is not

described as an unconscious process of “habituation” of norms or a “reactive” attitude

triggered by traumatic events or crisis but consists on a dynamic and regular process of

production of normative structures within processes of communication44. A reflexive

form communication based on the principle of free and equal exchange of arguments is

the starting point for the social production of the modern political order. Legal-rational

legitimacy rests upon the assumption that norms are intentionally made (and unmade).

Through the questioning of ingrained political traditions and institutional structures,

social movements, publics and civic associations play a decisive role at cultural change.

Cultural innovation presupposes a clash between the predominant norms, identities and

values and the alternative forms of self-understanding embodied by new social actors. In

this rendering of culture and cultural change, actors at not at the mercy of the cultural

legacy or heritage of a society as some of the distinctive tradition arguments suggest45.

The analysis of the cultural impact of social movements on processes of political

institutionalization in Latin America has been developed by several authors, who focused

on the contribution of identity politics to democratization46. The emergence of novel

civic actors in several of the democratizing societies introduced innovative discourses

and practices that eventually contributed to collective learning. New forms of self-

understanding and of politicization succeed in questioning specific aspects of the

Enrique Peruzzotti 17 IPSA

predominant political culture of each society. As Alvarez, Dagnino and Escobar argue,

“the cultural politics of social movements often attempt to challenge or unsettle dominant

political cultures.”47 In this rendering, political culture is always “the effect of continuing

struggles at the level of the political field48” where opposing political cultures confront

each other. The achievements of a politics of identity will be measured by the extent to

which those social actors were able to reshape the self-understanding of certain society.

In this way, social movements and other civic actors can contribute to undermine and

transform the questionable authoritarian legacies that concerned consolidation analysis.

Broadening the scope of analysis to include non elite actors might lead to a redefinition

of predominant diagnosis about the obstacles at democratic institutionalization49.

For instance, the emergence of human rights movements in societies that underwent

the traumatic experience of state terrorism served not only to delegitimize military

authoritarianism but to also question some problematic features of the populist

democratic tradition that are the main concern of the delegative and neopopulism

arguments. To experience a traumatic event such of state terrorism does not automatically

trigger learning as some of the previously theories seem to presuppose. Such experience

needs to be first thematized as being problematic. That was the contribution of the human

rights networks. The politics and discourse on human rights called attention upon the

normative dimension of constitutional democracy, introducing into the existing political

culture a healthy concern for the rule of law and for governmental accountability.50 In

this way, their struggle served to anchor the validity principles of a constitutional form of

democracy into the local political culture51.

Enrique Peruzzotti 18 IPSA

Collective learning in modern societies is intimately linked with the

institutionalization of a public sphere where processes of deliberation and learning can

unfold52. It is in the communicative networks of the public sphere where self-reflection

over existing norms and institutions can take place. This is not to say that identity

politics cannot take place under authoritarian situations, in fact, the Latin American

human rights movement was born and developed under highly repressive conditions that

make the existence of a public sphere impossible. Representative democracy, however,

establishes protective institutional conditions for such public space that are absent not

only under authoritarianism but also under other forms of democracy, such as

populism53.

What differentiates representative government from other types of regime is precisely

the establishment of an institutional setting that allows for the formation of active and

independent publics between elections as well as for the fluid channels of communication

between those publics and the institutionalized mechanisms of will formation. The

institutionalization of procedures and conditions of communication as well as the

interplay between formal political decision-making bodies and informally constituted

publics is distinctive of representative democratic regimes54. It is that feature what

prevents representative democracy from falling into an empty ritual of acclamation or on

the passive authorization of elitist rule.55

A crucial contribution of many of the new actors and forms of politics that emerged

in the last democratizing wave was to carve in a public space that would provide a

fundamental arena for contestation and learning56. This is no small accomplishment in a

region were political traditions were openly hostile to such project57. Such

Enrique Peruzzotti 19 IPSA

accomplishment, however, is being constantly threatened by delegative behaviors on the

part of governing elites. The existence of collective learning processes in some societal

sectors does not automatically translate into a betterment of formal democratic

arrangements and political practices. To affect the process of democratic

institutionalization, collective learning has to make an indent at the institutional level.

The renewal of political culture is certainly a crucial first step towards institutional

innovation, yet the problem that still remains is how to transfer those new elements of the

political culture into the political system. This is a problem that has been addressed by

some recent work on social accountability and on institutional innovation.

In his analysis of participatory budgeting in Brazil, Leonardo Avritzer employs the

concept of participatory publics to call attention to the establishment of institutional

forms that articulate and incorporate elements of political innovation into the decision-

making structure of municipal political systems in Brazil. The institutions of

participatory budgeting, Avritzer argues, establishes a formalized sphere of public

deliberation and negotiation that results in a more fair, accountable, and public form of

articulation of citizens with political authorities58. Similarly, the work on social

accountability focuses on the emergence of novel forms of civic initiatives that are

organized around a common effort at modifying institutional behaviors to increase the

accountability of public agencies and officials59. Both types of initiatives are undoubtedly

important steps in the direction toward institutional betterment. Participatory budgeting

or social watchdog’s organizations add new sites and actors to that can establish a

positive feedback with representative institutions, increasing their political and legal

accountability. There is, however, a more fundamental process of collective learning that

Enrique Peruzzotti 20 IPSA

democracies need to undertake to assure its institutional survival and durability: it

consists in institutionalizing public learning processes into the broader structure of

representative democracy. Democratic regimes need to establish certain threshold of

institutionalization to achieve this stage. Once public deliberation and contestation are

openly embraced and constitutionally guaranteed by a democratic regime, can we say that

representative democracy has been able to reach a degree of institutionalization that

incorporates the notion of learning into the political process.

Most of the Latin American democracies have certainly not reached such stage of

political institutionalization. While some democracies seem to be heading into such

promising direction, there are some troublesome clouds in the political horizon of the

continent that might threaten to undermine the accomplishments of this last

democratizing wave. Neopopulism is one of them. Poor economic performance is the

other one. While normative commitment to democracy has prevented democratic

breakdown despite poor economic performance, the persistence and/or worsening of

economic and social variables could eventually led to a reversal of such process of

learning and endanger the legitimacy of the Latin American democracies. Seymour

Lipset was right in stressing that the stability of democratic political systems depends on

a relative combination between legitimacy and effectiveness. Legitimacy, he argued, is

crucial is preserving the stability of a regime despite crisis of effectiveness. Yet, if a

democracy aspires to endure in the long run, a minimum degree of effectiveness need to

be created. The recent political crises that shocked several countries of the region are

early warnings about the imperative need to reach such difficult equilibrium.

Enrique Peruzzotti 21 IPSA

Delegative or populist behaviors on the part of political elites are the other major

obstacle to institutional strengthening. The resort to populist styles and behaviors by

political elites provides a tempting alternative to reconstitute political authority in those

countries where representative institutions are being questioned due to their inability to

steer the economy and the political system into the path of economic growth, social

justice and political accountability. While such course of action might appear as an easy

shortcut to political reconstruction, its short terms gains are overshadowed by the

negative consequences it poses to political institutionalization. Populism can provide

temporarily relief to crisis ridden societies yet the road that to institutional betterment and

sustained economic growth is more likely to emerge in a type of regime that has built in

reflexive mechanisms of collective learning and solid mechanisms of accountability.

Deliberation and accountability increase the intelligence of policy makers, contributing to

the coherence of policies. The present challenge is to solidify the processes of societal

learning through the establishment of a form of democracy that institutionalizes

deliberative forms of democratic opinion and will formation. If successful, the region will

finally reach the eluding goal of political institutionalization.

Enrique Peruzzotti 22 IPSA

1 Seymour Martin Lipset. 1959. Political Man. The Social Basis of Politics. Garden City, N.J.,

Doubleday & Company, chapter II, pp. 45-76; Daniel Lerner, The Passing of Traditional Society,

Glencoe, Ill., The Free Pres, 1958.

2 Gino Germani, “La Transición Hacia un Régimen Político de Participación Total en la

Argentina,” in Gino Germani, Política y Sociedad en una Época de Transición, Buenos Aires,

Editorial Paidós, pp.300-325.

3 Samuel P. Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies, New Haven: Yale University

Press, 1968, p. 80.

4 O’Donnell, Modernization and Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism; David Collier. 1979. The New

Authoritarianism in Latin America, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

5 Guillermo O’Donnell, Modernization and Bureaucratic-Authoritarianism. Studies in South

American Politics, Berkeley, Ca, Institute of International Studies, 1979, p.8.

6 Guillermo O'Donnell and Philippe C. Schmitter. 1986. Transitions from Authoritarian Rule.

Tentative Conclusions about Uncertain Democracies, Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press,

pp. 3-5; Philippe Schmitter. 1985. "Transitology: the Art or Science of Democratization?” en

Joseph Tulchin (ed.), The Consolidation of Democracy in Latin America, Boulder: Lynne

Rienner.

7 O'Donnell and Schmitter. Transitions from Authoritarian Rule, p. 72

8 Matthew Shugart and John M. Carey. 1992. Presidents and Assemblies. Cambridge, Cambridge

University Press; S. Morgenstern and B. Nacif (Eds.). 2002. Legislative Politics in Latin America.

Cambridge, Cambridge University Press

9 Dieter Nohlen y Mario Fernández. 1998. El Presidencialismo Latinoamericano: Evolución y

Perspectivas, Caracas, Nueva Sociedad; Scout Mainwaring y Matthew S. Shugart (Eds.). 202.

Presidencialismo y Democracia en América Latina, Buenos Aires, Paidós Editorial; Juan J. Linz

Enrique Peruzzotti 23 IPSA

and Arturo Valenzuela (Editors). 1994. The Failure of Presidential Democracy. Comparative

Perspectives, Baltimore, The John Hopkins University Press.

10 Scott Mainwaring and Timothy Scully (eds.). 1995. Building Democratic Institutions: Party

Systems in Latin America, Stanford, Stanford University Press; Michael Coppedge. 1998. “The

dynamic diversity of Latin American party systems.” Party Politics, #4; Marcelo Cavarozzi y

Juan Manuel Abal Medina (comps.). 2002. El Asedio a la Política. Los Partidos

Latinoamericanos en la Era Neoliberal. Rosario, Homo Sapiens.

11 Guillermo O’Donnell, “Horizontal Accountability: The Legal Institutionalization of Mistrust”;

Andreas Schedler, Larry Diamond, and Marc Plattner (eds.), The Self-Restraining State: Power

and Accountability in New Democracies, Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1999; Adam

Przeworksi, Susan C. Stokes, and Bernard Manin (eds.), Democracy, Accountability, and

Representation, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1999; Susan S. Stokes, Mandates and

Democracy. Neoliberalism by Surprise in Latin America, Cambridge, Cambridge University

Press, 2001.

12 Edward Gibson and Ernesto Calvo. 2001. “Federalism and Low Maintenance Constituencies:

Territorial Dimensions of Economic Reform in Argentina.” Studies in Comparative International

Development 35; Edward Gibson. 2004. Federalism and Democracy in Latin America. Baltimore,

The John Hopkins University Press.

13 Katherine Hite and Paola Cesarini (Comps.) Authoritarian Legacies and Democracy in Latin

America and Southern Europe, Notre Dame, Indiana, University of Notre Dame Press, 2004;

Frances Hagopian, “Traditional Power Structures and Democratic Governance in Latin

America”, in Jorge I. Dominguez and Abraham F. Lowenthal, Eds., Constructing Democratic

Governance: Latin America and the Caribbean in the 1990s, Baltimore, John Hopkins University

Press, 1996; Frances Hagopian, “After Regime Change. Authoritarian Legacies, Political

Representation, and the Democratic Future of South America”, World Politics; Guillermo

Enrique Peruzzotti 24 IPSA

O'Donnell, "Illusions about Consolidation", Journal of Democracy, vol.7, #2, 1995; Guillermo

O’Donnell, "Delegative Democracy", Journal of Democracy vol.5, #1, 1994

14 O'Donnell, "Illusions about Consolidation" and "Delegative Democracy". For a very insightful

discussion about the reasons behind the staying power of the populist persuasion in Latin

America, see Carlos de la Torre, Populist Seduction in Latin America. The Ecuadorian

Experience, Ohio, Ohio University Center for International Studies, 2000, chapter 4.

15 Alberti, Giorgio. 1991. "Democracy by Default: Economic Crisis, Movimentismo, and Social

Anomie," paper presented at the XVth World Congress of the International Political Science

Association, Buenos Aires, July 1991; José Nun,"Populismo, Representación y Menemismo"

Sociedad. Revista de Ciencias Sociales, #5, October 1994; Francisco Weffort, Francisco, "What

is a New Democracy?" International Social Science Journal #136, 1993; Graciela

Ducantenzeiler, Philippe Faucher, and Julian Castro-Rea, “Back to Populism: Latin America’s

alternative to Democracy,” paper presented at the American Political Science Association

Meeting, San Francisco, August 30-September 2 1990.

16 Juan E. Corradi, Patricia Weiss Fagen and Manuel Antonio Garretón (eds.), Fear at the Edge.

State Terror and Resistance in Latin America, O'Donnell and Schmitter. Transitions from

Authoritarian Rule, Berkeley, University of California Press, 1992; Karen L. Remmer, Military

Rule in Latin America, Boston, Unwin Hyman, 1989; Frances Hagopian, “After Regime Change.

Authoritarian Legacies, Political Representation, and the Democratic Future of South America,”

World Politics, vol.

17 Hagopian, “Traditional Power Structures and Democratic Governance in Latin America” and

Traditional Politics and Regime Change in Brazil, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press,

1996.

18 Adam Przeworski, Michael E. Alvarez, José Antonio Cheibub and Fernando Limongi,

Democracy and Development. Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950-1990,

Enrique Peruzzotti 25 IPSA

Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2000; Adam Przeworski, Michael Alvarez, Jose

Antonio Cheibub & Fernando Limongi, “What Makes Democracy Endure?,” Journal of

Democracy, Volume 7, Number 1, January 1996.

19 Przeworski, et. al. “What Makes Democracy Endure?” p. 41.

20 Przeworski, et al., “What Makes Democracy Endure?” p. 49.

21 The authors also recognized that their claim that democracies are more likely to survive in

intermediate levels of development does not reflect the Southern Cone experience that had been

the focus of analysis of Germani, Huntington and O’Donnell. Przeworski, et al., “What Makes

Democracy Endure?” p.41.

22 Karen L. Remmer, “The Sustainability of Political Democracy. Lessons from South America,”

Comparative Political Studies, Volume 29, Number 6, December 1996, p. 612.

23 The importance of a legitimating political culture for the stabilization of democracy had already

been highlighted by Seymour Martin Lipset. Following the steps of Max Weber, Lipset’s analysis

underscored the cultural basis of any process of institutional stabilization. See Lipset, Political

Man, p. 81.

24 Robert Dahl, Polyarchy. Participation and Opposition. New Haven, Yale University Press,

1971, chapter 3. Other paths to democratization, Dahl argues, are less likely to succeed, p.37.

25 Dahl, Polyarchy, p.

26 See Larry Diamond’s excellent review of the different approaches to political culture and

cultural change. Larry Diamond (Ed.), Political Culture and Democracy in Developing

Countries, Boulder and London, Lynne Rienner Publishers, 1993.

27 O'Donnell and Schmitter. Transitions from Authoritarian Rule, p. 3.

28 Nancy Bermeo, “Democracy and the Lessons of Dictatorship,” Comparative Politics, volume

24, April 1992, p. 274. “Crisis or trauma, Jennifer Mc Coy argues, is more likely to produce

learning than a gradual accumulation of knowledge.” Jennifer L. McCoy, “The Learning Process”

Enrique Peruzzotti 26 IPSA

in Jennifer L. McCoy (ed.), Political Learning and Redemocratization in Latin America: Do

Politicians Learn from Political Crises? Miami, North South Center Press, p. 5.

29 According to Nancy Bermeo, political learning is relevant in the foundational moment when a

democratic regime is being established. Whether learning affects other phases of the

democratization processes, she argues, is an open question. Bermeo, “Democracy and the Lessons

of Dictatorship,” p.273

30 Bermeo, “Democracy and the Lessons of Dictatorship,” p. 276.

31 Adam Przeworksi, “Some Problems in the Study of Transitions to Democracy,” in Guillermo

O'Donnell, Philippe C. Schmitter, and Laurence Whitehead (eds.). Transitions from Authoritarian

Rule. Comparative Perspectives, Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press, 1986, p. 59.

32 For Whitehead, the depoliticization that followed from the dramatic failure of past mobilizing

political projects is the main source of democratic stability. The alignment of the population

behind totalizing projects represented, in this interpretation, a key source of ungovernability and

institutional instability. The lowering of popular expectations of what can be achieved through

politics has consequently contributed to political governability. Societal depolitization and

privatization are seen as key variables for understanding the unusual endurance exhibited by the

new South American democracies. See Laurence Whitehead, "The Alternative to 'Liberal

Democracy': A Latin American Perspective", in David Held (ed.) Prospects for Democracy,

Cambridge, Polity Press, 1993. Giorgio Alberti also develops a similar argument about

democratization by default. See Giorgio Alberti, "Democracy by Default: Economic Crisis,

Movimentismo, and Social Anomie," paper presented at the XVth World Congress of the

International Political Science Association, Buenos Aires, July 1991.

33 McCoy, “The Learning Process,” p. 4; Bermeo, “Democracy and the Lessons of Dictatorship,”

p. 276

34 See O'Donnell and Schmitter. Transitions from Authoritarian Rule, chapter 5.

Enrique Peruzzotti 27 IPSA

35 Bermeo, ibid.

36 Przeworski, “Some problems in the Study of Transitions to Democracy,” p. 51.

37 Anthony T. Kronman, Max Weber, Stanford, Ca, Stanford University Press, 1983, p.39.

38 Max Weber, Economy and Society. An Outline of Interpretative Sociology, Berkeley, Ca,

University of California Press, 1978, volume 1, p. 214.

39 Przeworski, “Some problems in the Study of Transitions to Democracy,” pp. 50-1. See also,

Adam Przeworski, “Democracy as Equilibrium,” paper presented at the New School of Social

Research, March 27, 1996.

40 Weber, Economy and Society, p 213.

41 See the data compiled by Latinobarómetro regarding popular attitudes toward democracy in the

region: Marta Lagos, “Latin America’s Lost Illusions. A Road with no Return?” Journal of

Democracy, Volume 14, Number 2, April 2003.

42 Klaus Eder, The New Politics of Class. Social Movements and Cultural Dynamics in Advanced

Societies. London, Sage Publications, 1993.

43 Jean Cohen and Andrew Arato, Civil Society and Political Theory, Cambridge, Ma, Cambridge

University Press 1992; Alberto Melucci, Challenging Codes, Cambridge, Ma, Cambridge

University Press 1996

44 Klaus Eder, “Learning and the Evolution of Social Systems” in M. Schmid and F. M. Wuketits

(eds.), Evolutionary Theory in Social Science, Reidel Publishing Company, 1987, p. 104

45 This is the case of the analyses of Howard Wiarda in which Latin America seems to be

condemned due to its peculiar cultural heritage to authoritarianism. See, Howard Wiarda, “”Law

and Political Development in Latin America: Toward a framework of analysis,” in H. Wiarda

(eds.), Politics and Social Change in Latin America, Massachusets, University of Massachusets

Press, 1982.

Enrique Peruzzotti 28 IPSA

46 An important contribution was the collective volume of Sonia E. Alvarez, Evelina Dagnino,

and Arturo Escobar (eds.), Culture of Politics, Politics of Culture. Re-visioning Latin American

Social Movements, Boulder, Colorado, Westview Press, 1998. Also, Leonardo Avritzer,

Sociedade Civile e Democratizacao, Belo Horizonte, Livraria Del Rey Editora, 1995; Leonardo

Avritzer, “The Conflict between Civil and Political Society in Post-Authoritarian Brazil”

Constellations. An International Journal of Critical and Democratic Theory, number 3, 1995;

Sergio Costa, As Cores de Ercìlia. Esfera Pública, Democracia, Configuracoes Pòs-Nacionais,

Belo Horizonte, Editora UFMG, 2002; Enrique Peruzzotti, “Towards a New Politics. Citizenship

and Rights in Postdictatorial Argentina,” Citizenship Studies, vol.6, number 1, 2002

47 Sonia E. Alvarez, Evelina Dagnino, and Arturo Escobar, “Introduction: The Cultural and the

Political In Latin American Social Movements,” in Alvarez, Dagnino, and Escobar, Culture of

Politics, Politics of Culture, p. 8

48 Eder 1992a

49 Enrique Peruzzotti, “The Nature of the New Argentine Democracy. The Delegative Democracy

Argument Revisited,” Journal of Latin American Studies, volume 33, part 1, February 2001

50 Peruzzotti, “Towards a New Politics.”

51 The “democracy by default” argument fails to perceive how collective learning has led to a

revaluation of the normative validity claims of a constitutional form of democracy, placing

democracy as the only legitimate option. Democracy is not the unwilled product of a stalemate

generated by the failure of more appealing political alternatives, as argued by Whitehead; support

for democracy spawns out of a conscious collective decision of significant sectors of society that

was triggered by processes of normative (and not merely strategic) learning. Peruzzotti,

“Towards a New Politics”

52 Eder 1993, Jurgen Habermas 1981

Enrique Peruzzotti 29 IPSA

53 Historically, the institutional and cultural conditions for the flourishing of a public sphere were

threatened not only by military authoritarianism but also by the democratic traditions that

prevailed in large part of the region. Populist forms of democratic self-understanding endorsed a

plesbicitarian form of democracy opposed to a model of democracy built on the notion of public

deliberation. What are the elements of populist democracy that conspire against the idea of public

sphere? In the first place, a plesbicitarian reinterpretation of democratic institutions that replaces

deliberation by acclamation. To the discursive parliamentary mediation of interests and opinions

from below, populism counterpoises direct forms of communication between leader and mass that

bypass institutional and informal channels of opinion formation and interest aggregation. In the

second place, populism rests a form of identity-building organized around a friend-foe axis that

inevitably leads to overpoliticization and to political polarization. Being the leader and the

movement the incarnation of the popular will, the process of democratization is conceived as a

process of homogeneization of the political landscape whose final point is the untenable fiction of

a unanimous will. Such a fundamentalist form of political self-understanding necessarily leads to

political polarization and to the fragmentation of society into two irreconcilable (and over

politicized) camps. Both plesbicitarianism and polarization block communication and collective

learning. Populism destroys the constitutive conditions that allow for the establishment of a

vivid public sphere in which an autonomous public opinion can emerge. Enrique Peruzzotti,

“Cultura Política, Esfera Pública y Aprendizaje Colectivo en la Argentina Post-dictatorial”, in

Isidoro Cheresky and Inés Pousadela (eds.), Instituciones Políticas y Ciudadanía en las Nuevas

Democracias Latinoamericanas, Buenos Aires, Paidós Editorial, 2001; Enrique Peruzzotti, “Civil

Society and the Modern Constitutional Complex: The Argentine Experience,” Constellations. An

International Journal of Critical and Democratic Theory, volume 4, number 1, April 1997.

54 Jurgen Habermas, Between Facts and Norms. Contributions to a Discourse Theory of Law and

Democracy, Cambridge, Ma, The MIT Press, p. 298.

Enrique Peruzzotti 30 IPSA

55 I have developed this argument in Enrique Peruzzotti, “Two Approaches to Representation,”

paper presented at the XXVI International Congress of the Latin American Studies Association,

San Juan, Puerto Rico, March 15-18, 2006.

56 To stress the relevance of such civic actors and association does not imply that such actors are

the most conspicuous element of the public sphere, or even of civil society. The mass media,

political parties and interest groups organizations play in all cases a dominant position in such

space.

57 Leonardo Avritzer, Democracy and the Public Space in Latin America, Princeton, Princeton

University Press, 2002; Peruzzotti, “Cultura Política, Esfera Pública y Aprendizaje Colectivo,”

2001

58 Avritzer, Democracy and the Public Space. See also, Vera Schattan P. Coelho e Marcos Nobre

(orgs.), Participacao e Deliberacao. Teoría Democrática e Experiencias Institutcionais no Brasil

Contemporáneo, Sao Paulo, Editora 34, 2004; Evelina Dagnino (ed.), Sociedad Civil, Esfera

Pública y Democratización en América Latina, Brasil, México, Fondo de Cultura Económica,

2003, Enrique Peruzzotti and Andrew Seele, “Democratic Innovation at the Local Level in Latin

America,” Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars, unpublished manuscript, 2006.

59 Enrique Peruzzotti and Catalina Smulovitz (eds.), Enforcing the Rule of Law. Social

Accountability in Latin America, Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh University Press, 2006.

Enrique Peruzzotti 31 IPSA


Recommended