+ All Categories
Home > Documents > ACTA UNIVERSITATIS UPSALIENSIS Uppsala Studies in...

ACTA UNIVERSITATIS UPSALIENSIS Uppsala Studies in...

Date post: 16-Jun-2019
Category:
Upload: lekhue
View: 217 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
209
ACTA UNIVERSITATIS UPSALIENSIS Uppsala Studies in Economic History, 95
Transcript

ACTA UNIVERSITATIS UPSALIENSISUppsala Studies in Economic History, 95

Omslagsfoto: Vy över Sjuntorps bomullspinneriers fabrik vid Lilla Edet. Illustration nr. 51 (LI) i Sveriges industriella etablissamenter. Litografierade och tryckta hos A.L. Normans boktryck-eri-Aktiebolag. Andra serien. Stockholm 1879. Uppsala universitetsbibliotek. Omslag: Karin Ågren.

Vetenskap och politikBo Gustafsson 1931–2000, en minnesskrift

på 80-årsdagan av hans födelse

Redaktörer

Lars Magnusson, Klas Nyberg och Lynn Karlsson

Magnusson, L., Nyberg, K. och Karlsson, L. (red.). 2012. Vetenskap och politik. Bo Gustafsson 1931–2000, en minnesskrift på 80-årsdagan av hans födelse. (Research and politics. Bo Gustafsson 1931–2000. A memorial publication on the 80th anniversary of his birth.) Acta Universitatis Upsaliensis. Uppsala Studies in Economic History 95. 204 pp. Uppsala. ISBN 978-91-554-8401-9 .

Abstract

This book is a commemorative publication, with annotated, posthumously published material, in honor of Professor Bo Gustafsson on the 80th anniversary of his birth. Gustafsson was a professor at the Department of Economic History 1977−2000 at Uppsala University and one of the discipline’s most prominent figures during the late 20th century. The title “Research and Politics” refers to his political and publishing activity in 1960- and the 70’s left-wing movement and to his academic legacy up to the time of his death. His life and work are presented initially in an essay by Lars Magnusson, and thereafter for the first time Bo Gustafsson’s unfinished autobiography is published. The bulk of the book, however, is made up of his posthumously published essay, “The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories” on the emergence of mechanized cotton spinning in the 18th century. It is a weighty contribution to the debate on the origins of the factory system in England and is presented in an introduction by Klas Nyberg. Finally Bo Gustafsson’s bibliography, compiled by Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson, is published.

Keywords: Mechanized cotton mills, factory system, economic history, Lancashire, England, Industrial Revolution, cotton, scientific biography, scientific bibliography, the left movement, social movements, 1960s

Department of Economic History, Box 513, Uppsala University, SE-75120 Uppsala, Sweden

© The authors 2012

ISSN 0346-6493ISBN 978-91-554-8401-9

Printed in Sweden by Universitetstryckeriet, Uppsala 2012.

Distributor: Uppsala University Library, Box 510, SE-751 20 Uppsalawww.uu.se, [email protected]

Innehåll

Lars Magnusson, Ekonomihistorikern Bo Gustafsson – en inledning ............ 7

Bo Gustafsson, Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben. Några minnes­anteckningar ................................................................................................. 17

Klas Nyberg, Introductory Comments to Bo Gustafsson’s “The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories: With Special Reference to the British Cotton Industry” ............................................................................... 49

Bo Gustafsson, The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories: With Special Reference to the British Cotton Industry ................................. 61

Part I. A Preliminary Narrative and Explanatory Sketch .................... 63I. Abstract ..................................................................................... 65II. The Transition from Domestic Industry to Factory Production .. 68III. Some Problems of Meaning and of Research .......................... 70IV. An Overview of the Problem ................................................... 75V. The Structure of Domestic Industries and the Putting-out System ........................................................................................... 83VI. The Rise of the First Factories in the Cotton Industry ........... 97VII. Suggestions for future research ........................................... 123Literature .................................................................................... 124Appendix 1: Some suggestions as to how the problem of the transition from putting-out industries to factories may be ap-proached ..................................................................................... 127Appendix 2: A note on the concept of factory and on factory employment in England 1840. ..................................................... 138Appendix 3: Why were wages lower in domestic industries than in factories? ......................................................................... 141Appendix 4: Notes on Marx and the transition to the factory system .......................................................................................... 144Appendix 5: Three reviews ........................................................ 155

Part II. Preliminary steps towards modelling of the transition ......... 163I. Introduction .............................................................................. 165II. Definitions ............................................................................... 165III. Properties of the Economic Organizations ............................ 167IV. Putting-out and Factory Organization Compared .................. 169

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson, Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000 ........ 177

7

Lars Magnusson

Ekonomihistorikern Bo Gustafsson – en inledning

Bo Gustafsson var professor i ekonomisk historia från 1977 fram till sin död 2000. Hans engagemang vid institutionen sträcker sig emellertid mycket längre tillbaka i tiden. När han först kom till Uppsala i början på 1950-talet hade han nog tänkt sig att bli lärare eller möjligtvis pröva möjligheterna att ta en kandidatexamen i juridik. Men istället fångades han tidigt av den fria och öppna atmosfär som rådde inom det nyspirande ämnet ekonomisk histo-ria under ledning av preceptorn och från 1959 den förste professorn i ämnet, Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand. Ekonomisk historia var då ett nytt universitetsämne. Som ett separat lärämne hade det inte många år på nacken – i starkt motstånd från ledande historiker som Erik Lönnroth hade Eli F. Heckscher under nästan kuppartade former år 1947 förmått den dåvarande ecklesiastikministern Josef Weijne att etablera det nya ämnet inom samhällsvetenskaplig fakultet. I Upp-sala började Hildbebrand undervisa i det nya ämnet på höstterminen 1948.

Trots övergången till den samhällsvetenskapliga fakulteten huserade dock den nya föreståndaren eller preceptorn Hildebrand tillsammans med en halv amanuens till att börja med i ett litet rum i dåvarande Historiska institutens Ekermanska hus invid universitetsparken. Först 1957 flyttade den nya institu-tionen in i några rum på första våningen i det så kallade Skandalhuset bredvid universitet. Etablerandet av den självständiga institutionen hade inte skett utan spänningar. Vissa historiker uppfattade det nya ämnet som en gökunge vars självständiga ställning man inte förstod vitsen med. Hildebrand var ju i botten först och främst historiker. Det hans studenter sysselsatte sig med var väl någon form av historia? Hildebrand hade främst kommit i kontakt med den ekonomiska aspekten av historien genom sitt avhandlingsarbete som utmynnade i ett arbete om Falu stads historia som han disputerade på för doktorsgraden på 1946. När det gällde Faluns utveckling spelade förstås koppargruvan en central roll vilket ledde honom in i studiet av den svenska järn- och brukssektorns historia. Men till sin läggning och med sin humanis-tiska inriktning var Hildebrand främst en historiker med en ovanlig förmåga att på ett inlevelsefullt sätt återskapa äldre tiders sociala och kulturella tankar och miljöer samt framhäva de enskilda aktörernas aktiva roll i den historiska utvecklingens myller.

När Bo Gustafsson i början av 1950-talet knöt sina första kontakter med ämnet var det fortfarande ett oskrivet blad. Den historiska och aktörs-orienterade bakgrunden fanns redan – kunde en sådan även förenas med en

8

Lars Magnusson

samhällsvetenskaplig och rent av nationalekonomisk inriktning? Gustafsson var beredd att pröva den möjligheten. Det var visserligen fråga om en marx-istiskt präglad nationalekonomi som stod i motsatsställning till den gängse neoklassiska analysen. Redan under 1950-talet skrev Bo kritiska artiklar både i Sverige och internationellt mot den förhärskande nationalekonomin – som förutsatte jämvikt och att människor på marknaden var rationella aktörer – och han korresponderade med ledande marxistiska ekonomer i Storbritannien, i synnerhet Maurice Dobb och Ronald Meek i Cambridge. En av hans husgudar var även den polske-amerikanska marxistiska ekonomen Oskar Lange vilken utifrån en grundläggande kunskap om neoklassicismen samtidigt kunde er-bjuda ett alternativ. Sådant gillade den unge Bo Gustafsson. Med ekonomisk analys och djupborrande analytisk samhällsvetenskap kunde ordning och struktur skapas i de historiska skeendena. Samtidigt fascinerades han av den historiska skildringens must och kraft.

I detta fanns förstås också ett spänningsförhållande som han inte alltid lyckades överbrygga. Som samhällsvetare kunde han ibland hänge sig åt en stark kritik av historicismens försök att ”förstå” gångna tiders aktörer mot bak grund av den tid de levde i. Det var strukturerna och de ekonomiska krafterna som gällde. Men i praktiken var han samtidigt djupt skeptisk till anakronismer och genuint fascinerad av den enskilda människans möjlighet att påverka det historiska förloppet. Han var mycket kritisk till vad han uppfattade som re-duktionism eller ekonomisk determinism. I hans omfattande produktion finns utan tvivel många bevis på hur han nästan kunde dra i riktning mot personkult och en närmast voluntaristisk tro på den enskilda människans förmåga – detta är ett tema som vi skall återvända till.

Hos Bo Gustafsson fanns ett tydligt spänningsförhållande mellan veten-skap och politik. Själv försökte han lösa detta dilemma genom att dra en så tydlig gräns som möjligt. Man skulle inte blanda samman tro och vetande eller tyckande med kunskap. Som student i Uppsala under 1950-talet hade han vac-cinerats tillräckligt väl av Uppsalafilosofi från Hägerström till Hedenius för att ställa sig djupt skeptisk till en vetenskap som byggde på lösa resonemang och dålig empirisk grund. Han ställde sig ofta i debatter kritisk till den logiska positivismen såsom den utvecklats av Karl Popper och andra – men delade ändå dess grundläggande tro på möjligheten att via empiriska iakttagelser kunna verifiera eller falsifiera teorier och hypoteser. Han delade även Gunnar Myrdals syn på att ”fakta sparkar”. Som vetenskapsman måste man alltid vara beredd på att ompröva och tänka om. Som alltid i dessa sammanhang är det väl ibland svårt att leva som man lär. Det är klart att även Bo Gustafsson ibland slant på handen – utan att vara medveten om det. Men när det gäller vetenskaplig metodik var han snarast konservativ när han ställde stränga krav på akribi och källkritik. Han var en skarp kritiker av det som han uppfat-tade som ovetenskapligt och flummigt. Skadeglatt läste han uppgörelser med vänsterteoretiker som Herbert Marcuse och Samir Amin. Den senares teser om en den globala kapitalackumulationen som ett sätt att överföra resurser från

9

Ekonomihistorikern Bo Gustafsson

det som då kallades u-länder till i-länder ägnade han en hel kurs att kritisera på Stockholms universitet i början av 1970-talet. I sitt installationstal som ny professor i Uppsala kritiserade han den då så väletablerade latin-amerikanska beroendeskolan – som hävdade att u-länderna måste förbli fattiga så länge som världskapitalismen består – för att han ansåg att den inte stämde med ob-serverbara fakta. I själva verket befinner vi oss mitt i en industriell revolution av stora proportioner som avser den Tredje världen, hävdade han – och med all rätt som vi kan se trettiofem år senare.

Denna stränga syn på en uppdelning mellan politik och vetenskap delade förvisso inte alla. Inom dåtidens vänster var det flera som förundrade sig över hur lite ”marxistisk” Gustafsson var som vetenskapsman. I en seminarieupp-sats från Lund från slutet av 1970-talet kan man andas en viss besvikelse: ”I licen-tiatsframställningen Den norrländska sågverksindustrins arbetare 1890–1913 är det mycket svårt att hitta något marxistiskt.” Men för Gustafsson var marxismen ingen dogm som för länge sedan fastställt vad som är sant eller falskt. Den kunde ge stöd men gav inga entydiga svar. Dess satser måste prövas mot verkligheten som dessutom ständigt förändrades. Dessutom var den ingen metod som upphävde de gamla hederliga handgreppen när det gällde vetenskaplig analys. Hypoteser, teorier och frågor måste formuleras. Dessas sanningshalt skulle sedan prövas empiriskt. Något annat dög inte! För vissa var detta uppenbarligen inte tillräckligt radikalt. En annan fråga är förstås om han alltid lyckades upprätthålla rågången. Det är som redan nämnts förstås tveksamt. Men som vetenskapsman var Bo Gustafsson ovanligt grundlig och sträng. Att fuska med hantverket dög inte i hans närvaro. För övrigt var hans favoritbok inom historieämnet den franske Annales-historikern Marc Blochs pionjärverk om tidig fransk agrarhistoria Les caractères originaux de l’histoire rurale française (1931). Bo beundrade särskilt hur Bloch hade vandrat runt i det franska landskaper och likt en lantmätare försökt retrospektivt kalkylera hur forna tiders bysystem och åkersystem gestaltat sig.

*

Bo Gustafsson kom att förbli trogen den Ekonomisk-historiska institutionen i Uppsala – förutom några år runt 1970 då han vikarierade som professor vid den helt nybildade Ekonomisk-historiska institutionen i Umeå. Han kom till att börja med att jobba nära Hildebrand inom projektet kring Sågverks-förbundets historia som denne initierat inför organisationens femtioårsjubi-leum1957. Gustafsson skrev avsnittet om sågverksindustrins arbetare under åren mellan 1890 och 1945. Hans framställning mynnade ut i en närmast klassisk socialhistorisk undersökning med tyngdpunkt på löneutveckling och levnad standard. Men den siffermässiga framställningen förenas med en djup inlevelse av arbetarnas hårda arbetsvillkor, fattigdom och social misär. Han följde sedan upp temat i den nyss nämnda licentiatavhandlingen från 1962 (publicerad tre år senare), Den norrländska sågverksindustrins arbetare

10

Lars Magnusson

1890–1913. Här förenar han inlevelsen med det industriella genombrottets arbetare med användandet av nya och banbrytande socialhistoriska metoder. Under denna tid fördes en omfattande diskussion inom samhällsvetenskapen kring olika metoder att mäta välfärd och levnadsstandard. Inom brittisk ekonomisk historia fortsatte diskussionen kring den industriella revolutionens effekter för arbetarklassens levnadsstandard – en optimistisk syn stod i mot-satsställning till en mera pessimistisk som betonade hur den industriella ut-vecklingen under 1800-talet lett till en sjunkande levnadsstandard. Samtidigt publicerade den östtyske marxistske socialhistorikern Jurgen Kucyinski den ena volymen efter den andra kring levnadsstandardens utveckling i Europas olika länder i samband med den industriella revolutionen. För de svenska såg-verksarbetarnas del kunde Gustafsson dra slutsatsen att deras levnadsstandard faktiskt förbättrats under perioden 1890–1913. Den var därmed kanske inte särskilt ”marxistisk”. Men fakta hade sparkat och hans slutsats har senare kun-nat förstärkas av många andra studier.

När det gällde doktorsavhandlingen kom Gustafson dock att växla spår. Utan tvivel var avhandlingen Marxism och revisionism. Eduard Bernsteins kritik av marxismen och dess idéhistoriska förutsättningar – senare över satt till flera språk – hans magnus opus. Han försvarade avhandlingen i Uppsala universitetshus sal X på våren 1970. Det är ett lärt verk som visar Gustafssons enorma beläsenhet när det gäller marxismens idéhistoria, samt den socialis-tiska rörelsens ideologier och synsätt under det senare 1800-talet. Parallellt med licentiatavhandlingen och annat hade han arbetet med denna avhandling sedan mitten av 1950-talet. Längre forskningsvistelser främst i Amsterdam och Kiel, tillsammans med familjen, gav arbetet en internationell utblick som var unik när det gällde svenska historiska avhandlingar vid denna tid. Självfallet kryddades intresset för disputationen – och att så många fanns på plats under disputationsakten – av att Gustafsson vid denna tid seglat upp som en av ledararna för vänsterorganisation KFML (Kommunistiska förbun-det marxist-leninisterna) som hade bildats 1967 genom en utbrytning från den gamla Sveriges Kommunistiska Parti (som samtidigt passade på att byta namn till Vänsterpartiet Kommunisterna). I politiken ställde alltså Gustafsson upp för den ”rena” marxismen kontra vad han och andra uppfattade som en revisionism med rötter hos Bernstein. Han liksom andra var kritisk mot namn-bytet till VPK och menade att det innebar ett avfall åt höger. Men Gustafssons avhandling var ingen pamflett – även om somliga som inte läst avhandlingen felaktigt drog den slutsatsen. Den är och förblir en viktig källa för alla som är intresserade av marxismens idéhistoria liksom för det västerländska tänkan-dets utveckling i allmänhet under slutet av 1800-talet. Slutsatsen att Bernstein och andra (främst tyska) socialdemokrater starkt kom att ”revidera” och av-vika från det som kunde anses vara Marx och Engels läror bygger utan tvivel på solid grund – även om de politiska slutsatserna av detta faktum naturligtvis kan växla.

11

Ekonomihistorikern Bo Gustafsson

År 1977 blev Bo Gustafsson utnämnd till professor i ekonomisk historia vid Uppsala universitet. Arbetet med ett stort upplagt projekt kring att skildra och förklara den offentliga sektorns kraftiga tillväxt under 1900-talet i de utvecklade industriländerna hade inletts redan i början av 1970-talet. Detta projekt kom starkt – liksom Bo Gustafssons starka personliga lyskraft som forskare och vänsterman – att bidra till den Ekonomisk-historia institutionens snabba utveckling och tillväxt från och med mitten av 1970-talet. Ett stort antal personer kom att på olika sätt delta i projektet som i slutet av decenniet huserade i professorsvillan Åsen invid den Botaniska trädgården och Linne-anum. Bo själv satt i ett av rummen mot gården medan doktoranderna befol-kade tornrummen. Totalt kom projektet att ge upphov till fem avhandlingar som på olika sätt belyste den offentliga sektorns expansion i Sverige, främst under efterkrigstiden.

Större samlade forskningsprojekt av detta slag var ovanliga vid denna tid och väckte stor uppmärksamhet utåt. Internt innebar det som nämnts en snabb utveckling av institutionens forskning och undervisning. Men en annan effekt blev en ökad inriktning mot mera samhällsvetenskaplig teori och metodik. En viktig utgångspunkt för hela projektet var ekonomen Erik Hööks teori (som i sin tur byggde på teorier som utvecklats av brittiska ekonomer såsom Alan Peacock och Jack Wiseman) om det nästan naturnödvändiga sambandet mellan ökade realinkomster och en ökad offentlig konsumtion. Hööks teori stöttes och blöttes – inte minst i Anders Forsmans avhandling som var den första i sviten av de fem. Gustafsson och hans doktorander önskade en bredare förståelse av den offentliga sektorns betydelse för det moderna kapitalistiska samhällets utveckling. Inkomstökningen var en del av detta skeende. Men ännu större roll spelade företagen och det finansiella systemet som i symbios med staten skapade en ny form av monopolistisk kapitalism.

Många väntade i början av 1980-talet på Bo Gustafssons stora syntes av projektet. Det kom mycket riktigt ett slags syntes – men inte av det väntade slaget. Slutpunkt för projektet satte han med publiceringen av boken Den tysta revolutionen (1988). Denna bok förvånade säkert många som hade väntat sig en djuplodande teoretisk och idéhistorisk framställning. Istället var boken en konkret upplagd beskrivning av och finstämd lovsång till det svenska folk­hemmet utifrån exemplet Örebro. Bakgrunden till boken var egentligen en beställning från LO:s sida inför dess kongress 1986 då den svenska välfärds-politiken skulle diskuteras och nagelfaras. Genom sin kunskap om den offent-liga sektorn skulle Gustafsson bidra med ett gediget underlag. Tyvärr blev han inte färdig i tid utan boken utkom två år senare. En orsak var otvivelaktigt det ambitiösa och tidskrävande arbetssättet. Istället för att som brukligt sitta på kammaren och skriva ned sina funderingar utifrån ett givet källmaterial tog han initiativ till en serie studiecirklar i Örebro som engagerade kom-munalpolitiker, landstingsfolk, fackliga företrädare och många andra. Genom att kombinera deras kunskap om hur välfärdssystemet utvecklats på lokal nivå med mera traditionella källor förmådde han ge en konkret beskrivning av hur

12

Lars Magnusson

välfärdsutvecklingen påverkat förhållandena för vanliga människor under ef-terkrigstiden. Det var ett ovanligt grepp – en tillämpning av den ”gräv där du står” metod som vid denna tid förespråkades av författaren Sven Lindqvist och andra.

Från och med 1985 var Gustafsson annars djupt upptagen med något som förefaller vara närmast motsatsen till en sådan ”folklig” ansats – byggandet av ett svenskt elitinstitut för avancerade studier, Kollegiet för Samhällsforskning eller SCASSS (Swedish Collegium for Advanced Studies in the Social Sciences) som det hette från början. Bo Gustafssons insatser i detta sammanhang kan inte i detalj tecknas här, men så mycket kan dock sägas att Bo liksom historikern Rolf Torstendahl och statsvetaren Björn Wittrock som startade Kollegiet inte stack under stolen med att deras förebild var center för avancerade studier av en typ (likt Princeton i USA) som vid denna tidpunkt var mycket fåtaliga. Syftet var att skapa ett institut där svenska och utländska toppforskare inom samhällsvetenskap och humaniora kunde samsas. Här skulle sedan böcker skrivas och gemensamma projekt utvecklas. Vid denna tidpunkt var Kollegiet onekligen en främmande fågel i det svenska forskningslandskapet. Gustafsson, Torstendahl och Wittrock hade fått uppdraget att skissa på ett förslag av det dåvarande Humanistiskt-samhällsvetenskapliga forskningsrådet (HSFR) och Riksbankens Jubileumsfond. Upplägget var kontroversiellt i många kretsar. Att bara tala om ”avancerade” studier var uppkäftigt. Liksom att Kollegiet kunde förmodas dra till sig forskningsmedel som annars skulle ha tilldelats de svenska universiteten direkt.

Men SCASSS kom igång och under tiden fram till sin död femton år senare skulle det komma att utgöra Bo Gustafssons främsta hemvist både

13

Ekonomihistorikern Bo Gustafsson

vetenskapligt och personligt. Det innebar dock inte att han övergav den Ekonomisk-historiska institutionen. Men han lämnade prefektskapet vidare till Håkan Lindgren, Ragnhild Lundström och till sist till undertecknad – i en tid då åtminstone mindre institutioner leddes av en lärostolsprofessor och en prefekt som mycket ofta var samma person. Bo kom även i fortsättningen att dyka upp på institutionen och under många år fortsatte han att leda dess högre seminarium.

*

Här är förstås inte platsen att närmare skärskåda Bo Gustafsson som politi-ker och ideolog inom den radikala vänster som började framträda på allvar mot slutet av 1960-talet. Något skall dock sägas för att ge en kort överblick. Bo Gustafsson gick in i det svenska kommunistpartiet (SKP) 1957 – enligt egen utsago som en solidaritetsgest i ett läge där partiet fick uppleva spott och spe efter Ungernhändelsernas 1956. Den motsatta gesten var annars mera vanlig både i Sverige och på andra håll i Västeuropa. Under 1960-talet satt han periodvis i Uppsala stadsfullmäktige och senare i Uppsala kommun som representant för SKP. Från mitten av årtiondet blev han känd för sina redigeringar på svenska av texter författade av Marx, Lenin och Rosa Luxem-burg. Hans lilla bok Från kolonialism till socialism som utgavs 1963 – starkt påverkad av storheter som Maurice Dobb i England och Paul A. Baran i USA, liksom av diskussionen i den amerikanske marxistiska tidskriften Monthly Review som under årtionden gavs ut av Paul M. Sweezy – kom att få ett starkt genomslag i en begynnande svensk vänsterkritik av västerlandets behandling av utvecklingsländerna. Från och med 1968 kom han att bli en entusiastisk på-drivare för den nyöversättning av Marx Kapitalet som utfördes av hans svärfar och svärmor (Ivan och Ruth Boman).

Så tidigt som 1953 hade han dragits in i arbetet kring det svenska Clarté-sällskapet – till att börja med i lokalföreningen i Uppsala som då bestod av tre personer. Han kom med i redaktionen för tidskriften Clarté några år därefter och bidrog med många artiklar där han inte minst presenterade internationell marxistisk litteratur för en svensk publik. År 1960 deltog han i den delega-tion av unga kommunister som utsänts av Demokratisk ungdom – SKP:s ung-domsförbund – för att besöka Folkrepubliken Kina. Det var mitt under det så kallade Stora språnget (Maos version av Stalins tvångsvisa industrialiserings-kampanj under tidigt 1930-tal) som förorsakade den största hungersnöden i Kina sedan 1800-talets dagar; miljoner människor dog av svält. Efteråt har Bo berättat att de svenska besökarna inte hade fått sett något av detta. Man hade åkt omkring i sovjetiska Volgabilar med svärtade vindrutor. Till skillnad från andra kom Bo senare att mycket skarp kritisera denna enögdhet och inse att han blivit dragen vid näsan.

Bo liksom andra inom det svenska Clarté kom dock under 1960-talet att successivt bli alltmera influerade av Mao – i konflikten mellan Sovjet och Kina

14

Lars Magnusson

tog man Mittens rike i försvar. Själv uppfattade han sig i efterhand som att ha varit en svensk missionär för det kinesiska kommunistpartiets ståndpunkter. Midsommar 1967 bildade han tillsammans med den välkände Göteborgs-maoisten Nils Holmberg och företrädare för den ungdomliga Vietnamrörelsen (De Förenade FNL-grupperna) KFML, Kommunistiska förbundet marxist-leninisterna, och han blev dess förste ordförande. Som redaktör för förbundets teoretiska organ, Marxistiskt Forum, förutsattes han formulera dess huvudsak-liga ideologiska linje. Men KFML var på intet sätt en homogen företeelse. Här samsades gamla stalinister med unga FNL:are liksom med svärmiska maoister av vilka en del i Lund och i synnerhet Uppsala kom att bilda grundvalen för den extremradikala så kallade rebellrörelsen. På sikt var detta en häxbrygd som inte kunde hålla samman. Trots sin beundran av Maos Kina hade Bo svårt för den närmast eskatologiska maoism som kännetecknade de unga rebell-lerna – hos dessa blev följdriktligen Gustafsson en avfälling med namnet ”sosse-Bosse”. Inte heller hos de järnhårda stalinisterna hörde han hemma. Dessa bröt sig ut med göteborgaren Frank Baude i spetsen och bildade 1970 KFML(r) – Kommunistiska förbundet marxist-leninisterna (revolutionä-rerna). Det som blev kvar i det gamla förbundet utgjordes i hög grad av unga FNL:are. Det var dessa som tillsammans med några fackliga kritiker av LO:s solidariska lönepolitik – till exempel typografen Sture Ring som dessutom var Bos svåger – 1973 grundade det nya SKP, Sveriges kommunistiska parti. Det var folkfrontens politik från 1930-talet i lika hög grad som Maos paroll om att ”tjäna folket” som vägledde de unga SKP:arna. Så länge Vietnamkriget pågick kunde partiet utnyttja det folkliga stöd som FNL-grupperna till viss del åtnjöt. Men när kriget tog slut ökade motsättningarna inom partiet. Olika falanger uteslöt varandra – och vips hade även Bo Gustafsson (tillsammans med författaren av dessa rader) uteslutits ur SKP 1977. Successivt därefter drog han sig emot socialdemokratin och han kom att gå med i partiet några år därefter. Men det var ingen enkel seglats. Av många inom socialdemokratin betraktades han med viss skepsis. Några öppna armar var det inte tal om. Något stukad kunde han senare känna att han inte fått en sådan position inom socialdemokratin (inte ens på det lokala planet) som han hade hoppats på.

Hans kommunistiska övertygelse låg annars långt tillbaka i tiden. Som han skildrar i sin självbiografiska skiss ”Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben” som här publiceras för första gången, växte han upp i det lilla samhället Karlbo ut-anför Avesta. Hans relation till fadern, ”Rallar-Gustaf” Anders Gustaf Gus-tafsson var komplicerad, men han insöp säkert en god portion av dennes snarast syndikalistiskt färgade radikalism – eller tog åtminstone del av de radikala böcker som han samlade på sig, allt från Krapotkin till Upton Sinclair och de svenska proletärförfattarna. Fadern var från början anhängare av de så kallade unghinkarna och tog ställning för vänsterns avhopp från socialdemokratin i slutet av Första världskriget. Men Anders Gustaf var ingen enkel person att ha att göra med. Själv misstänkte jag alltid att en del av Bos socialt empatiska grundåskådning utgick från det faktum att han ofta fick ta moderns parti i de

15

Ekonomihistorikern Bo Gustafsson

konflikter som uppstod i hemmet och som färgade syskonen Gustafssons upp-växt (förutom Bo två bröder och en syster).

Bos första kontakt med marxism-leninismen hänförde han själv till läs-ningen av Arnold Ljungdahls Marxismens världsbild. Boken hade kommit ut mitt under uppstarten för det kalla kriget 1947. Bo hittade boken hemma i käl-laren året därefter och kom att färgas starkt av dess innehåll. Men vad var det egentligen som fångade Bos intresse till den grad att han långt senare i livet utnämnde den till hans kanske mest centrala läsupplevelse? Förmodligen för att Ljungdahl här lyckas presentera en filosofisk syntes som byggde på Marx och i ännu högre grad Engels. Den brukar benämnas den dialektiska materia-lismen och erbjöd möjligheten att utforma en sammanhållen världsbild. Fyrtio år senare menade Bo att han främst fångats av Ljungdahls öppna och generösa marxism. Till viss del känns det som en efterkonstruktion. Vi måste betänka att den i alla fall inte hindrade Bo att under sent 1960-tal försvara en ganska dogmatisk kommunism mot en mera frihetlig vänster som sökte inspiration från den unge Marx snarare än från Lenin och Stalin. Lenins hetsiga upp-görelse med (rysk) nykantiansk idealism Materialism och empiriokriticism (först utgiven på ryska 1909) var i svensk översättning en vältummad skrift i Bo Gustafssons bibliotek. Ljungdahls dialektiska materialism var knappast heller annorlunda än Lenins eller Stalins. Men han var poet och lysande stilist som lyckades med konststycket att utifrån Engels torra slanor skapa en syntes som vibrerar av känsla och engagemang – något som uppenbarligen starkt lockade den unge Bo sommaren 1948.

Det var draget av sammanhållande världsbild som mest fascinerande. Hela sitt liv var Bo en sökare på jakt efter mening och sammanhang. Ofta uttryckte han detta behov i närmast religiösa termer. Här skulle man kunna dra en parallell till föregångaren, Karl-Gustav Hildebrand. Hildebrand var en aktiv kristen, skrev psalmer och medverkade i arbetet med att nyöversätta Psalmboken på 1970-talet. Samtidigt var hans religiositet komplex och hade drag av mystik. Bos religiösa inriktning var mera öppen, närmast frireligiös. Förvisso var och förblev han konfessionslös. Men han letade efter en tro på något utöver det kända. Han sökte särskilt efter en motvikt till kristendomens lära om döden och uppståndelsen. Mot denna bakgrund är det inte underligt att han ständigt återkom till en passage som också finns att hämta i Ljungdahls bok: ”Det är inte bara döden som är evig utan även nyfödelsen, inte bara undergången utan även tillblivelsen.” Eller längre fram: ”Ur dödens famntag föds livet oavlåtligt på nytt.” Han återkom ständigt till dessa tankar: livet som kedjar fast vid döden och som sedan återuppstår igen. De förblev hans tröst också i svåra stunder.

Ibland fanns också något naivt över hans sökande efter en fast grund, ett slags barnatro. Han lyste och berörde alla med sin entusiasm när han tyckte sig ha funnit vad som var rätt och riktigt. För mera skeptiskt lagda tycktes hans frenetiska letande efter den Heliga Graal ibland som utmattande, ja nästan generande. Men det betydde också att han berörde alla som han mötte, som

16

Lars Magnusson

vetenskapsman, lärare och politiker. Också när det gällde bedömningen av människor hade han utan tvivel ett slags barnatro. Han bestämde sig snabbt för vilken typ av människa han hade framför sig. Det var inte sällan fråga om svart eller vitt. De som han uppskattade kunde nästan få göra vad som helst. Han var då även mycket generös med beröm och uppskattning. Hans björnlika omfamningar av dem han uppskattade är oförglömliga. På samma sätt kunde han vara avvisande mot dem som han ogillade. Han kunde bli osäker och på sin vakt. I sådana lägen kunde han förefalla mästrande och dominant. Men i all sin kraft och pondus var han en orolig själ som sökte trygghet.

*

Vi har här valt att publicera Bo Gustafssons bibliografi, förtjänstfullt sam­man ställd av hans hustru Larissa Gustafsson. Vi publicerar även en kort, ofullbordad självbiografisk text som han skrev under de sista tunga månaderna av sitt liv när han insåg att den cancer som han fått inte skulle ge med sig. Till sist har vi valt att göra tillgänglig en längre uppsats som han skrev inom ramen för ett av de projekt som han initierade vid SCASSS och som behandlar övergången från förindustri till industrialisering från och med slutet av 1700-talet; övergången till fabrikssystemet. Den blev väl aldrig riktigt färdig. Han skrev dessutom om delar av den vid flera tillfällen och vi har här valt att redigera samman de båda versionerna från 1987 respektive 1991 till en text. Men trots detta utgör den ett viktigt inlägg i debatten kring industrialismens förutsättningar som rasat inom det ekonomisk-historiska ämnet sedan slutet av 1800-talet. Genom att på ett syntetiskt vis samla många av de inlägg som gjorts i denna debatt framträder tydligt de olika argumenten, deras bärkraft och innebörd. Inte minst ger uppsatsen ett prov på Gustafssons förmåga att borra djupt analytiskt och ställa de relevanta frågorna. Det vore fel att utlämna den åt – som en av hans läromästare som vetenskapsman alltid talade om – råttornas gnagande kritik.

Vi vill med detta markera att Bo Gustafsson var en stor ekonomisk historiker. Hans omfattande skriftliga produktion innehåller många arbeten med stort vetenskapligt värde som förtjänar att bevaras och åberopas även i framtiden. Om hans vilja att försöka hålla isär det politiska från det vetenskapliga har vi redan talat om. Gustafsson hade en omutlig tilltro till vetenskapens förmåga att skapa grund för en sannare och bättre tillvaro. I detta stod han i nära sam-klang med upplysningens radikala budskap. Ansträngde man sig tillräckligt mycket kunde man tränga in i lejonets kula och få erfara sanningen. Hur svårt detta än kan verka är det ändå något som även i fortsättningen måste vägleda all god vetenskap.

17

Bo Gustafsson

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben Några minnesanteckningar

Jag föddes den 9 april 1931, just innan den stora depressionen bröt ut och min far var inlagd på Solbackens sanatorium för behandling av sin lungtuberkulos. Jag kom som nummer fyra i en syskonskara på fem barn – förutom jag Britta (1923), Anders (1925), Kjell (1928) och Kerstin (1936). Mina föräldrar hade tidigare bott i en liten stuga (”Friden” kallad) nära Avesta kyrkogård. De hade gift sig när mor blev havande med Britta. Mor kom från en järnbruksarbetar-familj, Johan och Johanna Hallgren, och fars föräldrar var en rallare, Per Adolf Gustafsson och hans maka, Maria, som arbetade som mjölkerska på Avesta Jernverks stora jordbruksanläggning.

Jag vet inte mycket om mina far- och morföräldrar. Morfar såg jag aldrig, eftersom han dog samma år som jag föddes. Mormor var en ytterst duglig och lite karg kvinna. Hon hade vuxit upp i en stor barnskara med en ensamstående mor och sades vara uppfödd på lingon, gröt och mjölk någonstans i Norbergs-trakten. Under kriget gick jag ofta till henne med söndagsmat där hon bodde i ett rum på Älvnäs, inte långt från kyrkogården. Farfar såg jag bara en gång på avstånd sittande vid badhuset i Gamla Byn, när mor och jag var på väg till stan för att handla. Han lär ha varit en svår man och farmor skilde sig från honom redan före första världskriget. Farmor var däremot en ljus och rar människa som också mor uppskattade. Jag minns ännu den skål med kladdiga karamel-ler som hon alltid bjöd på. Hon bodde vid den tiden i Djäknehyttan i Avesta, inte långt från Uppsjön, där vi bodde.

Mor – Judith Teresia Hallgren (1896–1955) – hade tidigt börjat arbeta i Stockholm som tjänsteflicka och kokerska i s.k. finare familjer, bl.a. hos en kapten Hallström, som tydligen var kartograf, bl.a. i Härjedalen, där familjen vistades på sommaren. När hon blev gravid med Britta erbjöds hon t.o.m. att få stanna i en av dessa familjer, ett erbjudande som jag tror hon övervägde, eftersom hon blivit tveksam till ett giftermål med far. Det var mor som stod för de litterära och konstnärliga intressena i äktenskapet. Hon förde med sig i boet verk av Snoilsky och andra författare och hennes stolthet var ett köksmöble-mang som ritats av Carl Malmsten. Det var mor som såg till att jag fick börja spela flöjt och hon själv var mycket musikintresserad. Tyvärr dömdes hon till att bli en hårt arbetande husmor i en omodern bostad och hade ytterst lite hjälp av min far. Hon fick hämta vatten från en brunn, som var frusen på vintern och för att tvätta stortvätt tvingades hon frakta tung och våt tvätt på en skottkärra mellan hemmet och älven, som låg flera kilometer bort.

18

Bo Gustafsson

Far, Anders Gustaf (1897–1973) fick börja arbeta i järnverket efter skolan och under 20-talet var han byggnadsarbetare i verket (”råtthålsmurare” kall-lade han det). Som byggnadsarbetare kom han i kontakt med syndikalisterna och anslöt sig mycket tidigt till Hinke Berggrens ungsocialistiska klubb i Av-esta. I klubbens bibliotek fanns arbeten av de stora ryska romanförfattarna, Dostojevskij, och Tolstoy, men också Krapotkin, Stirner m.fl. När klubben upplöstes delade man upp litteraturen och det var så jag själv tidigt kom i kon-takt med den ryska litteraturen. Särskilt Dostojevskijs roman ”Döda huset” gjorde ett starkt intryck på mig. Far hade också den danska översättningen (gjord av Trier) av Marx’ ”Das Kapital”, en av de första översättningar som gjordes av detta verk. Under 20-talet var far ofta arbetslös och sjuk. Under 30-talet började han slå slaggplattor i trädgården. De användes som isolerings-material i bostäder. Denna verksamhet betingades av den byggkonjunktur som socialdemokraterna skapat och pappa blev nu själv socialdemokrat och invald i stadsfullmäktige. Inom kommunalpolitiken kom han mest att syssla med byggnads- och socialpolitiska frågor. Bl.a. såg han till att Avesta fick en kommunal tvättstuga och det första daghemmet på 40-talet. Gustav Möller och makarna Myrdal var hans politiska idoler. Han låg ofta sjuk i magsår med socialpolitiska utredningar strödda kring sängen medan mor fick ta de besvärliga samtalen med Handelsbankens kamrer Stenå, som ibland hörde av sig om förfallna växlar. Far skaffade sig en liten primitiv plattfabrik i Rembo strax utanför Avesta åt Hedemorahållet. Han var nog en ganska dålig affärs-man och familjens inkomster var ytterst oregelbundna. Men han var samtidigt angelägen att ”dra till huset”, t.ex. under kriget då det var ont om mat.

När jag föddes 1931 bodde vi på Uppsjön strax utanför staden i ett litet hus med kök och vardagsrum på nedre botten och två sovrum på övre våningen. Huset ägdes av Avesta Jernverk och vi kunde bo där till 1938. Huset stod i en liten dälja med en häck av granar och lärkträd runt huset. Lärkträden drog ofta till sig blixtar, som en gång tog vägen ned genom skorstenen och ut i köket. Intill huset fanns en lada och en svinstia. Mina föräldrar höll tidvis både gris och höns som komplement till den magra kosten. Men mor var en stor artist på matlagning och sålde ibland både korv och fläsk på stadens torg. De vurmade båda för Are Waerlands hälsokostprogram och kruska med russin blev så småningom ett stående morgonmål. Men dessförinnan var hemmet ytterligt fattigt. Vi fick ibland besök från den s.k. dispensären genom en sträng dam som kom med avlagda barnkläder till mina syskon. Min syster Britta har berättat att hon vissa dagar i början av 30-talet fick nöja sig med hårt bröd och stekflott som enda kost.

Men för mig var tiden på Uppsjön en idyllisk tid. Nära oss bodde en bonde, Leonard Vikström, och jag följde ofta hans son Bror ut på fälten med häst och vagn. Jag var också mycket tillsammans med femverkets lantarbetare, som varje dag samlades vid stallet i Älvnäs, där rättaren och ibland förvalta-ren fördelade arbetsuppgifterna. Förvaltaren var en stor tjock karl som åkte omkring i en T-Ford med dåliga bromsar. När han parkerade bilen lade han

19

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

därför en sten framför ett av bakhjulen om vägen lutade. En gång plockade vi bort stenen, när han parkerat i en liten backe. Jag minns ännu hur han med skumpande mage sprang efter bilen och hotade oss med repressalier. Men vi gömde oss djupt inne i rågåkern. En gång kom rättaren på oss med att sitta i en av rovkällarna och mumsa mogna rovor; det var bara att pallra sig upp genom luckan och få en avbasning.

När jag tänker på dessa första sju år av mitt liv känner jag lukten av svet-tiga hästar och ser rykande sädesfält, sol och åska. På vårarna klättrade vi upp i björkarna runt huset och fäste tomma ölflaskor med ståltråd under en skåra i barken och drack sen den söta sav som rann ned i flaskorna. En tid hade mina föräldrar killingar, som betade längs åkanten. Men det slutade med att en av killingarna halkade ned längs åkanten och ströp sig i den lina, som var fästad vid ett spett ovanför åkanten. Det enda jag var rädd för var Vikströms stora katt som sades vara ”folkilsken” och jag gick långa omvägar för att slippa möta honom. Ibland fantiserade jag om att Thurneman-ligan (från Sala) var i antågande men det förblev fantasier. Det var mycket tal om Thurneman-ligan i början av 1930-talet och dess raffinerade sätt att ta livet av folk i södra Dalarna och norra Västmanland, särskilt det fall då de borrade ett hål i en stugvägg och gasade ihjäl en gumma på natten med bilens avgasrör. Men för övrigt var livet idylliskt. Jag hade bara en lekkamrat, Gunnel Söderlund, dotter till en supig smed som ofta slog både hustru och barn. Gunnel och jag var lika gamla och vi lekte oftast häst och körkarl, vanligen med Gunnel som häst. Jag kan inte minnas att jag hade några andra leksaker än tomma kryddburkar, grankottar som kor och med stickor till ben och så förstås barkbåtar. Mitt första minne är just en bild av mig och mamma sittande utanför huset en sommareftermiddag i gassande sol. Mamma har ett handarbete och jag leker med kanelburkar och grankottar. Kanelburkarna fyller jag med sand och jag stoppar fyra tändstickor i grankottarna, som därigenom förvandlas till kor. Det rann en liten å nedanför huset som var idealisk för kapplöpning med barkbåtar men annars fick vat-tenpussarna på vägen och vattenfyllda diken duga. Det var en stor händelse när Britta sydde en docka åt mig till julklapp. Stolt höll jag dockan i famn, när Britta skjutsade mig på sparken på vintervägarna runt Uppsjön. På den tiden fanns inget elektriskt ljus utanför stadsgränsen. Men på vårvintern kunde man se ganska bra, om det var fullmåne. Jag minns hur vi då kunde fara snabbt på skarsnön över fälten med spark eller skidor. En stor händelse var det s.k. TT-loppet på motorcykel i Avesta 1936, då finländaren Lampinen blev segrare. Det inspirerade oss bröder till att rigga upp en fingerad motorcykel i ett träd bestående av gamla däck och rostiga rör. Mina syskon hade faktiskt cyklar, eftersom det var långt till skolan. Själv lärde jag mig cykla genom att lägga en taggtrådsvinda i ramen på syster Brittas cykel och sen glida nedför backen till Uppsjön. Så lärde jag mig hålla balansen efter åtskilliga omkullkörningar och skrubbsår. En egen cykel fick jag först i 12-årsåldem, som jag plockade ihop av olika cykeldelar. Dessförinnan var det mitt privilegium att ibland få springa efter Kjell när han cyklade med handen på pakethållaren.

20

Bo Gustafsson

En annan stor händelse var när järnverkets ägare, Axel Axelson Johnson, installerade visenter från Polen i Stubbsvedan, strax ovanför Uppsjön. De hade köpts i Polen och var där utrotningshotade. Jag minns ännu så väl ka-ravanen med lastbilar när den dök upp vid horisonten med alla bufflarna. Jag sprang allt jag kunde över åkrarna för att hinna få en skymt av dem vid utlast-ningen. Det var en glimt ifrån den stora världen. Glimtar från den fina världen stod familjen Axelson Johnson för. De hade ridstall i Avesta och naturligtvis herrgård. När Johnson och hans döttrar red fram genom stan, stod vi barn i andakt vid vägkanten och tittade på. Ryttarna representerade en annan värld och rentav ett högre väsen.

Jag älskade hästar. Min favorit var mjölkstoet Lilly som mjölkkusken Elis Bergström på brukets ladugård körde, när han distribuerade mjölkflaskor till borgarna inne i stan. Jag fick äran att följa med och springa med flaskorna från vagn till dörr. Det var då jag första gången kom i kontakt med bilar i mörker. Det måste vara minst ett avstånd på 200 meter till bilarna innan jag vågade springa över gatan, trots att bilarna knappast körde fortare än 20 km i timmen.

Ett större äventyr var det att åka med på kuskbocken i bagartrillan, som körde ut bröd runt stan en gång i veckan. Kusken – en tonåring – var ganska vild och det var också den svarta ponny som drog trillan, som var försedd med en riggad presenning bak, under vilken brödet förvarades. Jag minns särskilt en gång i åskväder och hällande regn på de små vägarna runt stan, då den svarta ponnyn råkade i sken. Samtidigt hade några buspojkar lagt en stege tvärsöver vägen i slutet av en backe, då ponnyn galopperade ovanligt fort. Gudskelov tog ponnyn ett språng med både trilla och kuskar över stegen. Men brödet där bak hamnade förstås huller om buller i trillan.

En stor händelse under 30-talet var också byggandet av den stora kraft-ledningen till Krångede vid Indalsälven. Kraftledningen lades bara några hundra meter från vårt hus och de väldiga stålkonstruktioner som bar upp högspänningsledningen förändrade landskapssiluetten. Men viktigare var att just 30-talet kom med elektriciteten till en del av den svenska landsbygden. Den förvandlade mörker till ljus under den mörka årstiden, då tidigare endast månljuset hade gett vägledning.

Innan jag började i skolan 1938 tillbringade jag vanligen dagarna till-sammans med järnverkets lantarbetare, framför allt med en äldre man, Kalle Jansson, som var mycket vänlig. När han plöjde åkrarna kunde jag följa med fåra upp och fåra ned. På vintrarna körde vi timmer på släde i skogen. Och jag frågade honom om allt upptänkligt mellan himmel och jord. En gång sade han till mina föräldrar: ”Den här pojken han bara frågar och frågar.” Så var det nog och frågandet fortsatte senare i livet. När mina föräldrar frågade vad jag skulle bli, svarade jag: ”Luffare, taskspelare eller professor”. Kanske det blev så, i varje fall delvis.

1938 flyttade vi från Uppsjön in till stan, närmare bestämt Garmakaregatan, till ett flerfamiljshus i två våningar och två uppgångar som allmänt kallades Ångermansbo därför att byggaren som uppförde huset ångrade sig efteråt. Vi

21

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

fick där en tvårumslägenhet med kök, badrum med badkar, rinnande vatten, elspis och tvättstuga i källaren. För mamma var detta en stor lättnad i hushålls-arbetet. Men eftersom vi var sju i familjen var förutsättningen att Britta skulle skaffa sig husrum på egen hand. Så skedde också. Hon var först tjänsteflicka hos rektor Svedberg vid läroverket, sen arbetade hon på pensionat Bergslagen och Avesta Lasarett. Vid krigsslutet behövde hon hjälpa mamma i hemmet och fick då hyra ett rum hos en grannfamilj, Hagmans. Trots det var vi trångbodda. Mamma och pappa sov i sängkammaren tillsammans med minsta barnet, Kerstin, och vi tre bröder sov i vardagsrummet i en utdragssoffa med mej i mit ten och inte särskilt uppskattad av mina två äldre bröder. Efterhand fick jag en egen säng, som egentligen var en utdragbar stol. Under kriget ökade trångboddheten, när mormor tidvis bodde hos oss liksom en norsk flykting, som arbetade åt pappa och sov i tamburen.

Samma höst som vi flyttade började jag i småskolan inhyst i den s.k. Klos-terskolan i Älvnäs, ett par km från Uppsjön och byggd av slaggsten i skotsk klosterstil. Huset finns fortfarande kvar och utnyttjas nu bl.a. av katolska kyr-kan. Jag har inga direkta minnen av första skoldagen bortsett från att jag gjorde bort mig ordentligt. Fröken Nyvelius hade sagt vid uppropet att vi skulle få lov i tre timmar. Jag fattade detta fel och trodde att vi skulle få lov i tre dagar…. När jag kom efter tre dagar, efter att mamma fått anmodan att sända mig till skolan, stod jag i dörren till klassrummet och grät högljutt. Synden förläts och fröken Nyvelius hade i mig en trogen riddare, som plockade svamp åt henne men som tyvärr också kastade sönder en fönsterruta med mössan (svampen bestod av fem-sex trådar fingersvamp, upptäckta av mig och min kamrat Pelle Ståhl efter den första svamplektionen).

Mina skolminnen är ovanligt bleka. Jag hade förmodligen lätt för mig och har inget minne av traggel med läxor hemma: så trångbodda som vi var, var badrummet den enda fredade platsen och där fick man inte sitta länge. Mina bästa skolkamrater var de små och lite sjukliga. Jag minns den lille Pelle Ståhl, som jag lekte mycket tillsammans med. Han bodde i Nybyn, inte alltför långt från Garmakargatan. Min bänkkamrat var Ture Fröberg. Han var kavat men väldigt blek. På morgonen kom han till skolan med ögon som var igenklistrade av en gul, klibbig vätska. Först efter ett par timmar kunde han se ordentligt. Själv var jag ju ganska stor och stark och åtog mig gärna beskyd-darrollen. Men den innebar samtidigt att jag skulle testas av klassen, så fort det kom en annan stor och stark kille till vår klass. Vi var inte dummare än vi insåg att båda parter tjänade på allians eller åtminstone fredlig samlevnad. Jag kan inte komma ihåg att jag var invecklad i några slagsmål. Det var däremot min bror Kjell som aldrig kunde motstå en utmaning men som oftast vann tack vare styrka och envishet.

Det var lätt men långt att ta sig från Uppsjön till Klosterskolan i Älvnäs. Det var kortare men svårare att hitta hem till Garmakaregatan första gången, trots att avståndet inte var längre än högst en kilometer. Det var för att den tätare bebyggelsen med identiskt lika stora röda bruksvillor för järnverksarbe-

22

Bo Gustafsson

tare var så annorlunda från vad jag var van vid från de vida, öppna fälten runt Uppsjön. Där kunde man räkna husen på den ena handens fingrar: närmast oss Kalle Vesslén och hans bror, båda lite underliga, sen Solhlströms, så Perssons och därefter Djäknehyttan, där farmor och farbror Herbert med familj bodde, och halvvägs till Älvnäs Nybo, Storbo och Skärlsbo, där morbror Axel (som hade epilepsi) och moster Alerta från Gotland bodde och där också brukets jordbruksförvaltare Jakobsson bodde. Men så småningom lärde jag mig vägen mellan hem och skola, som bl.a. passerade konsul Jonssons ridstallar med alla hans ridhästar, som sommartid skrittade omkring i avlånga fållor runt stallet.

Från tiden i småskolan har jag ett minne som aldrig lämnar mig. Vår familj besöktes ofta av en snäll farbror från Karlbo utanför Krylbo. En gång gav han mig och syster Kerstin en hel tvåkrona var. Jag köpte omedelbart två stora chokladkakor för min peng. Efter några dagar stal jag Kerstins och gjorde sammalunda. Det var en lördag och jag ställde mig vid bron över Samuelsån och smaskade. Men tuggan växte i mun och till slut kastade jag resten av chokladen i ån. Väl hemma hade Kerstin upptäckt förlusten. Pappa frågade om jag tagit tvåkronan. Jag nekade rodnade. Han lät det bero vid detta. En an-nan gång hade jag och en lekkamrat, kallad Fläsk-Lasse, skurit ned tvättlinor för en tant för att ha som lasso. Jag var då säkert tio-tolv år och stor beundrare av Fläsk-Lasse, som fick cowboy-kläder och dito pistoler från en farbror i USA. Vi ertappades när vi skar ned tvättlinorna men lyckades schappa. På kvällen kom mannen i den förfördelade familjen hem till oss och påtalade saken för pappa. Jag fick loma iväg med honom till brottsplatsen och tillstå brottet, även om jag fegt skyllde på Fläsk-Lasse som den som ”tuppat i mig” att vi skulle ta linorna. Det hela slutade med en reprimand. Linorna hämtades förmodligen hemma hos Fläsk-Lasse.

Som barn var vi också organiserade i ligor för äppelknyckning (gärna iförda golfbyxor, s.k. äppelknyckarbyxor) som gruffade med varandra på mörka höstkvällar. Det fanns en Villa-liga från de röda fyrfamiljshusen av trä för bruksarbetarna (numera finns bara en eller två av dessa träslott bevarade, gulmålade), en Ollarsbo-liga, som vi tillhörde, och en By-liga från Gamla Byn i Avesta med 1600-talsbebyggelse från kopparverkets tid. Ollarsbo var en liten stadsdel med träkåkar mellan Garmakargatan och in mot stan fram till den plats där biografen Röda Kvarn låg. Numera finns högst ett eller två hus kvar av den bebyggelsen. Ligorna var ganska harmlösa och ägnade sig mindre åt slagsmål än åt att knycka äpplen i trädgårdarna och att spela harts-fiol vid stugknutarna. Förmodligen var det Thurnemans Sala-liga som var inspiratio-nen.

1940 började jag i den s.k. storskolan, d.v.s. klasserna 3–6 i folkskolan, i den stora skolbyggnaden nära Marcus-torget. Min debut var också där fatal. Vi stod på skolgården och pratade före uppropet. Jag råkade spotta på mar-ken men märkte inte att en skolfröken samtidigt promenerade förbi och fick spottloskan på skon. Jag fick en skopa ovett och fick torka bort loskan med min näsduk.

23

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

Krigsåren kände vi mest av genom ransoneringen, även om vi ibland fantiserade att kriget också nått oss, när vi hörde muller i fjärran. De flesta livsmedel var ransonerade: bröd, socker, mjöl, kött, fläsk, smör, kaffe m.m. Behov av och tillgång på ransoneringskuponger för enskilda livsmedel varierade mellan familjer med och utan barn, familjer på landet och i stad o.s.v. Det innebar att det uppstod en marknad på lösa kuponger: bönder behövde inte alla smör- och köttkuponger men saknade sockerkuponger i tillräcklig omfattning. Eftersom pappa hade kontakter med bönder i trakten klarade vi oss ganska bra. Kaffe drygades ut genom att mamma rostade havre i ugn till kaffeersättning, pappa köpte fläsk, kött och smör av bönder och höll kaniner och vi hade ett stort potatisland hos en bonde. Svårast var det att få tag i fisk. Jag stod ibland i fiskkö hos stadens fiskhandlare (Fisk-Pelle) för ett kilo strömming, sill eller vitling. Men jag har inget minne av att det var ont om mat för oss under kriget.

Vid det laget var pappa också egenföretagare i byggmaterialbranschen, ska-pad av 30-talets bostadsbyggande. Pappa tillverkade mellanväggsplattor och hålsten för husgrunder. Liksom många arbetslösa under 30-talet hade pappa börjat på egen hand hemma i trädgården på Uppsjön att slå mellanväggsplattor av slagg, sand och cement i enkla formar som torkade på pallar i långa rader. I slutet av 30-talet skaffade han sig en lastbil av märket Chevrolet för att frakta slagg från Spännarhyttan i Norberg till en liten ”fabrik” som han hade mellan Avesta och Rembo. Han hade ett par-tre anställda och dessutom en chaufför, eftersom han själv inte hade körkort. Plattfabriken gav större men mer oregel-bundna inkomster än tidigare, men pappa var ingen stor affärsman. Han var mer intresserad av politik än av affärer och låg ofta efter med faktureringen. Mamma fick rycka pengar av honom till hushållet, särskilt när han fått betalt och penningpungen nästan sprack av sedlar. Men det hände inte alltför ofta, eftersom köparna vanligen var egnahemsbyggande arbetare på järnverket.

När jag var i fyraårsåldern hade jag en dramatisk upplevelse. Pappa slog slaggplattor i trädgården och ställde upp dem i högra travar för torkning. Men marken var ganska ojämn. En eftermiddag när jag lekte vid travarna rasade de och jag begravdes under de blöta slaggmassorna. Pappa och en av hans hjälpkarlar grävde som besatta tills de fick tag i mig och jag bars in i huset. Jag tror inte jag fick några men av detta bortsett från att jag som vuxen led av klaustrofobi och var rädd för att bli instängd.

Mitt största nöje var att åka med i lastbilen, som kunde pressas upp i 40 km i timmen på Norbergsvägen. Jag har ännu oset av olja och bensin i näsan när jag tänker på dessa tillfällen. En gång lånade jag tio år gammal bilnycklarna och körde bilen 50 meter och backade tillbaka, medan kvarterets barn beund-rande bevittnade bravaden.

Efter krigsslutet konkurrerades pappas företag ut av större och tekniskt mer avancerade företag i branschen (jag tror det var Bröderna Forsell i Norberg). Då började pappa arbeta åt andra företag, t.ex. Ernst Sundhs byggföretag i Avesta och därefter Västerås Byggmaterial som dessas platschef i Avesta. Pappas

24

Bo Gustafsson

byggintressen övertogs av Anders, som blev verkmästare hos Sundströms byggnadsföretag i Krylbo, och Kjell, som läste till teknisk byggnadsingenjör i Solna och sedan blev egenföretagare i byggmaterialbranschen. Själv arbetade jag på somrarna, först i plattfabriken i Rembo och därefter med att slipa och ytbehandla golv åt Västerås Byggmaterial. Men pappa var en krävande arbetsledare, som hade lätt att ge kritik och svårt att berömma. Lyckligtvis såg jag inte av honom så ofta beroende bl.a. på att mina föräldrar skildes 1949 och pappa flyttade hemifrån.

Jag har nu gått händelserna långt i förväg. När jag slutade i folkskolan 1944 som näst bäste elev i min klass fick jag börja realskolan, som var fyraårig och som avslutades med realexamen. Realskolan var inhyst i en grå träbyggnad, som senare brann ned, och som jag upplevde som ganska nedsliten. Rektor var Josef Lindh, matematiklärare var först Folke Nordström (”Kalle”, en inte alldeles behaglig typ som hade lätt att bryta ut i kommentarer som ”Heliga Enfald!”, ”Du måste vara en tänkande August(a)”! etc.) Matematik var inte mitt bästa ämne och i tredje klass fick jag B- i betyg. Då köpte jag från NKI-skolan samtliga uppgifter som getts i realexamen i matematik sedan 1917 och räknade igenom dessa och fick litet a i betyg i fjärde klass! Efter ”Kalle” fick jag Ingrid Tunell som matematiklärare, en underbar lärare som tog fram det bästa hos eleverna. Läraren i biologi var ”Fimpen”, passionerad rökare, vänlig men excentrisk. Han fick mig att samla och pressa växter till ett stort herba-rium, som jag övertagit av mina bröder. Men den viktigaste läraren för mig i realskolan var dr Stig Backman i historia. Han var en fascinerande lärare med stora kunskaper som han gärna delade med sig av. När jag kom till Uppsala fann jag att han skrivit en avhandling om Karl XII:s polska fälttåg, som tyvärr inte fick docentbetyg och som uppenbarligen hade haft Karl-Gustaf Hilde-brand, min blivande lärare i Uppsala, som opponent. (Hildebrand själv lär ha sysslat med Karl XII-forskning innan han skrev avhandlingen om Falu stads historia men han hade enligt ryktet tvingats lämna ämnet efter att ha stupat på ogenomtränglig chiffertext. När han under 1950-talet meriterade sig för pro-fessuren i ekonomisk historia skrev han en lång uppsats om Karl XII-bilden hos Bernard Beskow, vill jag minnas.)

Mina stora intressen under tiden i realskolan var läsning och musik. Jag läste gärna de ryska klassikerna, särskilt Dostojevskij, men också pojkböcker av det enklare slaget: böckerna om Biggles och Bill den förskräcklige, Lisa Tetzners böcker om sotarpojken m.m. I hemlighet släpade jag hem deckar-magasin i högar – särskilt norrmannen Richter-Frichs om kommissarie Ask i Oslo. Men jag blev så uppskakad av läsningen att mamma förbjöd den. Det var återigen den äventyrlige Fläsk-Lasse som var leverantör av den förbjudna frukten.

Någon gång under åren 1943–44 blev jag tidningspojke på kvällarna och sålde den av LO nystartade Afton-Tidningen (AT), som väl var tänkt som en motvikt mot det nazianstuckna Aftonbladet, ägt av Torsten Kreuger. AT var en verkligt bra tidning, som lyckades engagera intressanta journalister som

25

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

A. Gunnar Bergman, James Rössel och Stig Ahlgren men som också räknade Karl-Gerhard till sina medarbetare. Tidningarna togs hem av bokhandlare Emmanuel Törnqvist och vi, ett tiotal tidningspojkar och -flickor, sålde dem i stan. Jag tror jag fick två eller tre öre per sålt exemplar och som mest sålde jag 120 tidningar per kväll. Men då tog jag ibland hjälp av någon kamrat, som då fick ett öre per tidning. En del köpare ville betala för varje tidning den kväll de köpte, vilket gjorde att upplagan fluktuerade, eftersom dörrknack-ningen ibland inte gav resultat. Det bästa var de köpare som betalade i förväg en vecka eller en månad. Då var det bara att leverera. Det krävde å andra sidan att jag förde bok över betalningarna. Värst var det fåtal köpare som envisades med att köpa tidningen på kredit och dröjde med betalningen. Då måste jag ligga ute med pengarna till bokhandlaren. Jag minns en trist person, som ideligen lovade att betala men inte gjorde det. Till slut stod jag gråtande utanför hans dörr och bad honom att bättra sig. Jag tror han gjorde det. Tack vare inkomsterna från min tidningsförsäljning kunde jag köpa kläder på egen bekostnad och t.o.m. en enkel Agfa lådkamera, som gav alldeles utmärkta bilder. När AT lades ned försvann också inkomsterna. Strax före krigsslutet fick jag scharlakansfeber. Det började en vinterkväll då jag med hjälp av min vän Tord Hall bar ut de 120 exemplaren. När jag kom hem hade jag hög feber. Efter ett tag konstaterades scharlakansfeber och jag lades in på epidemisjuk-huset i Krylbo i sex veckor. Bokhandlare Törnqvist kom personligen dit med bokpresenter, bl.a. Perry Mason-boken ”Mysteriet med den tjutande hunden” av Earl Stanley Gardner. På sjukhuset ådrog jag mig huvudlöss. Eftersom jag hade mest med löss betraktades jag som upphovet till dess man fann att källan var en liten kille från Malung som hette Mats Matell. Vi försågs alla med s.k. sabadill-huva indränkt i ättika och efter ett tag var vi alla lusfria. Mina kära bröder förärade mig inte desto mindre med öknamnet Luskungen.

Året innan jag tog realexamen 1948 hade stadens fäder lyckats inrätta ett kommunalt gymnasium i Avesta med två reallinjer (matematisk-fysisk respektive biologisk linje) med fria tillval. Jag valde den biologiska linjen och valde till franska språket. Biologin var intressant men ganska knappologisk (vi sysslad med lansett-fisken en hel termin) och genetik fick man läsa sig till själv, om man iddes (jag gjorde det, bl.a. på grund av den då upphetsade diskussionen om ryssen Lysenkos hybridiseringsförsök, skarpt kritiserade av Julian Huxley i England och Åke Gustavsson i Sverige). Jag köpte och läste en fin framställning av genetikens grunder författad av en dansk genetiker vid namn Henning Poulsen. Franskundervisningen var ganska slapp på grund av att läraren inte ansåg att realstudenter egentligen var intresserade av franska. Jag tog dock specialarbete i franska och läste Voltaires Candide. Men mitt stora intresse i gymnasiet var litteraturhistoria och jag var med om att bilda en litterär klubb och ingick också i redaktionen för studenttidningen ”Plumpen”. Jag skrev studentuppsatsen i form av en jämförelse mellan Thomas Mann och G. Bernard Shaw. Däremot gick det dåligt i matematik. Jag skrev B- på studentskrivningen och kom upp i muntlig prövning i matematik. Där lyfte jag

26

Bo Gustafsson

mig själv i håret. Jag fick till uppgift att bevisa Guldins regel i stereometri. Jag kunde inte beviset men jag lyckades härleda det från en annan sats. Jag fick därigenom godkänt betyg i ämnet.

Det var extra svårt att gå upp i studentmuntan på grund av att mamma under natten fått hjärnblödning. År 1949 hade mamma och pappa skilt sig och alla barn utom jag och Kerstin, min yngsta syster, var utflugna. Kjell och Anders var gifta eller på väg att gifta sig (med Olga Bergkvist från Storsjökapell och Gävle i Kjells fall och med en flicka från Tänger nära Dalgränsen (Annagreta) i Anders. Britta, min äldsta syster, hade flyttat till Västerås och var sambo med Emil Olsson från Fornby, som fått arbete vid ASEA. Jag hade stött mamma i hennes beslut att acceptera skilsmässa och var ganska glad att vara av med pappa i huset. Hans närvaro innebar ett psykiskt tryck på oss alla och mamma hade länge farit illa i det äktenskapet. Vi stod varandra mycket nära. Mamma led av reumatism och när jag kom hem från skolan masserade jag hennes ben, när hon vilade sig och ofta somnade hon in under massagen. Dagarna före min studentexamen i slutet av maj 1951 hade mamma storstädat, eftersom hon väntade hem folk med anledning av min examen. Det blev för mycket för henne. Hon blev sjuk under eftermiddagen och kvällen. Jag kallade hem provinsialläkaren, vars namn jag här inte ska nämna men som var känd för sina alkoholproblem. Han ställde diagnosen ”förkylning”, trots att det rörde sig om hjärnblödning. Mamma blev allt sämre under natten och jag kallade på eget bevåg på ambulans och vi for till Avesta Lasarett, där rätt diagnos snabbt ställdes. Samtidigt fick jag bannor av jourhavande läkare för att ha kommit ned. Det var på den tiden som man inte gjorde något särskilt åt hjärnblödning. Det var en dramatisk natt och jag for hem och sov ett par timmar före den muntliga examen, som alltså trots allt gick ganska bra. Såvitt jag minns tog jag studenten den 21 maj 1951. Det firades med att vi först besökte mamma på sjukhuset, som emellertid ännu låg i koma. Det blev en dämpad kaffebjudning hemma. Britta beslöt att stanna kvar och tog hand både om Kerstin, mej och mamma när hon kom hem från sjukhuset. Själv var jag tvungen att rycka in till 114 i Gävle för att göra rekryten.

Men innan jag berättar om tiden i lumpen måste jag säga något om min personliga utveckling fram till dess. Jag var inte särskilt mycket tillsammans med andra jämnåriga utan gick för mig själv mest. Helst läste jag men jag var också aktiv idrottsman med inriktning på kulstötning men framför allt diskus och så småningom slägga. Musik var mitt andra stora intresse. Jag var förskräckligt blyg för flickor och kunde inte dansa. När jag en gång vågade gå till en skoldans satt jag mest i omklädningsrummet och trotsade all försök av flickor att dra upp mig på dansgolvet. Jag smet hem så fort jag kunde och stod och smygrökte pappas Gapstan-cigaretter i källaren, innan jag gick upp. Sam-tidigt hade jag en stark sexualitet. Jag kunde ligga timmavis på balkonggolvet och smygtitta på den vackra grannen, fru Britta Lindberg, som gärna låg ute på gräsmattan och solbadade. Men som sagt, flickor vågade jag inte närma mig. På stadsbiblioteket satt jag ofta hela kvällarna i ett innerum och tittade på

27

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

bilderna i en illustrerad utgåva av Casanovas memoarer tills bibliotekarierna undrade vad jag var så intresserad av och jag parallellt började läsa ett stort vetenskapligt verk som avledningsmanöver.

Inom idrotten var det friidrotten som lockade. Jag levde ju i efterdyningarna av Berlinolympiaden 1936 och Sveriges storhetstid inom medeldistanslöpning (Gunder Hägg, Arne Andersson, Lennart Strand och Henry Eriksson) fram till och med Londonolympiaden 1948. I Berlin hade Jesse Owens sprungit 100 meter på 10,3 och hoppat 8 meter i längd, samtidigt som den amerikanske jättebabyn Jack Torrance stött otroliga 17,34 i kula med tysken Helmuth Woelcke på andra plats med 16,40. Samtidigt tog Sverige guldmedaljen på 110 meter häck och om jag inte minns fel blev Lennart Strandberg trea på 100 meter. Helmuth Woelcke var min idol som kulstötare. Senare blev europamästaren Adolfo Consolini från Italien min idol i diskus. (Consolini var den förste som kastade diskus med ryggen i stället för vänster sida i kastriktningen, vilket varit mönster alltsedan Myrons diskuskastare från det klassiska Greklands tid.) Själv gick det bäst för mig i diskus, eftersom jag inte var tillräckligt snabb i kulstötningen. Senare blev slägga min bästa gren, eftersom min tyngd hjälpte mig att utnyttja centrifugalkraften i de tre svängarna. I slägga var Bosse Eriksson svensk mästare tills han för en tid fick avstå titeln till Erik Johansson från Umedalen, som emellertid började fuska med släggvikten. En stor upplevelse för mig var året 1949, då Avesta IF reste till Oslo och tävlade med en klubb i staden, och vi samtidigt kunde bese Europamästerskapen med inslag av amerikanska fenomen, bl.a. diskuskastaren Fortune Gordon, som väl var den förste som kastade över 60 meter (Consolini hade kastat 54 meter tror jag). Jag deltog också i Mellansvenska Ungdomsmästerskapen samma år i Uppsala och hade glädjen att placera mig före den kommande svenske mästaren Erik Uddebom i diskus. Men sen var det slut på tävlandet. En dag när jag stod på planen och kastade hojtade en av stadens ledande kommunister att jag borde ge idrotten på båten och ägna mig åt politik i stället. Han lånade mig Stalins ”Leninismens problem” och bad mig läsa den. Något senare valdes jag till ordförande i lokalavdelningen av Förbundet Sverige-Sovjetunionen och förärades Stalins samlade verk i tretton band på engelska. De blev inte mycket lästa men kom till bra användning i Uppsala som sängunderstöd för en utdragsbädd i studentrummet, efter det att jag träffat Kristina, min första fru.

Den stora läsupplevelsen under gymnasietiden blev Arnold Ljungdals ”Marxismens världsbild” (1947), som inhandlats av pappa men knappast lästs. Ljungdals öppna marxism tilltalade mig och för mig var det som en vandring till Damaskus: jag såg plötsligt ljuset och sammanhangen, framför allt i historien. Jag tillbringade en hel sommar – det kan ha varit 1948 mel-lan realskolan och gymnasiet – med att läsa den grundligt. Det som för mig kändes så befriande var att Ljungdal lyckades att foga in marxismen i ett större idéhistoriskt perspektiv. Marxismen var den lejonets kula dit alla spår ledde från den föregående utvecklingen: tysk filosofi, franskt politiskt tänkande och engelsk politisk ekonomi. Jag betraktade mig som marxist från 17 års ålder

28

Bo Gustafsson

därför att marxismen enligt min mening var den mest överlägsna av exis-terande världsåskådningar, när det gällde att förklara och ge mening åt den historiska utvecklingen. Men marxismen var och förblev huvudsakligen ett intellektuellt intresse. Jag var aldrig intresserad av praktiskt politiskt arbete, vilket jag emellertid drogs in i så småningom på grund av en fäaktig oförmåga att säga nej. Jag blev ett slags politiker mot sin vilja. Men det skulle dröja. För även åren i Clarté i Uppsala handlade mest om studier och diskussioner.

Jag sade ovan att musiken vid sidan av idrotten var mitt andra stora intresse under tonåren. Intresset kom säkert från mamma, som väl kände både den klassiska och den moderna musiken. Men det stimulerades också av syster Britta och hennes fästman Emil Olsson, som kunde vissla Fritz Kreislers låtar nästan lika bra som Kreisler spelade dem på sin fiol. Bach, Beethoven och Mozart – de stod i centrum. Ingen i familjen trakterade något instrument. Men mamma ville att jag skulle lära mig spela cello (Pablo Casals, den spanske mästaren, var hennes store idol). Sagt och gjort. När jag började i realskolan hösten 1944 anmälde jag mig för musikdirektör König. Vi fick visa upp oss och tala om vilket instrument vi ville spela. För mig var saken klar: cello. Nej, sa han, du ska spela basun för du har så bra basunläppar! Jag blev jätteledsen, men tvingades släpa hem en stor ventilbasun. Efter en veckas traktering av instrumentet var jag less och lämnade tillbaka det. Jaså, sa den stränge herr König: om du inte vill spela basun så får du inte spela någonting alls!

Långt senare lärde jag mig hjälpligt cellospelning under gymnasietiden genom att ge privatlektioner i engelska till en pojke, Kjell Berglund, som be-hövde läsa upp sig i engelska och som samtidigt spelade cello. Men det var mer en episod. När pappa hörde Königs beslut blev han arg och skaffade mig en flöjt, en gammal halvböhm som han köpt billigt i Stockholm men som blev en bra startpunkt: halvböhmen hade bara några få klaffar, resten fick man klara av genom att täcka hålen med fingerdynorna. Som lärare fick jag flöjtisten i Avesta orkesterförening, en f.d. militärmusiker som hette Westin och liksom andra musiker i den av Axel Axelsson Johnsson finansierade Avesta orkes-terförening (dirigent Lennart Nerbe, som sen tror jag kom till Norrköpings symfoniorkester och vars dotter Kerstin också blev en duktig dirigent) hade en kontoristtjänst på järnverket som bas för musicerandet. Westin var en liten, rödhårig och ganska kolerisk f.d. musiksergeant som tyvärr ofta förgyllde sin, men inte min, tillvaro med alkohol. Jag gick en timme per vecka hos honom och Westin krävde för det tio kronor. I dagens penningvärde motsvarade det kanske 200 kr. Han kallade mig sitt ”guldägg” för denna extrainkomst. Redan i realskolans andra klass kunde jag framträda på en klassfest och framföra Haydens Serenade. I tredje klass fick jag spela en sats ur Mozarts flöjtkonsert i G-dur på hela skolans avslutningshögtid i början av juni. Då hade jag fått en riktig flöjt (helböhm) av franskt märke av min bror Anders. Jag tror den kostade nära tusen kronor, vilket i dag väl skulle vara 15–20 000. Jag fort-satte att spela flöjt gymnasiet igenom, samtidigt som jag började sjunga bas i gymnasiekören och i den nybildade jazzkören ”Avesta Steel Singers”, som

29

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

specialiserade sig på Glenn Miller-låtar. När mamma dog spelade jag en av hennes favoritstycken på hennes begravning, Glucks Dans i de saligas ängder ur operan ”Orfeus och Euridike”. När jag därefter for ned till Uppsala sålde jag flöjten och köpte en gitarr. Det var dumt men jag var redan tidigare intres-serad av att sjunga till gitarr och hade bl.a. fått Carl Sandburgs ”An American Songbag” av Anders och jag hade dessutom köpt en bok med negro spirituals. Först långt senare köpte jag återigen en tvärflöjt, nämligen strax efter min andra hustrus, Katrins, död. Jag tog några lektioner igen men intresset ville inte riktigt infinna sig.

Jag arbetade naturligtvis en del under skoltiden. Jag har tidigare berättat om att jag var tidningspojke några år vid krigsslutet. Under kriget hjälpte jag också till som hantlangare vid pappas cirkelsåg, en vedkap som drogs om-kring i stan, mest av min farbror Herbert. Vanligen sågade vi meterved och min uppgift var att lägga vedklabbarna i vaggan, som farbror Herbert därefter sköt fram med ena knäet så att de sågades igenom på ca 3–4 ställen avpassat för vedeldning i köksspisarna. När gubbarna kom ut med en ölflaska åt Her-bert och en åt mig, 12–14 år gammal, kände jag mig enormt vuxen och njöt av de beundrande blickarna från de omgivande barnskockarna. Värre var det på vintern då vi ibland måste såga två meter lång kolved, som kunde vara frusen och isig. Om farbror Herbert då var bakfull en måndag och vresig, så var det inte lätt att vara hantlangare. Pappa själv aktade sig för vedkapen sen han en gång nästan sågat tummen av sig.

I slutet av realskolan och i början av gymnasiet fick jag också arbeta i pappas plattfabrik i Rembo utanför Avesta på somrarna. Det var ett trist jobb eftersom jag oftast arbetade ensam i den lilla ladan långt nere i en mörk grus-grop, där jag själv blandade till en tombola (grus, slagg, cement, vatten) och sen kärrade in resultatet in i den lilla mörka ladan, där det inte fanns någon annan belysning än en osande karbidlampa. Det var ganska kusligt att stå där från 7 till 5 dagarna i ända. Det enda jag hörde var trafiken från vägen ovanför gropen och då och då grusbilarna som åkte fram och tillbaka till en grusgrop i närheten. Senare fick jag arbeta med att slipa och bona golv. Lyckligtvis slapp jag lackbehandlingen med s.k. Synteco-lack. Alla de som arbetade med detta lack fick senare problem med andning och nerver. Efter militärtjänsten arbetade jag ett par somrar på Avesta Järnverks Inköpsavdelning, mest med att ordna och katalogisera reklammaterial och därefter på Krylbo Mejeri. På det senare stället arbetade jag dels med att tillverka ost av ostmassa och paraf-finera om ost som möglat. Jag minns att jag en söndag var ensam om osttill-verkningen, vilket var maktpåliggande. När vi paraffinerade om ost, tappade vi ibland ostarna i det kokande paraffinet. Ville det sig riktigt illa måste osten ”slaktas” och styckas upp bland oss som arbetade med detta. Vi var nämligen ersättningsskyldiga för förlorade ostar. Ostbitarna var en välkommen löneför-stärkning för de flesta. På samma sätt gick det till i smörtillverkningen från vilken grädde och smör smugglades ut, särskilt när mejeristen var bortrest. Mitt sista sommarjobb hade jag i Uppsala vid mitten av 1950-talet på Uppsala

30

Bo Gustafsson

Ättiksfabrik som också gjorde slottssenapen. Det var ett arbete vid bandet eller också sysslade jag med att köra ut kartonger på lagret. Fabriken, som senare köptes av Cadbury, var på den tiden mycket idyllisk. ”Varma korvgub-bar” kom dagarna i ända med sina burkar för att köpa senap. En sommar arbetade jag tillsammans med en pingstvän, som trots bemödanden inte kunde omvända mig.

Samma sommar som mamma fick sin hjärnblödning började jag göra min rekryttjänstgöring på 114 i Gävle, d.v.s. sommaren 1951. När jag mönstrade året förut ville militärerna först sända mig till ett pansarregemente i Enkö-ping, alternativt luftvärnet i Sundsvall eller artilleriet i Östersund. Det första alternativet föll, eftersom jag var för stor för att komma upp och ned i en pansarvagn, i varje fall tillräckligt kvickt. De två andra alternativen föll, ef-tersom de enligt min mening låg alltför avlägsna från hemorten. Så det blev infanteriet i Gävle, som var huvuddestination för rumpmasar och som hade bra järnvägsförbindelser med Avesta. Jag placerades så småningom på ett pan-sarvärnskompani och fick specialisera mig på kulsprutor (m/36 och m/42) men fick också utbildning på mausergevär, kulsprutepistol, kulsprutegevär, pansarnäve, raketgevär m.m. Jag låg inne under Koreakriget, som delvis fär-gade av sig på utbildningen. De fientliga styrkorna kom alltid in från öster i Gävlebukten och när vi skulle sikta och skjuta ute i terrängen uppmanades vi att se skäggiga ryssar för vår inre blick. Eftersom jag var kommunist fortfaran-de med illusioner om Sovjetunionen, reagerade jag naturligtvis. På ren trots hade jag beställt till logementet alla s.k. vänskapstidningar, d.v.s. Sverige-

31

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

Sovjetunionen, Sverige-Polen etc. och lät dessa ligga framme. Det var natur-ligtvis barnsligt och det tyckte nog också mina kamrater fast de inte sade det. För att testa lämpligheten för utbildning till underbefäl (jag var student, men låg inte på studentkompaniet) fick vi skriva en självbiografisk uppsats. Röd och naiv skrev jag att jag var kommunist och revolutionär och att jag därför var angelägen att lära mig hantera skjutvapen, men att jag tyvärr först måste rikta dessa mot befälet för att kunna försvara folkets och landets egentliga intressen. Min plutonchef, löjtnant Trång, tyckte nog att jag var en konstig prick, underofficerarna och överfurirerna brydde sig inte. Kapten Rosenius – kompanichefen – förklarade efter ett tag att jag naturligtvis förstod att jag med mina åsikter inte kunde anförtros att leda svensk trupp! Det tyckte han nog var synd för jag var en väldigt disciplinerad soldat och en utmärkt skytt. I slutet av utbildningen försökte man placera om mig till en mindre utsatt enhet, nämligen trängkompaniet, som stod för mathållningen i fält. Men efter ett tag tackade man på det hållet nej. Kanske man var rädd att jag skulle kunna för-gifta ärtsoppan. Efter nio månaders utbildning och tre månaders påbackning med hänsyn till det internationella läget, fick vi åka hem. Utbildningen på den tiden bestod mest i marscher, skjutövningar, krigsövningar och manövrer i lite större skala. Hela första veckan var vi instängda på regementsområdet för att vi skulle vänja oss vid miljön. En orolig själ från hälsingeskogarna, Bladin, höll på att bli tokig. En natt rann han över stålstaket och kom aldrig mer till-baka. Vi hade intrycket att han gömde sig djupt inne i skogarna.

Vi var 16 mannar på varje logements och låg i våningssängar. Det rådde en rå men hjärtlig stämning. Jag umgicks mest med två killar från Avesta, Olle Tandberg, som utbildade sig till lärare i Uppsala och Olle Jernberg, som jag kände från Avesta Steel Choir. Vi hade ett gemensamt intresse i musiken. Under regementstiden kunde man få gratis utbildning i vissa ämnen. Jag tog flöjtlektioner för en musikfanjunkare och lärde mig skriva skrivmaskin utan att se på tangenterna, vilket jag hade stor nytta av senare när jag blev redak-tör för Clarté. Under lumpartiden blev mamma en helg svårt sjuk i gallsten och jag måste stanna hemma. Jag ringde och anmälde detta till regementet men uppmanades komma omedelbart. Först efter tre dagar kunde jag lämna mamma och åtalades då för rymning när jag kom tillbaka. Det blev tingsrätt under hösten men mina befäl insisterade inte på att jag skulle dömas. På frå-gan om de hade någon anledning att tro att motivet för bortovaron var avsikt att rymma, svarade de nej. Jag frikändes. Det var biträdande kompanichefen med utmärkelser från finska vinterkriget som högt och klart deklarerade att han inte trodde att jag hade velat hålla mig undan. Jag tyckte det var strongt gjort för han kunde ju ha velat ge den eldröde kommunisten en minnesbeta.

Jag åkte hem nästan varje helg – förbindelsen Krylbo, Storvik, Hofors, Sandviken, Gävle tog väl knappast mer än ett par-tre timmar. Det var alltid uppställning på kaserngården kl. 11 och så lunch och avfärd, så det blev ett dygns hemmavistelse. Men ibland var man kasernvakt eller sjuk och då kunde

32

Bo Gustafsson

man åtnjuta den fina helgmenyn, för maten var överlag mycket bra och lagad på platsen. Men i allmänhet var det trist att stanna kvar över en helg.

Det var skönt när vi ryckte ut i maj 1952. Jag fick höga betyg i min soldat-bok men tilläts som sagt inte att avancera till vicekorpral. På sommaren arbe-tade jag som nämnts på Avesta Järnverks Inköpsavdelning och nu måste jag bestämma vad jag ville bli. Mamma hade nog gärna sett en tvåårig folkskol-lärareutbildning och därefter hemkomst igen. Själv lekte jag med flera idéer. En var att bli postassistent eller tullkammarskrivare. En annan var fortsatta studier vid Uppsala universitet och då närmast för en filosofie magister i his-toria, nordiska språk och litteraturhistoria, så att jag kunde bli läroverkslärare i historia och svenska. Det blev det sistnämnda alternativets som segrade, även om tanken att bli tullkammarskrivare på en ort utan både sjöfart och tull och med möjligheter att få ägna mig åt läsning lockade mig.

Det var vemodigt den dag jag vinkade farväl åt mamma. Jag minns henne ännu där hon stod i trappfönstret och såg efter mig. Det måste ha varit i slutet av augusti eller början av september 1952. Jag hade fått ett s.k. statsstipen-dium, d.v.s. fri kost och logi i tre år och hade dessutom tagit ett mindre lån för övriga utgifter, kanske 2–3 000 kronor. Det var ett lån med s.k. statlig kredit-garanti och fast ränta (jag tror det var 3,5 procent), som betalades ut av det lokala riksbankskontoret. Ännu förmånligare på den tiden var de s.k. räntefria studielånen. Men eftersom jag var statsstipendiat kunde jag inte komma i åt-njutande av dem förrän statsstipendiet upphörde. Jag hade fått hyra ett rum ge-nom annons i Uppsala Nya Tidning hos pensionerade riksbanksvaktmästaren Sandelin och hans fru på Sysslomansgatan 15 i det s.k. Rappska huset i hörnet av Sysslomansgatan och Skolgatan, på samma ställe som det nuvarande huset som rymmer Nordbanken, systembutik, postkontor m.m. På 1950-talet var det Upplandsbanken som var bank där. Jag kunde också se tvärsöver Skolgatan apoteket Hägern, som låg där restaurang Commedia nu ligger och där man då fortfarande kunde få piller trillade med och utan recept. En av apotekarna där var f.ö. medlem av Karl-Gustaf Hildebrands seminarium.

Det var ett stort ögonblick för mig när jag kom fram efter att ha åkt järnväg med uppehåll på en rad stationer längs vägen som t.ex. Heby, Morgongåva, Järlåsa, Brunna, Ålandsdal och sist Uppsala Norra. Mitt emot Sandelins på andra våningen bodde professor Torgny Segerstedt, som strax skulle efter-träda Åke Holmbäck som rektor för universitetet, Jag var oerhört nervös och gick och satte mig vid Fyrisån bakom flickskolan Magdeburg och rökte Philip Morris tills det snurrade runt i huvudet. Jag tog en promenad för att titta på matstället där mina matkuponger gällde, nämligen Bruhns matsalar i hörnet av St. Larsgatan och Skolgatan (som väl då hette Jernbrogatan). Eftersom jag aldrig tidigare ätit ute ensam på restaurang vågade jag mig inte in utan strök omkring utanför för att se ”hur man gjorde”. Det var s.k. gåendes bord och man tog vad man ville ha. Först följande dags frukost störtade jag in, slet till mig bestick och tallrik och fick väl i mig något. På kvällen satte jag mig i uni-versitetsparken för att studera Historiska institutionen. En medelålders man

33

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

kom släntrande genom parken från Carolinahållet. Han var klädd i grå flanell-byxor och blå kavaj och sneglade vänligt på mig genom sina tjocka glasögon. Det var Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand. ”Du vet inte du men jag vet”, sa jag tyst för mig själv för det var klart att jag skulle börja med att studera historia parallellt med att jag kompletterade latin (som då var obligatorium för historiestudier med hänvisning till att äldre tiders dokument ofta var avfattade på latin).

Jag trivdes ganska bra med att bo hos Sandelins. Fru Sandelin var mycket vänlig och hon gav mig andra dagen en frukt som jag aldrig sett, nämligen en persika. Herr Sandelin gav ett mer misantropiskt intryck och tillbringade ofta dagen med att stå i fönstersmygen i stora rummet med utsikt över både Skol-gatan och Sysslomansgatan. Paret levde upp på de kvällar då de jämte deras ogifta dotter fick spela kort med den gifta dottern och hennes make, baron Cederschiöld på Fredrikslund, som var en trevlig prick och – tror jag – bror till eller i varje fall släkt med flygarbaronen.

Bortsett från måltiderna satt jag mest hemma och läste, d.v.s. när jag inte strövade omkring i stans antikvariat, som på den tiden var tre om jag inte missminner mig: Cederblads ungefär mitt emot nuvarande Studentbokhan-deln på Sysslomansgatan, Bok-Victor på Drottninggatan ungefär mitt emot nuvarande Bergmans Herrkonfektion och så ett litet dammigt ställe i källaren i Rappska Huset, där jag köpte min första antikvariska bok, nämligen en gam-mal upplaga av Putzgers ”Historische Atlas”. Men det var låg standard på antikvariaten och hos Bok-Victor var allt en förfärlig röra, även om Victor själv visste vad och var han hade. Victor var son till en framstående klassisk arkeolog, Axel W. Persson, som varit professor i Uppsala. Snart började jag därför åka till Stockholm och där botanisera i Rönnells antikvariat på Birger Jarlsgatan. Otaliga var de dyrgripar i samhällsvetenskap som jag fann där, bl.a. Marx’ ”Grundrisse” (författad 1857) i 1939 års utgåva som var nästan okänd och som först på 1960-talet trycktes om igen.

I Uppsala kompletterade jag som sagt studentlatinet och lärde då känna Ragnar Henriksson från Sandviken, som under flera år var min bäste vän. Han skulle också skaffa sig en fil. mag. i svenska och historia och vi valde båda his-toria enligt den ekonomisk-historiska linjen för Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand. Rag-nar var lång, smal och fåmäld med en torr humor. Vi förenades i vårt intresse för klassisk musik och han lärde mig uppskatta Bruckner, som vi båda tyckte var den mest intressante av de sena Wien-klassikerna och mycket mer seriös än Mahler och Richard Strauss. Vi gick på bio tillsammans och drack kaffe på kondis 1–2 gånger i veckan, vilket vi ansåg vara utomordentligt lyxigt: vi föredrog Tischners på Sysslomansgatan. Efterhand förlorade vi kontakten när jag blev mer och mer engagerad i Clarté och samtidigt min minsta syster Kerstin flyttade till Uppsala och vi hyrde en dubblett tillsammans på Österplan hos lokförare Borg. Dubletten saknade rinnande vatten och vi delade toalett med värdfolket, som också saknade badrum. När vi ville bli riktigt rena gick vi till badhuset och dessemellan kokade vi upp vatten med en doppvärmare, blötte en badhandduk i det heta vattnet och tog heta avrivningar. Detta var

34

Bo Gustafsson

åren 1953/54 sen jag flyttat från Sandelins. Efter året hos Borgs skaffade vi en dubblett på Torkelsgatan, där vi bodde 1954/55 såvitt jag minns. Det var året då mamma dog (september 1955) och jag träffade Kristina Bohman. När jag började vara mer tillsammans med henne, flyttade Kerstin till en skolkamrat, Margareta Löfberg, dotter till lektor David Löfberg på lärarseminariet och jag flyttade till det s.k. Klosettpalatset – varje rum hade egen toalett, därav namnet – på Skolgatan 45, nuvarande hotell Linné. Men Kerstin fortsatte att finnas i min närhet och blev så småningom förlovad först med Arne Gadd, min gode vän från Hedemora, och därefter med min kollega på Ekonomisk-historiska institutionen, Thore Hammarland, som hon också gifte sig med.

Hela första läsåret pluggade jag latin och historia men min första tentamen i historia kom så sent som hösten 1953, då jag tenterade medeltidsdelen för Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand. Innan jag berättar om min relation till Karl-Gustaf vill jag säga något om det dåtida Uppsala. Uppsala var en idyllisk småstad och saknade vid den här tiden den omfattande randbebyggelse som nu återfinns i Gottsunda, Västra Eriksberg, Flogsta, Kvarngärdet och Årsta. Sala och Tuna Backar fanns. Inte heller stadskärnan såg ut som nu, eftersom de stora varuhu-sen i centrum var en skapelse av 1960- talet. Skillnaden mellan lärdomsstaden väster om ån och industristaden öster om ån var mycket mer markant än nu, framför allt socialt. Första vårterminen i Uppsala satte jag på mig studentmös-san och cyklade Svartbäcksgatan fram. ”Ta av dej den där högfärdskapsylen”, sa ett gäng arbetare som satt och åt frukost längs gatan. Gatorna var trånga och ofta trafikerade av häst och kärra. Den nuvarande järnspången över Fyris vid Linnégatans slut och som endast tillåter cyklister och gångtrafikanter att mötas var på 50-talet bro över Fyris lite längre norrut där nuvarande St. Olofsgatan går mellan Ofvandahls och Fjellstedtska skolan, den s.k. Jernbron. Då kunde knappast två hästskjutsar mötas på bron, än mindre bilar. Det fanns också kro-gar som sen försvunnit, t.ex. Stadshotellet vid korsningen av Drottninggatan och Trädgårdsgatan och Lejonet på Dragarbrunnsgatan. Spårvagnarna var ett annat karakteristiskt inslag i stadsbilden. Såvitt jag minns gick det en linje från Grindstugan – kanske rentav från Sunnersta – fram till Carolina, ned i backen och över Fyris och Torget bort till Vaksala torg. En annan linje gick från Norra Station Sysslomansgatan framåt och vidare in i centrala staden, såvitt jag minns. Det ständiga pinglandet från spårvagnarna satte sin prägel på ljudbilden. Men på vintern måste det ha varit svårt för spårvagnarna att ta sig upp för Carolinabacken om det var isbildning på spåren. Senare när spårnätet bröts upp kunde lastbilar stå och slira i Carolinabacken på vintern och rentav rutscha baklänges ned igen. Först värmeslingorna i gatnätet som kom med fjärrvärmen ändrade situationen.

Uppsala var på den tiden över huvud taget så idylliskt. Som barn hade jag under kriget förtjust läst böckerna om Pelle Svanslös av Gösta Knutsson. Den sistnämnde såg man ofta på baksidan av universitetshusets nedre bot-ten, där Sveriges Radio då höll till. Han var ju chef för lokalradion. När jag kom till Uppsala fick jag också reda på att flera av katterna i Pelle Svanslös

35

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

hade lokala förebilder. Måns var naturligtvis allmänt inspirerad av Hitler och Gösta själv var Pelle Svanslös liksom hans fru, Erna, var Maja Gräddnos. De klösiga på Övre Slottsgatan var överbibliotekarie Tönnes Kleberg (Fritz) med fru (Frida) och barnen Olof, Lars m.fl. (Fridolf, Fridolfin, Fridolfina), som verkligen bodde just där eller möjligen på den bakomliggande Kyrkogårdsga-tan. Trisse i Observatorieparken med sina strömmingssymfonier var director musices Sven E. Svensson, vars institution verkligen låg i Observatorieparken och som själv var rund som en ost. Richard från Rickomberga var musikpro-fessorn Richard Engländer, flykting från Hitlers Tyskland. Men dumskallarna Bill och Bull och Murre från Skogstibble – han som luktade lagård – kunde jag inte identifiera. Var Gamla Maja i domkyrkotornet möjligen ärkebiskopin-nan Söderblom?

Samtidigt upplevde jag universitetets Uppsala som begränsat. Man gick omkring i konfirmationskostym och slips, hackordningar måste respekteras

36

Bo Gustafsson

och avvikelser fördömdes eller sågs som enbart konstiga. På seminarierna – bortsett från Karl-Gustafs – rådde en rigorös ordning: först yttrade sig profes-sorn, sen docenten och sen gick det i senioritetsordning. Det är klart att denna miljö inte befrämjade kreativitet (det var kanske bättre i naturvetenskaperna). Allt förändrades naturligtvis med det nya gymnasiet som skapade en massbas för universitetsstudier på 1960-talet. Jag återkommer till året 1967 då den stora förändringen kom. Nationslivet var också ganska konventionellt med mycket av supa och nöjen och inte alltför mycket levande kultur. Jag tror det var bl.a. därför som politiska och ideella organisationer hade en marknad. Universitetet var så litet med sina 8 000 studenter och bara tre procent av dessa rekryterades från socialgrupp III, som jag själv tillhörde. Man förstår att även arbetarstudenter vanligen blev konservativa i denna miljö. Endast Verdandi – frisinnat – Laboremus – socialdemokratiskt – och Clarté utgjorde vattenhål för andligt törstande studenter. Men dessa föreningar var samtidigt präglade av det kalla kriget: Clarté hade sprängts 1948 efter Pragkuppen, då Fria Gruppen bröt sig ut; Laboremus var väldigt socialdemokratiskt och Ver-dandi hade förlorat stinget från gamla dar, då Hjalmar Öhrvall uppmanade studenter som inte vågade visa färg: ”Kompromettera er i tid så har ni det gjort!” Jag skall nämna ett exempel på Laboremus konformism eller snarare stalinism. Min syster Kerstin var förlovad med Arne Gadd, socialdemokrat och medlem i Laboremus, senare riksdagsman. Det var omkring 1954/55. Arne bodde i samma korridor som jag på Klosettpalatset. En kväll ringer en grupp ledande laboremiter – Nils Elvander, Herbert Söderström och Bo Sö-dersten eller Kjell-Olov Feldt – till Arne. Arne kommer in blek om nosen och säger, att de hade förehållet honom det olämpliga i att vara förlovad med Kerstin Gustafsson, Bo Gustafssons syster. (Jag var ju clartéist men ännu inte kommunist, det blev jag först 1957.) Vi tog oss båda för pannan. Men så kunde det gå till på den tiden.

När jag kom till Uppsala hade jag bestämt mig för att gå med i Clarté. Men det var inte lätt. Organisationen låg i själatåget: ordföranden hade bli-vit konsthandlare i Schweiz, kassören studerade för P. M. Blacket i England och sekreteraren, som bodde på Värmlands nations studenthem ”Fyllebo” på Odengatan, var inte heller lätt att få tag i. Jag gjorde också ett studiebesök på ett offentligt möte med Andres Andreen, ordföranden i Svensk-kinesiska för-eningen i Stockholm. När alla åhörare hade satt sig tågade clartéisterna in på ett led: de såg mycket exklusiva ut, särskilt de kvinnliga medlemmarna med mycket läppstift, svartfärgat hår, långa naglar och tättsittande dräkt. Jag kände att jag inte skulle trivas bland dessa skönandar och skrev nästan av tanken på medlemskap. Men så kontaktades jag på hösten 1953 av Sune Johansson, sekreteraren, som ville ha mig med, mest tror jag för att få ett ombud till den förestående Clartékongressen i Stockholm, där röstboskap behövdes i John Takmans uppgörelse med Hans-Göran Franck (som ömsesidigt talade om ”King Oliver”, eftersom Takman hette John Oliver Takman och om ”Franck-ligan”, eftersom Takman var övertygad om att Franck var CIA-agent). Clarté

37

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

som kontrollerades av Kommunistiska partiet skulle rensas från opålitliga element. Jag sade som det var att jag var helt oprövad och inte visste något om den förestående kongressen. Det gjorde jag tydligen inte heller efter kongres-sen för när jag kom hem och skulle redogöra för vad som ägt rum rättades jag oupphörligen i snäsig ton av Sune Johansson, som varit sekreterare och en av Takmans anhängare. Jag hade bett att få slippa berätta om kongressen men Sune insisterade. Det var ett mycket obehagligt möte. Från kongressen kom jag bara ihåg att de två fraktionerna stred med varandra men jag hade inte en aning om vad som försiggick. Följande år var jag ensam clartéist i Uppsala, eftersom Sune Johansson tagit familjen med sig till Strömsund i Jämtland för ett lärarjobb. Han var gift med Ragnar Jändels dotter Ragna, som var en fin och känslig människa men som inte hade det lätt med att hantera Sune. Senare blev Sune rektor i Strömsund och därefter vid Blombackaläroverket i Söder-tälje och han slutade sina dagar som expert åt Skolöverstyrelsen – bl.a. genom att bygga upp grundskolor i Mellersta Östern – och ledamot av SACO:s sty-relse. Han var en intelligent men rastlös och ganska olycklig människa.

Läget för Clarté var inte bättre i andra delar av landet. John Takman var redaktör för tidskriften. Men de enda medlemmar att räkna med i Stockholm utom han själv var Matts Rying och Annmarie Lindh – förbundsordförande – på Sveriges Radio och de var ganska passiva. Det växte inte precis runt Takman. Därför var en snäll och foglig, oerfaren och hyfsat intelligent och ambitiös ung man typexemplet på en assistent som han behövde och som kände sig smickrad av uppmärksamheten. Takman själv utsåg mig till ”Lille Faciet” och jag efterträdde honom mycket riktigt som redaktör 1956, när han med pukor och trumpeter och på egen hand satte samman ett nummer om Linné på 56 sidor. Att detta innebar att han samtidigt överlämnade en skuld till mig att klara av på 10 000 kronor visste jag inte då. I Göteborg fanns Kurt Aspelin och Lars Herlitz men jag vet inte om de bedrev någon verksamhet. I Stockholm var Ola Palmær, son till Eva Palmær och Ny Dags chefredaktör Gustav Johansson, en ny, charmfull och energisk kraft. Ola och jag gick om-kring på byggen i Stockholms förorter – Norsborg bl.a. – och sålde litografier av Albin Amelin, som skulle ge pengar till förbundet.

I Uppsala ändrades läget radikalt höstterminen 1955, när Kristina Bohman, Jan Stenkvist, Gun Molin, Ingrid Dahl och – vill jag minnas – Per Anders Hörling kom till Uppsala. Kristina skulle läsa psykologi och pedagogik, Jan Stenkvist blev känd litteraturvetare, Gun Molin och Ingrid Dahl från Kram-fors blev läroverkslärare och detsamma gällde Per Anders Hörling. Alla dessa var seriösa unga människor som fördelaktigt skilde sig från den tidigare röd-vinsvänstern i Clarté, som mest ville sitta och prata. Nu blev det verksamhet i Clartésektionen med offentliga möten och intern studieverksamhet och vi studerade både Engels ”Anti-Dühring”, Lenins ”Materialism och empirio-kriticism” och även Stalins ”Marxismen och språkvetenskapens frågor” både länge och väl. Uppsalasektionen blev känd för sina teoretiska intressen. Mö-tesverksamheten präglades ännu av våra litterära intressen och Karl Vennberg,

38

Bo Gustafsson

Artur Lundkvist, Maria Wine, Sara Lidman, Ruth Hillarp m.fl. ställde gärna upp. De företrädde den s.k. tredje ståndpunkten som möttes av större förstå-else när det kalla kriget avlöstes av Genevekonferensens anda 1954. Det s.k. tövädret i Sovjetunionen med Chrustjovs tal mot Stalin på sovjetpartiets 20:e kongress våren 1956 gjorde det politiska klimatet ytterligare något mildare. Ungernrevolten hösten 1956 skapade dock stor förvirring bland oss clartéister. Vid det laget hade jag av John Takman designerats till ny clartéredaktör efter honom på ett stort party hos honom i Alvik. Det första nummer jag gav ut handlade till stor del om ungernrevolten. För de sovjettrogna kommunisterna var saken klar: revolten i Ungern var en kapitalistisk kontrarevolution och bevisen var de inslag av fascister och brutala illdåd mot ungerska säkerhets-poliser, som publicerades i bl.a. amerikanska tidskrifter och tidningar. Att säkerhetspoliser hade blivit brutalt mördade var alldeles säkert. Men det var resultat av folklig vrede mot de illdåd dessa under flera år begått mot det ungerska folket. Inslaget av högerkrafter var också verkligt men hade andra proportioner än de som sovjetpropagandan framställde. Upproret var folkligt och kunde slås ned bara på grund av den sovjetiska interventionen, stödd av bl.a. Kina. Många upprorsmän dödades, reformkommunisten Imre Nagy frak-tades iväg till Sovjetunionen, där han så småningom avrättades. När ryssarna väl satt in János Kádár som sin man i Ungern vidtog hårda år av utrensningar i Ungern.

Jag själv trodde på den officiella sovjetiska bilden av upproret, huvud-sakligen efter att ha sett bildmaterial och text i ”Life” m.fl. tidskrifter som mest visade de brutala morden på de hatade ungerska säkerhetspoliserna. Jag trodde att detta var kärnan och visste ingenting om Petöfi-klubben och studenternas och arbetarnas roll. Clarté i Stockholm höll på att rämna. Därför måste Ola Palmær och jag sammankalla ett diskussionsmöte. Dit kom ett 20-tal personer, bl.a. Nils Bejeroth, Molly Åsbrink. Erland von Hofsten, Matts Rying och andra. Bejeroth ville att mötet skulle fördöma den sovjetiska interventionen. Men de sovjettrogna lyckades avvärja detta. Såvitt jag minns blev det en resolution som beklagade hela händelsen och i mitt första nummer som clartéredaktör sattes signaturen av Matts Rying med dikten ”Alla döendes dag”. Men att inte helhjärtat fördöma upproret var ett stort framsteg, trots att jag besvarade frågan ”Förelåg fara för fascism i Ungern?” jakande.

Min främsta ambition var emellertid att komma ifrån beroendet av det svenska kommunistpartiet och dess hejdukar. När jag gick med i partiet efter Ungernrevolten så var det mest på trots och för att solidarisera mig med min fästmö Kristina, som sedan länge var ungkommunist och medlem (om än inte alldeles helhjärtad). Ungernrevolten ledde nämligen till en sådan hets mot svenska kommunister att jag slog bakut. Jag var visserligen övertygad marxist men politiskt var det de engelska vänstersocialisterna med Anurian Bevan och Jenny Lee i spetsen som jag sympatiserade med och jag började tidigt prenu-merera på ”New Statesman”, deras veckotidning. Jag lät därför översätta för Clarté ganska mycket material från den engelska vänsterdebatten. Över huvud

39

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

taget fick nog Clarté under de två år jag var redaktör en mer samhällsveten-skaplig inriktning (1956–1958). Sedan valdes jag till ordförande för Clartéför-bundet för ett par år. Samtidigt måste jag erkänna att det fanns clartéister som var betydligt mer kritiska till sovjetkommunismen än jag vid denna tid, t.ex. Jan Stenkvist och Kurt Aspelin, båda litteraturvetare.

Vid den här tiden strävade jag också efter att låta den dåtida marxistiska vetenskapliga debatten återspeglas i Clarté. Den största debatten hade fram-kallats av den engelske ekonomen och ekonomhistorikern Maurice Dobbs ”Studies in the development of capitalism”, publicerad redan 1946. Dobb var legendarisk marxistisk ekonom i Cambridge med ett författarskap som sträckte sig bakåt till 1920-talet. Hans bok var det första försöket att på grund-val av modern forskning beskriva och förklara övergången från feodalism till socialism i Västeuropa, den s.k. transitionsdebatten. Tidskriften ”Science & Society” i USA lät då samla en rad inlägg för och emot som sedan kom ut i bokform. Jag bad Dobb sammanfatta resultatet en lång artikel, som jag översatte för Clarté. Som vanligt var texten från Dobb skriven för hand i fin, nästan kalligrafisk, piktur. När jag sedan försökte sälja numret med artikeln till Ekonomisk-historiska seminariet på ett post-seminarium på Ofvandahls café, sade Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand att han köpte den för min skull, trots att det var en kommunistisk tidskrift. Det torde ha varit 1957 eller 1958. Tiderna var sådana att man måste markera avstånd till kommunismen, vare sig det behövdes eller inte.

Men i stort sett var Hildebrand mycket tolerant. Han t.o.m. inbjöd mig att öppna en seminariediskussion med anledning av den sovjetiska översätt-ningen med kommentarer av Ingvar Andersons ”Sveriges historia”. Kommen-tarerna hade översatts till svenska och publicerats i en särskild liten skrift med kommentarer av Ingvar Anderson själv. Egentligen var dessa kommentarer tämligen andefattiga och stelbenta, vilket jag bara delvis såg. Men seminariet lyssnade artigt och jag blev inte alls utbuad.

Mina tentamina för Karl-Gustaf gick mycket bra och i maj 1954 var jag klar med historieämnet och skulle gå vidare med litteraturhistoria, nordiska språk och pedagogik. Trots min kommunism var han angelägen att jag skulle fortsätta: jag hade bl.a. skrivit en trebetygsuppsats om konsumentkooperatio-nen och margarinkartellerna i Sverige, som nog inte var så tokig, samtidigt som jag talat om att mitt egentliga intresse var att skriva något om Marx’ anteckningar till Geijers svenska historia. Men Karl-Gustaf ansåg att det var viktigt att man lärde sig hantverket i ämnet, innan man ägnade sig åt dylika vidlyftigheter. Jag var nog också en ganska frimodig historiestudent. Det bör-jade redan vid inskrivningen på hösten 1952. De som tänkte börja läsa historia uppmanades att komma till sal IX i universitetsbyggnaden för information. Det var andra gången jag var där. Första gången skulle jag skriva in mig vid universitetet, vilket ägde rum på nedre botten där rektors sekreterare nu sitter: 1952 var hela universitetsadministrationen inrymd där och omfattade herrar Kihlgren och Nyberg, fru Dintler, kassören herr Mårdh och möjligen någon

40

Bo Gustafsson

till! Man fick köa vid disken men jag tror inte det var mer än ett tjugotal re-centiorer som erlade en avgift och fick tentamensbok. (Sen skulle man skriva in sig i nation, vilket för mej var Västmanland-Dala nation. Vid den tiden lekte jag med tanken att bli jurist. Men jag avråddes kraftfullt av l. Qurator Björn Bosaeus med motiveringen att ”det väller ut jurister från krisorganen”; alla följde prognosen och fem år senare var det brist på jurister!)

Men nu skulle det bli information om historieämnet. Den sköttes dels av amanuens Folke Rudberg från Historiska institutionen som med militärisk disciplin klargjorde vad man skulle och inte skulle göra och dels av Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand, nybliven preceptor i ekonomisk historia och inhyst i ett rum på Historiska institutionen, där han dels skulle meddela undervisning i ”ren” ekonomisk historia (inte många studenter) och dels i historia efter den ekonomisk-historiska linjen som accepterades som alternativ i fil. mag. examen i historia. (Det hade blivit precepturer i ämnet, sedan någon bonde-förbundare i riksdagens utbildningsutskott (Skabersjö?) eller möjligen i koalitionsregeringen Erlander-Hedlund hade fått klart för sig att en preceptor hade lika stor undervisningsskyldighet som en professor, fast till lägre be-talning…) Rudberg tog större delen av tiden i anspråk och Karl-Gustaf gav några strödda synpunkter på sitt ämne med tillägget att han fanns tillgänglig i rummet bakom sal IX om någon till äventyrs skulle vara intresserad. Jag tror jag var den ende och mottogs därför välvilligt. Jag presenterades en del stenciler över böcker som jag skulle läsa och jag gav genast en recension av dem som jag hade läst. ”Mja, den där Röpke är kanske inte så bra” eller ”Jo, den är ganska intressant” o.s.v. Karl-Gustaf som är en konciliant människa höll hela tiden med. En annan episod var hans föreläsningar i nationalekonomi för ekonom-historiker. Han hade själv motarbetats av Heckscher när han sökte tjänsten med hänvisning till att han inte var så framstående i nationalekonomi. Han hade därför tagit tre betyg i nationalekonomi för Erik Lundberg och skri-vit en alldeles lysande uppsats i Ekonomisk Tidskrift om den monopolistiska konkurrensen som ekonom-historiskt problem. Över huvud taget visste Karl-Gustaf mer om det mesta än han ville visa. Föreläsningarna i nationalekonomi var som vanligt intelligenta men kanske ibland lite vimsiga. Det blev inte bättre av att vi okunniga studenter gärna kommenterade det sagda och ökade på förvirringen. Jag minns ännu hur spänd och nervös Karl-Gustaf var när vi resonerade på rasterna om det han sagt på föreläsningarna. Som alla mycket intelligenta människor såg Karl-Gustaf att allt hade många sidor och många möjliga tolkningar.

Karl-Gustafs seminarier präglades av öppenhet och tolerans och alla skulle känna sig välkomna. Hans valspråk var: ”Alla stämmor i kören skall höras”. Men naturligtvis fanns det även där en stämning av högaktning och under-kastelse, som hörde tiden till och som försvann först efter 1968. Karl-Gustaf sade ofta att han var helt oteoretisk, vilket inte var riktigt sant och som, om det var så, hade en ganska nyttig effekt på oss. Han lärde oss att se under ytan och förstå det sammansatta i historien och han gav oss ofta aha-upplevelser

41

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

som var mycket lärorika. Uppblåsthet och arrogans var det värsta han visste och han punkterade gärna företrädarna för dessa egenskaper med en diabolisk mildhet.

Jag själv hade utpräglade teoretiska intressen och fick söka utlopp för dessa på annat sätt, bl.a. genom brevväxling med Maurice Dobb och den skotske ekonomen Ronald Meek, som sen blev berömd ekonomisk idéhistoriker med inriktning främst på Adam Smith och hans föregångare. Men också Paul M. Sweezy, som startat transitionsdiskussionen, stod jag i kontakt med. Jag följde hans och Leo Hubermans tidskrift, ”Monthly Review”, med stort intresse lik-som tidskriften ”Science & Society”. Maurice Dobb träffade jag aldrig men jag läste allt han skrivit. När Karl-Gustaf skulle avgå som professor 1976 kunde han föreslå fakulteten hedersdoktor detta år. Generöst bad han mig föreslå ett namn och jag föreslog Maurice Dobb. Men först måste denne kontaktas. Jag ringde upp Trinity College i Cambridge och fick tala med Richard Goodwin, en berömd kollega till Dobb. När jag framfört mitt ärende blev det alldeles tyst i telefonen. “I’m sorry”, sade Goodwin till sist, “but Mr Dobb died one week ago.” I stället blev, tror jag, Reinhold Olsson, sågverksarbetarnas krö-nikör, hedersdoktor. Däremot träffade jag Meek en gång. Han och Alexander Baykov – en känd rysk-engelsk ekonomhistoriker från Birmingham – skulle åka färja från London till Leningrad och de hade ett par timmar till förfogande i Stockholm, där vi träffades vid Slussen. Paul Sweezy mötte jag i Peking vid republikens 25-årsjubileum 1976, dit han var inbjuden som gäst tillsammans med medredaktören Harry Braverman. Vi växlade endast några ord strax före den stora banketten (som var en egendomlig tillställning; mer om den längre fram).

Av den tidens föreläsare i historia var det egentligen endast Erik Lönnroth som imponerade genom sin bredd och idérikedom. Med endast en liten min-neslapp i handen höll han en hel föreläsning, som gott hade kunnat tryckas direkt. Tyvärr försvann han till Göteborgs universitet redan vid mitten av 1950-talet. Senare blev jag mer kritisk till Lönnroths skarpsinniga men sam-tidigt retoriskt övertalande framställningssätt och det tog ännu längre tid för mig att inse att hans kritik av historisk mytbildning innebar ny mytbildning, om än på en högre och mer sofistikerad nivå: när man skrapade på texterna fann man att ganska mycket bestod av obevisade men pompöst framförda påståenden, vilket var naturligt med hänsyn till det torftiga medeltida källäget som inbjöd till konstruktion efter företagen dekonstruktion. Med åren blev Lönnroth alltmer pontifikat men behöll samtidigt åtskilligt av sin ungdoms vitalitet. Han älskade att omvärdera även när det inte behövdes. Nya historiska kaniner trollades fram och förevisades för en förtrollad publik. Jag tror att han saknade inte bara självsyn utan också, och mer fatalt, humor.

När mina historiska grundstudier var avslutade hösten 1954 eller möjligen våren 1955 började jag studera nordiska språk, som fascinerade mig djupt. På den tiden läste man isländsk grammatik och isländska texter, innan man började med fornsvenskan, eftersom fornsvenskan redan var ett språk i upp-

42

Bo Gustafsson

lösning. Lärare var Lennart Moberg, som entusiasmerade oss, och Valter Jans-son, som var lärd men som lärare något sömngivande. Jag blev så intresserad av språkhistoria att jag allvarligt övervägde att ägna mig åt nordiska språk i stället för ekonomisk historia. Därefter läste jag in en grundkurs i litteraturhis-toria för Viktor Svanberg, som gav mig spets och ville att jag skulle fortsätta. Det var nu våren 1957 och jag erbjöds en halv amanuenstjänst i ekonomisk historia av Karl-Gustaf, som behövde en ersättare för Ragnhild Lundström, som nog var hans älsklingselev men som fortsatte med studier i USA för sin licentiat. Jag accepterade erbjudandet och skulle just börja i september, när jag och Kristina drabbades av den s.k. asiaten, d.v.s. en besvärlig influensa. Vi låg däckade i tre veckor i hög feber, medan Karl-Gustaf obarmhärtigt ringde och ville att jag skulle börja arbeta. Institutionen skulle nämligen få egna lokaler i Skandalhuset mitt emot universitetsbyggnaden i Pedagogiska institutionens tidigare lokaler.

Vi hade inget bibliotek att tala om men Karl-Gustaf hade fått löfte om att vi skulle kunna få dubbletter av för oss intressant litteratur från Carolina. Jag tillbringade två månader i en av universitetsbibliotekets dammiga käl-lare och lyckades skrapa ihop några hundra volymer att börja med. Samtidigt påbörjade jag mina licentiatstudier med att läsa in kurserna över antikens och medeltidens ekonomiska historia, som på den tiden var betydligt mer omfat-tande än vad de senare blev. Såvitt jag minns fick jag också undervisa en del, i varje fall mot slutet av 50-talet.

Den stora händelsen i mitt personliga liv vid denna tid var att jag träffade Kristina. Jag var fortfarande extremt blyg för flickor. Jag hade lärt känna en flicka från Örebro, som läste historia, 1953 vid namn Gunvor Larsson. Jag var nog mycket förälskad men hon kom från ett religiöst hem. Vi gick på bio och kafé och som mest blev det i sexuellt avseende lite kyssande, kramande och petting. Så for hon till Grekland på arkeologiska utgrävningar och träffade där en pojke, vilket medförde att när vi träffades efter sommarlovet 1954 en kväll på Domtrappkällarens utekafé, så var hon tämligen kylig mot mig. Dessutom var jag ju kommunist. I varje fall avslutade hon bekantskapen och jag var förstås ganska ledsen. Hösten 1955 inträffade två omvälvande saker. Först dog mamma i september och därefter träffade jag Kristina som kom till Upp-sala denna termin. Jag visste att hon skulle komma för det hade jag läst om i kommunisttidningen ”Ny Dag” och jag hade vissa förväntningar. Vårt första möte hemma hos mig på Torkilsgatan – där min syster Kerstin och jag delade en dubblett – var lite stelt. Jag gick fortfarande omkring i svart kostym och vit skjorta med hängslen efter mammas begravning och Kristina tyckte jag verkade högdragen, framför allt när jag inte uppskattade att hon skulle börja läsa psykologi. Hon kom för att anmäla sig som medlem till clartésektionen och några dagar senare anmälde sig också Jan Stenkvist m.fl.

Den sommaren bjöd Kristina hem mig till sina föräldrar i Gisslarbo utanför Kolsva i Västmanland, där hennes pappa Ivan Bohman var folkskollärare. Jag mottogs mycket hjärtligt av honom och hans fru Ruth. Ivan var betydligt äldre

43

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

än henne, elva år tror jag, och skillnaderna mellan dem var mycket stora. Hon hade gift sig med honom som 20-åring och äktenskapet blev svårt så småningom, när hon ville vara självständig. Ivan var nämligen mycket do-minerande och patriarkalisk och dessutom ganska nervös och irritabel, även om han samtidigt var mycket humoristisk och gladlynt. Ruth var lugn och resonerande och hon var dessutom en mycket vacker kvinna, vilket inte gjorde saken lättare, eftersom Ivan var ganska svartsjuk. Ivans skämtsamhet kunde också vara ganska grov. Första dagen jag åt middag i det Bohmanska hemmet sade Ivan: ”Ät du, du har det väl inte så fett därhemma!”, vilket var alldeles sant eftersom jag inte ens längre hade något hem. Det Bohmanska hemmet i Gisslarbo och sedan Kolsva blev mitt nya hem och jag trivdes där. Nyårsafton 1957 förlovade vi oss, Kristina och jag, genom att gå ned till den s.k. Kärleks-udden vid Kolbäcksån och byta ringar. Kristina tyckte nog det var lite tidigt, eftersom jag var ganska nervös vid denna tid och hade så varit ända sedan mamma dog, då jag ibland fick ångestattacker som nästan fällde mig i gatan. Det var separationsångest och tyvärr flyttade jag över denna negativa känsla till Kristina, vilket gjorde henne mycket betänksam.

Men vi trivdes bra ihop och 1958 blev det bröllop på sommaren. En anled-ning till att vi gifte oss då var att vi som gifta kunde få en dubblett med pentry på nykterhetsvännernas studenthem på Sturegatan 12, där Kristina hade ett s.k. lic-rum, d.v.s rum med kokvrå. Det lyckades, bl.a. för att jag själv kunde åberopa meriten att ha grundat den första nykterhetsföreningen vid gymnasiet i Avesta. Men när vi gifte oss bodde vi fortfarande var för sig, Kristina på studenthemmet och jag på Klosettpalatset. Det blev ett mycket enkelt bröllop. Vi var mycket fattiga den sommaren och jag minns att baskosten var filmjölk och kaviarsmörgås. Före bröllopet hade vi medverkat vid en internationell fredskongress i Stockholm, Kristina som tolk och jag som bokhandlare. För att bättra på Clartés finanser köpte jag in billiga men intressanta böcker från Almqvist & Wiksells bokhandel i Stockholm, vars danske chef gärna gynnade Clarté. De gick som smör, eftersom många av delegaterna kom från östlän-der och hade svårt att skaffa bra västerländsk litteratur, även s.k. progressiv sådan. Många delegater tillbringade mer av sin tid vid min bokhandel än i kongresslokalen, där jag antar att det mesta var uppgjort i förhand. Dessa sov-jetfinansierade fredskongresser hade ju till uppgift att stödja Sovjetunionens utrikespolitik, vilket inte hindrade att de samtidigt säkerligen spelade en posi-tiv roll i en tid då supermakterna ännu inte lärt sig hantera den situation som uppkommit till följd av vätebomben. En av de flitigaste kunderna hos mig var den berömde polske ekonomen Oskar Lange, som bl.a. köpte en pocketutgåva av Alfred North Whitehead’s ”Science and the Modern World”. När Lange något senare publicerade första bandet av sin ”Political Economy” citerade han bl.a. Whitehead och jag inbillade mig – förmodligen felaktigt – att det var jag som förmedlat bekantskapen.

Det viktigaste som hände på kongressen var att vi blev vänner med indiern Baren Ray från New Delhi. Baren var intresserad av historia och filosofi och

44

Bo Gustafsson

hade många intressanta idéer om kontrasten mellan västerländsk och öster-ländsk civilisation. Han följde med oss till Uppsala och blev ett av bröllops-vittnena. Vi tillbringade hela dagar i Uppsala stadspark diskuterande orsakerna till att det blev Europa och inte Indien eller Kina som tog ledningen i den historiska utvecklingen från renässansen. Giftermålet var snabbt avklarat hos borgmästaren och bröllopslunchen bestod av en omelett och kaffe med kaka på Flustret. På restaurangens toalett bad jag min bror Kjell betala lunchen, vilket han gjorde. Mina pengar räckte nämligen inte, trots att antalet gäster bara uppgick till fem vuxna och tre barn.

Vi flyttade in i dubbletten på Sturegatan 12, förmodligen på hösten 1958 och där blev vi grannar med Bengt och Birgitta Kettner, båda socialdemokra-tiska politiker, Birgitta (född Dahl) så småningom socialdemokratisk minister och talkvinna i riksdagen. När Kristinas mormor lämnade sin lägenhet på Swedenborgsgatan flyttade vi dit och därifrån till det nybyggda höghusområ-det i Västra Eriksberg, nämligen Marmorvägen 7 A på sjunde våningen. Det måste ha varit 1961 eller 1962 eftersom Maria föddes den 9 januari 1963. Pengar till möbler fick vi genom att ta ett s.k. statligt bosättningslån, som utgick till unga par som ville gifta sig och belöpte sig efter vad jag minns till 1 500 kronor. För att få det måste vi besöka en bankdirektör i hans hem i Kåbo på Södra Rudbecksgatan. Han tog emot oss sittande bakom ett skrivbord medan vi fick stå som supplikanter framför honom medan han förhörde oss, om vi verkligen behövde det, om vi skulle vara i stånd att betala tillbaka det o.s.v. Kristina skummade av raseri men höll tand för tunga. Jag tror vi köpte IKEA-möbler av enklaste slag för lånet.

Under dessa år blev Kristina färdig med sin akademiska grundexamen i pedagogik, psykologi och sociologi och hon ville inte fortsätta, eftersom hon inte kände sig uppskattad, framför allt inte i pedagogik som var hennes stora intresse. Hon tog arbete på Stockholms skolförvaltning och måste alltså pendla mellan Uppsala och Stockholm. Senare blev kvällsgymnasiet i Upp-sala, sedermera Cederbladsskolan, hennes arbetsplats där hon arbetade som bl.a. SYO-konsulent.

Själv strävade jag på med min licentiatexamen och undervisade samtidigt på institutionen, där jag väl fortfarande innehade den halva amanuenstjänsten. Som ämne valde jag att skriva om de norrländska sågverksarbetarnas arbets-, löne- och levnadsförhållanden kvartsseklet före första världskriget. Inspiratio-nen kom från den långa engelska debatten bland ekonom-historiker alltsedan 1800-talet om den industriella kapitalismen hade sänkt eller höjt arbetarnas levnadsstandard. Den ”optimistiska skolan”, bl.a. företrädd av J. H. Clapham och T. S. Ashton menade att levnadsstandarden steg, medan den ”pessimis-tiska skolan”, bl.a. företrädd av makarna Hammond ansåg att den sjönk. De-batten anknöt naturligtvis indirekt också till den av Marx väckta diskussionen om utarmningen under kapitalismen, varvid Marx’ egen sofistikerade upp-fattning var att arbetarna utarmades, även om deras materiella förhållanden inte försämrades. Frågan fick ny aktualitet på 1950-talet i och med att nytt

45

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

källmaterial drogs fram, samtidigt som frågeställningarna gjordes mer precisa och specifika. Menade man samma sak med ”levnadsstandard”? Mäts den på samma sätt? Avser man samma tider, områden och/eller populationer? Medan Ashton på sin tid deducerat en stigande levnadsstandard ur det faktum att pro-duktionen av tegel steg, deducerade nu Hobsbawm en sjunkande levnadsstan-dard ur det faktum att antalet slaktdjur på Smithfield Market i London sjönk. Mitt bidrag var väl närmast att jag tillämpade den s.k. komponentmetoden, d.v.s. att levnadsstandarden betraktades som en summa eller produkt av flera olika slags komponenter som arbetstid, livsmedelsstandard, boendestandard etc. Problemet med den metoden var förstås att komponenterna inte kunde reduceras till ett gemensamt mått, vilket var besvärligt om de utvecklades åt motsatt håll. Lyckligtvis fann jag att arbetstiden sjönk samtidigt som livsmed-elsstandard och boendestandard steg och att det sammanfattande reallönemåt-tet också visade en stegring under den undersökta perioden. I de tankemödor jag då upplevde återupptäckte jag – utan att veta det – det s.k. Pareto-kriteriet på välfärdsökning (om åtminstone en komponent ökar och inga andra minskar är man berättigad att tala om en ökning av levnadsstandarden).

Jag blev klar med licentiatavhandlingen i början av 1960-talet och den kunde också tryckas som första numret i serien Ekonomisk-historiska studier, bl.a. tack vare stöd från dåvarande Svenska Sågverksarbetareförbundet, som förband sig att köpa in en stor del av upplagan. Parallellt därmed medverkade jag med ett avsnitt om sågverksarbetarna från 1890 till 1945 i en monografi om Sågverksförbundet med Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand och Thore Hammarland som medförfattare, den förstnämnde också redaktör. Vi hade tämligen fria händer i författandet och mycket omfattande diskussioner med förbundets re-presentant, Torsten Thornander. Men för min del innebar erfarenheten att jag inte gärna skulle åta mig ett liknande uppdrag igen. Även om det inte fanns några snören som någon ryckte i, så medförde medvetandet om uppdragsgiva-rens intresseposition förmodligen en viss självcensur.

När licentiatexamen var avlagd hade jag turen att också få doktorand-stipendium i tre år (1963/64 till 1965/66) som hakade i där det tidigare licen-tiatstipendiet – också på tre år – slutade. Men vid det laget hade jag varit med om omvälvande politiska upplevelser, som kom att påverka valet av tema för doktorsavhandlingen. Alltfler vänstermänniskor började under 1950-talet att förstå, att sovjetkommunismen inte kunde vara någon bra modell för socia-lismen. Chrusjtjovs uppgörelse med Stalin 1956 och upproren i Ungern och Polen på hösten samma år satte stenen i rullning. Kommunister i Västeuropa bröt sig ur de gamla partierna och grundade nya partier – som i Danmark – el-ler tidskrifter – som ”New Left Review” i England. En verklig diskussion kom till stånd och den fick ökad intensitet i och med att också Kinas kommunis-tiska parti började kritisera sovjetpartiet. Visserligen var denna kritik mycket motsägelsefull, eftersom de kinesiska kommunisterna (läs: Mao) å ena sidan kritiserade ryssarna för att de nedvärderade Stalin alltför mycket (den s.k. 70:30-doktrinen, enligt vilken Stalin till 70 procent var bra och till bara 30

46

Bo Gustafsson

procent dålig) och likaså hävdade att ryssarna (läs: Chrusjtjov) lade alltför ensidig vikt vid möjligheterna till fredlig samlevnad med kapitalismen. (Det var i det sammanhanget som Mao yttrade de famösa orden att även om världen skulle utsättas för ett kärnvapenkrig, så skulle det efter ett sådant finnas till-räckligt många människor (kinesiska kommunister?) kvar för att en ny skön värld skulle resa sig ur den gamla.) Men å andra sidan kritiserade kineserna ryssarna för att ha förvanskat socialismen genom att upphäva demokratin och massinflytandet, centralisera alltför många ekonomiska beslut, lägga alltför stor vikt vid tung industri och utarma jordbruket. I en officiös skrift (”De tio stora relationerna”) gjorde sig Mao till tolk för en demokratisk socialism som till och med gav utrymme för konkurrerande partier, eftersom kommunist-partiet enligt Mao behövde motståndarpartier för att inte göra alltför många och stora misstag. Detta var 1956. Vad vi inte visste men som kom fram långt senare var att Mao med detta gillrade en fålla för att locka fram oppositionen och att fällan slog igen 1957, då han slog till mot det ”ogräs” som vuxit upp i hägnet av ”Låt-hundra-blommor-blomma-politiken”). Men vi godtrogna vän-sterintellektuella i Väst trodde på den officiella retoriken och dessutom låg ju Kina tillräckligt långt bort för att det skulle vara svårt att undersöka de verk-liga förhållandena. T.o.m. vetenskapliga icke-kommunistiska västtidskrifter som ”The China Quarterly” innehöll ingenting eller föga som kunde korrigera bilden. 1958 satte Mao igång med folkkommunerna för att integrera jordbruk och industri och 1959 kom det s.k. Stora Språnget, då alla skulle producera järn i Kina. När fri litteratur om Kina började publiceras under 1980-talet fick vi reda på sanningen om dessa projekt och hur de ödelagt både människor och produktion.

Jag själv var mest intresserad av de tankemodeller som låg bakom denna politik och tog för givet att de också omsattes i praktiken. Den kinesiska kom-munismen tycktes erbjuda en tredje väg mellan å ena sidan den förstelnade och diktatoriska sovjetkommunismen och å andra sidan socialdemokratins förvaltande av kapitalismen som priset för att kunna genomföra välfärds-samhället. När jag avgått som redaktör för Clarté hösten 1958 fick jag friare händer i den krönika jag stod för där (Klippkrönika, Saxen såg). Tiden var så omvälvande att de stenhårda kommunisterna inte riktigt visste hur de skulle vända sig: ryska och jugoslaviska kommunister var i luven på varandra lik-som kinesiska och ryska. Kommunismen var inte längre monolitisk. Samtidigt inträffade stora förändringar i Asien, Latinamerika och Afrika. Efter Indiens, Kinas och Indonesiens dekolonisering, drev vietnameserna ut fransmännen från Vietnam (slaget vid Dien Bien Puh), vilket resulterade i Genèvekonfe-rensen 1954 med Vietnams delning. (Kineserna hade önskat att nordvietna-meserna under Ho Chih Min skulle ha erövrat hela Vietnam. Men ryssarna gick med på delning av landet. Jag minns ännu de hånfulla kommentarerna från en kinesisk diplomat som med pipig röst citerade vietnamesernas vack-lande ställning – ”The Soviet comrades are good. And the Chinese comrades are also good” – i Gèneve men i realiteten stödde den ryska ståndpunkten.) I

47

Jag flög med ett rött hallon i näbben

Latinamerika tog Castro makten från Batista 1959 och avvärjde samtidigt den amerikanska invasionen i Grisbukten. I Afrika inträffade Kongokrisen 1960 och i Algeriet kämpade NFL mot fransmännen. I Mellersta Östern tog Nasser makten i Egypten, i Västafrika Nkrumah i Ghana. Det skedde alltså jordskred-slika förändringar som livade sinnena. Vi trodde oss se en ny värld födas och den kinesiska kommunismen framstod som den allra mest dynamiska kraften.

Våren 1960 fick jag ett erbjudande av ledningen för Demokratisk Ungdom (kommunistpartiets ungdomsförbund) med Rolf Utberg i spetsen att följa med som tolk i en delegation till Kina inbjuden av All-China Youth Federation. Jag skulle tolka från engelska till svenska och tvärtom. I början av april satte vi oss på ett Caravelle-plan till Moskva, där vi först skulle prepareras av Komso-mol inför Kina-besöket, för nu var konflikten helt öppen. Samma dag sköts det amerikanska U-2 planet med Gary Powers ned över Sovjetunionen, Chrusj-tjov bankade med skon i bordet i FN:s generalförsamling och vägrade att möta Eisenhower vid det planerade Paris-mötet, eftersom denne inte ville ta ansvar för U-2 incidenten. När vi några dagar senare reste omkring i Kina såg vi överallt sovjetiska biståndsarbetare på väg hem från Kina på Chrusjtjovs order

Det var första gången jag var i Sovjetunionen och Moskva. Atmosfären var ganska trist. Komsomol-företrädarna som tog emot oss torde ha varit mel-lan 30 och 50 år och hade redan lärt sig det rätta byråkratiska uppträdandet: att vara knapp och vänligt nedlåtande. De gav sin syn på de frågor som stod till debatt mellan dem och kineserna men försökte inte pressa på oss några åsikter efter vad jag kan minnas. Vi visades runt och fick se Leninmausoleet m.m. Mitt livligaste minne är av de ryska restaurangerna, där personalen inte lyfte många fingrar för att hjälpa gästerna. Sen gick färden vidare med ryskt inrikesflyg till Omsk, Tomsk och Irkutsk, där vi fick bekanta oss med Intou-rist som påstod att vi inte fick övernatta tills någon kommunistisk funktionär fixade logi. Från Irkutsk vidare till Ulan Betor i Mongoliet, där vi äntrade ett litet tvåmotorigt propellerdrivet kinesiskt flygplan som tog oss skumpande till Peking. Vi togs emot på flygplatsen av en barnkör och blomsterkvastar. Det var en fantastisk upplevelse att känna den varma vårluften slå emot oss som nästan var vinterklädda. När vi fraktades i bil in till Peking kunde vi knappt se mer än några meter på grund av det fina stoft som yrde i luften och gjorde den alldeles gul.

På kvällen togs vi emot av ledare från All-China Youth Federation. De upp-trädde värdigt och nästan högdraget. ”Detta är mandariner”, tänkte jag. Det var första gången jag åt kinesisk mat och drack risbrännvin, hiskeligt starkt. Man hade lagt upp en resplan åt oss. Först skulle vi norrut till Heilungkiang och Kirin med sight-seeing av kinesiska muren på vägen. Sen tillbaka till Pe-king för vidare befordran till Sian och därifrån till Kwang-tung och Kanton, upp längs kusten till Shanghai och Hang-chow och så tillbaka till Peking – allt per tåg. Det var en månads program.

Året 1960 var dramatiskt inte bara internationellt utan också i Kina. År 1958 hade folkkommunerna bildats och det s.k. Stora Språnget inletts med

48

Bo Gustafsson

mass omfattande hungersnöd som följd både 1959 och 1960. Samtidigt kom brytningen mellan Kina och Sovjetunionen, efter det att det kinesiska kom-munistpartiet publicerat ”Länge Leve Leninismen!”, som var en uppgörelse framför allt med idén om fredlig samlevnad eller – som kineserna själva fram-ställde saken – med ryssarnas (Chrusjtjovs) ensidiga utläggningen av idén. Medan vår delegation sorgfälligt skyddades från insyn i Kinas verkliga pro-blem, överöstes vi med propagandamaterial för den kinesiska ståndpunkten. Inte så att de kinesiska värdarna trängde sig på. Men de såg till att vi fick ta del av deras synpunkter. Vi såg för det mesta bara välnärda människor och vi själva närdes väl med både mat och dryck. Tyvärr fick jag skämmas för de svenska ungkommunisterna, som på resorna hela tiden beställde in och hinkade i sig konjak. Vid två tillfällen anade jag att det inte stod så väl till med levnadsstandarden för en del. På järnvägsstationer kom folk rusande mot tågen och bad om mat från resenärerna och på själva tågen bestod de kinesiska resenärernas kost nästan uteslutande av ris och grönkål. På tågen såg vi också ofta ryska specialister och biståndsarbetare på väg hem.

I norra Kina fick vi se de små masugnar som uppförts under det Stora Språnget men som nu var helt övergivna. Ingenstans användes de. På ett stort gruvområde stod massor av dem. Trettiofyra stycken hade uppförts under loppet av ett par månader. Den grundläggande idén var god. Mao ville upp-muntra småindustri, kombinationen av jordbruk och industri, utvecklingen och spridningen av enkel industriell kunskap och utnyttjande av lokalt kapital såväl som arbetskraft under jordbrukets lågsäsong. Många människor skulle därmed få mer resurser till sitt förfogande utan att man skulle inkräkta på andra resurser. Om Kina skulle invänta utbyggnaden av storindustrin, skulle det ta lång tid innan en modern ekonomi fanns till hands. Det var teorin. Men i praktiken jagades alla kineser utomhus för att producera järn dag och natt, om inte annat så genom att smälta ned de egna husgeråden. Resultatet blev en katastrof och efter ett par år talade ingen mer om det Stora Språnget och Maos inflytande minskade starkt, innan han tog tillbaka initiativet i Kultur-revolutionen från 1966

Förutom järnindustri besökte vi en bilfabrik, en filmstudio, affärer i Chang-chun och dessutom universitet i Kirin (f.d. Harbin), där vi bl.a. fick träffa koreanska studenter på en fest. Vår delegation uppmanades att visa något av svensk kultur och det enda vi kunde göra var att hoppa runt i ring och sjunga ”Små grodorna”, vilket gjorde stor succé!

49

Klas Nyberg

Introductory Comments to Bo Gustafsson’s “The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories: With Special Reference to the British Cotton Industry”

The emergence of the first centralized factories, namely the growth of the mechanized cotton mills in North-West England at the end of the eighteenth century, had a unique allure and magic even in contemporary Europe. Facto-ries, such as the Arkwright mills in Cromford, simply created a feeling that a pioneering transition to a new kind of society was underway.1 Already by the turn of the nineteenth century, developments in Lancashire were the actual symbol for the factory system and the alarming social consequences in the initial phase hardly changed this impression.2 The factories were thought to promise the solution not only to the problems of hand spinning, but also to the many limitations of mass production that characterized the archaic putting-out industry. Manufacturing by hand, but organized as large-scale putting out, had been around since the High Middle Ages. In Lancashire, it was dominated by the manufacture of fustians — cheap, light cloths made of flax warp and cotton weft.3

The textile-factory system developed by way of early modern forms of pro-duction. The factories in England and most of Europe grew out of a wide-spread, large-scale cottage industry rather than out of the much-debated manufacturing stage Karl Marx highlights in the first volume of Das Kapital. There were proto-factories in most countries; however, in research, they increasingly appeared as a peripheral phenomenon.4 As early as the 1960s and the beginning of the 1970s, the now classic studies by Herbert Kisch (the Rhineland) and Franklin Mendels (Flanders) demonstrated the large size of the putting-out system.5

1 Aspin, 1969; Babbage, 1986 [1835]; Baines, 1966 [1835]; Charlton et al., 1973.2 Aspin, 1969, p. 34f; Hopwood, 1969; Chapman, 1987 [1972], pp. 45−52 summarizes the research on child labor. Some of the other social impacts are presented in Kittel, 1967 och McKernan, 1994.3 Aspin,1969; Babbage, 1986 [1835]; Baines, 1966 [1835]; Chapman, 1972; Dodd, 1967 [1842]; Guest, 1968 [1823], pp. 10–35, Plate 5–12; Mann, 1968 [1860]; Mann and Wadsworth, 1931; Wood and Wilmore, 1927, ch. IV, XI. A relatively recent overview of the cotton industry’s development during the 1800s can be found in Farnie, 2003 and for Lancashire in Timmins, 1996. Lancashire in the global context is analyzed in Farnie & Jeremy, 2007 [2004].4 Henderson, 1958 and 1985; Braudel, 1986.5 Kisch, 1989 and Mendels, 1972.

50

Klas Nyberg

In this anthology, the Marxist economic historian Bo Gustafsson’s arti-cle “The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories: With Special Reference to the British Cotton Industry” (1987/1991), has been published for the first time, and it should be seen in the light of this altered view of the putting-out system.6 Gustafsson was, however, not only interested in the transition to a factory system at the end of the eighteenth century and during the nineteenth century. As a Marxist economic historian, he had a genuine academic interest in the broader problem of economic transitions.7 Already in the 1950s, he corresponded with both Maurice Dobb and Paul Sweezy. In the present anthology, Gustafsson points this out in his unfinished autobiography and Lars Magnusson also touches upon the context of the correspondence in the introduction to the volume. Between 1986 and 1994, Gustafsson was also in charge of the international project “From Verlag to Factory” at the Swedish Collegium for Advanced Study in the Social Sciences (SCASSS; later Swed-ish Collegium for Advanced Study, SCAS). Apart from the already-mentioned Lars Magnusson, Amit Bhaduri (University of Vienna), Maxine Berg (De-partment of Economic and Social History, Warwick University), William Lazonick (Barnard College, Columbia University) and Jürgen Schlumbohm (Max Planck Institute for History, Göttingen) were also involved in this proj-ect.

Gustafsson’s posthumously published article can be seen as the last in a series of three separate contributions that all deal with various important tran-sition problems. The other two have already been published: one discusses the decline of ancient slavery and the growth of smallholdings (coloni) at the end of the Roman period, and the other the fundamental, inherent limitation of the medieval guild system’s production method compared with capitalism’s. These three related articles have a similar fundamental way of applying eco-nomic-theoretical models to the main problems in the debates on econom-ic-historical transitions.8

The final article can, as far as Gustafsson is concerned, be seen particularly as an underlying dispute with Marx’s manufacturing stage, although Marx’s evolutionist approach characterized most of Gustafsson’s scholarly — and po-litical — work. Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson, who has compiled his complete bibliography for this anthology, classifies it as “…scholarship and politics”.

The proto-factories were regarded as a transitional stage heralding the emergence of the factory system during the end of the eighteenth century and the nineteenth century. The emergence of textile factories in the Marxist sense, and that of many subsequent researchers, with their centralized production,

6 This current version has been compiled by the editors from two earlier versions that were presented at SCASSS, in September 1987 and November 1991 respectively. The latter version was also presented at the senior seminar of the Department of Economic History in Uppsala during the academic year 1991/92. The present essay is an edited version of these two drafts.7 Sweezy & Hilton, 1985; Aston et al., 1985.8 Gustafsson, 1985, 1987 and 1991.

51

Introductory Comments

where mechanical spinning machines (spinning jennies, water frames, and spinning mules) and mechanical looms were connected to a single power source, had long been seen as the fundamental dynamic in the British and — as it was also viewed at the time — the subsequent European Industrial Revolu-tion. The analysis was based on a limited supply-oriented explanatory model with the new method of production as its starting point.9

After the proto-industrial debate of the 1970s and 1980s, the manufacturing stage was rejected as an envisaged independent development stage in the transition. As previously mentioned, this rejection was rooted in empirical observations. There turned out to be relatively few proto-factories. Their production was small scale and often exclusive, whereas the mass production of the putting-out system appears to have existed throughout Europe where the conditions for traditional agriculture were limited.

As early as the thirteenth century, a large-scale, mass market production of standardized textile goods for export existed in Flanders and other places. Merchants or their representatives provided rural labour with raw materials for spinning or yarn for weaving — a kind of decentralized home production. This was then collected and distributed for further preparation and treatment in the towns, where the textiles were dyed and finished.10 For many post-war researchers, such as Fernand Braudel, Herman Kellenbenz, Paul Sweezy, and later even Jürgen Schlumbohm, the whole putting-out industry played a cru-cial role in the transition to the early textile factories. In the influential 1977 anthology Industrialisierung vor der Industrialisierung (published in English in 1981), Schlumbohm develops a Marxist stage model. In this model, promi-nent merchants are at the heart of the theory formation of proto-industrializa-tion, the concept coined by Mendels in 1972.11 This resulted in different kinds of variations: Kaufsystem and Verlagsystem run by merchants who arranged for the purchase of raw material and organized the production, treatment, in-spection, and selling of the cloth.

The term putting-out system also here includes a social dimension. In this system, craftsmen and farmers became increasingly subordinated and in debt,

9 See Chapman, 1974 on various factory types in England up to the birth of the mechanized cotton mill. For the genesis of the factory system in New England, see Jeremy, 1973 and Tucker 1984. Gross, 1987 and Laurie, 1987, are reviews of Tucker, 1984; Miskell, 1999 deals with Dundee, which was the Scottish linen industry’s equivalent to the development in northern England. A typology of proto-factories in Sweden was developed in Nilsson & Schön, 1978 and was applied in Schön, 1979.10 Braudel’s three volumes Civilizations and Capitalism, 1400–1800 has been translated into Swedish and many other languages and appeared in the 1980s, 1982–1986. They are summa-rized in a short volume, Braudel, 1988. Mendel’s article “Proto-industrialization: The First Phase of the Industrialization Process”, published in 1972, was followed by Kriedte, Medick & Schlumbohm. 1981. Also see Kisch, 1989; see Tilly, R., ‘Prologue: Herbert Kisch, the Man and His Work’, pp. 3–38, in this volume that explains the context. This was followed by the studies that were published in the early 1990s: Kriedte, 1991, Medick, 1996 and Schlumbohm, 1994.11 Kriedte, Medick & Schlumbohm, 1977.

52

Klas Nyberg

and an industrial proletariat emerged.12 Gustafsson’s article should be seen as a contribution to the topical debate of the 1970s and 1980s. However, the ar-ticle is not about whether “proto-industry” — a term the so-called “Göttingen Three” further developed in the 1970s after Mendel had coined it — preceded the factory system, but what forms the causal relationships in the transition took.13 Gustafsson is especially interested in the development in northern Eng-land. Many, including David Landes in The Unbound Prometheus, have seen this development as the starting point for the technology transfer of British technique and organization, which soon spread to the Continent and Scandi-navia.14 When the first draft of Gustafsson’s article was presented in 1987, this was a hypothesis in which he took a keen interest.

The historical growth of the European textile-factory system outside En-gland was, however, more influenced by the formation of society’s institutions than Gustafsson and most researchers of his generation thought. The varying institutional conditions produced different regional developments in various parts of Europe.

From the outset, quality wool, cotton, and silk were international raw materials. The putting-out and factory systems were integrated through these materials into world trade even before the finished products were exported.15 In Western European settings, such as England as well as Scotland and the Netherlands, where the guild system soon waned, the transition from the putting-out cottage industry to the textile-fabric industry is now regarded as the historical focal point, even though the development was by no means uniform: old industrial regions sometimes went into decline and were de-industrialized.16 However, researchers are divided over to what extent early modern proto-industrial activities, besides the putting-out system, led to the factory system in the German principalities, France, and Spain. In addition to the guild system, these countries and principalities had several institutions, including state-owned, princely, and royal proto-factories with special priv-ileges. The manufacturing stage is more prominent in the Central European research tradition, although in present-day research the prevailing school of

12 Nyström, 1955, chapter 1.13 Hans Medick, Peter Kriedte & Jürgen Schlumbohm, the term after Tilly, 1989.14 Landes, 1969; Bruland, 1989. 15 For the wool trade, see Barnett, 1987 and Ulrich, 1994. For trade and textiles in the global historical context, see for example Broadberry & Gupta, 2005; Lindner, 2002; Morris, 1989; O’Hearn, 1994; Otsuka, Ranis & Saxonhouse, 1988 and Tirthankar, 1996.16 Chapman (ed.), 1997, put together the most important articles that were current 15 years ago in four volumes. Subsequently David Jenkins published two volumes in 2003 with new material that presented new perspectives and took into account results from current primary works; Jenkins (ed.). 2003, vol. I−II. He had previously, a few years before Chapman’s edition, edited volume 8, which reflects what was considered as the most important contributions on the place of the textile industry in the first industrial revolution in facsimile print of the classic edition of a total of 11 volumes in the series, The Industrial Revolution edited by R. A. Church & E. A. Wrigley; see Jenkins, 1994. Mann and Wadsworth, 1931 is a standard work on the British cotton industry’s origins and is still regarded as the main work of from an older period.

53

Introductory Comments

thought is that, quantitatively speaking, proto-factories played a limited role, even in areas other than Western Europe. Many proto-factories were, if any-thing, of an arts-and-crafts nature, like, for example, Les Gobelins in Paris. Where the guild system was particularly strong, such as in the Württemberg Black Forest in southern Germany, the kind of development towards mass production for export discussed here was discouraged by the guilds.17 It was often the countryside, which was outside the guild system’s control, that was home to the pre-industrial textile mass production, while generally speaking all the production in the putting-out system was then finished, marketed, and sold from the towns under the auspices of merchants.18 In his article, Gustafs-son’s elaborate definitions of the pre-industrial conditions do not actually consider the question whether society’s institutions are preconditions for, or obstacles to, industrial development and industrialization. He stresses the rise of free wage-earners almost as an axiom, which, of course, narrowly restricts the causal relationships to British conditions.

Gustafsson’s overall approach in his analysis of the causal relationships behind the transition to the factory system in northern England — which many, including Pat Hudson, have felt was a development, even in England, with strong regional features for both the cotton and wool industries — is essentially demand-based. 19 The huge increase in demand, first for cotton yarn and then for cotton fabrics, was historically unique and put pressure on the old method of production. In the end, the organization of the cottage industry could not increase its production at the same rate as the change in the demand. The putting-out system’s many general problems — a lack of control, a waste of ma-te rial, and social antagonisms — are well known and were complicated.20 When production was increased, the biggest difficulty was procuring enough yarn. The labour-intensive spinning had a limited capacity, despite accounting for approximately a third of the labour costs, which in turn amounted to roughly half of the total production costs. As for the number of employed workers, spinners and others who prepared the yarn (winders, bobbiners, and reelers) accounted for between 50 and 80 per cent of the workforce. This depended on how much they worked. Spinning was often a spare-time occupation in extended households. Therefore, the number involved could be very large and spatially dispersed.21 The much discussed mechanization of spinning marked the beginning of the end of the putting-out system. At the end of the eighteenth 17 Ogilvie, 1997 and 2003; Marx, 1970; Conradi-Engqvist, 1994. 18 Cerman & Ogilvie, 1996.19 Hudson, 198920 Randall, 1991 and Mann, 1971 on the putting out system in the West of England which created major social tensions. Conflicts there were, according to Randall, a contributing factor to the woollen industry’s regional shift to the West Riding of Yorkshire during industrialization, where workers and small businessmen were integrated in the production structure and could coexist with the larger factories.21 Nyberg, 1999, chapter 2 and references therein. Biggs & Hutchinson, 2009; Cohen, 1985; Harley, 1992; Lazonick, 1984; Saxonhouse & Wright, 1984; Soderlund, 2006.

54

Klas Nyberg

century, machine spinning in England paved the way for centralized production within a couple of decades. Between 1770 and 1830, the British consumption of raw cotton increased fifty-fold, and at the beginning of the 1830s, the prices of yarn were approximately a thirteenth of the 1780s level.22

Initially, however, mechanized spinning was to be done in the workers’ homes. The first generation of spinning machines, Hargreaves’s spinning jen-ny (1766), was manually operated and sometimes meant to be used in the homes within the decentralized putting-out system. Spinning jennies, how-ever, only produced a relatively loosely spun yarn suitable as weft yarn. The more-tightly spun warp yarn, which required a different thinness and durabil-ity, continued initially to be spun by hand using traditional treadle spinning wheels. The spinning jenny first replaced the great wheel. Nevertheless, it was an important innovation because to make the cloth, somewhat more weft yarn than warp yarn is usually needed. The fluffier and feltier the fabric, the more weft yarn is used. Only with the development of Englishman Richard Arkwright’s famous water frame (so-called because it was powered by water), completed in 1775, was a machine-spun yarn produced that could be used for warping.23 This machine reduced the need for skilled workers and laid the foundations for the controversial and heavily criticized use of child labour in the first generation of cotton spinning mills in Lancashire and many other places.24 The subsequent spinning mule, developed by Samuel Crompton in the 1770s, was a combined machine, i.e. a hybrid that rolled Hargreaves’s and Arkwright’s machines into one.25

All in all, the mechanization of the first generation of spinning mills was, therefore, not radical in the way that characterizes nineteenth-century integrat-ed textile factories, where a single power source was used for the treatment of raw material and yarn, weaving, and finishing.26 That Gustafsson’s article focuses on the predecessors, namely the mechanized cotton spinning mills, is probably because their emergence represents the linchpin of the birth of the factory system. Primarily, this was done by taking the first step towards cen-tralized mass production, with a new kind of full-time wage earner compared with the conditions of the guild and putting-out systems. The actual factories, with centralized production and a single power source, can be interpreted as a consequence of the fundamental departure of the first generation of spinning mills from the earlier conditions in the cottage industry and handicrafts.

Despite attempts to prevent the spread of the new technology, it quickly reached the Continent. On the Continent and in Scandinavia, the mechanized

22 These figures date back to Edward Baines’ classic study from1835, Baines 1966 [1835].23 Aspin & Chapman, 1964; Cameron, 1951; Charlton et al., 1973; Crankshaw & Blackburn, (year of publication is missing); Dobson, 1911; English, 1969; Fitton & Wadsworth, 1958; Gilbert, 1971; Jeremy, 1990; Tucker, 1984; Unwin, 1924; Usher, 1954.24 Aspin, 1969, p. 36; Engels, 1983 [1845].25 Note 23.26 Chapman, 1974, p. 451; Schön, 1979, p. 8f.

55

Introductory Comments

cotton spinning mills had their heyday during the first half of the nineteenth century. However, in such a far-off country as Sweden, the breakthrough did not come until the 1830s, despite the fact that, until 1830, importing coarse cotton yarn was prohibited and thereafter was expensive due to the high tariffs. Just before the middle of the 1830s, factory production overtook the handicraft industries’ production level, and around 1840 the cotton spinning mills produced as much as the imports. Not long after that, there was a drop in the latter. After 1850, the spinning mills in both Scandinavia and most other places began to be gradually integrated with the mechanized cotton textile factories and a new epoch began in the textile-factory system.27

The textile-factory system’s breakthrough was, nevertheless, a gradual, ongoing process not really complete until the 1860s. Gustafsson’s article also shows the continuity of the past, and this is a fundamentally important observation. The mechanized cotton spinning mills, and later the textile fac-tories of the 1850s, were not only the result of the dissemination of tech-nology from Belgium and England as the import bans on textile machines were lifted during the first half of the nineteenth century.28 Already within the non-mechanized textile industry — principally organized as putting-out systems, but also as handicraft and proto-factories, and often regarded as an early modern phenomenon that had nothing to do with the late-eighteenth- and nineteenth-century industrialization — efforts were underway to develop technologically. On the Continent, many of those who built the first factories were part of a social nexus of innovators, where practising engineers were part of a larger cluster of scholars, merchants, and directors who actively sought out the leading region for trade and industry of their time, namely Lancashire in North-West England.

*

With his important theoretically analytical approach, we believe Gustafsson’s contribution should be seen as a significant one in the 1980s debate on the emergence of the factory system. Although by now Gustafsson’s article is almost twenty-five years old, it feels strangely timeless — still refreshingly new and vital. As the editors, we hope the article will be widely read.

27 Schön, 1979, pp. 100–101. See also Bagge, 1889. For the emergence of the Swedish mecha-nized cotton weaving mills, see Jonsson, 2000.28 Landes, 1969, chapter 3.

56

Klas Nyberg

BibliographyAspin, C. Lancashire, The First Industrial Society. Helmshore Local History Society.

1969.Aston, Trevor Henry & Philpin, Charles Harding English (eds.), The Brenner debate:

agrarian class structure and economic development in pre-industrial Europe. Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge 1985.

Babbage, Charles, On the economy of machinery and manufactures, Repr., Kelley. New York, 1986 [1835].

Bagge, Daniel Henric, Anteckningar om Sveriges bomullsspinnerier samlade under en lång lifstid, utg. på författarens åttionde födelsedag. Norrköping 1889.

Baines, Edward Jr, History of the cotton manufacture in Great Britain. With a notice of its early history in the East, and in all the quarters of the globe. ...[Illustr.]. London 1966 [1835].

Barnett, D. E., “Angora Goats in Texas. Agricultural Innovation on the Edwards Pla-teau, 1858–1900.” The Southwestern Historical Quarterly, Vol. 90, No. 4 (Apr., 1987), pp. 347–372.

Biggs, N. & Hutchinson, J., “Research Note. Knowles’ Patent Yarn Balance.” Textile History, 40 (1), 97–102, May 2009.

Braudel, Fernand, Civilisationer och kapitalism 1400­1800. Band 2, Marknadens spel. [Civilisation matérielle, économie et capitalisme, XVe–XVIIIe siècle. T. 2, Les jeux de l’échange.] Stockholm 1986.

Braudel, Fernand, Kapitalismens dynamik. [La dynamique du capitalisme.] Hedemo-ra 1988.

Broadberry, Stephen N. & Gupta, Bishnupriya, “Cotton Textiles and the Great Di-vergence: Lancashire, India and Shifting Competitive Advantage, 1600–1850.” CEPR Discussion Papers: 5183, 2005.

Bruland, K., British technology and European industrialization. The Norwegian textile industry in the mid nineteenth century. Cambridge, New York, Melbourne 1989.

Cameron, Hector Charles, Samuel Crompton. [inventor of the spinning mule]. London 1951.

Cerman, Markus & Ogilvie, Sheilagh, C. (eds.), European proto­industrialization. Cambridge 1996.

Chapman S. D. (ed.), The Textile Industries I–IV. London, New York 1997. Chapman, S. D., James Hargreaves and the Spinning Jenny. Helmshore Local History

Society. Helmshore 1964.Chapman, S. D., The Cotton Industry in the Industrial Revolution. (Studies in Eco-

nomic and Social History). London 1987 [1972].Chapman, S. D., “The Textile Factory before Arkwright. A Typology of Factory De-

velopment.” Business History Review, Vol. 48:4, pp. 451–478, 1974. Charlton C. et al., Arkwright and the Mills at Cromford. Matlock 1973. Cohen, Isaac, “Workers’ Control in the Cotton Industry: a Comparative Study of Brit-

ish and American Mule Spinning.” Labor History, pp. 53–85, 1985.Conradi-Engqvist, C., Les Gobelins i Paris. Tre franska manufakturer förr och nu.

Stockholm 1994.

57

Introductory Comments

Crankshaw, W. P. & Blackburn, A., A Century and a Half of Cotton Spinning 1797–1947. (Year of publication is missing).

Dobson, B. P., The Story of the Evolution of the Spinning Machine. Manchester 1911.Dodd, W., The Factory System Illustrated in a Series of Letters. Cass Library of Indu-

strial Classics , 10. London, Edinburgh 1967 [1842]. Engels, Friedrich, Den arbetande klassens läge i England. Från egna iakttagelser och

autentiska källor. [Die Lage der arbeitenden Klasse in England. Nach eigner An-schauung und authentischen Quellen, 1845.] Göteborg 1983.

English, W., The Textile industry. An Account of the Early Inventions. Harlow 1969. Farnie, D. A. & Jeremy, D. J. (eds.), The fibre that changed the world. The cotton

industry in international perspective, 1600–1990s. Oxford, New York 2004.Farnie, D., “Cotton 1780–1914.” Jenkins, David T. (ed.), The Cambridge history of

western textiles. 2. Cambridge 2003, pp. 721–760.Fitton, R. S. & Wadsworth, A. P., The Strutts and the Arkwrights, 1758–1830. A study

of the early factory system. Manchester 1958. Gilbert, K. R., Textile Machinery. London 1971. Gross, Laurence, “Review of Samuel Slater and the Origins of the American Textile

Industry, 1790–1860 by B. M. Tucker.” The Pennsylvania Magazine of History and Biography, Vol. 111, No. 1 (Jan., 1987), pp. 132–135.

Guest, R., A Compendiuos History of the Cotton Manufacture. Cass Library of Indus-trial Classics, 16. London, Endinburgh1968 [1823].

Gustafsson, B., “The rise and economic behaviour of medieval craft guilds.” Power and Economic Institutions: Reinterpretations in Economic History. Gustafsson, Bo (ed.), pp. 69–106. Introduction, pp. 1–50. Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 1991.

Gustafsson, B., “The rise and economic behaviour of the medieval craft guilds. An economic-theoretical interpretation.” The Scandinavian Economic History Review 1987, 25 (1): 1–40.

Gustafsson, B., “Det antika slaveriets nedgång: En ekonomisk teori.” Uppsala papers in economic history. Research report No 10. 91 pp. Uppsala: Department of Eco-nomic History, 1985.

Gustafsson, B., “Det antika slaveriets nedgång: En ekonomisk teori.” Aktuellt om historia 1985, häfte 1/2, pp. 70–88.

Harley, C., “International competitiveness of the antebellum American cotton textile industry.” Journal of Economic History [serial online]. September 1992;52 (3), 559−584.

Henderson, William Otto, Manufactories in Germany. Frankfurt am Main 1985.Henderson, William Otto, The state and the industrial revolution in Prussia 1740–1870.

Liverpool U.P, Liverpool, 1958Hopwood, E. A., History of the Lancashire Cotton Industry and the Amalgamated

Weavers’ Association. The lancashire weavers’ story. Amalgamated Weavers As-sociation. Manchester 1969.

Hudson, P., Regions and Industries. A Perspective on the Industrial Revolution in Britain. Cambridge, New York and Melbourne 1989.

Jenkins, D. T. (ed.), The Cambridge History of Western Textiles. I–II. Cambridge 2003. Jenkins, D. T. (ed.), The industrial revolutions. Vol. 8 , The textile industries. General

editors R.A. Church and E.A. Wrigley. Oxford 1994.

58

Klas Nyberg

Jeremy, D. T., “Innovation in American Textile Technology during the Early 19th Century.” Technology and Culture, Vol. 14, No. 1 (Jan., 1973), pp. 40–76.

Jeremy, David J., Technology and power in the early American cotton industry: James Montgomery, the second edition of his “Cotton manufacture” (1840), and the ‘Justitia’ controversy about relative power costs. (American Philosophical Society). Philadelphia 1990.

Jonsson, Pernilla, Marknadens väv: svenska mekaniserade bomullsväverier i distribu-tion och försäljning 1850–75. Uppsala 2000.

Kisch, H., From Domestic Manufacture to Industrial Revolution. The Case of the Rhineland Textile Districts. New York, Oxford 1989.

Kittell, Allan H., “The Revolutionary Period of the Industrial Revolution: Industrial Innovation and Population Displacement in Belgium, 1830−1880.” Journal of Social History, Vol. 1, No. 2 (Winter, 1967), pp. 119−148.

Kriedte, P., Eine Stadt am seidenen faden. Haushalt, Hausindustrie und soziale Bewe-gung in Krefeld in der Mitte des. 19. jahrhunderts. Göttingen 1991.

Kriedte, Peter, Medick, Hans & Schlumbohm, Jürgen, Industrialisierung vor der Industrialisierung: gewerbliche Warenproduktion auf dem Land in der Formati-onsperiode des Kapitalismus, 1. Aufl. Göttingen 1977.

Kriedte, P., Medick, H., Schlumbohm, J., Industrialization before Industrialization. Rural Industry in the Genesis of Capitalism. (With contributions from Herbert Kisch and Franklin F. Mendels). Cambridge 1981.

Landes, David S., The unbound Prometheus: technological change and industrial development in Western Europe from 1750 to the present. Cambridge 1969.

Laurie, Bruce, “Review of Samuel Slater and the Origins of the American Textile Industry, 1790­1860 by B. M. Tucker.” Technology and Culture, Vol. 28, No. 1 (Jan., 1987), pp. 155–157.

Lazonick, William, “Rings and Mules in Britain. Reply.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 99, No. 2 (May, 1984), pp. 393–398.

Lindner, S. H., “Technology and Textiles Globalization.” History and Technology, 2002, vol. 18 (1), pp. 1–22.

Mann, J. A., The Cotton trade of Great Britain. Its rise, progress and present extent. Cass library of industrial classics. no. 20. London 1968 [1860].

Mann, de Lacy J. & Wadsworth, A. P., The Cotton Trade and Industrial Lancashire. Manchester 1931.

Mann, J. de Lacy, The cloth industry in the west of England from 1640 to 1880. Oxford 1971.

Marx, Karl, Kapitalet. Kritik av den politiska ekonomin. Bok 1. Kapitalets produk-tionsprocess. [Das Kapital: Kritik der politischen Ökonomie, Bd 1.] Lund 1970.

McKernan, Anne, “War, Gender, and Industrial Innovation: Recruiting Women Weav-ers in Early Nineteenth-Century Ireland.” Journal of Social History, Vol. 28, No. 1 (Autumn, 1994), pp. 109−124.

Medick, H., Weben und ûberleben in Laichingen 1650–1900. Lokalgeschichte als allgemeine Geschichte. Göttingen 1996.

Mendels, F., “Proto–industrialization: The First Phase of the Industrialization Pro-cess.” Journal of Economic History, vol. XXXI, 1972, pp. 241–61.

59

Introductory Comments

Miskell, Louise, “‘Juteopolis’ in the Making: Linen and the Industrial Transforma-tion of Dundee, c. 1820–1850.” Textile History Autumn 99, Vol. 30, Issue 2, pp. 176–198.

Morris D. Morris, “Review of Comparative Technology Choice in Development. The Indian and Japanese Cotton Textile Industries By Keijiro Otsuka, Gustav Ranis, and Gary Saxonhouse. St. Martin’s Press, New York, 1988.” Journal of Japanese Studies, Vol. 15, No. 1 (Winter, 1989), pp. 186–196.

Nilsson, Carl-Axel & Schön, Lennart, “Factories in Sweden 1820–1870. A typologi-cal approach.” Economy and History, 1978 (21), pp. 89–103.

Nyberg, K., Kommersiell kompetens och industrialisering. Norrköpings ylleindustri-ella tillväxt på Stockholms bekostnad. 1780­1846. Uppsala 1999.

Nyström, Per, Stadsindustriens arbetare före 1800­talet. [bidrag till kännedom om den svenska manufakturindustrien och dess sociala förhållanden]. Stockholm 1955.

Ogilvie, Sheilagh C., A bitter living. Women, markets, and social capital in early modern Germany. Oxford 2003.

Ogilvie, Sheilagh, Institutions and European Trade. Merchant Guilds, 1000–1800. Cambridge 2010.

Ogilvie, Sheilagh, State corporatism and proto­industry. The Württemberg Black For-est, 1580–1797. Cambridge 1997.

O’Hearn, D., “Innovation and the World-System Hierarchy: British Subjugation of the Irish Contton Industry, 1780–1830.” The American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 100, No 3 (November 1994), pp. 587–621.

Otsuka, Keijiro & Ranis, Gustav & Saxonhouse, Gary, Comparative technology choice in development. The Indian and Japanese cotton textile industries. New York 1988.

Randall, A., Before the Luddites. Custom, community and machinery in the English woollen industry, 1776–1809. Cambridge 1991.

Saxonhouse, Gary, R. & Wright, Gavin, “New Evidence on the Stubborn English Mule and the Cotton Industry, 1878–1920.” The Economic History Review, New Series, Vol. 37, No. 4 (Nov. 1984), pp. 507–519.

Schlumbohm, J., Lebensleufe, Familien, Höfe. die Bauern und Heuerleute des Osna-brückischen Kirchspiels Belm in proto–industrieller Zeit, 1650–1850. Göttingen 1994.

Schön, Lennart, Från Hantverk till fabriksindustri. Svensk textiltillverkning 1820–1870. Lund 1979.

Soderlund, Richard J., “Resistance from the Margins. The Yorkshire Worsted Spin-ners, Policing, and the Transformation of Work in the Early Industrial Revolu-tion.” International Review of Social History, Vol. 51; Part 2, 2006, pp. 217–242.

Sweezy, Paul M. & Hilton, Rodney (eds.), The transition from feudalism to capital-ism. Verso ed. London 1985.

Tilly, R., “Prologue: Herbert Kisch, the Man and His Work” in Kisch, H., From Do-mestic Manufacture to Industrial Revolution. The Case of the Rhineland Textile Districts. New York, Oxford 1989, pp. 3–38

Timmins, G., Four centuries of Lancashire cotton. Preston 1996.Tirthankar, Roy, “Review: Textiles and Industrialisation.” Economic and Political

Weekly, Vol. 31, No. 49 (Dec. 7, 1996), pp. 3174–3175.

60

Klas Nyberg

Tucker, B. M., Samuel Slater and the origins of the American Textile industry, 1790–1860. Ithaca, London 1984.

Ulrich, Pamela V., “From fustian to merino. The rise of textiles using cotton before and after the gin.” Agricultural History; Spring94, Vol. 68 Issue 2, pp. 219−32.

Unwin, G., Samuel Oldknow and the Arkwrights. Longmans 1924. Usher, A. P., A History of Mechanical Inventions. Cambridge, Mass. 1954.Wood, L. S. & Wilmore, A., The Romance of the Cotton Industry in England. London

1927.

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

With Special Reference to the British Cotton Industry

Bo Gustafsson

Part I

A Preliminary Narrative and Explanatory Sketch

65

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

I. Abstract*1 The transition from domestic industries and putting-out systems to factories is an important problem in economic history and economics from several points of view. In the first place, the problem has been insufficiently investigated. The standard explanation referring to technological causes — “machines and steam-power” — takes one important structural condition into account. But it is deficient in so far as it treats technological change as an exogenous vari-able, it has nothing to say on other as important conditions, such as manifest changes in economic, social, demographic or cultural structures or changing marketing conditions, and it disregards the fact that the new technology was to a great extent utilized parallel in domestic industries and factories and that the first factories did not utilize steam-power at all. Secondly, the transition from domestic industries to factories had wider ramifications in so far as it was a part and an expression of a larger and more fundamental phenomenon: the transition from (developed) simple commodity production with more or less independent producers, although under the growing command of merchant capital, to a mode of production made up of proletarianized wage earners and capitalists having monopolized the ownership of the means of production. Thirdly, an investigation of the transition from domestic industries may throw light on the general problem of centralized versus decentralized production in a market economy, a recurring phenomenon in industrial capitalism.

The transition from domestic industries to factories seems to have orig-inated in the rapidly rising demand for final output in the textile industries, especially the cotton industries, from the middle of the 18th century and espe-cially from the 1770’s. This expansion of demand was of course conditioned upon the take-off of industry resulting in growing production and, at least for some strata, growing real incomes. But it may also be a reflection of a struc-tural transformation of production from rapidly decreasing self-sufficiency to increasing division of labour and increasing reliance on markets. If domestic producers specialized in specific lines of production and some strata were divorced from land and commons, the effects should be an increased mar-ket demand especially for consumers’ goods but also producers’ goods (à la Lenin’s model in “The market question”). In any case it should be possible to treat demand, especially foreign demand, as an exogenous variable for a separate industry, like cotton.

The rapidly increasing demand put domestic industries under severe strains. To an astonishingly large extent domestic industries succeeded in meeting the requirements of expanding demand, partly by a simple extension of production * This essay has been compiled from two, somewhat different, papers that were presented at SCASSS, in September 1987 and November 1991 respectively. The latter version was also presented at the senior seminar of the Department of Economic History in Uppsala during the academic year 1991/92. The present essay is an edited version of these two drafts. Language has been corrected, and some text has been edited for clarity. Underlined text is as it appears in the orginal versions.

66

Bo Gustafsson

to new households and partly by increasing productivity assisted by innovations, like the flying shuttle, the spinning jenny, carding machines etc. Still, domestic industries operated under constraints that were difficult to overcome: in the first place the inelasticity and irregularity of labour supply (conditioned by the existence of agricultural pursuits and by “leisure-preference”); the uneven quality of products (conditioned by the great variation in skills in and between families); high costs of transportation of raw materials, through-puts and outputs; low rates of turnover of capital (conditioned by the large amount of fetching and carrying and the decentralized decision-making process); embezzlement of raw-materials (conditioned by the shared responsibilities between domestic producers and putters-out). These constraints became more pronounced when demand and production increased and competition was intensified both in input and — especially — in output markets. Employers became anxious to get hold of the most important factor of production, labour, to exploit it more efficiently, to lower the time of production from the purchase of labour and means of production to the realization of final output, to lower capital requirements and to increase control over labour, the process of production and final output. Thus, strong incentives to change the relations of production arose by centralizing production under the command of the capitalists.

This was made possible by parallel changes in social structure and pro ductive forces (population and technology). The enclosure movement concentrating land and dissolving the commons increased rapidly during the course of the 18th century. This tended to marginalize or proletarianize domestic producers and dissolve the traditional ties between labour and land, making domestic producers more mobile and more dependent upon both the labour market and the market for food-stuffs. Increasingly they had to sell their labour-power and buy their subsistence (wood, milk) on the market for wages earned. The industrialization increased demand for labour-power and favored family formation, increasing birth rates. The growing families needed supplements to the family income and the labour of women — freed from supplementary work on the commons — and children gave rise to an increasing pool of labour to be tapped. Similarly the growing production and demand for final output gave incentives to continuously innovate and increase the size of machinery, e.g. jennies and carding machines. To begin with these enlarged and more expensive machines could be accommodated within domestic industries. But sooner or later they became beyond the reach of many domestic producers. The more prosperous among them and putters-out started to concentrate machines and workers (often whole families) in workshops and primitive factories, sometimes combining carding, spinning, winding and weaving and other processes. By this development of productive forces class differentiation of direct producers increased. Some direct producers were transformed into pure wage labourers, while putters-out, manufacturers and merchants got control over labour utilization, the process of production and the quality of

67

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

products, lowered capital requirements and transaction costs and increased the intensity — and sometimes also the productivity — of labour as well as its profitability.

This development took a qualitative leap forward with the invention of the Arkwright water-frame and carding machine, which represented a substantial investment out of reach for most domestic producers. It is noteworthy that Arkwright’s patented water-frame was considerably larger than was technical-ly necessary. If this was because his large machine was more productive (and thus more profitable) than smaller variants or because he wished to exclude competition from domestic producers is uncertain. In any case, Arkwright’s machines could definitely not be accommodated within domestic production. Thus arose those first large factories with large machines propelled by wa-ter-power turning out products of higher and more even qualities (although not finer yarn) and making an increased productivity of labour and a higher profitability possible.

Since the growth of production and demand to begin with far outstripped the capacity of the first factories, the pressure on labour to take up employment in the first factories was not strong. Indeed, the increased production of yarn gave increased employment possibilities to weavers as well as to those jenny spinners  —and later mule spinners — who put out yarn of higher counts. This fact, in combination with the forced localization of the Arkwright factories to places where water-power could be supplied, created a labour problem for the first factory masters. Thus, they devised their machines preferably for children and apprentice children and women constituted the main labour force. Parish apprentices were successively substituted for free labour children when the utilization of steam-power loosened the constraints on localization put up by water-power and when it was found that parish apprentices’ efficiency wages were relatively high. Still the utilization of children and women as labour power long remained characteristic for cotton manufacture, partly because it was profitable and partly because labour families were in need of the supplementary income provided by them. To begin with it was very difficult to recruit male labour to the factories except as overseers and foremen, even if factory wages are reported to be higher than in domestic industries and employment certainly more continuous. This may have been conditioned partly by the existence of alternative employments and partly by culturally conditioned resistance against factory work, which was looked upon as, and in fact was, work-house labour.

This seems to have changed with the new conditions of factory production arising after 1820 with the introduction of mechanized mule-spinning (the self-actor mule) and mechanized weaving (the power-loom). In these facto-ries productivity was high enough to permit the combined existence of low unit-labour cost, high capital productivity and high profits (not necessarily high profit rates) on the one hand, and relatively high labour earnings made possible by the high productivity and enforced by labour organizations. When

68

Bo Gustafsson

labour had been won over for the factory system the transition was finally safe-guarded. The dominance of production of absolute surplus value gave way for the dominance of the production of relative surplus value.

Putting this transitional problematic in a nutshell, we might say that the transition from domestic industries to factories was conditioned by on the one hand the increasing market demand for final output and on the other hand the increasing costs of domestic industries caused thereby. This created incentives to develop machines to increase labour productivity and to centralize labour and production, which also was made possible by the intensified primary accumulation creating more mobile and marginalized labour but also by in-vestible funds among merchants and manufacturers. Evidence shows that the first factory owners were recruited from employers of the preceding industrial systems.

Centralized labour and production provided the basis for a more efficient utilization of labour and for control of product quality, but also — and this became progressively more important — for innovation activity and its effi-cient incorporation into the capitalist business firm. It was these far-reaching technological changes, ultimately ending in the automatized factory, which consolidated the factory system as a new and successful mode of production. It struck a new, if precarious, balance between the opposite interests of the employers and the direct producers.

II. The Transition from Domestic Industry to Factory ProductionThe purpose of this paper is to provide a preliminary explanatory sketch of the historical transformation from domestic industries to factory production, based upon a classic case, the British cotton industry. The importance of this problem is not only that the transition in question signaled a change of the technical-organizational form of production, from households to factories or from decentralized to centralized production. More important is that this change of technical-organizational form was embedded in a fundamental change of the relations of production from a system of predominantly simple commodity production, with more or less independent small producers, to a system of capitalist relations of production with capitalists monopolizing the means of production and exploiting the labour power of property-less workers. This change was mediated by an intervening stage called the Verlag or the putting-out system, which originated in the late Middle Ages and grew in importance, especially during the course of the 18th century. The Verlag system was a transitional stage in so far as it entailed the successive encroachment of nascent capitalist relationships on domestic industries and

69

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

implied an increasing centralization of ownership of the means of production and final output, before the direct operation of production was transferred to centralized workshops or factories. Thus the Verlag system should be looked upon as an extension of simple commodity production in the direction of capitalist relations of production and the factory system.

It is this transition from simple and developed commodity production to capitalist relations of production, which lends the whole transitional problem-atic its great historical interest. If it had only been a story of how decentralized production became centralized in its technical-organizational aspects, we would not treat this transitional problematic as unique, since one may observe recur-rent waves of centralization and decentralization of production in the course of industrial history, without such upheavals and fundamental structural changes of the whole fabric of society as witnessed in the first industrial revolution.

The transition from domestic industries and putting-out systems to factories thus involved a change of the relations of production (the rise to predomi-nance of the capital-labour relationship) as well as a change of the forces of production (the transition from domestic industries to factories). In fact, this transition may be taken as a very interesting example of the complicated in-terplay of relations of production and forces of production in the development of economic society with now the relations of production, now the forces of production playing the role of prime mover, the two sets of determinants of change usually inter-mixed and sometimes difficult to isolate or even to define consistently. The following simple time matrix may provide a preliminary interpretative frame of reference:

What occurred in the transition was that, firstly, property relations were centralized in the growing dominance of merchant capital over domestic in-dustries. Only on the basis of this change of relations of property did the ope-ration or management of production completely change from decentralized to centralized forms (the victory of the factory). (One may also note that the

Production

Ownership Centralized Decentralized

Centralized

Decentralized

Capitalist factory

Cooperative factory

Putting-out system

Domestic industries

(1)

(2)

= arrow of time

70

Bo Gustafsson

possible combination of centralized production and decentralized ownership, e.g. in the form of producer-owned factories — cooperatives — never materia-lized, although the breakthrough of the share-company later signified to begin with a limited “collectivization” of ownership on the basis of capitalist rela-tions of production. This problematic should probably be studied in order to make clear why only the capitalist factory became a viable alternative in the industrial revolution. In fact, it occurred, as e.g. Unwin noted in his book on Samuel Oldknow and the Arkwright (1924), p. 130, that some spinners centra-lized in Oldknow’s premises may have owned their jennies. More important, there existed a tradition of cooperative ownership in the fulling branch of the woollen industries and there are also instances of small-scale share-ownership or renting of premises in the first primitive cotton factories. Why could not domestic producers pool their resources and establish successful factories as producers’ cooperatives? Was it because of cultural traditions and social habits inhibiting a new role? Or, because of a hostile capitalist environment strang-ling producers’ cooperatives? Or, as Alchian and Demsetz want us to believe, because of problems of shirking and mutual monitoring (the 1/n-problem) or what? This should be investigated!)

III. Some Problems of Meaning and of ResearchThe process of transition from domestic industries to putting-out and further to factories was exceedingly complicated and drawn-out with complications, short-cuts and bifurcations in the organizational set-up, as well as in the dynamics of the process in specific industries, between different industries and between different countries. There were domestic industries that remained domestic industries, domestic industries that switched directly over to factory production, factories that arose qua factories from the beginning, putting-out industries that remained putting-out industries, putting-out industries that degenerated to sweating industries, putting-out industries that were transformed to factory industries, putting-out industries that were combined with factory production and vice versa and so on. Still, over time the sequence domestic industries > putting-out system > factories was the dominant trend and the differences noted were mainly important for the phasing of the transition, sometimes early and sometimes late. But they may also give us insights into the mechanisms of transition and the relative weight of different conditions. In the woollen industries extensive regulations, technical problems in spinning and weaving and the enormous variety of products may explain the delay of the factories.

Further, when we talk about “factories” we imply that this is a thing rather than a process. Factories arose, developed and were transformed during the course of the industrial revolution. The first workshops with some carding machines and jennies and a dozen workers — often ex-domestic industry fam-

71

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

ilies — is something different from the first Arkwright mills with water frames and child labour and propelled by horses or, ultimately, water. And the last mentioned cannot be compared in all respects with the full-blown integrat-ed cotton factories of the 1840’s with mechanized mule spinning and pow-er-looms and propelled by huge steam engines. Much of the confusion around the causation of the factory system may emanate from this fact. When Ure, probably correctly, professes that the long-run victory of the factory system may have been conditioned by the fact that it made possible both higher wages and higher profits than the preceding forms of organization, his frame of ref-erence are the developed and highly mechanized factories of the 1830’s. But it is doubtful how far that factory system and its mode of operation are relevant for the early factories. Still, if we want to explain the causes of the rise of the factory system it is those early factories that demand our attention. Maybe we have to assume that the causes leading to the victory of the factory system were different in different time periods? It is possible that at one point of time a specific set of causes gave rise to factories, while other causes, developing at a later point of time, became determining for the succeeding development. At least we should be aware of this problematic.

There are also other problems connected with the question of causation. It is sometimes held that one should allow for the operation of different sets of causes for different industries (S.H.R. Jones, 1986), e.g. technological deter-minants, transaction cost considerations or improved possibilities for exploita-tion. It has also been pointed out that the necessity of using water power or the scale of operation in certain industries like iron works and paper mills explain why they were organized in a centralized way already before the rise of the factory system in textile industries, while such causes could not have been important in the early phase of textile industries. This would only apply to the Arkwright factories of the 1780’s and 1790’s, which had to use water power (originally horse power) in order to propel the water frames and hence were located at water falls (natural or constructed with the help of reservoirs) in the countryside. While different sets of causes may have had unequal importance in individual industries or among firms in individual industries, a general set of causes is required for the explanation of the rise of the factory system as a general phenomenon. But it is exceedingly difficult to know whether a factor should be regarded as general or specific, especially since the evidence is so meagre and unevenly distributed over time and industries.

A still more difficult problem connected with the question of causation confronts us when we want to know how the causation in fact did work. Let us put the problem in this way. Domestic industries and putting-out systems were ways of organizing production and producing industrial products at a certain time, t1, and later, at time t2, these systems have been superseded by the factory system. It is reasonable to assume that the change of industrial organization was effected by a change in “data” or the initial conditions of industrial orga-nization on the path from t1 to t2. These changes could, e.g., either refer to the

72

Bo Gustafsson

inputs of labour and/or capital, to the process of production, to the marketing of final output or to combinations of them together or in some sequence, like a massive rise of free labour, market expansion etc. The task then is to find out which of those conditions were the most important in bringing about the tran-sition of industrial organization. But it is also possible to assume that nothing particularly new or important is happening in the “data” of the problem or the conditions. These being more or less unchanged one may imagine that the factories represented not an induced but an autonomous organizational inno-vation, which did not exist in (this new form) earlier and, because of efficiency properties, superseded the domestic industries and putting-out systems. In this case one might refer to new ways of organizing work or the invention of ma-chines or new sources of power like steam.

Up to now problems of explanation have been framed only with reference to objective conditions and impersonal factors giving rise to the event or effect to be explained. But the transition could not have occurred if it had not been for the aims, plans, decisions and acts of the actors. concerned. That these were important in the process of causation seems to be confirmed in several ways. (Framing the explanation in terms of aims etc. implies that we are confronted with a teleological explanation. But at least formally such explanations may be reduced to regular causal explanations, if we regard the aims etc. as part of the conditioning factors.) One may refer, e.g., to the reluctance of ordinary work-ers to take up employment in the early textile factories in spite of the fact that the earnings in those factories seem to have been both higher and more regular than in domestic industries or putting-out systems. The drawn-out decline of hand-loom weaving also seems to be a case in point in so far as hand-loom weavers refused to take up employment in factories because of social pride etc. Generally speaking capitalists may have wanted to establish factories at a certain point of time but could not do so, because workers would not take up employment in factories. Or, capitalists could do it, because workers also would do so. Thus, we should pay attention to the fact that not only capitalists but also workers — and probably other actors as well, like governments and their policies — were engaged in the process of transition.

Since there were different actors we should also assume the existence of different objective functions and behavioural rules of the actors involved and probably also changing objective functions and behavioural rules in the same actors over time. This problematic has been very important in the debate about family households in pre-industrial socio-economic structures (the existence of self-exploitation, backward-sloping supply curve of labour/leisure preference, satisfying behaviour etc.). Knowledge about such things may be important for the transitional problematic, at least as to timing and phasing, since they influenced reactions towards incentives, margins of survival etc. Attempts by factory owners to get hold of labour by offering higher wages may, e.g., have resulted in a corresponding decrease of the labour supply and, thus, resulted in the employment of children or in the introduction of harsh factory discipline.

73

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

Likewise the conditions of existence and capacity for survival of sweating industries must surely partly have been conditioned by something more than purely objective conditions, e.g. traditions of self-exploitation.

Let us now turn to problems of definition of the entities concerned. When speaking about a “factory” we usually refer to a technical-organizational enti-ty as well as to a financial unit or a “firm”. But in the early days of the factory system factories and firms were not always synonymous entities, nor were they so later. To begin with many firms owned or rented a factory building together and later one firm could and did own several factories. Thus, what occurred in an early factory sometimes was the outcome of the operation of several firms and the success or demise of later factories was conditioned by the decisions of one firm. When we in this paper talk about factories we make the extreme simplification that factories and firms are more or less identical.

Also domestic industries and the putting-out system varied in organiza-tion and — probably — behaviour and function and were affected by changing initial and boundary conditions during the course of development. Take for instance the amount of land available for a domestic industrial household. If the amount of land at disposal was considerable, the bargaining position of the domestic industrialists was probably stronger than in cases when the amount of land at disposal was marginal. This should have had consequences for the outcome of the bargaining with putters-out and merchants and hence also for the living standard of the domestic industrialists and the profitabil-ity of the putting-out system or the merchant activities, respectively. But it also affected the amount of labour supplied, especially in the spring-time and the summer months, because of the time-consuming agricultural tasks. This should have made merchants and putters-out anxious to have at their disposal domestic industrialists with little land and thus highly dependent upon their industrial pursuits. On the other hand it is sometimes held that the putting-out system profited upon domestic industries offering low wages for the products precisely because there was land available so that the domestic producers had to “exploit” their agricultural side-lines. We do not know if there existed any clear trend as to the relative importance of agriculture and other primary economic activities for the primary producers during the course of the 18th century. Rapidly rising population and enclosures should have decreased the relative importance of agriculture, while the expansion of domestic industries, e.g. weaving, as a consequence of the rising demand from the factories, on the one hand should have made industrial production more rewarding, while on the other hand the extension of domestic industries into the countryside should have worked in the opposite direction. On balance it seems fair to assume that agriculture decreased and industry increased in the household economy of the domestic producers. Even if the evidence for such a general conclusion is missing, one gets the impression that this view is the dominant one (e.g. S.H. Chapman, 1904, Daniels 1920, Tupling 1927).

74

Bo Gustafsson

We shall not go into the complicated problems of various varieties of the putting-out system with very intriguing relationships between the direct pro-ducers, various sorts of middlemen (shop-keepers, putters-out, factors etc.) and merchants selling the end product, usually after some kind of finishing in their own premises. A specific variety is met with in the Midland hosiery industries with its developed debt system based upon the renting of knitting-frames. The degree to which the direct producers owned the means of production also varied between different industries and probably also over time. At the one extreme the direct producers owned both raw materials and the means of labour; at the other extreme they did not even own the cottages wherein they worked and lived. Usually they seem to have owned their means of labour.

Lastly there is the problem of sources and evidence and it has various dimensions. It is, firstly, striking that most of our knowledge about the op-eration of domestic industries and the early factories, respectively, rests on conjectures inferred from observations or obiter dicta of contemporary ob-servers, pamphlets, regulations etc. and the most interesting passages are so few that they repeatedly recur in the secondary sources (like Aikin, Guest, Radcliffe, Kennedy and others). But have these sources ever been subjected to the stringent methods of historical source criticism by, preferably, British historians? One notes very little of such source criticism except occasionally, as by shrewd historians like T.S. Ashton. Mostly one meets with plain story-telling taking sources at face value. Take for example the celebrated and often utilized speech by the cotton lord John Kennedy in the Manchester Literary Society in 1819, “Observations on the rise and progress of the cotton trade in Great Britain”. Although Kennedy probably was in a privileged position to observe his trade, repeated reading of this piece has convinced me that it is nothing but a literary construction aimed at impressing the learned society by the speaker’s reading of Adam Smith! At least, this goes for his completely idealized rendering of the transition from domestic to factory production in the cotton trade. I noted above Unwin’s observation that the first jenny spinners at Oldknow’s premises owned their jennies. Although Unwin at least makes clear how he reached that conclusion it remains a fact that he did not have any document telling him that such was the case. He inferred this from the fact that some spinners had higher wages than others. Likewise, in all those cases when authors on the subject affirm that factories often arose because jennies or carding machines “became larger” and, hence, could not be owned by most domestic producers, I have the impression that we are confronted by a case of hypothetical inference, based on scattered observations of the renting of machines. Still, we cannot disregard this very common assertion met with in the literature.

I mention these problems just to make us aware of very complicated problems involved in the project of explaining the transition from domestic industries to putting-out and I am fully aware that it is impossible wholly to avoid them, as the following pages probably will testify!

75

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

IV. An Overview of the ProblemThe transition from domestic industries and the putting-out system to factories was a process that originated in the early 18th century and took off by degrees after the 1760’s and, particularly from the 1780’s. (Here we talk about factories only or mainly as centralized work-places with a few machines, some times driven by water power.) Structural changes of importance for this transition seem to have been: 1) The growing commercialization of the economy from the end of the 17th century; 2) As a part of this process the concentration of land holding (i.a. through enclosures) and the dissolution of the commons; 3) The quickened pace of industrialization during the course of the 18th century before the rise of the factories, propelled by the commercial revolution being at the same time a part of and a condition for this; 4) The ensuing rise of population fundamentally conditioned by the growing demand for labour power.

As Mantoux aptly phrased it: “The Commercial expansion ... preceded ...the changes in industry” and he added: “The growth of Lancashire, of all English counties, the one most deserving to be called the cradle of the fac-tory system, depended first of all on the development of Liverpool and of her trade.” (Mantoux, p. 91 and 108). This observation first and foremost applies to the role of foreign trade, which may be regarded as exogenous compared to the parallel growth of domestic production and domestic trade. Foreign trade obviously played an important role for British industry from the middle of the 18th century. But also domestic trade grew and may be regarded as exogenous in relationship to specific industries like textiles and particularly the cotton industry. While it would be pointless to refer to trade or demand in general as a prime mover of industry, since demand originates in production and income, it is certainly not pointless to do the same in relation to external trade for the industry of a particular country as a whole or in relation to domestic trade for specific domestic industries.

Already before the middle of the 18th century British industry and trade had grown considerably since the end of the 17th century. According to the estimates of Gregory King there were in 1688 110,000 families engaged in industry and trade. If we add to this a probably too large part, say 1/3 of King’s 364,000 “labouring people and servants” we get a total of about 230,000 families. In 1760 Joseph Massie made a more detailed breakdown of the occupational structure of England according to which there were about 480,000 families engaged in trade and industry (exclusive of 220,000 “labour-ers”). Thus while total population may have increased by probably no more than 20 per cent, that part of it that was engaged in industry and trade may have doubled. While King registered 50,000 merchants and traders, Massie registered 175,000. While according to King there were 60,000 “artisans and handicrafts”, Massie held that there were more than 300,000 “manufacturers” of different kinds. Although the figures of course are unreliable and difficult

76

Bo Gustafsson

to interpret they lend credence to the qualitative evidence we have according to which trade and industry had started to grow quicker than before already in the first half of the 18th century (calculations based upon P. Mathias, 1957). It was on this basis that the putting-out system started to develop rapidly from the middle of the 18th century, especially in the textile trade.

Of similar importance for the conditions of the domestic producers and the supply of free labour-power were the concentration of land holding and the dissolution of the commons during the course of the 18th century. Even if the extent and consequences of the enclosures have been disputed it seems fair to assume that the concentration of land holding and the dissolution of the commons had considerable consequences. In the first place, many domestic producers would have been more dependent upon non-agricultural pursuits, i.e. industry. Secondly, the dissolution of the commons had the same conse-quences and even took away an important source of subsistence for cottagers and squatters, especially the women, while transforming parts of the popu-lation to proletarians (J.L. and B. Hammond, The Village Labourer, p. 98ff.; Pinchbeck, p. 44 and 53; Bowden, p. 218, 244, 223, 234 and 240–41; Man-toux, p. 170 and 183–84; Moffit, p. 62, 110–111 and 125). Nothing is more revealing of these aspects of the enclosures than the re-evaluation of their effects made by Arthur Young in 1801, saying that “by nineteen enclosure acts out of twenty, the poor are injured, and, in some grossly injured. The poor in these parishes may say, and with truth, ‘Parliament may be tender of property, all I know is, I had a cow, and an act of parliament has taken it from me’” (Quoted by Bowden, p. 223). Mantoux (p. 183–84 ) sums up the tendency:

The changes in the conditions of rural life had still more direct influence on the progress of industry. We know that one of the characteristic features of the domestic system of manufacture was the scattering of workshops in the villa-ges, the very basis of that system consisting of small holdings. We have noticed how a weaver would eke out his earnings with the product of a plot of ground, and how a rural family would in the evening spin wool for the merchant manu-facturer. The blow dealt to peasant property broke that time-honoured alliance of labour on land and industrial work. The village artisan, when deprived of his field and of his right of common, could not continue to work at home. He was forced to give up whatever independence he still seemed to have retained, and had to accept the wages offered to him in the employer’s workshop. Thus labour was becoming more and more concentrated, even be fore the competi-tion of machinery had finally destroyed the old village industries.

If the fact and the tendency could not be denied, it remains to evaluate the proper role of these structural changes in agriculture for the problem of the transition from domestic industries and putting-out systems to factories.

Even if agricultural improvement may have increased the demand for la-bour, the concentration of land holding and the dissolution of the commons should have increased the supply of labour from marginalized or evicted cottagers and squatters. Bowden, quoting contemporary observers on the

77

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

situation in Lancashire, suggests that agricultural employment decreased in the Granary to one-sixth during the 18th century and that similar conditions may have prevailed in e.g. Staffordshire and the Warwickshire region, “where enclosures seem to have resulted in an unusual amount of unemployment” (Bowden, p. 254f.). On the other hand agricultural labour flowed into the manu facturing districts. A Bolton cotton spinner, who himself had started out as a textile employee in 1780, told half a century later: “A good many (came) from the agricultural parts; a many from Wales; a many from Ireland and from Scotland. People left other occupations and came to spinning for the sake of the high wages. I recollect shoemakers leaving their employ and learning to spin; I recollect tailors; I recollect colliers; but a great many more husband-man left their employ to learn to spin” (quoted by Bowden, p. 218–19). It also seems quite clear that the wages of industrial labour — although not nec-essarily factory labour — were higher than agricultural wages and acted as a magnet on employment-seeking labour power (Bowden, p. 257). Also Pollard emphasizes that the progress of manufacturing during the 18th century effect-ed a redistribution of labour from agriculture to industry and particularly to the industrial north (Pollard, 1978, p. 100–105) and that the further shift from domestic industries to factories also led to increased earnings. If this last effect was made possible by an increased productivity per time unit rather than by an extended work week or work year is doubtful. The difficulties of the early factory owners to recruit labour points rather to the second explanation.

While it seems clear that the enclosures and the dissolution of the com-mons on the one hand and the growth of manufacturing on the other hand increased the industrial population, primarily in domestic industries, and thus contributed to the creation of a potential reservoir of free labour for the com-ing factories, other effects are not at all sufficiently investigated and analysed. Prima facie one is inclined to think that the supply of labour power should have been more elastic than earlier, ceteris paribus leading to an increased surplus for the employers from the mobilized labour power without any kind of (substantial) landholding as an alternative employment opportunity. The following diagram may capture this contrast illustrating the static surplus ef-fect of the employment decision of a capitalist, in A of a putter-out confronted by land-holding domestic producers and in B of a factory owner hiring free labour (S = supply of labour power, W = wage rate, MPL = marginal product of labour (= capitalists demand schedule for labour power) and Ld = employ-ment of labour power):

78

Bo Gustafsson

Surplus generation in putting-out industries and in factories emanating from different elasticities of supply of labour power

Per se an increased elasticity of the supply of labour on the part of free and mobile labour would, thus, ceteris paribus, increase employment and surplus for the employing factory owner compared to the situation for a putter-out. So far the creation of free labour is a possible candidate among causes for the transition from domestic industries and putting-out systems to factories. Since, however, we also meet with domestic producers without means of production (S.J. Chapman, 1904, p. 10f. and G.H. Tupling, 1927, p. 189) it is doubtful if this circumstance — alone — can further our understanding of the transition to the factories. It occurred that free labour rented a cottage with a plot and thus was in no better position than factory labour, perhaps in a worse position, since it may have been easier for factory labour to terminate the employment contract. (Unfortunately we know very little about contracts of employment in this period apart from the fact that we can read about some factory own-ers trying to tie labour to long-time employment contracts (R.S. Fitton – A.P. Wadsworth, p. 233). It is also difficult to believe that wage rates — at least ef-ficiency wages — were higher in putting-out industries than in factories, since so much evidence points in the opposite direction and since the tenacity of the putting-out system may have been due precisely to low wages made possible by the alternative income provided by agricultural pursuits (see above). In this connection Bowden has made a very interesting observation, which should rather lead us to believe that the factories emerged as a salvation for labour. I offer it for what it is worth:

When mechanical methods and factory organization began to encroach upon the older forms of industry, a large proportion of English laborers were pri-marily dependent upon agricultural employments and secondarily dependent upon manufacturing for subsistence. This two-fold dependent forms the back-ground of one of the major tragedies in English history. The workers were

MPLf

MPLd

A B

MPLd1 MPLf1

Wd Wf

W*d

W*f

L*f L*d

Surplus

Surplus

Sd

Ld

Sf

Lf

79

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

denied a subsistence wage by farmers and landlords, because their families were expected to eke out a subsistence by spinning or some other form of in-dustrial employment. They were denied a subsistence wage as industrial wor-kers, because they were expected to depend primarily upon agriculture. Wages, which historically by law and by custom, were at the time of the origin of the factory system being rapidly forced farther and farther below the subsistence level —indeed, in many cases cut off entirely — by the jealous competition of the two sets of employers, agrarian and industrial, in reducing wages; by the upward trend of prices; and by the agricultural processes of enclosing and en-grossing…. (Bowden, p. 252–53).

It is difficult to know the empirical value of this observation. While it does not apply to the experience of certain parts of domestic producers in the late 18th century, e.g. hand-loom weavers in the last quarter of the century when the tremendous rise in output from spinning increased the demand for weaving, it may still have some general relevance. If it is true it implies that irrespec-tive of whether domestic producers had alternatives or not, the position of the employers was so strong that agriculture and industry, respectively, could not be used as an alternative by the domestic producers. This could be the case, if the situation in the labour market was characterized by a general surplus of labour power making it easy for employers to hire labour and depress wages.

To what extent did the quickened pace of population growth during the 18th century contribute to this? That there was a marked increase of population from the middle of the 18th century is quite certain and it may well be that the rate of growth of population doubled (R.D. Lee and R.S. Schofield, p. 17ff.). As a consequence the age structure of the population underwent a dramatic change leading to a substantial increase of children and young people. The main cause of the increased rate of growth of population was probably the increased birth rate, in its turn caused by an increased frequency of marriages and by marriages at an earlier age. Why? Because of an increased demand for labour, making family formation easier and more rewarding. If these obser-vations are true the increase in population (and in labour participation rates) was mainly an effect of industrialization and economic growth (Pollard 1978, p. 105). Hence, it is difficult to imagine that the increased supply of labour and the rise of a proletarian factory population, making factory production more profitable than before, could have been caused by an exogenously determined rise of population and labour. Also here the earlier observation is relevant, viz., that the demographic revolution starts already during the expansionary period of domestic industries and the putting-out system and is not specifically associated with the transition to the factory system.

From this we may conclude that while the agricultural and the demograph-ic revolutions of the 18th century are important for creating the labour supply necessary for the industrial revolution and the rise of the factory system of the late 18th century, these revolutions were mainly induced by the higher rate of growth generally and the higher rate of growth of industry in particular. This

80

Bo Gustafsson

conclusion also agrees with the generally acknowledged fact that population movements regionally as well as labour migrations were called forth by in-dustrialization and expectations of higher incomes. The industrialization, as well as the transition to the factory system, may thus have been conditioned by demand- rather than supply-side factors.

The textile industry in general and the cotton industry in particularly ex-panded vigorously from the middle of the 18th century. The most dynamic growth was experienced by cotton manufacture and trade. This growth is clearly associated with the qualities of cotton products — fustians, calicoes, muslins etc. — which were light to wear and easily washed and hence increas-ingly replaced woollen and linen products. The cotton industry became the first industry producing for a mass market both at home and abroad. To some extent this growth was conditioned by the advent of machine spinning, card-ing and printing and the organization of these processes in factories, which increased productivity and product quality and decreased costs per unit of output. To this extent it was the adoption of the factory system that made increasing trade possible. Nonetheless, demand for cotton products increased well before the coming of the factories, i.e. when the overwhelming part of production was organized and performed by domestic producers, putters-out and merchants.

It is believed that domestic demand was of greater importance than foreign demand up to the 1790’s (Edwards, p. 27), after which foreign demand took the lead (expanding by well over 10 per cent per year in fixed prices). If this is true, domestic demand must have grown very rapidly from the middle of the 18th century, since from this time foreign demand — which at least sym-bolically may be appreciated thanks to figures on exports — suddenly started to grow quickly:

Exports of cotton piece goods 1699–1769

Year Exports (in constant £)1699 13,1381739 14,3241750 19,6671759 109,3581769 211,606

Source: Wadsworth-Mann, p. 146.

Also John Kennedy relates the rise of the cotton industry to increasing demand and widening markets (Kennedy, p. 117), even if his stylized version of the early history of the cotton trade smacks too much of an Adam Smith success story (see above). Aiken, a more reliable source, confirms the im-por tance of demand when dividing the development of the cotton trade into

81

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

four periods: 1) before 1690, 2) 1690–1730, 3) 1730–1770 and 4) after 1770. (According to S.J. Chapman Aiken may have relied upon information from James Ogden.) Aiken writes:

The trade of Manchester may be divided into four periods. The first is that, when the manufacturers worked hard merely for a livelihood, without having accumulated any capital. The second is that, when they had begun to acquire little fortunes, but worked as hard, and lived in a plain manner as before, in-creasing their fortunes as well by economy as by moderate gains. The third is that when luxury began to appear, and trade was pushed by sending out riders for orders to every market town in the kingdom. The fourth is the period in which expense and luxury had made great progress, and was supported by a trade extended by means of riders and factors through every part of Europe (quoted by S.J. Chapman, p. 5).

The story is also in this case stylized. But we may well believe that the role of demand (“luxury” and “expense”) was clearly perceived and we have no reason to doubt the existence of foreign-based factors around 1770.

Pure cotton goods could be manufactured only after Arkwright’s successful application of roller-spinning (water-frames) to warp-spinning and the finer varieties of cotton products appeared only after the invention and application of Crompton’s mule, which made possible the combination of the fine-yarn spinning of the jennies with the strength and evenness of yarn achieved by water-frames. By the middle of the 18th century cotton cloth was a mixture of cotton weft and linen warp and the industry “was well established in parts of Lancashire, Cheshire, Nottinghamshire, Derbyshire, and Scotland, chiefly around Glasgow and Paisly” (Edwards, p. 3). By this time cotton manufacture may also have started to become more complex in organization due to the growth of demand and production. In a much discussed passage Guest in-forms us that in 1740 “the Manchester merchants began to give out warps and raw cotton to the weavers, receiving them back in cloth and paying for the carding, roving, spinning and weaving”. Further that about 1750 there arose, chiefly in the country districts, a class of “second-rate merchants called fustian-masters”, who “gave out a warp and raw cotton to the weaver, paying the weaver for the weaving and the spinning” (Guest, Compendious history of the cotton manufacture (1823), p. 10). Even if we should not believe that the putting-out organization did not exist before 1740 in the Manchester cotton trade, there is reason to believe that the system started to develop vigorously around the 1750’s. By then fustian weavers “were certainly the work-people of capitalist employers, as probably many of them were long before that time” (Daniels, p. 39).

Domestic industries and putting-out systems were put under pressure from the rapidly rising demand. Kay’s flying shuttle, which upset the balance between spinning and weaving, had by the 1750’s increased the productivity of the weavers, causing the demand for and the price of cotton yarn to rise.

82

Bo Gustafsson

Solutions to this yarn problem were supplied by the successive inventions in the spinning of yarn provided by Hargreave’s spinning jenny, patented in 1770 and developing from the original sixteen spindles to eighty spindles by the middle of the 1780’s; Arkwright’s water-frame patented in 1769, driven by water power and because of its dimensions utilized in factory buildings, thus making the first large-scale inroads on the domestic structure of the industry; Arkwright’s carding engine patented in 1775, placed in rudimentary factories and thus challenging domestic industry; and Crompton’s mule, gradually introduced during the 1780’s. By this time “the larger jennies and carding engines were moving into workshops, while the water-frame required artificial power, and was housed in ‘factories’” (Edwards, p. 5). But since much jenny-spinning as well as mule-spinning was still performed by domestic producers, the expansion of spinning and even of factory spinning and, particularly, of weaving, also implied a vigorous growth of domestic industries. Until at least the 1790’s the mule remained in the cottage. But at that time a centralization of mule spinning started to appear in two forms. First spinners were gathered to work hand mules in sheds, especially around Manchester. Secondly the mule was harnessed to water power and as a result “the mules were removed from the cottages to factories, were constructed more substantially and upon better mechanical principles and produced yarn of a more uniform quality and at less expense” (Kennedy, p. 129). Mule spinning early also adopted steam as source of power; in 1812 two-thirds of the steam engines then in existence turned mules (Smelser, p. 122). But first after the invention of Robert’s self-acting mule, patented in 1825, did mule spinning become essentially mechanized. And the mechanization of weaving through the power-loom followed close in suit. Also the power-loom factories were preceded by hand-loom factories, the first probably erected by Samuel Oldknow in the 1780’s. In 1833 six hand-loom-factories were reported to exist in Manchester, some with more than two hundred looms (Smelser, p. 142).

Summing this up it seems fairly clear that the transition from domestic industries and putting-out systems to factories not only was a rather drawn-out affair, but also that it took place in an environment of strongly rising demand, originating already well before the transition to factories and putting the or-ganization of the industry under heavy strains. It became imperative to raise the output of the spinners. Was this possible by simply extending domestic industry? Was an extension of domestic industry and putting-out compatible with the demand for increased or at least not decreased productivity? To an-swer these questions we have to study the operation of domestic industry and the putting-out system under the new conditions. It is not enough to just single out growing demand as such as a condition for the rise of the factory system (E. Gilboy, 1932), since domestic industries and putting-out systems earlier had grown pari-passu with increasing demand and widening markets.

83

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

V. The Structure of Domestic Industries and the Putting-out SystemDomestic industries had arisen and expanded for centuries but particularly since the end of the 17th century because of two fundamental conditions. On the one hand the restrictive practices of the city-based organized industries (guilds etc.), which pushed manufacturing activities to the countryside. On the other hand the secularly expanding domestic and foreign markets. Domestic industries arose as side-line activities in agriculture and other primary sec-tors mainly in regions where, on the one hand, expanding population caused diminishing returns in primary production and, on the other hand, where in-creasing returns made a division of labour between agriculture and industry possible. In the first case domestic industries served to preserve subsistence standards. In the second case domestic industries served to increase the level of real income.

The putting-out system arose more or less pari-passu with domestic indus-tries and particularly in those domestic industries where demand expanded beyond local markets or where the raw materials were expensive compared to the resources of the domestic producers. When demand expanded and the scale of production was extended, several effects ensued. In the first place the domestic producer encountered difficulties in financing the purchase of raw materials. Secondly he/she had to wait a longer time before the proceeds from the sale of the products (the realization) had returned and he needed funds to finance the waiting. Thirdly, the domestic producer lost the overview over the market and it was costly for him/her to acquire the information on demand patterns and prices and their change. If the domestic producer was of some substance he might solve these problems by expanding into becoming a mer-chant-manufacturer. But in most cases he/she became dependent upon one or several merchants, who put raw materials and money at his disposal from the starting-point of the process of production up to the realization of the products and who also marketed the final output.

Thus nascent capitalist relations of production arose and developed in domestic industries. The domestic producer more and more lost control of parts of the means of production (mainly raw materials, but increasingly and especially in cotton manufacture also other means of production). Further he/she became dependent upon merchants or agents of merchants as to borrowing of money so that debt-interest relationships arose between merchants and do-mestic producers. Thus domestic industries under the putting-out system were shot through by credit-debt relationships. (See e.g. Tupling, p. 174ff.)

While the loss of ownership to parts of the means of production and the dependence upon merchants and putters-out for credit gave merchant capital a certain measure of control over the domestic producers, the latter were not wholly at the mercy of merchants and putters-out. The availability of alterna-tive means of employment and income in agriculture, the possession of the

84

Bo Gustafsson

means of labour (in contradistinction to the objects of labour) and the control over his/her labour utilization and the process of production — to the extent this control had not been more or less lost due to monopsonistic contracts and/or closely prescribed and enforced product quotas and patterns — gave the do-mestic producers some bargaining power vis-à-vis merchants and putters-out. The domestic producer was not, like the factory worker, forced to work under the direct command of the capitalist and the merchant could not usually prevent the domestic producers from also working for other employers if there were any. If the merchant or putter-out was a monopsonist the domestic producer, on the other hand, was probably in a worse situation than the factory worker, since he was dependent upon his cottage and his plot for subsidiary income. (For general surveys of domestic industries and putting-out system, see Lip-son, Heaton, Ashton, Moffat, James, Smelser, Wadsworth-Mann, Pinch beck, Unwin, Smelser, Fitton, Rule, Styles, Tupling, Hudson, Pollard, Berg.)

Let us take a closer look at how domestic industries and putting-out systems were structured and behaved in different aspects and their merits and demerits for the respective agents. Since there were large variations between different industries and at different points of time the resulting picture has to emphasize the fundamental anatomy of the system. Since many of the descriptions seem to have been made from the vantage point of the victorious factory system there is probably an in-built bias in the sources.

The unit of production was the household with some division of labour between the members of the household: spinning and other preparatory pro-cesses performed by women and children, weaving by men. The capacity to produce was limited by the labour force of the family. It could be extended by the household by engaging members of other households or, if the employer took the initiative, by engaging new domestic producers. Since the domestic producers were attached to the land, an extension of production at constant productivity necessarily implied that production was extended spatially with consequential increases in the carrying and fetching of raw materials and final output.

1. Even if the working-day of the domestic producers was amorphous and self-exploitation occurred, the existence of agricultural side-line oc cupa tions as well as work-habits put limits to the utilization of labour. The most charac-teristic trait of labour utilization in domestic industries was the irregularity of employment over the week as well as the year. In fact, when the first factories were established, factory owners emphasized in their advertisements for la-bour power that employment was continuous (Chapman, 1967, p. 163). On the one hand labour was under-utilized because of the undeveloped markets for output. Market demand fluctuated and to safeguard themselves against this putters-out hoarded labour:

... the normal condition of most domestic producers was one of under-employment. Each master manufacturer liked to have at his disposal a number

85

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

of workers in excess of his need in ordinary times so that in periods of brisk demand he would not be hampered by shortage of labour. The possibility of working on their own scraps of land, of obtaining jobs on the farms and (in the case of women spinners) of falling back on the earnings of other members of the household, led the workers to acquiesce in the arrangement. Hence there existed at many points of the economy a pool of labour similar to that at the docks in our own day. More men and women were attached to each industry than could normally find full-time employment in it: the surplus of labour to which many writers called attention at various times was made up less of men permanently out of work than of those whose hold on employment was preca-rious. (Ashton, p. 203.)

With reference to the complaints of the small-ware weavers of Lancashire in 1756 of an oversupply of labour in their trades, John Rule remarks that underemployment rather than redundancy was the rule:

In order to keep contact with their weavers so as to be ready to expand pro-duction quickly when the market changed, masters preferred to spread what work was available rather than keep a small number fully employed. (Rule, p. 49–50.)

At the same time (according to those weavers) there was a seasonally con-ditioned mechanism leading to an over-supply of labour in the winter. During the summer the weavers engaged in agricultural pursuits. The masters then had to replace the missing labour power if possible with new workers. When the weavers returned in the autumn they had “to work at the looms upon any terms they could get” (ibidem). These side-line activities of the domestic producers seem to have reduced the availability of labour during summer drastically in the normal case. In a memoir of a worsted manufacturer of West Riding referring to conditions in the last quarter of the 18th century (Henry Hall, Esq. Leeds), this manufacturer writes:

In this manufacture, it was difficult to regulate employment of the weavers by the supply of yarn, the spinning being in a great measure done in the winter in the farming districts, there being out-door work for the families in the summer. I have known our stock of yarn so low in summer, that weavers have sometimes had to wait a few days for yarn. This evil was partly met by some of them going annually to the harvest in the low country, a work now performed by the Irish. The manufacturers of the present day can form no conception of the labours of their predecessors. The old manufacture was necessarily restricted, and an increased demand could not be met by a proportionate increased supply. (James, p. 312.)

According to Lipson “in the West Country it was not unknown for a weav-er to be unemployed seventeen weeks altogether” (Lipson, p. 59). Rule sum-marizes this problem of labour utilization thus:

86

Bo Gustafsson

Workers of all kinds went into the fields for the harvest. Harvest was not then accomplished in a matter of days with a combine harvester. Striking evidence survives in the letters of a west-country clothier of the time lost to manufacturing every year, as he apologized to disappointed customers for his inability to keep up supplies. By mid-June the hay harvest was underway and after it there was only a brief interlude before the corn needed gathering in mid-August. In a late and difficult year that might not end before October at which time in the West Country the apple harvest and the cider-making occupied weavers until the end of the month. The earliest dated letter from him complaining of being deserted by his employees is 15 June; the latest 26 October. For around one-third of the year he was reduced accordingly to a low level of production. (Rule, p.16.)

If, as was the case particularly in cotton manufacture, markets and de-mand rose strongly during the second half of the 18th century, the problem of labour utilization must have increased. It furnished the capitalists with a strong incentive to increase their control over labour and labour time. To begin with they may have resorted to the earlier mentioned method of supplying out-workers not only with raw materials but also with a rented cottage with a land plot attached thereby monopolizing the labour power. But sooner or later it must have paid to centralize the labour power in workshops and factories in order to be able to control the very labour process. If this observation is correct it lends support to Marx’s view of the transition to the factory system, according to which the first phase did not change technology but only the control and continuity of labour:

In der Productionsweise selbst findet hier noch keinen Unterschied statt. Der Arbeitsprozess — technologisch betrachtet — geht gerade vor sich wie früher, nur als jetzt dem Capital untergeordneter Arbeitsprozess. Es entwickelt sich jedoch im Productionsprozess selbst, wie früher entwickelt worden ist, erstens ein Verhältnis der Ueber- und Unterordning, indem der Consum des Arbeitsvermögens vom Capitalisten geschieht, daher von ihm überwacht und dirigiert wird: zweitens es entwickelt sich grössere Contiunität der Arbeit. (Marx, p. 2130–31.)

This formal subsumtion of labour under capital with the production of absolu-te surplus value as the dominant form is later replaced by the real subsumtion of labour under capital based on primarily the production of relative surplus value conditioned by the general introduction of machines and continuously working power machines.

At that later stage of the introduction of the factory system the mechanism suggested by Ure (Philosophy of Manufacture, p. 321–24) and developed by Lazonick, viz. that work effort, productivity, earnings and profits became pos-itively correlated, started to work, wiping out domestic industries to a large extent and changing the behaviour of labour as to work effort in response to increased earnings. But earlier, when the productivity of labour was constant or only changed slowly, workers did not “by nature wish to earn more and

87

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

more money but simply to live as [they were] accustomed to live and to earn as much as is necessary for that purpose” (Weber, p. 159).

This brings us to the third aspect of labour utilization under the putting-out system, the backward-sloping supply curve for labour, i.e. that rising wage rates normally led to reduced labour supply. This behaviour of domestic producers and wage earners generally led to that “economy of low wages” described by Heckscher. The testimonies on this mechanism are so many and come from so many different observers that we cannot doubt its reality. William Hutton, who had himself worked as a framework knitter, held in 1781 that manufactures tended to decline because of high real incomes and that “a man who could support his family with three days’ labour would not work six” (Rule, p. 53). Peter Mathias’ objection that employers did not reduce wages when they wanted to increase labour supply is of course irrelevant, since the saticficing behaviour of domestic producers as to wages implied that they maximized leisure. Employers certainly wanted to increase labour supply by reducing wages when the demand for final output was rising. But to succeed in this strategy they would have been obliged to act as a monopsonis-tic cartel. Since this was not possible, some employers offered higher wages, which made it possible for workers to increase leisure. The only thing that could counter-act the wage/labour supply trade-off was a rising cost-of-living. This was the reason why the master manufacturers of Manchester, as noted by Arthur Young, hoped most of all for high prices (Rule, p. 53).

Since textile industries in general and the cotton industry in particular ex-panded during the second part of the 18th century one may assume that the trend of wages generally tended upwards. Wages, at least, tended to rise in the northern districts. “The annual (300 days) £15 for 1750 becoming in the north £22 10s by 1775, while in the west £17 10s became £18. For London £30 remained constant from 1750 to 1790” (Rule p. 68–69). Also Ashton notes the rapidly rising wages in the northern textile areas (Rule as well as Ashton rely on Gilboy):

Day rates for unskilled labour in England 1700–1790

Year Lancaster Oxford London

1700 8d 14d 20d

1750 12d 14d 24d

1790 20d 16d 24d

Source: Ashton, p. 232.

Thus, while day rates were practically constant in southern England they increased by 2/3 in Lancaster from 1750 to 1790. Real wages certainly did not parallel this rise, since the trend of prices was also upward. But at least at particular periods particular sections of domestic producers experienced

88

Bo Gustafsson

considerably rising real incomes as e.g. those proverbial weavers of Radcliffe, “the men with each a watch in his pocket, and the women dressed to their own fancy” (Radcliffe p. 67). If we may assume some upward trend of real wages before 1790 it should have resulted in a tendency towards a reduced or at least not markedly increasing labour supply matching the secularly rising demand for cotton and other textile products.

Lastly labour supply during the work-week was less than what might have been possible in domestic industries and certainly less than in the factories to be established. The practice of the short week was, according to Ashton, “almost universal”. A writer remarked in 1752 that the great problem was not one of general idleness but that people worked “but half their time”. Another commentator asserted that few of the working people in Manchester were regularly employed more than two-thirds of the week (Ashton, p. 204). There does not exist, of course, any comprehensive information about the length of the working-day in domestic industries. Maybe it averaged about 12 hours a day over the year, being considerably longer in spring and early autumn than in the winter (Rule, p. 60ff.). But during the week it varied more. After a “blue Monday” it started in a hectic tempo and lasted for five days, the tempo of work declining or collapsing towards the end of the week. The course of the work-week of the domestic producers is somewhat reminiscent of the work-month in Soviet industry although inverted (the “sturmovshina” at the end of the month in order to fulfill the monthly plan). Whatever the reason was for this lay-out of the working-week, it hardly was beneficial for product quality or for the long-run intensity of work.

Summing up these observations we may conclude that the supply of effort under the putting-out system was characterized by a low elasticity in response to demand for labour and also that the overall supply of labour was less than it would have been, if the workers had devoted themselves full-time to industrial work and under the direct control of the capitalist employer. Rule has made some comparisons with the supply of labour in the factories. If the average working-week in domestic industries was gross 72 hours (net 66 hours), it was 84–96 hours gross (78–90 net) in the factories up to the early 19th century. According to these estimates workers in the factories worked about 20 per cent more per week than domestic workers on the average (Rule, p. 60–61). According to estimates by Freudenberg and Cummins the average working week should have increased from about 58 hours by 1750 to perhaps 72 hours for factory workers in the early 19th century. This calculation has, however, been disputed by Bienefeld, who suggests that the main difference between domestic workers and factory workers was that the former worked 5 days and the latter 6 days per week indicating an increase from 50 to 60 hours per week at a ten hour day. If this is true, the introduction of factories should have increased the supply of effort per week by about 20 per cent and per year by probably more, taking the decreased labour supply in the domestic industries during summer into account (Tranter, p. 220). This estimate concurs with that

89

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

of Rule although for a different reason (extension of the working week rather than the working day).1

2. Turning from the supply of labour to the quality of the products pro-duced in domestic industries, the recurring theme in the sources is that factory spinning and weaving resulted in a product of higher and more even quality, especially in the production of cotton articles for mass consumption. This ob-servation applies to weaving as well as to spinning and to woollen and worsted as well as to the cotton industries. When the power-loom was introduced “it not only worked faster than the hand-loom ... but also produced a more even texture, because of the uniform strength of the blows administered mechani-cally to the shuttle, a uniformity which no human agent could hope to rival” (Chapman, 1904, p. 27). According to Radcliffe power-loom cloth became so popular because of its evenness that fabrics made by hand were stamped “power-loom” by dishonest manufacturers (Radcliffe, p. 54). Of course, for very fine cloth hand-loom weaving remained superior, at least until the middle of the 19th century. In the memoir by Henry Hall, quoted earlier, and referring to conditions in worsted manufacture in the last quarter of the 18th century it is stated:

The hand yarn manufacture ... was an anxious and laborious occupation, re-quiring the eyes and hands of the master in its several processes. The spin-ning was performed in cottage houses by the wife and children, partly in the neighborhood, and partly in distant parts of the West-Riding, in which case we employed agents, mostly shop-keepers. On these you could not depend for em-ploying only good hands: they would not offend a shop-customer by refusing her work ... and in sorting our yarns, we not only met with whole hanks clum-sily spun, but, not seldom, good and bad reeled in the same hank. This rendered the sorting of yarns a vexatious process. (James, p. 311–12.)

Lipson emphasizes this problem, too:

Hand-spinning had one serious defect. The spinner often lacked the requisite technical skill; the yarn was therefore neither uniform in quality, not firm enough to stand the strain of the loom, and the cloth, as a result, was uneven in texture. The Suffolk clothiers drew attention to this evil as early as 1575: “The custom of our country is to carry our wool out to carding and spinning and put it to divers and sundry spinners who have in their houses divers and sundry children and servants that do card upon new cards, and some upon old cards, and some spin hard and some soft, by reason whereof our cloth falleth out in some places broad and some narrow, contrary to our mind and greatly to our disprofit.” There were sometimes as many as ten hands engaged on one chain, and as it was spun very irregularly the thread was always breaking: a considerable portion of the weaver’s time, in fact, was spent in repairing broken threads. To remedy this it was proposed to establish spinning schools

1 Fitton and Wadsworth found that the percentage time lost during a 21 week period in the first half of 1787 was 9.6 per cent for “home workmen”, while it was 19.2 per cent for “Out workmen” in the Strutts factories. I assume that “home workmen” were employed at the mill, while out workmen were domestic workers. (Fitton-Wadsworth, p. 239.).

90

Bo Gustafsson

where children could be taught the art of spinning by experienced teachers. (Lipson, p. 64–65.)

In the early 1780’s, before the introduction of machine-spinning in Scot-land, the directors of the Chamber of Commerce in Glasgow drew up a fairly complete list of spinning faults they met with: “slack twine, ill thum’d and dry spun, hard twine, thumb knots, different colors in the same hank, slip ekes, coarse pieces, roaney, or having the shows or straw adhering, spun beyond the grist and hairy, check spales, lumpy, low spun etc.” (In G. Stewart, Progress of Glasgow, 1883, quoted by Smelser, p. 65, note 4.) Pinchbeck sums up:

Hand spinning was by no means satisfactory from the manufacturer’s point of view. In an occupation which was considered suitable for all classes, and for the young and aged alike, it is evident that the degree of skill must have varied considerably. Moreover, the yarn produced by a single household was often the work of six or eight different spinners, including servants and children, some of whom would spin “hard” and some “soft”, with the result that when the thread was all put together and woven inequalities in the cloth were only too apparent. The coarseness of much of the yarn spun was another disadvantage, although skilled spinners, some of whom still preferred to use the distaff, could produce an astonishingly fine thread by hand labour. (Pinchbeck, p. 130.)

The products turned out by domestic industry thus were not only inelastic in supply because of an inelastic supply of labour time and of effort but also uneven in quality and limited as to product differentiation (mainly coarse qualities). This unevenness of quality was conditioned by the fact that the ultimate employer did not control the selection of labour power utilized nor the quality of the means of production. Labour power was “self-owned” and consisted of mainly the members of the family with widely differing strengths and skills, and also the means of labour were usually owned and controlled by the domestic producers themselves. The consequences of this were that there were considerable costs in controlling the quality of products and in sorting out qualities of differing grades.

To some extent the ultimate employer — a merchant or a merchant-manufacturer — could handle this problem, partly by specifying qualities in ordering or by the selection of domestic producers employed and partly by himself taking care of some processes of production, mainly finishing, in his own premises. Unfortunately it seems as if no written contracts, if such existed, have been preserved and whether these contracts contained stipulations as to quality and penalties for contract obligations not fulfilled is unknown. We only know that domestic producers frequently complained of “deductions” made by merchants and putters-out for deficiencies in products delivered. Still, control of quality was costly and, in the case of yarn spun on hanks, in practice impossible. Only when yarn was used by the weaver could the ultimate test be made.

91

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

As long as demand for final output was relatively constant or only rising slowly the quality problem may have been manageable. But when markets started to expand rapidly during the latter half of the 18th century it should have been intensified. The number of out-workers employed increased sub-stantially. Pollard gives examples of putters-out with 300–4000 out-workers employed (Pollard, 1965, p. 45). When the putting-out organization expand-ed, any single domestic household responding to the increased demand had to utilize more members of the family and even members of neighbouring households. Further, the number of households engaged also increased. It is reasonable to assume that the merchants and putters-out, when demand was restricted, had tried to engage households that were most productive and produced the best products from a quality point of view. When demand and production expanded they had to resort to domestic producers who were less productive and less capable of producing high-quality goods. This would have meant that the proportion of low-quality goods increased with increas-ing demand and production and also that the quality variations increased. At the other end of the scale — the market for final output — the demands for an even quality of products increased, partly because of increasing competition (particularly in the yarn market, where supply increased disproportionately to the cloth-market, still hampered by the hand-loom weaving technology) and partly because of the increased importance (absolutely and after 1790 also relatively) of foreign markets. At the same time product differentiation increased, particularly after the introduction of mule-spinning after 1790, and the composition of the output-mix was increasingly dictated by the market and communicated to manufacturers by their agents (Edwards, p. 157). Thus the new situation arising after the 1750’s should have made the problem of quality control of final output and, hence, of labour and means of production, more acute than before.

3. The third characteristic of domestic industries was that a very large part of the process of production consisted in transporting the product in its various stages. Also on this aspect authors of different ages and different views con-cur. Ashton describes the general problem:

It was obviously impossible for the merchant clothier, hosier, or ironmonger to have direct contact with all who worked for him. Intermediaries were necessary [who] ... received a commission on each piece ... delivered … But most large merchant manufactures employed persons to travel from place to place to give out materials, collect finished work, and pay wages, not at the cottage door but at depots set up in various parts of their industrial province. Often the putter-out was a man in an entirely different occupation ... Generally the worker had to do his own fetching and carrying, to and from whether a local warehouse or the headquarters of the clothier or merchant ... The distances covered were often as great as most men would care to traverse in a day. The weavers of Farnworth had to tramp eight miles to Manchester and back again: those of Gridleton made each week a ten-mile journey to Barnoldswick. In other domestic industries it was the same ... As in most underdeveloped countries today, a large part of

92

Bo Gustafsson

the energies of poor men and women was given to transport. It is said that in the hosiery trade of the east Midlands as much as two and a half days a week might be taken up in getting orders and material, returning finished work, and collecting wages. (Ashton p. 101–102.)

Also other authors lay great stress on this aspect (James, p. 323–325; Lipson, p. 178; Pinchbeck, p. 123 and 137; Smelser, P. 66; Hudson, p. 9–13).

The many and interconnected transports of products under the putting-out system, conditioned by the fact that the direct producers were independent and spatially distributed according to the location of their small holdings, not only made the system vulnerable for stoppages at any point in the chain, causing delays and a wastage of time in both production and marketing. The problems must have increased with an increased scale of production multiplying the number and length of transactions — carrying and fetching — in the organi-zation. Just the effect of increased distances of transport must have increased transport costs. But since the number of domestic producers and middlemen also increased, search costs, bargaining costs and enforcement costs must have increased as well.

4. Fourthly the putting-out system was characterized by the fact that it demanded large capital outlays for stocks of raw material, goods in process, finished goods and customers’ debts. This followed from the organization of production with a large number of scattered producers. Its effect was a slow turn-over of capital invested. According to Pollard the sums of capital employed “were large by any standards and very much larger than anything employed in the early ‘factory’ industry in fixed equipment”. The complex or-ganization sometimes tied up capital from £40,000 up to £100,000 or 200,000 (Pollard, 1965, p. 44). Chapman gives an example of a Leicester firm of hosiers, Coltman & Gardiner, existing between 1766 and 1808. The number of stocking-frames of this firm of average size increased from about ten in 1783 to almost fifty by 1800. The total capital employed by the firm increased from about £5,000 in 1783 to £10,000 in 1800. For the whole of this period circulat-ing capital made up 80–86 per cent of total capital and customers’ debts alone made up 50 per cent or more of total capital (Chapman, 1967, p. 25–26). It was not until the fully mechanized factories were established after the 1820’s that fixed capital started to play a more important role compared to circulating capital, even if fixed capital increased both absolutely and relatively from the very beginning of the factory system (Hudson, p. 6). But if we compare the first factories with a “pure” putting-out organization (usually combined), it is clear that the putting-out organization was very capital-intensive both from the point of view of the merchant/putter-out (circulation capital) and from the point of view of the combined domestic producers (fixed capital). In the latter case the fixed capital engaged became substantial because each domestic pro-ducer needed independent equipment (cottage, land plot) for production; the absence of far-reaching specialization and division of labour also increased

93

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

total outlays for raw material and also increased wastage. Summing up this aspect of the putting-out system, we might say that the spatially widespread nature of the system, the absence of far-reaching specialization of tasks and the slow speed of through-put in the process of production implied that it was strongly capital-intensive compared even to the first primitive factories, which by means of centralization of labour, raw materials, buildings and equipment could lower the capital-output ratio and increase profit rates.

5. The four aspects of the putting-out system treated above — mainly from the point of view of the demise of the putting-out system and the rise of the factories with reference to the rapidly rising demand for textile products after the 1750’s — its inelastic supply of labour (days and/or intensity of labour) and of output, the great dispersion in skills and quality of output, the large amount of transporting in the process of production and its capital-intensive character are of course not only of a technical-organizational nature, but are also aspects of the relations of production of the putting-out system. These, however, also include other aspects related to the relation of property and the behaviour and interaction of the actors involved. The putting-out system once arose, as emphasized, as a super-structure on domestic industries because of the expansion of markets and the ensuing difficulties of domestic producers to finance the increased waiting between the starting point of the process of production and the realization of the products, as well as of the increased difficulties of the domestic producers to have access to the necessary infor-mation about these expanding markets. These circumstances gave merchants and merchant capital a strategic role as initiators, financiers and marketing agents of the putting-out system. It was from these functions that the employ-er function and control function of merchant capital arose. When merchants and putters-out started to take control over parts of the means of production, capitalist relations of production were also introduced into the system. In so far as merchants or putters-out lent domestic producers money for buying raw materials or for financing subsistence during the process of production and the process of realization of the products, there was also a creditor-debtor relationship between merchants/putters out and domestic producers and the former charged an interest. This specific debtor-creditor relationship was very marked in the Midlands’ hosiery industry, where the hosiers owned and rented the knitting-frames to the domestic producers charging quite substantial rents. These rents were deducted in the settlement of wages, irrespective of the price of final output or whether the frame was employed or not, or even whether the hosier owned the frame or not (Felkin, p. 454ff and Chambers, p. 133). The subletting of frames by middlemen increased rents and it is believed that the vested interests of frame-owners and middlemen in this renting system is one of the causes for the delay of the factory system in the framework knit-ting industry (Chambers, ibidem). Since merchants and putters-out usually owned raw materials and paid domestic producers a piece-rate wage for work performed, the capitalist relationship between employer and direct producer

94

Bo Gustafsson

was emphasized. Still this “wage” was not yet as clearly demarcated as in the coming factory system, where the employer had monopolized all requisites of production, including the premises and means of labour of production, and only bought the labour power. The merchant or putter-out strictly speaking did not buy the labour power of the domestic producer but his labour product (not v but v + s in Marxist terminology). Formally speaking, the distribution of the value added (v + s) between merchant and direct producer was indeter-minate and depended upon the relative strength of the two in the bargaining process. The frequency of embezzlements on the part of the direct producers and of deductions and “long pay” (payment of wages one or two month after the delivery of the final product on the part of merchants and putters-out) are signs of this indeterminateness of the distribution of value added between merchants and putters-out on the one hand and direct producers on the other hand. (On embezzlement, deductions and the long pay, see Rule, Styles and Ashton.) On the other hand, it is often emphasized that wage rates remained astonishingly stable over time and of a customary character, which points to a “fixed-wage” world. This once again applies to their appearance, since the wage systems were so varied and so complicated that nobody up to now seems to have penetrated them (Rule, p. 63).

Putting these observations together it is clear that the relationship between direct producers and merchant capital in the putting-out system was very com-plicated and included elements of buyer-seller of commodities, buyer-seller of labour (not labour-power), creditor-debtor of interest-bearing money and of owner-tenant relations. Merchant capital was more or less dominant and was by tradition mainly interested in “profits upon alienation”, i.e. buying cheap and selling dear, which meant that merchants and putters-out tried to press domestic producers to accept the most favourable conditions for mer-chant capital. This fact as indicated above was mirrored in the practices of deductions and long pay and the counter-strategies of domestic producers. Since the domestic producers to a varying extent were independent producers controlling at least their own work-situation and the process of production and, furthermore, were not obliged to enter into a monopsonistic contract with only one employer, they also had some elbow room for asserting their own interests. This fact was expressed in the practice of embezzlement (of raw material, false reeling etc.) and in working for several employers playing these out against each other and causing delays in the deliveries of products. (On embezzlement, see further below.)

6. At the same time the putting-out system may perhaps also be regard-ed as a risk-sharing arrangement similar to share-cropping in agriculture. In share- cropping one party — the landlord — supplies the direct producer — the tenant — with a part of the means of production, e.g. seeds and animals for traction, while the tenant puts in his labour and the product is shared between landlord and tenant. The rationale of this arrangement is probably to share risk in agriculture with strongly fluctuating crops (at least this may be observed

95

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

historically; in addition the direct producers are also generally too poor to afford the financing of necessary investments). What can be observed in the putting-out system is that the merchant or the putter-out minimized their risk, since they only contracted some final output without themselves investing anything but raw materials, at least in the general case. From the point of view of the merchant and with respect to fixed investments, the putting-out system thus was attractive, especially since market demand was strongly fluctuating. If the demand for final output vanished, there were no fixed costs for equip-ment or for labour (food and housing) to be met. For the direct producer this arrangement was possible to accept, since he, in case of vanishing demand, usually had alternative employment on his own plot or in agriculture. But if the direct producer no longer had access to alternative employment, because he had lost his plot or rights to the common, and if the market for final out-put became larger and more permanent, the conditions for this risk-sharing to work disappeared.

7. Above I referred to the phenomenon of embezzlement, which has been widely discussed in connection with the putting-out system. The fact that legislation on embezzlement increased in intensity during the 18th century, while punishments also became more and more harsh, has been taken as evidence for the conclusion that the embezzlement problem also became graver (Pollard, 1965, p.46) and one of the conditions for the transition to the factory system. However, as Styles has pointed out, the increased intensity in legislation can only prove that merchants and manufacturers became more concerned to fight embezzlement. Furthermore the harsher character of the punishments may also mainly have been restricted to the legislation but not applied (Styles, p. 194). Another aspect of the increased concern with the embezzlement problem was the gradual extension of the legislation to new industries (fustian cotton since 1711). The worsted industry furnishes us with the most interesting evidence on the nature and extent of the problem. The two most usual forms of embezzlement was substitution of wool or yarn of higher quality for lower quality — made possible by the fact that spinners and weavers worked for several, often 5–6 employers — and false or short reeling of yarn. “False and short reeling involved the use of a reel of a circumference shorter than the customary standard or the inclusion in each hank of a smaller number of threads than was customary. By these practices spinners were said to be able to conceal frauds involving less work than that paid for, the appropriation of the raw material and the production of yarn inferior in fineness to that demanded. It was claimed to be impractical to check all the hanks for length by unwinding and remeasuring them.” (Styles p. 176.) Rule summarizes other methods of embezzlement:

A Gloucestershire clothier giving evidence in 1774 in support of a campaign for tougher laws instanced various forms of theft and deception to which he was subject. Pickers embezzled one pound in 20 and disguised the lost weight

96

Bo Gustafsson

by throwing the wool on wet stones to impregnate it with water. Scribblers kept back wool and added oil to make up the expected weight. They could take out a pound of Spanish wool worth about 3–4 s in this way. Spinners held yarn over a boiling pot impregnating it with steam — a disguise sufficient to conceal the removal of half-a-pound in every six. Weavers could keep five or six pounds (worth 4–5 s) out of every amount put out for weaving as a 60-pound piece a time, a fraud which was difficult to detect as the wool was delivered wet. The clothiers of Minchinhampton were said in 1784 to have become so weary of the local people that they sent their wool further afield to have it spun. (Rule, p. 132.)

According to calculations concerning embezzlement in Gloucestershire, the total cost of embezzlement in the various stages of manufacturer added up to about 25 per cent (Styles, p. 175) and in the 1770’s the contribution of embezzlement to wage earnings could amount to 20 per cent (Styles, p. 181). There even was a market in embezzled yarn (e.g. among the bagmen of the Midland hosiery industry).

While we cannot take the increased intensity of legislation against embez-zlement as evidence for the conclusion that the problem became more wide-spread or intensified, we cannot doubt the existence and seriousness of the problem, even if embezzlement very well may have been the response of the direct producers against the malpractices of merchants and putters-out, like deductions and delayed payments. We may also note that the existential condi-tion for the problem was the decentralized character of the putting-out system and the lack of control of the employers over their property and the process of production. Hence, when the putting-organizations were extended during the second half of the 19th century, in response to the rapidly growing demand for textile products, embezzlement costs may well have increased pari passu and even in in a rising proportion to production, especially if the propensity or possibilities to embezzle was higher among the newly employed and more distantly located domestic producers. “When the numbers employed were large (and they could amount to several thousands in some putting-out con-cerns) detailed checking for such frauds on redelivery might be prohibitively time consuming and expensive for the employer, who was usually anxious to achieve a rapid turnover.” (Styles, p. 175.)

The putting-out system was successively abandoned from the end of the 18th century and replaced by factories with centralized production. Still it was characterized by a remarkable tenacity far into the 19th century and for a long time was frequently combined with factory production, while parasitic forms — like sweating industries — survived still longer. From the point of view of the direct producers, domestic industry remained a traditional way of life and was not easily discarded with reference only to economic incentives, and these became tangible only when the high-productivity factories of the second quarter of the 19th century could compensate for low and even decreasing wage rates. Domestic industries also offered direct producers tangible advantages

97

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

and they were mainly two: control over the work-situation with possibilities to space labour input over the day or the week according to personal preferences and habits; and the possibility to choose among employers, made easier by having some property in the back when choosing and bargaining.

From the point of view of merchants and putters-out, too, the putting-out system offered advantages: no fixed costs for means of production and labour in periods of disappearing demand and thus low risks for output decisions; possibilities to lower labour remuneration below subsistence costs because of the alternative employment sources of the direct producers and their self-exploitation as a last resort; and few and inefficient combinations of the work-men conditioned by their spatial dispersion.

But these advantages easily turned into disadvantages, when the market conditions of industry radically changed and some disadvantages were inten-sified. For the direct producers the successive lagging productivity of domestic industries relative to the factories became decisive in the very long run. For the employers the disadvantages accumulated still more markedly: the inelastic supply of labour, the variations of labour skill and product quality, the transportation costs, the increase of middlemen dissipating surpluses, the increasing costs of transaction and embezzling, the increasing capital requirements and slow turn-over of capital, the irregularities in the supply of output and the difficulties in introducing and generalizing innovations in processing and products. The essential problems of the domestic mode of production and the putting-out system may very well have been those pointed out by Marx: it put up a barrier toward the utilization and exploitation of labour time and effort and it precluded a sufficient control over production. To discover the essential causal factors in the transition requires first and foremost evidence, since a multitude of explanatory models may be devised, resulting in an over-determination of the solution. The problem is not to give convincing arguments for the demise of the putting-out system. The real problem to explain is why it survived so long in view of its obvious disadvantages.

As will be made clear in the following section the first factories did not arise primarily because of superior technology and/or superior energy sources.

VI. The Rise of the First Factories in the Cotton Industry Marx in “Capital” and the manuscripts preceding this work made an impressive analysis of the necessary and sufficient conditions for the rise of the factory system, in practice = modern industrial capitalism. These consisted in two sets of structural changes in society at large and in industrial development. On the one hand the “primary accumulation” creating a proletariat dispossessed of the means of production and thus forced to sell their labour power; and a

98

Bo Gustafsson

class of capitalists having accumulated money capital on a sufficient scale to be able to invest in modern factory production. On the other hand an increasing division of labour going on inside traditional manufactures creating a class of specialized and de-skilled labourers, whereby the innovation of mechanized machines was made possible; when the number of machines had increased sufficiently much, steam-engines were introduced to supply them with continuous energy on a mass scale. Evidently there is much in this analysis that is backed up by empirical evidence. Domestic producers had to be made free from the ownership of their means of production before they could be transformed into a permanent and reliable class of factory workers. (During the period of transition, when they still had the option to choose, they fluctuated between the two modes of existence looking upon the old mode as a paradise lost, even if monetary rewards seem to have been higher even in the early — if not the earliest — factories; this changed when the high-productivity factories of the second quarter of the 19th century in combination with trade-union organization made higher real wages possible.) It is also true that the first mechanical machines, like the spinning jenny, were invented by simulating the working-process of the human hand and fingers. And it is finally true that the introduction of the steam engine was effected by the introduction of machines. But it is doubtful if particularly large accumulations of capital were necessary for investment, at least in the early factories, since fixed capital initially played a minor role, since small capital owners often joined in common projects (see further below) and since one of the points of the factory system was that it was capital saving. In this regard Ashton (and even Lenin in his “On the market question”) had a much more realistic view. This does not preclude the possibility that capital was important for the rise of the class division between owners and not-owners, since even relatively small capital requirements acted as a barrier of entry for most domestic producers. Secondly, it is difficult to believe that the mechanization of manufacturing, at least in the textile industries, should have taken off from the division of tasks in manufactures. We simply do not need this hypothesis, since all evidence points to the fact that the factories arose on the foundation of developments in domestic industries and the putting-out system. It is also striking that Marx in developing his analysis of the rise of the factory system in “Capital” lost sight of the two fundamental points he had made in the manuscripts of 1861–1863, viz. that factories arose to increase the command over labour and that they made continuous labour possible. In view of the fundamental boundary condition of the phenomenon — i.e. the rapid rise of demand for final output — and in view of the existing evidence, this hypothesis seems much more promising than the technological one for the explanation of the rise of the factory system. This does not mean that technological change was not important in connection with the rise and, still more, the further development of the factories. But technological change occurred also in domestic industries and in the putting-out system and the really important technological breakthrough occurred

99

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

when factories already had started to arise. It remains to be noted that Marx, of course, had little or nothing to say on the detailed operation of domestic industries and the putting-out system indicated above.

1. Before mapping out the rise of the first factories, three points should be noted. Firstly, when we speak of the factory system we refer to several essential aspects of a specific mode of production. From the point of view of relations of production, the factory system is characterized by the existence of two classes, capital-owning employers and proletarianized workers. From the point of view of organization, factories are characterized by the hierarchy of employers over the workers and by a centralized work force and produc-tion. From the point of view of technology, factories are using machinery propelled by non-human power making high productivity possible. But while all these aspects should be present to define a fully developed factory system, it is not necessarily so when regarding the factory system as a process and, particularly, in its genesis. It may well be that in the process the different aspects were successively acquired. It is clear that before the introduction of mechanized technique and non-human power was possible, workers had to be centralized, organized and controlled and free workers also had to exist. If workers to begin with were centralized in factories in order to make it possible for capitalists to tap their labour-power more efficiently, as a response to the increasing demand for output, one may assume that the sustained operation of the fundamental boundary condition, i.e. the increasing demand for output, made further innovations necessary, e.g. technological change, which in the end resulted in the fully developed factory system.

2. The second point is that the putting-out system also went through several developments before its demise or transformation into sweating-systems. In response to the increasing control problem — increasing with the scale of production and demand — subcontracting was utilized in many industries. In the cotton industry subcontracting mainly appeared as putting “skilled spinners in charge of extensive machinery in the understanding that they paid and recruited their own child assistants, the ‘scavengers’ to clean the machines, and the ‘piecers’.” As long as the child assistants were children of the “subcontractor” and wages were paid out on a family basis, it is doubtful if we have to do with a subcontracting system; rather it was a survival of the domestic system inside factories. But the system persisted even when the child assistants no longer were children of the “subcontractor”. More relevant is the subcontracting system operating in the woollen and lace industries: “as late as 1815 most of the weaving (in Benjamin Gott’s large woolen mill), even on the premises, was done by independent ‘manufacturer’ contractors who were not paid by the firm, but on the contrary paid Gott a commission for the use of the factory, ‘on the cloth which they made to his order and which be bought from them’ ... Heathcote, developing his large lace mills within an old and tradition-bound industry, created the most astonishing mixture of direct and indirect employment in his Loughborough factory; while using foremen

100

Bo Gustafsson

to supervise his own workers, he allowed each foreman to employ two or three machines, and hire his own labour for them, as subcontractor.” (S. Pollard, 1965, p. 51 and 57.)

3. Thirdly, even after the rise of the factory system putting-out industries not only survived but were also combined with factory production (P. Hudson, p. 71). This was also quite rational from the point of view of the factory-own-ing capitalists. One of the main problems with putting-out industries was the irregularity of supply. This problem could be solved by factory production. But since demand was fluctuating, putting-out industries were convenient to utilize for top demand, while the more constant demand was supplied from the factories.

4. Turning to the problem of the genesis of factories, the evidence suggests that the process started by centralizing workers. According to S. J. Chapman “we can assert with confidence that somewhere about the beginning of the eighteenth century a strong centralising tendency revealed itself and it was assisted by the economies associated with centralised warping after the inven-tion of the warping mill”, the cause being that “it did not pay the individual weaver to keep a warping-mill for occasional use only, and frequently the contracted space of his workroom precluded even the possibility of his doing so” but also that “warps cannot be delivered partially like weft, in quantities sufficient for each day’s work. To ensure continuous working in the industry, therefore, it was almost inevitable that the merchant should himself prepare the warps for such fabrics as he required, or possibly have them prepared” (Chapman, 1904, p. 15). Chapman goes on to quote Butterworth, the historian of Oldham, describing conditions in and around Oldham “in the latter part of the 18th century”. According to Butterworth “a large number of weavers ... possessed spacious loom shops, where they not only employed many jour-neyman weavers but a considerable proportion of apprentice children” and many masters both put out warps and arranged for some weaving to be done on their own premises (Chapman, p. 23–24). The foregoing observations refer to weaving long before the introduction of the power-loom. These centralising weavers were called “master weavers” and “a man working in a manufactur-er’s shed was known as a ‘factory weaver’ or ‘shop-weaver’” (p. 24). Unwin has shown how Samuel Oldknow at about the same time (the 1780’s) had started to centralize weavers to his factories (Unwin, p. 110) and he quotes an offer of a factory sale of “25 pair of weavers’ looms” along with jennies and carding machinery (p. 116). While “the majority of weavers would (also) con-tinue to work on their own looms at home”, it “was hoped that the loom house at Stockport, where some of the more skilled were working under inspection and control, would serve as the nucleus for the establishment of the factory system in weaving” (p. 128). Unwin describes these centralised workers as follows:

101

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

Sometime in May 1787 Oldknow seems to have organized the processes of warping, sizing, and muslin trimming on a factory basis. It will be noted that these operations, which required but a small outlay in the instruments of pro-duction, were the most clearly allied to the central work of weaving. The war-ping mill was a simple but effective device for labour saving, and had been in common use from the 17th century ... [There are] incomplete records of 13 warping mills in the period 1787–94 (the maximum number being 29) ... It will be realized how important it was that the entrepreneur, who alone was in touch with the market conditions, should direct this process, for the nature of the warp determined the pattern and quality of the manufactured goods.

It is not surprising to find that the developments in warping were followed by a similar step in the subsequent process of sizing ... By relieving the weaver of this task the entrepreneur prevented the delay which sometimes attended the drying of the yarn and secured a greater uniformity of the final appearance of the cloth ...

The finishing processes were of great importance, for the value of the wea-vers’ work depended largely on the final appearance given to the cloth ... The apparatus of this department (for the trimming of the figures of the pattern wo-ven) was simple, consisting of 30 finishing frames and several darning frames. The staff comprised 81 girls and a foreman or forewoman. The names of the girls suggest that members of one family often worked together ... The records also afford brief but clear indications of the gradual transition of the winding process from the domestic to the factory system. Towards the end of 1788 there were about 90 outside winders, who wound in their homes ... and a refusal to accept [the piecework rates], coupled with a need for a quicker and more ef-ficient service, led to the setting up of nine winding machines in the Hillgate premises, of the operation of which there is a fragmentary record for July and August 1788. The first use made of steam power three years later was for the turning of these machines. (Unwin, p. 107–110).

But even before weaving was centralized, centralization of the prepatory processes of cotton manufacture took place, well before the advent of the wa-ter-driven mechanized Arkwright factories of the 1770’s. J. de L. Mann writes:

Arkwright has so far overshadowed his contemporaries that it has not been clearly enough realized that, in the years before his patent rights ended, his were by no means the only factories in the industry, although they were the largest and the best organised, and that he did not hold the monopoly of cotton warp production at which he aimed. Besides the factories in which the carding engine and the roller spinning frame had been installed, and which were worked either by Arkwright himself or under his license, there was an increasing number of rudimentary factories, based on the carding machine, in which cotton twist was produced. It might, indeed, be argued that even had the water frame not been invented, the Lancashire industry would have made considerable progress towards factory production and the application of power to the earlier processes of manufacture ...

The numerous mills which were springing up, especially in Lancashire, at the same time that his factories were being established, were more varied in character. The carding engine, which was coming rapidly into use after 1770, usually formed the nucleus of these undertakings. In its first crude forms it was capable of being employed as a domestic machine to be turned by hand

102

Bo Gustafsson

and it found a place in the warehouse of the manufacturer, who could give out the cardings to be roved and spun by domestic workers. Then he would add to his carding engine one or two of the improved jennies which had been adapted for making rovings, and give the cotton out in that form. The great demand for cotton warps, created first by the velvet manufacture, and then by the calico manufacture, which Arkwright brought into existence, and supplied at such profit to himself, gave strong inducement for the small capitalist to add spinning-jennies, twisting and warping mills. No inconsiderable part of the cotton twist for the large production of velvets that is reflected in the export returns for the later seventies must have been furnished by these new carding and jenny mills, since at that time Arkwright’s factories were hardly numerous enough to have met the demand ... These carding and jenny mills were of all sizes, from the small shop with nothing but a hand-carding engine, to the more elaborately organised factories in which all the operations from the cleaning and picking of the cotton to warping were carried on and in which horse or water power was used.

It is a point of some importance that the preparation of cotton warps, which was virtually a new industry, was accompanied almost from the beginning by some degree of factory organization ... Among many instances that might be quoted, the equipment of a jenny factory at Heaton Norris in 1780 will serve to show how many of the processes that had formerly been carried on in the homes of the workers were being transferred to the employer’s premises. The factory contained an iron pot, probably used for washing cotton, a stove and 48 “flakes to dry cotton on”, and a “large willey for cleaning and opening” it. There were three carding machines and another “unfinished”; three slab-bing jennies of 46, 36 and 26 spindles; twenty slabbers’ wheels; and thirteen spinning jennies — three of 120 spindles each, “new with all the late improve-ments”; three of 100 spindles; one of 84; one of 80; two of 60; one of 59; and two of 50. For the later processes there were a fine jack and “feeders” (per-haps for twisting); three Dutch wheels; a warping mill and bobbins, and seven looms ... The motive power of the factory is not stated ...

The developments at Nottingham were closely parallel, and probably pre-ceded those in Lancashire. The establishment there of Hargreaves and Ark-wright had led to the establishment of a trade in the making of carding machines as early as 1773–4 ... mainly sold to hosiery manufacturers ... Nottingham also had its jenny mills. (Wadsworth – de Mann, p. 488–494.)

It may be noted in passing that also T.S. Ashton in his book on the file master Peter Stubbs of Warrington shows that centralization of workers came before systematic mechanization:

The advantages to him of the aggregation of labour are obvious enough. So long as he had to rely on the services of outworkers spread over a wide area delays in execution of orders were inevitable, specialization of labour to particular tasks was difficult, and damage might be done in carrying unhardened files from the place of manufacture to the warehouse ... it is possible that supervision of work was becoming less efficient as the scale of operations increased ... For these reasons, therefore, Peter Stubbs decided to construct workshops near his own home. (Ashton 1939, p. 26. Unfortunately Ashton does not quote any evidence for this statement so that we really do not know, whether it is Stubbs or Ashton who speaks in the text.)

103

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

Quoting Guest (A compendious history) Edwards suggests in conformity with J. de L. Mann that in 1780 there were only 15–20 water-frame factories and that “until the later 90’s the small carding engine, jenny and mule work-shops and block printing concerns were more typical of the industry than the water-frame factories” (Edwards, p. 182). While the number of water-frame factories was to have increased rapidly after 1785 (Arkwright’s loss of patent rights), to 143 in 1787 and 155 in 1790 (Colquhoun’s disputed estimates), while investment in bleaching and printing also soared, Edwards refers to at least one remarkable instant of pure centralizing in weaving. “By April 1788, the weavers in Perth had built a ‘house’ large enough to contain 300 looms ‘which employ 600 people at a cost of £600’. But this kind of example is exceptional” (Edwards, p. 183–84). After the outbreak of the war with France in 1793 there was a standstill in factory construction which lasted until the end of the 90’s. Then came a new burst up to about 1803, featuring in part a more advanced type of factory:

By the temporary peace factory building had become more elaborate than a decade earlier. The small mills, four storeys high, about 30 ft. wide and up to 100 ft. in length, with timber frames, were gradually giving way to larger cast-iron structures, thus ensuring greater protection from fire. This type of construction, however, increased capital outlay by about 25 per cent, and was probably adopted only by the larger spinners (p. 184).

When Samuel Crompton carried out his ambitious survey of cotton facto-ries in 1811 he found in factories equipped with mules (though not factories without mules, since they were not counted): 310,500 water-frame spindles, 156,000 jenny spindles and 4,600,000 mule spindles, these representing “only a part of what is in upwards of 650 cotton mills within 60 miles of Bolton.” Still this tremendous increase of factory buildings in the cotton trade probably mostly consisted not in newly erected buildings but in converted corn mills, barns, dwelling-houses etc., which often were rented by individuals or groups of individuals. Renting converted or newly built cotton mills became itself a flourishing business. (Edwards, p. 193.)

Edwards summarizes the development of machinery nicely:

From 1785 until the end of the period, 1815, there was a rapid development of machinery and equipment in most sections of the trade, although the spinners mechanized more fully than either the weavers or the finishers. The power loom remained a technical novelty until after 1815 and the calico printers were dominated by the wood and copper block methods until the mid ‘90’s; by 1800, however, roller printing was increasing very rapidly; in bleaching there was an increase in the amount of equipment necessary to the efficient working of a good craft in the later ‘90’s, with the introduction of a variety of chemicals, and the vats and pans in which they were stored. But it was the spinners who were confronted with the greatest range of mechanical devices. The water-frame and carding engine were adopted by an increasing number of spinners after 1785, but the most spectacular progress was seen in the progress of the mule. When

104

Bo Gustafsson

it left Crompton’s hands in 1779 it was a crude piece of wooden machinery; by 1795 it had become a most efficient cast-iron device, the number of its spindles were increasing very rapidly, and it was soon greatly to outnumber the water frame and jenny spindles at work in the industry. (p. 200.)

Since there were scale economies involved in mule-spinning — the larger the number of spindles per mule, the lower the investment cost per spindle, and the larger the factory premises, the larger the mules to be installed — increasing size of mules and factories was encouraged (Edwards, p. 200–201). According to the memoir by John Kennedy earlier referred to, the mechanization of mule-spinning and the utilization of steam-power for mule-spinning (mule-spinning being the main area for the utilization of steam-power in the cotton trade up to 1815 or later) were instrumental in the rise of the factory system in this later stage of the process:

Before the year 1790, the mules were turned by hand, and were confined chie-fly to the garrets of cottages. — About that time Mr. Kelley of Lanark first turned them by machinery. The application of the steam engine to this purpose, produced another great change in this branch of the trade. The mules were removed from the cottages to factories, were constructed more substantially and upon better mechanical principles, and produced yarn of a more uniform quality and at less expense. (Kennedy, p. 129.)

When it comes to the question of motive power Edwards indicates the main course such:

Throughout these years cotton manufacturers used various forms of motive power. In carding and spinning the hand-operated machine survived until well after 1815; although from the 1770’s water was used to drive the water-frames and the larger carding-engines; the mule was worked by hand until the early 1790’s, after which it was also gradually adapted to water-wheels and steam-engines. In weaving, the hand-loom remained supreme until well after 1815, while in finishing, the bleachers and the printers did not adopt power-driven devices until the later 1790’s. The Boulton and Watt steam-engine made little impact on the structure of the trade. Lord estimated that between 1785 and 1795 about 47 of their engines, with a total of 736 horse-power, had been set up in cotton-spinning mills; only one of 12 horsepower was being used in bleach-ing; and one of 4 horse-power in calico printing. Between 1795 and 1800, 35 engines, with a total of 637 horse-power, were said to have been installed in the spinning section, and only two in bleaching, with 34 horse-power; none was recorded in calico printing, although one had been sold to a calenderer and glazier. (Edwards, p. 204).

Although the research by Robinson and Musson has shown that the Boul-ton firm was not the only supplier of steam-engines, wherefore the estimates by Lord probably underestimate the utilization of steam-engines in the cotton trade, still, the general trend is clear. Edwards thinks that the causes of this slow introduction of the steam-engine in the cotton trade were many and of

105

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

various kinds: the limited supply of engines; long delivery dates; inadequate sales representation in the north; high initial costs; the yearly premiums to be paid; the resistance of the leading Manchester spinners; the recurrent periods of idleness because of wars etc. which made water-wheels more profitable; the possibilities of getting regular power from water-wheels by utilizing res-ervoirs (Edwards, p. 205–209).

5. The growth of factories (mills) in the woollen and worsted industries was slower and was delayed compared to the cotton trade. Probably this was due both to the stronger traditions of handicrafts and domestic industry in woollen and worsted as well as to technical problems caused by the nature of the woollen fibres. The varieties of products in these industries were also much greater than in the cotton industries and thus mass markets and long se-ries did not exist. Still water-driven factories multiplied according to Jenkin’s study of the West Riding wool textile industry, from one factory in 1774 to 52 in 1780. The 1790’s signified a period of great expansion also in the woollen and worsted industries: the number of factories jumped up to 257 in 1800. After this date there is a more continuous growth of factories up to 446 in 1820 with a new expansion during the 1820’s to 636 factories in 1830. While factories in the late 1790’s were small and located close to streams, there was a concentration of factories to larger centres of population and along lines of communication in the 1820’s. (Jenkins, p. 16–17 and 46–47.) This re-location of factories of the woollen and worsted factories was of course conditioned by the gradual introduction of steam-power, which made it possible to locate factories close to markets. Also in these industries the factory system did not start, as Heaton believed, with machines and power, but by the centralization of workers:

There is evidence of considerable transference from the domestic scene to spe-cially constructed or converted buildings before the application of mechanical power. In spite of the outlay involved, many manufacturers saw advantages in having their work-people and their machinery controlled under one roof where the work could be supervised to maintain a constant standard; where perhaps a greater division of labour could be organized, the working hours of the labour force controlled and the time normally wasted in the carriage of raw materials and finished products under the domestic system eliminated. (Jenkins, p. 71).

The results of Jenkins are corroborated by Rogers for the Somerset and Wilt-shire woollen industries (K.H. Rogers, p. 26f.) It should be noted, however, that “the outlay involved” in acquiring factory premises may not after all have been so extensive, neither absolutely, nor relatively. In the first place it was not necessary to construct a new building and buildings could be rented. Secondly the outlay involved in a putting-out organization was probably much larger, since what was gained in low fixed costs was lost in large variable costs cau-sed by high transport costs and the slow circulation of capital.

106

Bo Gustafsson

6. Stanley D. Chapman has investigated the rise of cotton factories in the Midlands textile industry. It is noteworthy that the first attempts of Arkwright occurred here and it is likewise noteworthy that the continued history of the cotton industry did not take place in the Midlands but in Lancaster. Also Chap-man underlines the fact that factories arose before the Arkwright factories:

Although the domestic industry and clothing industries were predominantly cottage industries, there was already a marked degree of concentration in workshops and factories by the time Arkwright and Hargreaves came to Not-tingham. Hosiery frames were already being concentrated in workshops, some of them employing juvenile and female labour. In Nottingham a number of factories were opened, primarily to maintain innovations in secrecy, while in Derby and elsewhere in the hosiery districts, Lombe’s silk mill found numbers of imitators, though on a more modest scale than the prototype. All these pro-vided important precedents for the development of the cotton and worsted-spinning .... (Chapman, 1967, p. 34.)

The evidence provided by Chapman for this statement is, however, as usually is the case, rather sketchy: framework-knitters’ workshops of the hosiery districts established by merchant hosiers with a dozen or so frames for ex-ecuting special orders; larger workshops in Leicester containing a dozen or more frames built as annexes to workers’ houses and cottages; the frame-work factory of Samuel Fellows in Nottingham in the 1720’s employing more than 40 parish apprentices; some “safe-box” factories by Fellows and others in Nottingham for innovating practices; worsted stockings workshops employing “girls and women”; the Derby silk-reel factory of the 1720’s employing about 300 people as well as some Nottingham silk mills of the 1780’s; and twist-mills of unknown size in Birmingham and Lancaster (p. 34–45).

In this work Chapman makes two other observations of interest for the problem of the rise and development of factories. In the first place it seems as if costs for social infrastructure (mainly houses for workers) at the early fac-tories were exceedingly low. Community expenditure at Oldknow, Copwpe & Co’s Pleasly Mills in the 1790’s amounted to only between 6 and 14 per cent of total capital expenditure (p. 136). Secondly, “the evidence from insurance valuations and other scattered sources gives the impression that steam-power mills like Cartwright’s [Chapman refers to Major Cartwright’s Revolution Mill at Retford in the Midlands, a modern multi-storeyed factory designed to employ only steam-power founded in 1788] cost three or four times as much to build as the early water mills ... Thus most of the extra cost of establishing a factory lay in the purchase of machinery and stock.” From similar data Chapman concludes that “some seventy per cent of the capital outlay was devoted to machinery, compared with thirty per cent for the early Arkwright Mills.” (Chapman, p. 131–133.) He also notes that 50 per cent of the Midland cotton and worsted spinneries introduced steam-engines between 1785 and 1815 (p. 151).

107

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

In a later work (Chapman, 1971) on fixed capital formation in the British cotton industry Chapman points out that spinning jennies and water-frames “called for different kinds of building and a different scale of investment” (p. 58). He also stresses that the first spinning factories usually were housed in already existing buildings (barns, mills etc.), often rented or shared with other entrepreneurs, the smallest ones housing 8–10 workers, the largest 2–3 storeyed buildings (p. 59). Summarizing the evidence Chapman notes three fundamental types of factories between 1770 and 1803:

A. Small factories with horse-driven carding machines and hand-operated jennies or mules, sometimes with some looms for one family and 3–4 work-ers. The capital value of these proto-factories may have been £l–2,000.

B. Water-powered Arkwright mills for water-frames med 1,000–2,000 spindles in 3–4 storeyed buildings. Capital value: £3–5,000.

C: Steam-powered factories from the end of the 18th century with 2,000–4,000 spindles. Capital value: at least £10,000.

Chapman also tries to estimate the number of cotton factories around 1800. In the Midlands there should have existed 121 cotton factories around 1803, but almost no jenny workshops. In Scotland in 1795 there were at least 50 cotton factories valued at £5,000–10,000 and also 1,200 jennies, valued at £6 each, and 600 mules worth £30 each. In northwestern England there were at least 70 cotton factories. The sum total of this will be about 250 cotton factories in England and Scotland (plus workshops) around 1800.

7. Before turning to the problem of causes of the rise of factories discussed in the relevant literature, it may be appropriate shortly to describe some basic (and well-known) structural conditions affecting cotton manufacture during the second half of the 18th century. The introduction of Kay’s flying shuttle around the middle of the century considerably increased the productivity of the weavers and upset the input-output relations between spinning and weav-ing. The demand for yarn increased. This increased the yarn prices. While the raw material costs of weaving should have increased (also because of the increased time spent by weavers shopping for yarn, so vividly described by Guest), to some extent off-setting the productivity increase conditioned by the shuttle, the profitability of spinning should have increased. To increase the productivity of the spinners the Hargreave spinning jenny was invented, patented in 1770. While Hargreaves patented model contained 16 spindles, their number increased to 80 already in 1784. Hence it was possible for a single spinner to produce 80 times as much yarn as on a single-spindle wheel per time unit. But still the problem of producing cotton warp was not solved: the warp still being made by linen, which was more scarce than cotton. The larger jennies could indeed produce cotton warps. But only with Arkwright’s water-frame, patented 1769, were strong cotton warps on a large scale made possible. It was the Arkwright type of factory (adapted by many others), which became the prototype of the early cotton factory. The water-frame made the first substantial inroads on the domestic mode of production, because it was

108

Bo Gustafsson

too large to be housed in the workers’ homes and also driven by water-power (the first factory of Arkwright was driven by horse-power). Thus these Ark-wright factories also had to be located in the countryside. This may have been caused by the fact that the labour power was recruited among parish appren-tices and women. In any case there was a mismatch between sources of energy and sources of labour power. According to another interpretation the factories were consciously built for child labour in order to reap the benefits of low wages (if not low efficiency wages, as was later held). It may also be noted that these factories became a success for capitalists because the prices of warp were considerably higher than prices for weft.

The Arkwright factories increased most rapidly after 1785, when Ark-wright’s patent was cancelled.

The improvements in spinning had caused a carding problem that also was solved by Arkwright’s carding engine (to some extent at least as there were also other carding engines — see above). The patent was obtained in 1775. It was on the basis of carding machines and the larger jennies that the above-mentioned “rudimentary” factories arose and spread in the 1770’s pre-ceding and paralleling the Arkwright factories.

But jennies and water-frames could not produce the fine yearns suitable for the manufacture of muslins. This problem was solved by Crompton’s mule after 1779. The mule made a substantial impact on the industry only from the late 1780’s.

From the 1780’s the linen spinners and weavers in Lancashire, Scotland and Ireland went over to the production of pure cottons. Jenny spinning reached its peak in the 1780’s and jennies with 80 or more spindles became fairly common. Many jenny spinners combined carding with spinning and moved into workshops parallel with the increase of the size of the machines. After 1785 water-frames were rapidly adopted but still the very large water-frame factories were exceptional.

The expansion of spinning, resulting in more and more varied qualities of yarn, may have spurred the master-weavers to increase their control over their outworkers. In part a system of foremen or “festers” were employed (sub-con-tracting), in part a growing number of master-weavers, like the jenny spinners, moved their workers into weaving sheds (like Oldknow — see above).

Because of the enormous expansion of spinning the number of hand-loom weavers expanded too, since it probably was a rather rewarding trade. Maybe this caused the hand-loom weaver problem encountered later, when the power-loom was introduced.

8. Of some importance for solving the problem of the rise of the factory system may also be the changed conditions of the market for final output. In the first place, cotton products were more and more diversified. While Edwards accounts for only 6 different qualities in the early 1780’s, their number increased to 12 in the late 1780’s and to 17 in the first years of the 19th century (Edwards, p. 247). Secondly, and parallel to this, production was increasingly governed

109

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

by the preferences of final consumers so that agents and commissioners for the producers determined what should be produced and in which qualities. The implications for the governance of the production system are obvious: the need for rapid decisions, innovations and product control.

9. We should also know something about some other structural conditions of the cotton industry. What do we know about the first factory owners and how did they finance factories? What about productivity and profitability of the factories? Who were the workers, how were they recruited and from where did they come? And lastly: what do we know about labour conditions and wages, especially in comparison with domestic industries?

a) The problem of business leadership in the industrial revolution has re-cently been studied by Katarina Honeyman (1983). The entrepreneurs of the early cotton industry were examined in 1787 and 1811, the first survey re-ferring to owners of Arkwright-type mills, the second to mills operating on (mainly) Crompton’s principle in Oldham and Bolton. This means that the investigation hardly gives us any information on the first small-scale factories referred to earlier. From Honeyman’s data it seems fair to conclude that many of these early manufacturers disappeared. Honeyman concludes:

The majority of the [1787] entrepreneurs had previously been engaged in the local textile trade, whose importance was being superseded by the cotton in-dustry late in the eighteenth century. In Lancashire many of the cotton spin-ners were former fustian or calico manufacturers; early hosiery and silk mer-chants or manufacturers constituted the majority of entrepreneurs in the Mid-land counties of Nottinghamshire, Derbyshire and Staffordshire; in Yorkshire former wool and worsted manufacturers predominated. These men, therefore, were hereditary manufacturers, which suggests a continuity of leadership from preindustrial to industrial production.

In the early phase of the development of the cotton industry there were many techniques to minimise fixed capital requirements. The renting of buil-dings and machinery was commonplace, as was buying second-hand, and these practices undoubtedly helped the individual with little capital. Despite the opportunities that were available, however, the part played by the narrowly defined “self-made man” in the early cotton-spinning industry was small. It is clear, however, that a large proportion of the 1787 cotton spinners had emerged from class II [skilled craftsmen working on their own account, retail traders and yeomen] with a modest accumulation of capital. (Honeyman, p. 163.)

According to Honeyman’s table p. 61, class II made up 56 per cent of the factory owners, class I (members of the aristocracy and gentry, large business men, professional people such as doctors, lawyers, clergy and large farmers and landowners) made up 38 per cent and class III (skilled craftsmen work-ing for another, very small landholders such as husbandman) and class IV (semiskilled and unskilled workers and agricultural labourers) made up 5 and 2 per cent, respectively. This seems to be a rather strong case for Marx’s “really revolutionary way” to capitalism, even if occupational terms are vague and difficult to interpret! If one uses Honeyman’s data for a regroupment into

110

Bo Gustafsson

broader categories it is found that “manufacturers” made up ca 50 per cent, merchants 35 per cent, landowners 7 per cent and the rest 8 per cent. As to the term “manufacturer” Unwin states that up to the end of the 18th century it had been “applied sometimes to the domestic weaver but more commonly to his employer. In the 19th century it was transferred to the employer in any indus-try under the factory system, although in Lancashire it has been appropriated by the employer in power-loom weaving as distinct from the master spinner.” (Unwin, p. 38.)

Honeyman continues her conclusions as follows:

Table 6.1. indicates that the majority of mills operating on Crompton’s princi-ple in Oldham 1811 had been established and subsequently enlarged by men of at least moderate wealth, and the largest and most successful mills were owned by the most affluent local families, who also held extensive land and coal resources. Several former retailers and small textile manufacturers (class II) invested their limited accumulation of capital in cotton spinning, the initial fixed capital requirements for which could still be modest. Although indivi-duals from classes III and IV were fairly well represented among the Oldham entrepreneurs, their enterprises were typically very small, and all were short-lived. (Honeyman, p. 164.)

Also in this case II (43 or 28 per cent) or class II and class III (11 or 26 per cent) together seem to be dominant, while class I (39 per cent) comes second, leaving 7 per cent for class IV. The entrepreneurs were in this case recruited from three separate groups: landowners, individuals with coal-mining connec-tions and those previously occupied in the textile trade, typically in hatting, the local pre-cotton specialisation.

The majority of the 1811 Bolton cotton spinners belonged to families estab-lished in the textile industry, and had been involved in branches peculiar to the district, particularly fustian and muslin manufacture. A smaller group com-prised men who had previously been engaged in a non-textile business and who, typically, joined in partnership with a hereditary leader for the purpose of cotton spinning. The third and smallest category consisted of individuals with no previous experience of or contacts in the textile trade but who, like similar men in Oldham, ran small-scale enterprises and did not remain long in busi ness ... the long-term failure resulted from financial weakness, which the heavy demands of frequently unexpected working capital exposed. (Honeyman, p. 106.)

In this case the dominance of class II is still more prominent, class II making up 59 or 74 per cent of the entrepreneurs, class I 21 or 6 per cent, class III 18 per cent and class IV 2 per cent. Ca. 56 per cent were “manufacturers”.

Despite the differences between the two periods in terms of technology and organisation, the pattern of entrepreneurial recruitment was remarkably similar. Upward social mobility was present in both periods, indicated by the movement of individuals from class II to class I. There were, however, very few instances of long-distance social mobility, or of new industrial leasers emerging from

111

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

class III or class IV ... Despite the transformation of the economy and of society c. 1750–1830, there appears to have been little real change in the industrial leadership ... The demands of working capital ... in the long term usually proved fatal to the survival of the small man .... (Honeyman, p. 165–166 and passim.)

b) Turning to the question of the productivity and profitability of cotton factories, there does not seem to exist systematic investigations, at least not for the early factories. That cotton factories as a rule could be both very pro-ductive and profitable seems clear. Writing in the 1830’s Baines stated that “a spinner now produces as much yarn in a day, as by the old processes he could have produced in a year; and cloth, which formerly required six or eight months to bleach, is now bleached in a few hours” (Baines, p. 7). Aiken considered in 1795 that Yorkshire manufacturers could gain as much as a three-fold greater production from a centralised workforce (Hudson, p. 71). Official reports from 1840 on the hand-loom weavers suggested that “the hand-loom factories’ productivity advantages was such that they could finish a hundred webs while domestic weavers finished fifty” (Smelser, p. 143). According to an estimate made in 1779 of the costs per lb of cotton in spinning and allied activities in Arkwright factories compared to hand spinning, the cost difference should have been enormous: being 6d in the Arkwright factories and 3s in hand spinning. “This estimate of a six-fold advantage for the factory in spinning and allied activities about 1780 cannot be taken literally. In the light of Arkwright’s reported profits, however, it is probably not far off the mark.” (Smelser, p. 99). According to Howe (1984) net profit rates for three (successful?) firms between 1778 and 1809 varied between 10 and 25 per cent per year (p. 27). That at least machinery was immensely productive compared to handwork seems to emerge from Lipson’s figures comparing 1781–1796 with 1796–1805 (Lipson, p. 258–59.)

c) When it comes to the question of the recruitment of labour to the early factories it seems as if the small jenny factories often relied upon families who before had been domestic workers (see e.g. Unwin, p. 106). The Arkwright factories, of course, very much relied on children (to begin with parish ap-prentices) and women. In Arkwright’s Cromford mills in 1789 87 per cent of the 1,150 workers were children and women and factory owners often adver-tised for families with many children, their age frequently being 8–10 years (Chapman, 1967, p. 165 and 169). Parish apprentices were much in demand but according to Chapman’s investigations 1/3 run away, died or had to be sent back (Chapman, 1967, p. 170). It was generally difficult to recruit labour to the Arkwright factories and it was often necessary to give the adult men employment in agricultural pursuits in order to get access to the labour of the women and the children in families (Chapman, p. 156f.) It is, however, un-clear whether children and women were demanded because of the cheapness of their labour-power or whether men were difficult to get. Ure writes:

112

Bo Gustafsson

Children of a small size, and therefore young, were much more in demand during earlier periods of the cotton trade than they are at present, reference be-ing had to the total number of hands employed in it, and to the amount of work done. Arkwright’s water-frames were built very low in the spindle-boxes to accommodate children, and consequently sometimes caused deformity, by the frequent act of stooping to the ground. The throstle, which hardly ever requires the operative to deviate from the perpendicular posture, has for many years superseded entirely that machine. It is managed by young persons from fifteen years of age and upwards, and does not necessarily involve the employment of children ... Again, in mule-spinning, the number of children is not increased, but rather diminished, in reference to the number of spindles and the quality of yarn produced, because fewer ends break upon the modern than upon the older machines. (Ure, p. 362.)

This is an interesting paragraph, because it indicates that the Arkwright water-frames were built for the utilization of child labour. But was this because of a profit calculus or because Arkwright assumed that only children could be recruited or both? Likewise Kelly, the inventor of the self-acting mule, also made his invention with a specific kind of labour power in sight. In a letter to Kennedy in 1829 he wrote: “The object then was, to spin with young people, like the water twist. For that purpose it was necessary that the carriage should be put up without the necessity of applying the hand to the wheel.” (Quoted by Baines, p. 206.)

The Hammonds thought that the utilization of child labour proceeded in two stages. To begin with apprentice children were utilized, because the (Ark-wright) factories were located to the countryside (water) and the labour power thus was brought to the factories. In a second stage, free-labour children were utilized and this stage is connected with the growing utilization of the foot-loose steam-power energy. (J. L. and B. Hammond, 1928, p. 144). The same point is made by Collier, who stresses that the new (Arkwright) machinery “was adopted for the employment of women and children”:

The changes involved arose owing to the great demand for labour at certain places whereas previously the workpeople had been scattered throughout the cotton manufacturing area. Consequently, even if there had been no prejudice against entering the factories it would have been impossible for most of the people who had worked in their own homes to become millhands. To do so would have involved migration and as the early spinning mills absorbed little skilled male labour there was no great attraction for weaving families to move. Hence many of the factory masters resorted to the apprenticeship system and much of the male labour which migrated to factory towns was unskilled, or had families for whom employment in a cotton mill meant a substantial increase in income. (Collier, p. 3.)

Collier also suggests that “there can be no question as to the better position of the factory workers in times of depression compared to those still employed outside the factory”, because of higher and less fluctuating wage rates (and employment) . Collier also thinks that the labour power of apprentice children

113

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

was comparatively inefficient and that this fact explains “the rapid disappea-rance of the apprentice system from the cotton industry once free labour could be obtained.” (p. 4 and 45.)

Also according to Pollard pauper apprentices were used as labour power in the first (Arkwright) factories, not primarily because it was cheap but be-cause it was the only available alternative for certain tasks.2 (Pollard, 1965, p. 194–95.) He characterizes labour in the first factories as “only the riff-raff, the paupers, the displaced Highlanders and discharged soldiers” and “even later many entered only as a last resort.” At the same time he underlines that “domes-tic workers who transferred to factory raised their earnings.” (Pollard, 1978, p. 161 and 163.) And this in a period of “a general labour surplus” (p. 100).

What conclusions may be drawn from this kind of seemingly contradictory information for the understanding of the transition from domestic industries to factories with regard to the recruitment of the labour force? The first thing to note is probably that it was a contradictory process from two points of view, at least with respect to the “second generation” of factories like the Arkwright factories. In the first place, these factories represented a quite new way of life with regard to habitat, working-habits, work control etc. Thus the complaints of contemporary capitalists that factory workers were “transient, marginal and deviant” and that the factory population was characterized by a “restless and migratory spirit” may well refer not only to Pollard’s “riff-raff” but also to regular domestic workers.

Secondly, the rise of the factories not only signified that they out-competed domestic industries, but also and especially to begin with injected a new way of life in these by increasing the demand especially for weft but also for specific qualities of yarn. This may have implied that domestic workers or any other workers were not forced to take up employment in factories but had a choice. Thus we might explain the seemingly contradictory fact that on the one hand it was difficult to recruit workers to factories and on the other hand (family) earnings in factories were higher than in (many) domestic industries. The reason are, firstly, that workers did not react only or perhaps not even mainly to economic incentives, particularly not in the period of transition when a new mode of existence and social culture clashed with the traditional ones; and, secondly, that the very rise of factories to begin with gave domestic industries a new life and even favourable conditions of existence. This would have changed at a later stage, when the competitive role of factories became more prominent because of technological progress increasing the productivity of factory labour and, as a consequence of this, the earning gap in relation to domestic industries had widened sufficiently and could be utilized by stronger

2 “Recruiting to the textile factories was geared chiefly to overcome ... the shortage of labour willing to work regular hours and endure factory discipline. The unfree labour ... did not in most cases amount to more than one-third of the labour force and usually much less: free labour also had to be recruited and adapted.” (Pollard, 1965, p. 203). Fitton-Wadsworth noted that the em-ployment contracts were longer in the 1770’s and 1780’s than later (Fitton-Wadsworth, p. 233).

114

Bo Gustafsson

labour organizations. One may also assume that with the passage of time, the labouring population willy-nilly became accustomed to the mode of life of factory work and its social surroundings.3

10. Let us now at last look at some representative views, contemporary and modern, as to the causes of the rise of the factories. This is a very complicated problem of interpretation, because statements are seldom sufficiently precise as to meaning. Causes may be conditions (structural) or aims (teleological), necessary or sufficient and they may operate on different levels and apply to different areas of observation. Similarly factories, as already stressed, were of various kinds and represented a process rather than a thing. For some ob serv-ers the rise of factories is simply the effect of the shortcomings of domestic industries and putting-out systems, while for others factories implied the intro-duction of some quite new elements not existing earlier (like technological in-novations). Still it is of interest to note how different authors have approached the problem.

Edward Baines, writing from the perspectives of the 1830’s, holds that the factory system arises with the Arkwright factories housing water-frames and carding-machines propelled by water-wheels. He enumerates a great many factors responsible for the establishment and superiority of these factories: 1) The new machines were too large and too heavy to be accommodated in a cottage; 2) Their operation required non-human energy, preferably water pow-er; 3) They made possible a more extensive division of labour; 4) There were extensive economies in manufacturing cotton in one centralized building: a) economies in energy-production (one larger water-wheel instead of several smaller, b) economies in supervision and control against wasteful or fraudu-lent consumption of material, c) economies in transport of the labour object from raw material to final output, d) avoidance of interruptions in the process-ing in domestic industries conditioned by “the failure of one class of workmen to perform their part, when several other classes of workmen were dependent upon them” and e) economies in the use of mechanics on the spot to construct and repair the machinery, since many machines made them fully employed. “All these considerations drove the cotton spinners to that important change in the economy of English manufactures, the introduction of the factory system; and when that system had once been adopted, such were its pecuniary advan-tages, that mercantile competition would have rendered it impossible, even if it had been desirable, to abandon it.” (Baines, p. 184–85.) Elsewhere Baines through-out his treaties on the cotton trade stresses that machine-spun yarn

3 In this process stick and carrot were used: harsh work discipline including confinement of workers within the factory premises, fines and dismissals, as well as gift-giving and arrange-ment of feasts. The role of wage-systems should be studied. Although domestic workers were used to piece-work, it may be that piece-rates became more incentive-oriented. “In many enter-prises the ‘discovery’ of payment by result was greeted as an innovation of major significance, and at times the change-over does seem to have led to marked improvements in productivity.” (Pollard, 1965, p. 223.)

115

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

was of a higher quality (more even and allowing finer threads to be produced) and cheaper than hand-made yarn. To the extent that machines could not be accommodated in cottages or workshops (like the Arkwright machines and very large jennies) these conditions of the superiority of factory manufacture should also be added to the list.

For Marx (as his views are expounded in Capital and the manuscripts pre-ceding it) capitalist relations of production start before the introduction of the factories, viz. by the control of capital over free labour and the increased utili-zation of labour, e.g. through more continuous labour, thereby made possible. This is the “formal subsumtion of labour under capital” and the increased production of absolute surplus value as it arises in pure centralized produc-tion, e.g. in traditional manufactures. This mode of production is superior to domestic industries. Even if those industries allow for some division of labour, it remains limited.

There are a lot of time-consuming improductive mediating processes, which are conditioned by the fact that the different stages of the commodity processed exist as independent commodities and their connection is mediated by the exchange of commodities, i.e. buying and selling. The mutual labour in the different branches is conditioned by various chance occurrences, stoppings etc. Only the forced connection in the workshop produces the simultaneousness, evenness and proportionality in the mechanism of these various operations and connects them as a whole to a proportionate working mechanism. (Manuskripte 1861–1863, 11:3.1., p. 245f.)

Thus, for Marx there occurs a transition from domestic industries to factories proper in two stages: from domestic industries to centralized production and from centralized production to factories. The introduction of factories implies a transition from the formal to the real subsumtion of labour under capital and from the pre-dominance of absolute to relative surplus production.

The whole of part IV of Capital, I, is devoted to machinery and the factory system and its heading is “Production of relative surplus value”. The factory system with its machinery and extensive division of labour and cooperation implied first and foremost a sustained increase of labour productivity and thus made increased production of relative surplus value possible. The factory system, at the same time, also made an increase of absolute surplus value possible, generally by condensing amorphous labour time and, specifically for a period, by extending the working day.

The factory to begin with implies concentration of labour-power, which evens out product quality and saves constant capital and thus raises the rate of profit. It also makes cooperation between workers possible. This cooperation is expressed in an increased productivity of labour made possible by an im proved distribution of tasks according to capabilities, a lowered time of transportation of the labour objects and an improved perception of what is going on.

116

Bo Gustafsson

The distinguishing characteristic of the factory, in contradistinction to the manufacture, is the large-scale application of machinery. In the factories the instruments of labour became converted from tools to machines: “the tool proper is taken from man and fitted into a mechanism, a machine takes the place of a mere implement”. A fully developed machinery consists of three essential parts: the motor mechanism, the transmission mechanism and the tool or the working machine. The revolution of the mode of production effected by the factories start with the machinery and it is the development and growth of the machines that calls forth the development and growth of the motor mechanism (water power and then steam engine) and of the transmission mechanism.

The development of machinery undermines the power of skilled labour —the deskilling of labour with the ensuing fall in the value of the labour power. Radical changes in machinery in one sphere of industry also creates pressure on other spheres of industry, as when spinning by machines induced the inven-tion of weaving by machines and both together induced the mechanical and chemical revolution in the bleaching, printing and dying of cloth as well as the gin for separating seeds from the cotton fibre.

The essence of the new factory system, according to Marx, is to be found not in technology per se but in the new social and economic relations arising and growing upon the new technological basis. First, machinery enhances the productivity of labour in various ways. Machinery always enters into the labour-process as a whole and thereby it increases the physical productivity of labour. It also saves labour by replacing human labour power. It makes possible the utilization of cheap labour power (women and children). It prolongs, at least to begin with, the working-day because machinery is a perpetuum mobile. It increases relative surplus value by depreciating the value of labour power, cheapens the commodities entering into the reproduction of labour power and creates extra surplus value for the capitalists first introducing machinery at the pre-determined value of commodities (determined by the old technology). Further, machinery, at least to begin with, creates an incentive for increased absolute surplus value, when the increased relative surplus value effected by the introduction of machines is more than off-set by the loss of surplus value effected by the decreasing number of workers. It creates the industrial reserve army, depressing wages, and it intensifies labour by making labour time less porous than before, through increases of the speed of the machines and by giving workmen more machines to tend.

The factories also, as Marx suggests in the manuscripts, increase the physical productivity of capital (lowers the capital/output ratio) and hence raises the profitability of capital. (Thus even with unchanged profit shares the profitability of invested capital is increased, since R/K = R/Y x Y/K.) This occurs through economizing on the common conditions of labour and on the use of these conditions. In the first place, economizing on premises (Gebäu-lichkeit), heating, lighting etc., on power motors, since the cost of a power motor does not increase in the same proportion as its effect (incidentally, this

117

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

is confirmed by late eighteenth century business correspondence quoted by Edwards, p. 204), by economizing through the buying of raw materials on a larger scale, by economizing on transmission machinery and on management and lastly by economizing on waste products to be re-used in production or transformed into by-products. This economizing on the conditions of produc-tion “wholly depend on the common utilization of these by the concentrated cooperating labour.” (Manuskripte, 11:3.6., p. 2163ff.)

Most other authorities do not supply so extensive and reasoned explana-tions as Baines, not to speak of Marx. To James factories were introduced because of the defects of the domestic industries as to economy, regularity of supply and quality of products but also because of an inability to expand when demand expanded. Machinery and spinning in the worsted manufacture in Bradford came about in the late 18th century because of

the impossibility of obtaining from the common wheel the necessary supply of yarn to meet the continuously increasing demand led to the introduction in Bradford of spinning machines, which were first used there about the year 1794, by Mr. James Garnett, who set them up in the Paper Hall High Street. Soon after Mr Garnett’s spinning machines were set up, the late Mr. Robert Ramsbotham worked several of them by means of a gin horse on his premises in Kirkgate ... Nearly contemporaneous with the first use of spinning machinery in Bradford an effort was made to build a factory here [it succeeded in 1800]. (James, p. 591).

The first carpet factory in Halifax, erected after 1780, is to have come about also because of increasing demand: “The spinning of both weft was accom-plished by hand, in various parts of the country, at cottages and arm houses. Mr. Currie found his trade increased so much as to require more extended premises, and he built a large factory at Luddenden Foot (about four miles from Halifax), where he carried on the carpet manufacture until his death in 1816.” (James, p. 621.)

Unwin suggests several different causes. In the first place, he mentions the increasing size of machines: “Whilst the invention of the billy prolonged the usefulness of the jenny, and the smaller jennies and mules continued to be used by cottage spinners, the prevailing tendency was towards the increase in size of both jennies and mules and towards the collection of them in small factories where they were operated in conjunction with carding and roving machinery by workers who did not own them.” (Unwin, p. 32). Winding was transferred to a factory in Stockport because it was to have made lower wages possible and have increased the efficiency of work:

Towards the end of 1788 there were about 90 outside winders, who wound in their homes about 70,000 hanks a month. Winding had always been done by children or old people, who earned one or two shillings a week by it. The piecework rates were very low and a refusal to accept them, coupled with a need for a quicker and more efficient service, led to the setting up of nine

118

Bo Gustafsson

winding machines in the Hillgate premises, of the operation of which there is a fragmentary record for July and August 1788. The first use made of steam power three years later was for turning these machines. (Unwin, p. 110.)

The motivations of Oldknow to set up a spinning factory in Stockport in 1791 is described thus by Unwin:

The chief problem of his business from the first had been that of ensuring adequate and regular supplies of yarn of increasing fineness at prices that would enable him to compete successfully with other muslin makers whether of India, Scotland or Lancashire. As early as 1784 he had been recommended by Arkwright to start a spinning mill. The factory system in lesser or greater degree was becoming universal in spinning. Oldknow’s neighbors, the calico manufacturers of Stockport, were solving the problem of the yarn supply by setting up as factory spinners and were running a race with each other to secure water-power of the Mersey and the Goyt ... That manufacturers should seek to invest their surplus capital in spinning mills was inevitable. The prices of the yarn, which constituted half the cost of their fabrics, had been reduced 25 per cent in a few years by the new machinery, and experience was to show that by the application of power and organization of labour it could soon be further reduced by a like amount .... (p. 124–126.)

This is an interesting statement, since it not only relates the costs of machine spinning to those of hand-spinning but also the cost of factory machine spin-ning to machine spinning per se.

To E. Lipson the centralization of cloth weaving in the West Country and in Yorkshire in the 18th century creating miniature factories was effected because of three causes: “The advantages of the system were threefold. It enabled the employer to supervise in person the processes of manufacture; it prevented delay in return of the work, which was wont to occur when a weaver wove in his own home for different masters; and it rendered more difficult any embezzlement of the raw material.” (Lipson, p. 50–51.)

Sidney J. Chapman (1904) indicated many various factors behind the rise of the factory system in the cotton industry. In weaving three different causes were operating: 1) “the need of water or steam for driving heavy machinery”, 2) “the increasing complexity of machinery, which magnified its cost” and 3) “the increasing complexity of business (the outcome on the one side of constant additions being made to the variety of cotton goods and the rapid changes that took place in patterns), which augmented greatly the economies to be derived from a through-going organisation” (p. 18). Thus a need for new energy sources, expensive machinery out of the reach of domestic producers and changes in the market for final output are pointed out as conditioning factories for the transition in weaving. He also shows that looms successively became more expensive (looms with “draw-boys” separate or affixed as in “harness looms” plus extra appliances like reeds, healds and gaiters). These changes took place already during the 18th century. During the 19th century “the hiring of looms from those who let lodgings, or others, became so usual as

119

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

to excite no comment.” (p. 25). The power-loom which definitely could not be housed in a cottage was superior to the hand-loom because “it not only worked faster than the hand-loom … but also produced a cloth of a more even texture, because of the uniform strength of the blows administered mechanically to the shuttle, a uniformity which no human agent could hope to rival.” (p. 27.)

Also in spinning, according to Chapman, two distinct factory systems arose. Spinning by rollers (Arkwright factories) initiated a real revolution, while jenny and mule spinning implied an evolution to the factory system (p. 53). While the jenny multiplied human hands, the water-frame was a substitute for human hands. Thus the water-frame recruited unskilled labour, children and women, but it did not appreciably displace skilled cotton spinners, since it was confined chiefly to warps, previously made of linen or wool. The jennies, on the contrary, put a premium on skilled and male labour, since greater strength was required to use them than the one-spindle wheel, and this meant that it increased employment opportunities for men while decreasing those of women and children. The mule, still more, required great skill. Thus jenny and mule spinning factories could be of varying size and quite small, while the water-frame factories were large and could rely on economies with respect to power, buildings, managing, marketing and the division of labour (p. 57–58). Of some importance was probably also that Crompton’s mule was unprotected by patent besides being small and cheap. (According to Stanley D. Chapman, 1967, the cost of a mule amounted to about £ 30.) The mule was generally employed for fine spinning (muslins) and mules were installed bit by bit in garrets, lofts or barns. Quoting French, Chapman writes: “Many industrious men commenced business with a single mule worked by their own hands, who as their means increased, added to their machinery and progressively extended their business until they rose to honorable eminence as the most useful and extensive manufacturers of the Kingdom.” (p. 59–60.)

But also jennies and mules grew in size and complexity like the hand-loom with effects for the competition between domestic industry and factories. This occurred already before the introduction of the self-acting mule. Chapman describes this development thus:

In course of time, however, the enlarged number of spindles on the jenny, and the increase in subsidiary machinery and in its complexity, called for a more economical source of power than the gin-horse, and, in addition necessitated larger business. By the invention of the self-actor mule spinning was ultimately to be rendered almost as automatic as weaving; but some time before the self-actor appeared power was used to drive out the mule-carriage. Further, changes in machinery led to changes in the arrangement of hands “tending” it.

When the mule was altogether a hand-machine one spinner was required for each machine; but when the carriage driven out by power and needed only to be put back by hand, it was possible, if somewhat exhausting, for the spinner after putting up one carriage to turn his heel and thrust back the carriage behind him, which had been driven out by power into the wheel-gate while he was tending the other. The arrangement whereby one man controlled the pair soon

120

Bo Gustafsson

became almost universal, and as the mules increased in weight, owing to the additions made to the number of spindles carried by them, power began to be applied also for driving the carriage back.

But spinning still involved the exercise of no inconsiderable skill, for the winding had to carefully regulated by the operative, who guided “the faller” (or wire which by rising and falling determined the part of the spindle upon which the thread should by wound) with one hand and varied the speed of the revolving spindles by turning a screw with the other. The need for skill of this kind — which meant the specialisation of the operative’s organism for delicate actions to be rapidly repeated, and was therefore wholly mechanical in character — was removed ultimately by the self-acting mule ... Among the medium and coarse counts the self-actor was finishing its conquests from about 1850 to 1860. (Chapman, 1904, p. 69–70.)

Neil J. Smelser (1959), who from the point of view of the historical so-ciologist, has made a very systematic investigation of the Lancashire cotton industry 1770–1840, based upon an extensive reading of both con temporary printed sources and relevant literature before 1959, considers very many as-pects of the transitional problem. On the one hand the increasing prob lems of domestic industries under the pressure of increasing demand and production, like increased quality variations of products, increasing carrying and fetching, the low elasticity of the supply of labour and the low mobility of labour be-cause of its attachment to the cottage and the soil. (Smelser, p. 65–77.) On the other hand the increasing size of jennies and carding machines leading to the establishment of the first primitive factories and workshops, a process repeated with the introduction of the mule. At the same time he does not accept a purely technological explanation, since also organizational aspects, like authority and control, were involved (p. 90). While increasing size and increasing need for power generation evidently explains the rise of the Arkwright factories as well as the mule-spinning factories after Kelley’s application of water-power to mule-spinning from 1790, factories survived as a new mode of produc-tion because they turned out better and more varied products and were more productive and more profitable. (Even if the new work organization and the new technology per se were more productive and more profitable than the old modes, the factories would not have been successful if they had not been able to turn out products which equalled or surpassed the products of domestic industries.) In the final analysis the superiority of the factories was, so Smelser seems to suggest, based on a more efficient organizational rationality than that of the domestic industries and putting-out systems, because they implied a higher degree of control over resource use (capital and labour), over the de-cision to produce or not produce and over the process of production. Leaning on Weber (and ultimately Marx) the three decisive aspects of this increased organizational rationality were that 1) the capitalists succeeded in monopoliz-ing control over the means of production, 2) absence of appropriation of jobs by workers and conversely absence of appropriation of workers by owners

121

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

(formally free labour) and 3) calculability of the technical conditions of the productive process, including labour discipline (p. 100).

The above does not represent a complete list of views on the problem of the causes of the rise of the factory system in cotton manufacture in England. But it is doubtful whether an extension of the number of authors would give much additional information. Two things stand out quite clearly. In the first place, there evidently existed factories of different kinds and of different complexity and there was a development over time, from the primitive jenny-, carding- and mule factories mainly centralizing workers to the Arkwright factories and, after 1800, the mule-spinning factories up to the fully developed factories of the 1830’s and 1840’s with self-actor mules and power-looms. Likewise there was a development of the sources of power, from primitive factories relying on human power and horses to water-wheels and steam engines and the way there were combinations of those sources. The labour power of the factories con-sisted to begin with of families or members of families in domestic industries in the case of the first jenny and carding workshops and mills. The Arkwright mills relied primarily on children, women and marginal workers as the main staff. Women and children remained a substantial proportion of the labour force for a long time. But the proportion of men may have increased over time in certain branches of cotton manufacture. The scale of investment differed between different kinds of factories. While a jenny- or mule-spinning mill, allowing for a flexible scale of operation, did not require substantial capital investments, the Arkwright mills did. But given the right social connections it was always possible to raise capital from capital owners of different kinds. Still, the first cotton factory owners arose from manufacturers and merchants within the industry in the general case. Over time the scale of investment rose with more expensive machinery and larger factories. To operate a cotton factory the most important problem, however, concerned the circulating cap-ital. Therefore factory owners were seldom self-made men but were recruited from the higher middle and the upper class with some additions from average middle class people.

Secondly, the problem of causation has been attacked on different levels and from different angles. No really systematic investigation seems to have been undertaken meeting the rigorous requirements of strict causal analysis, although Marx is the one who comes closest to the ideal. But not even Marx, although handling the most complex explanatory model, seems to take all relevant factors into account. He gives material for a fairly systematic ex-planation. But sufficient evidence is lacking, the interrelations of different explanatory variables are not wholly clear and he seems to underestimate the importance of social and cultural factors.

Provisionally it seems as if a full-fledged causal explanation for the rise of the factories should take many different aspects into account. In the first place, we should devote attention to the proper definition of factories, since there is a vast difference between the first primitive factories and the later

122

Bo Gustafsson

“proper” factories and the explanations of their respective origins will differ to some extent. The second area of study and reflection concerns the domestic industries and the putting-out system and their operation under the impact of the rapidly increasing demand for final output. If the problem of quality of products, transportation, inelasticity of supply, embezzlement etc. were as great as is indicated in the relevant literature, it seems clear that some kind of re-organization of the industry became imperative. Maybe, the first relevant step, then, was to centralize production under the control of the capitalist as evidently occurred in the first primitive factories.

Assuming that centralized production pure and simple was the first step towards a full-fledged factory system, one may assume that the sustained increase of demand and production led to an increasing size and complexi-ty of machines, given competition and thereby induced innovative activity. Thereby an important factor differentiating factory production from domestic industries is introduced, since the scale of investment increases continuously. Even if some domestic producers may develop stepwise to factory owners through the accumulation of savings (the case of the proverbial mule-spinners quoted above), the minimum capital requirements are increasing all the time and put up a barrier for an increasing number of domestic producers. Existing class differences are deepened and factory owners emerge as a distinct and superior class. This development takes a jump with the Arkwright factories with expensive machines, large factory premises and water-wheels. The same thing occurs when mule-spinning after 1790 starts to utilize steam-power.

At this stage, the factories become firmly established in the main lines of cotton manufacture and domestic industries are more or less reduced to a secondary or complementary role (serving factories or producing specific qualities of products). The superiority of factories is to begin with conditioned by their use of more advanced machinery and powerful energy sources con-ditioning higher productivity and higher profitability than in the domestic industries. This state is also conditioned by the fact that the factories are able to pump out labour from labour power more efficiently and by the fact that they turn out products of higher and more even quality and, further, can produce new qualities. Of importance is also the fact that the factory owners by their command over the process of production can serve and utilize markets and market changes quicker and more efficiently and also can introduce necessary innovations with less effort.

But there was one problem which it took considerable time for the factory owners to solve: to discipline the work force and, still more, to engage the mo-tivation of workers in the process of production. The factories were to begin with, and rightly so, looked upon as work-houses. The new factory labour is handled by the factory owners with stick and carrot. But the decisive victory over the factory workers occurs when new incentive systems of payment are introduced linking work effort with productivity. From then on the victory of the factory system is definitive.

123

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

VII. Suggestions for future research The preceding preliminary overview of the problem concerning the transition from domestic industries to factories points out some problems to be further researched:

1. To begin with it seems necessary to canvas the research situation of today in order to know from where to depart. Probably such an investigation would not give too much additional information on the general problem of the project, especially not the conceptual ones. But since much has been written during the last years or so on proto-industrialization, industrialization and factories, an investigation of research already made would probably cast light on partial aspects of the project. A new project should not preferably solve problems already solved!4

2. A second area concerns problems of explanation and modelling. The primary purpose of the project should not be to describe the main outline of the transition from domestic industries to factories — although good and relevant description is a necessary condition for explanation — but to furnish an explanation. But what do we exactly mean by an explanation? Traditionally explanation implies answers to the question “why?” by pointing out causes or conditions, sufficient and necessary. But what are causes of a phenomenon which is an historical process, wherein the object to be explained undergoes a transformation and shows different aspects at different points of time? To put it concretely: are we out to explain the rise of the first jenny and carding facto-ries, the Arkwright factories, the power-loom factories or all of them? One set of modelling may be appropriate for one category of factories, another set for another. The problem is complicated by the fact that the transition had some-what different characteristics in different industries and different countries. Further, how do we define necessary and sufficient conditions and how do we define initial and boundary conditions in an explanation of the transition and how do we delimit them from each other?5

My suggestion is, firstly, that we start by trying to explain the rise of fac-tories for certain well-defined types of factories before we try to generalise to find out essences. Secondly, as I have argued above, market conditions may be treated as boundary conditions of the phenomenon to be explained. But what about the problems encountered by domestic industries in view of 4 Gustafsson is referring here to the research project “From Verlag to Factory” (1986–1994). See Klas Nyberg’s article above. — Eds.5 Two other problems in modelling explanations may also be mentioned. 1) Since it is possible to point out so very many independent conditioning factors, one may run the danger of present-ing over-determined solutions (vide the many deficiencies of the putting-out system confronted by expanding demand). 2) Since causal factors were operating on several different levels it seems important to pin down, at least to begin with, some “prime mover” of the transition paral-lel with the efforts to define and connect the causes operating on different levels. Such a “prime mover” could be, in the case of capitalists, strivings for maximum profits (accumulation), and, in the case of workers, strivings for maximum real income or welfare. At least, there must be some force or forces propelling the model!

124

Bo Gustafsson

the rising demand for final output? Are these sets of problems also part of the boundary (or initial conditions) or do they belong to the necessary conditions for the rise of factories? The developing capitalist relations of production in the putting-out system? The concentration of workers and production before large-scale technological change? Those large-scale technological changes? Which are, really, the sufficient conditions for the rise of the factories? One may continue to add questions. But the point is that thinking and working on the conceptual problems is important for avoiding muddling-along.

3. One of the most crucial problems encountered is, I suggest, the proper definition of factory. Granted that factories are developing entities, one should at least start by defining some point of departure. To put it concretely: is it possible to regard the first primitive factories like the jenny and carding fac-tories in cotton manufacture as factories in view of the fact that they implied capitalist relations of production, implied concentration of labour and implied at least some important organizational aspects of the capitalist factory (like hierarchy, control etc.) — but did not imply integrated machinery system and — often — not non-human energy sources? How should such difficulties be handled properly?

4. Lastly, there is the problem of finding sufficient facts or evidence. Of course this problem to some extent depends upon the level of abstraction we choose to apply. But in my overview I have found this problem embarrassing. To take some examples. Is it possible to know something more concretely of the organization and operation of domestic industries and putting-out systems? I find this question important to the extent that it influences the conditions of the rise of the factories. Are there figures on costs, productivity and earnings? What kind of changes really did occur prior to and parallel with the rise of factories? Can we dig out some concrete information about behaviour as to supply of labour etc.? To me it also seems important to know more about the early factories and I would be prepared to do research on this, since I suspect it would tell us much on how it all started and why. We also need more informa-tion about the wages, productivity and profitability of the factories compared to domestic industries, since such information is evidently very relevant.

Literature Ashton, T.S.: An economic history of England in the 18th century (1955).Ashton, T.S.: An eighteenth century industrialist. Peter Stubs of Warrington 1756–1806

(1939, reprint 1970).Baines, E.: History of the Cotton Manufacture in Great Britain (1836, reprint 1966).Berg, Maxine: The age of manufacture (1985).Bowden, Witt: Industrial society in England toward the end of the eighteenth century

(1925).Chambers, J.D.: Nottinghamshire in the eighteenth century (2nd ed. 1966).

125

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

Chapman, S.J.: The Lancashire cotton industry (1904).Chapman, S.D.: Fixed capital in the British cotton manufacturing industry, in J.P.P. Higgins

– S. Pollard, Aspects of capital investment in Great Britain 1750–1850 (1971).Chapman, S.D.: The early factory masters (1967).Collier, D.: The family economy of the working classes in the cotton industry 1784–1833

(1965).Crafts, N.R.F.: British economic growth during the industrial revolution (1985).Crouzet, F. (ed.): Capital formation in the industrial revolution (1972).Daniels, George W.: The early English factory system (1920).Dobb, M.: Studies in the development of capitalism (1946). Edwards, M.E.: The growth of the British cotton trade 1780–1815 (1967).Fitton, R.S. – Wadsworth, A.P.: The Strutts and the Arkwrights 1758–1830 (1958).Floud, R. – McCloskey, D.M.: The economic history of England since 1700, I (1981).Gaulide, E. (ed.): The Dundee Textile industry 1790–1885. From the papers of Peter

Charmichael of Arthurstone (1969).Gilboy, E.W.: Demand as a factor in the industrial revolution, in A.H. Cole Facts and

factors in economic history (1932).Guest, R.: A compendious history of the cotton manufacture (1823, reprint 1968).Hammond, J.L. and B.: The village labourer 1760–1832 (1911).Hammond, J.L. and B.: The town labourer 1760–1832 (1928). Hartwell, R.M.: The causes of the industrial revolution (Economic History Review,

vol. 18:1, 1965).Heaton, H.: The industrial revolution, in Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences,

vol. VIII, (1933).Honeyman, K.: Origins of enterprise (1983).Howe, A.: The Cotton Masters 1830–1860 (1984).Hudson, Pat: The genesis of industrial capital (1986).James, J.: History of the worsted manufacture in England (1858, reprint 1968).Jenkins, D.T.: The West Riding Wool Textile Industry 1770–1838 (1975).John, A.H.: Aspects of English economic growth in the first half of the eighteenth

century (Economia, May 1961).Kennedy, J.: Observations on the rise and progress of the cotton trade in Great Britain

(1819).Kriedte, P. – Medich, H. – Schlumnohm, J.: Industrialization before industrialization

(1982).Lazonich, W.: Work effort, pay and productivity. Theoretical implications of some

historical research (Harvard University and Barnard College, Oct. 1985).Lipson, E.: The history of the woollen and worsted industries (1920, reprint 1965).Mantoux, P.: The industrial revolution in the eighteenth century (1928).Marx, Karl: Capital, I (1867 and later).Marx, Karl: Zur Kritik der politischen Oekonomie. Manuskripte 1861–1863, 11:3:1:6

(1982).Mathias, P.: The social structure of England in the 18th century (Economic History

Review, vol. X, 1957).McCulloch, J.: Cotton, in A dictionary, practical, theoretical and historical of com-

merce and commercial navigation, I (1834).

126

Bo Gustafsson

McKendrick, N. – Brewer, J. – Plumb, J.H.: The birth of a consumer society. The commercialization of eighteenth-century England (1983).

Moffit, L.W.: England on the eve of the industrial revolution (1925, reprint 1963).Musson, A.E. (ed.): Science, technology and economic growth in the eighteenth cen-

tury (1972).Musson, A.E. – Robinson, E.: Science and technology in the industrial revolution

(1969).Owen, Robert: The Life of Robert Owen by himself (1857, reprint 1920).Pinchbeck, Ivy: Women workers and the industrial revolution (1930).Pollard, S.: The genesis of modern management (1965. ed. 1968). Pollard, S.: Labour in Great Britain (Cambridge Economic History, vol. VII, 1978).Radcliffe, W.: Origin of the new system of manufacture (1820, reprint 1974).Rimmer, W.G.: Marshalls of Leeds. Flax-Spinners 1788–1886 (1960). (Rare for its

extensive series on employment, production, costs, wages, profits, capital stock, fixed and circulating capital etc.)

Rogers, W.H.: Wiltshire and Somerset Woollen Mills (1976).Roll, E.: An early experiment in industrial organization. Being a history of the firm of

Boulton & Watt, 1775–1805 (1930, reprint 1968).Rule, J.: The experience of labour in eighteenth century English industry (1981).Schulze-Gävernitz, G. von: Der Grossbetrieb. Eine Studie auf dem Gebiet der Baum-

wollindustrie (1892).Smelser, N.: Social change in the industrial revolution. An application of theory to the

Lancashire cotton industry 1770–1840 (1959).Styles, John: Embezzlement, industry and the law in England 1500–1800, in M. Berg

– P. Hudson – M. Sonnenscher, Manufacture in town and country before the fac-tory (1983).

Tann, Jennifer: The employment of power in the West-of-England Wool textile in-dustry 1790–1840, in N.B. Harte – K.G. Pouting, Textile history and economic history (1973).

Tunzlemann, G.N. von: Steam power and the British industrialization to 1860 (1978).Tupling, G.H.: The economic history of Rossendale (1927). Unwin, George: Samuel Oldknow and the Arkwrights (1924). Ure, A.: The philosophy of manufacture (1835, reprint 1967). Ure, A.: The cotton manufacture of Great Britain, I–II (1836, reprint 1970).Wadsworth, A. P. – Mann, J. de L.: The cotton trade and industrial Lancashire

1600–1780 (1931).

127

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

Appendix 1: Some suggestions as to how the problem of the transition from putting-out industries to factories may be approached

1. Since the factory system conquered the industrial world between 1750 and 1900, originating in England, the rise and multiplication of factories in dif-ferent countries must have been determined by some common, very general, powerful and, historically speaking, newly introduced causes. It is the task of the project to track down, define and analyse the mode of operation of those causes and bring forth convincing empirical evidence for the truth of the explanation presented.

2. How to begin? Since even economic history according to my opinion is essentially a discipline of cumulative knowledge, we should take as the point of departure the present state of research on the problem. a) Which are the most promising avenues of research? b) Can we define a reasonably secured store of generally acknowledged general facts? c) Which are the main gaps in our knowledge and understanding of the problem? d) Do the main explana-tions advanced really have identical aims, scope and level of generality? Are they competing and/or supplementary and if so to what extent? Some exam-ples. Sometimes debate is confused because the participants move on different levels of generality. As a consequence arguments may be advanced which are not to the point, because they may be relevant for a concrete case but not for a more general phenomenon. Sometimes conditions of the existence of fac-tories are confused with conditions of the timing of their introduction (early in one industry, late in another). Such differences may be important for the understanding of the phenomenon studies but are of a different nature. Some-times necessary and sufficient conditions are not accounted for. E.g. Marglin seems to regard control of labour as a sufficient condition for the existence of factories, although it is rather a necessary condition or an effect of other conditions. There existed centralized workplaces before the factories proper. The differentia specifica of factories was that they combined centralized pro-duction with new energy machines and new working machines. Why should capitalists have utilized e.g. steam engines and lathes to control labour?

3. I have the impression that different positions as to the fundamental causality in regard to the transition from putting-out to the factory system are to a considerable extent determined by the value orientation, the research tradition and/or the temporary accepted research trend of the researchers involved. Observers of the 18th century were impressed by the marvels of the

128

Bo Gustafsson

division of labour. In the early 19th century observers took it as a matter of fact that the rise of factories was conditioned by steam-power and machines because of the cost-reducing effects. Ricardian socialists and Marx introduced the conditioning effects of class power. The early practitioners of economic history — from Mantoux to Ashton — upheld and deepened the early 19th century notions. Some re-discoverers of Marxism revived one-sided interpreta-tions of the Marxian standpoint. Contemporary transaction costs economists have similarly one-sidedly applied a Coasean approach. And today it is à la mode to engulf economic structure and processes into more or less vaguely defined social and cultural processes. Depending upon the choice of standpoint and research tradition, problem formulation, questions asked, hypotheses advanced and demands on what constitutes a scientific explanation, various aspects of the problem have been investigated and various results have poured down like fall-out.

I think it is important that the participants of the project try to lay bare the respective underlying meta-scientific notions in order to make an orderly and rational communication possible. Let me squarely state my own fundamental point of departure. 1) In progressive modes of production like those which have dominated the West European scene since the introduction of generalized commodity production (the three historical bursts coming around the 12th, the 16th and — most important — the 18th centuries) concomitant upon likewise increasing levels of division of labour and productivity of labour, the two fundamental laws of economic behaviour are, on the one hand, the law of the progressive development of human needs and, on the other hand, the law of economizing of time (first propounded by Marx in his Grundrisse). These laws operate in different conditions of relations of production and class power, as well as in different cultural and national contexts, which determine the concrete modes of operation. But in contradistinction to e. g. Asiatic societies, the growth of productive powers and of human needs, although halted and twisted for considerable time periods, are never ultimately blocked by en-trenched relations of production and of class power cemented by likewise entrenched cultural values and traditions. It is precisely this difference which gives the clue to the differentia specifica of the so-called Western Industrial Society. The implications of the above-mentioned two fundamental laws are, first, that more is preferred to less, more useful to less useful and the cheaper to the more expensive. (Vide the success of barchent cloth in the late Middle Ages to the despair of traditional woollen cloth producers or the success of cotton cloth of different qualities in the late 18th century so vividly described by Pinchbeck.) Secondly, a premium is put on cost-reductions in general and cost-reducing inventions in particular, leading to ruthless exploitation of labour as well as to technological progress. Thus we have to keep in mind the utility as well as the value aspect of economic processes. To be sure, the advent of the factory system was conditioned upon and extended the power of one class over another. But it did so because the new relations of production

129

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

were based upon the fact that the new mode of production served human needs more efficiently than the preceding ones. If we do not accept this standpoint we are in for serious trouble in the research process and I do not know how the conceptual apparatus should look which is not based upon some fundamental assumption about the rationality of the economic agents; or which assumes that economic behaviour and change is mainly determined by cultural values and/or traditions.

4. Since the factory system arose in several countries and regions at differ-ent intervals and under different economic, social and cultural conditions we should try to give some attention to the diversity of the change, the more so since our group is internationally constituted and a comparative approach can give insights into the general problematic. Still I think we have to lay bare the essence of the putting-out and factory system, respectively, in order to be able to handle the enormous analytical and empirical problems involved:

a) Probably we should not forget to concentrate on “classical cases” as when Marx chose England as the locus classicus for the analysis of the genesis, structure and behaviour of industrial capitalism, although from a purely em-pirical point of view this system was an exception in his day; or, as when analysing the rise and behaviour of the craft guilds, those of northern Italy in the Medieval Ages probably should be selected. Should not, from this point of view, the English textile industry (cotton, worsted, wool) be an appropriate main object of study, the more so as this industry is better researched than any other comparable branch?

b) Should we not also prefer to study some cases in depth rather than try to canvas the whole field evenly? Besides textile industries we should probably investigate some “heavy” industries (e.g. iron?), where centralized production existed already before the advent of the factory system. By taking these early instances of centralized production into account we might get an understand-ing of what centralization per se implied and presupposed. (It occurs to me that Aiken sometime in the late 18th century suggested that centralization per se in the Yorkshire textile manufacture increased productivity by a third — see Pat Hudson, Genesis, p. 71).

c) We should, likewise, try to isolate representative “progressive” histor-ical cases of the transition from secondary or “parasitic” cases. The choice between centralized and decentralized modes of production seems to be a per-manent one in many different historical conditions and societies depending upon a multitude of concrete circumstances like type of product produced and of the process of production, constraints on organizational capacities, scale effects, existence of surplus pockets of labour power, relative wage levels, varying customs and traditions (vide the English hand-loom weaver who out of pride preferred to starve rather than go — or let his children go — to the factories). We should probably find some such general a-historical conditions in our historical problem but we should first of all not lose sight of the specific historical circumstances in our project.

130

Bo Gustafsson

d) One of the most difficult points is to start from a convenient and rele-vant definition of “putting-out system” and “factory” respectively. I am no friend of long discussions of definitions isolated from empirical examples and we will probably find that our definitions have to be reworked during the course of our studies so that the proper definition will be a result rather than the starting point of research. Here I suspect that our greatest problem will be associated with the putting-out system. In the first place we have the agricultural connection. Dobb following Marx suggested in his “Studies” — if I do not err — that the putting-out workers represented a barrier to capital-ist factory production, since they possessed some means of production and hence represented an inelastic supply of labour-power resulting in a smaller surplus for the employer, a higher relative rate of wages and the well-known backward-bending supply curve of labour-power. Hence capitalist factories presupposed free labour-power and an ensuing elastic supply of labour-power and a lower rate of wages. There seems to be a good case for this standpoint. Many have stressed the high rate of growth of free labour-power in the British case from the end of the 18th century and the enormous consequences of the enclosures and the dissolution of the commons.

But on the other hand, precisely these things have also been played down by other researchers, who also have stressed that the wage rates of putting-out workers were lower than those of factory workers and that many putting-out workers before the advent of the factories were proletarians with very limited plots of land rather than agricultural producers with industry as a side-line occupation. These putting-out workers were rather locked-in in their occupa-tions — by force or by choice — and the existence of a side-line occupation did not increase their bargaining power but rather made them prepared to accept very low wages. In some cases the putting-out workers seem, indeed, to have been very poor, in other cases they seem to have been comparatively pros-perous. How do we handle this problem, which seems to be very central to a relevant definition of the structure and characteristics of a putting-out system? Our understanding of the transition to the factory system obviously to a great extent depends upon our knowledge of the relative profitability of the two systems and whether labour power was forced to take up factory employment or preferred to do so. Sometimes when studying cursory data on the wages of putting-out workers — which usually seem to be lower than those of factory workers — one may wonder what wage rates quoted, e.g. weekly wages, real-ly represented. Maybe putting-out workers received lower monetary weekly wages, because they worked fewer hours per week? On the other hand, since data also often show enormous rates of increase of productivity by transitions from e.g. handcraft processes to machine processes it would be natural to assume that machine workers (here = factory workers) were paid higher wage rates, still leaving a higher rate of surplus value and profits to the factory owner (the essence of factory production being a higher rate of relative sur-

131

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

plus value). To sum up: how should we model the typical putting-out system preceding the transition to factories?

When it comes to the proper definition of “factory” we should devote at tention to the classic problem of the difference between manufacture and factory. Would it be possible to state squarely that a factory is a) a centralized locus of production, where b) the energy input is mechanical (not restricted by the vagaries of water supplies or animal traction) plus c) machines which to a considerable extent have replaced the movements of the human hand?

5. After having determined our object of analysis (our “ideal type”) and our objects of research (the ideal type with suitable concrete qualities) we should, I suggest, start by describing and analysing the states of organizational structure and behaviour at certain points of time, e.g. 1750, 1800, 1850 and 1900 and make preliminary hypothetical linkages between on the one hand the prevailing organizational structures and, on the other hand, certain vari-ables — to begin with perhaps intuitively selected — like utilized technology, type of products, type of production processes, organization of work, origins and character of labour, marketing and demand, profitability, relative costs, industry structure, financing and growth. Is it possible to relate empirically, on the one hand, changes in organizational structure to changes in some of the variables in an essential way? Such a description would furnish us with some kind of empirical framework suitable for sorting out real from possible worlds.

6. When describing structure and change in our representative industries we should also try to connect these changes to the broad macro-economic changes of the period. In the ideal case the changes in our industries should be related to and part of the following broader changes:

a) the rise of a free and mobile labour power, as a mass phenomenon, seeking employment, being one condition of centralized production.

b) another condition being the existence of investible funds necessitated by the larger investments in mechanical centralized loci of production (if facto-ries were not capital saving!).

c) further, the introduction of new sources of energy — primarily coal-fuelled steam engines — requiring centralized production, requesting larger outlays of investment and allowing larger and more continuous energy input. (Vide the decentralization of industrial units around 1900 consequent upon the introduction of electric energy machines!).

d) also, the continuous introduction of inter-related mechanical machines into the process of production allowing increased specialization and division of tasks and effecting increased productivity, decreased value of labour power, continuous mass production and improved and more even quality of products.

e) the saving of labour and the intensification of the utilization of labour-power by means of d) and by the increased possibilities of control of labour.

132

Bo Gustafsson

f) mass production and mass marketing for the general public of cheap consumption goods making continuous production more important than be-fore and thereby also more closely linking production and marketing.

g) increased competition between producers making continuous techno-logical change more important and necessary for survival.

h) an increased profitability of capital.i) the increasing importance of fixed capital (at least in the long run).j) an increased rate of growth of production and of consumption.7. How are these — or maybe other — structural traits of the period essen-

tially linked to the great organizational transition from putting-out sys tems to factories? Granted that the catalogue of factors indicated above are rel-evant, should we not expect some kind of causal links between those gen-eral phenomena on the one hand and, on the other hand, the equally general phenomenon of the transition to the factory system? The problem will be how to establish the linkages. I think they are very complicated. Take for example the Smithian hypothesis of widening markets as the most fundamental con-dition. It seems to be fairly well-established by much research that domestic production in general and putting-out production in particular expanded from the 16th century on (with interruptions) because of widening markets, not the least international markets. But what does “widening markets” mean? Increas-ing demand originating from an increasing per capita product? Or in creased demand spatially because of decreased transportation costs? Or increasing demand because of substitution effects in consequence of lowered production costs? Or because of the introduction of new more useful products? When cotton industries expanded from the late 18th century the basic reason seems to have been the qualities of the products meeting mass needs of at least the middle classes (to begin with). But later on, when the new product had been widely accepted, further expansion was propelled by improved quality, cost reductions and intensified competition. What is now cause and what is effect? Maybe technological change becomes the most important cause of the widen-ing of markets?

With these remarks I will just point out that the explanation searched for simply cannot be one pointing to technological change, control of labour or transaction costs pure and simple. It must rather, after having isolated the most important conditions and causes, attempt to show how the different causal forces were interrelated. Only by doing this, I think, can our project ad vance the state of research on the problem of the transition from putting-out industries to factories.

8. What is needed with respect to evidence and empirical proof? What should be requested in this respect? As always in historical research we will have to move on a modest level. We will find that some questions cannot be answered. Probably this applies to the most interesting questions — as always. I would suggest three things. First, that we devote attention to the formulation of testable implications of our hypothesis. Suppose that we make the hypothesis

133

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

that putting-out industries were abandoned and factories established because of increased cost-differentials and that these cost-differentials were caused by transaction costs of different kinds in putting-out (distribution and collecting of products, embezzlement and what not) as a consequences of an increased scale of operation. This hypothesis would generate a series of testable hypotheses:

1) that transaction costs were lower in industries with a smaller scale of operation, 2) that firms with a larger scale of operation, ceteris paribus, hade larger transaction costs than firms with more restricted scales of operation, 3) that a given firm which increases its scale of operations experiences larger transaction costs etc. I give this simple example just to indicate the idea. If we are lucky we may perhaps be able to formulate at least some weak form of testable hypotheses which may make some weak form of testing possible on the basis of an empirical material. Second, that we try to find some cases with good sources where there is a concrete link between a former putting-out organization and a factory. If this is a good and fairly representative case, we may take it as an example of some more general trend. Thirdly, that we combine micro and macro studies in order to be able to arrive at an expla-nation that may capture the concrete as well as the abstract and the internal mechanisms as well as the broad conditioning factors.

9. When we approach the problem of “stylized facts” we have to find some common norm of evaluation. Given a specific industry — and I am aware of the fact that organizational forms vary between different industries — it seems to me that “a stylized fact” must capture both quantitative and quantitative aspects even if they are contradictory. If we find that at a given point in time 2/3 of the workers in an industry were employed in some kind of putting-out industries, it would still be possible to state — on the assumption that the re-maining 1/3 of the workers in the industry are employed in factories — that the factory system is dominating, if we were to find, e.g., that a) the share of employed workers in the factories is rapidly increasing, while the share of putting-out workers rapidly decreases, b) that the capital invested in factories surpasses the capital invested in putting-out industries, c) that factories rapidly wring market shares from putting-out industries, and/or putting-out industries in various ways are dependent upon factories. In this example the qualitative aspects are that you judge the situation at a specific point of time also from the point of view of the future and that aspects of dominance and/or power (capital, markets) are taken into account. If we only judge a situation from the point of view of qualitative aspects I think we may misjudge a situation (as I think Clapham once did in the first volume of his magnum opus on the industrial revolution in Britain).

10. How are we going to tackle the aspects of economic factors versus cul-tural (broadly speaking) factors, markets and technology versus class struggle and efficiency versus distribution issues? When it comes to the first mentioned aspect, i.e. economic versus cultural factors, it seems reasonable to me, first, that cultural traditions had a greater impact on behaviour in the beginning

134

Bo Gustafsson

of our period than later, the simple(-minded) assumption being that cultural traditions are progressively broken down in the course of industrialization; secondly, that cultural factors may modify (advance or block) the operation of the economic factors for some time but not perpetually. I am afraid that this will sound like vulgar marxism at its worst. Therefore, I would appreciate some convincing counter-arguments. Maybe the technology-markets versus class struggle issue is a sub-set of the afore-mentioned problem. It is plain that industrial change broadly speaking was influenced by the class struggle, as Maxine Berg convincingly has shown. But how and to what extent and how should we assess the results in our approach? I hope that Amit Bhaduri, who has thought much about this problem in other contexts, will be able to sharpen our thoughts. The class struggle is important not primarily because of machine-breaking activity but because successful organization and mobiliza-tion influence the distribution of the net product and, hence, profitability and accumulation.

11. This brings me to the efficiency/distribution issue. Broadly speaking the learned opinion seems to be divided on the question of whether the main emphasis should be placed on productivity or on profitability when ex plaining the success of the factory system. I think we must think deeply on this issue. To begin with, what do we know about objective functions? Should we assume that putters-out and factory owners tried to maximize profits or what? And, if profits, was it total profits, profit shares or profit rates? And what about the putting-out workers? Should we assume that they tried to earn some kind of a customary standard of living, did they try to maximize the average income of the households or what? Clearly the choice of assumption will influence the analysis and results. Secondly, should we analyse the issue from the point of view of the putter-out/capitalist as the main actor, or, should we look upon the decisions made also from the point of view of the workers? (See the class struggle issue above.) Thirdly, what are the appropriate assumptions on the relationship between profitability and productivity? In a fully developed capi-talist system with a reasonably high degree of competition and technical and organizational progress we should assume, at least for the long run, a positive association between profitability and productivity: given a certain average level of profitability at a specific point of time, the introduction of a more productive technical or organizational process increases the profitability of the firm that makes the innovation. But under other assumptions this positive association is not obvious. Suppose that the degree of monopoly in input and/or output markets is high and that technological progress is slow. In such a situation the association between profitability and productivity need not be positive. I suppose that the sweating industries are a case in point. Further-more, in putting-out industries where the direct producers could influence the work-process, one can imagine that they reacted against an increasing rate of exploitation by lowering labour input, deteriorating product quality and/or by embezzling raw materials and final output. Maybe, we could in this case re-

135

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

present the issues as in the following figure, where (s/Y) is the rate of surplus value of the putter-out/capitalist and (Y/L) is the productivity of labour. At high rates of surplus value the productivity of the putting-out workers is low and vice versa, while there is a positive relationship between the rate of sur-plus value and productivity in the case of factory workers. (Furthermore, the direction of causality is different in the two modes of production: an increased rate of surplus value leading to lower real wages is assumed to cause a lowe-red level of labour productivity in the case of the putting-out workers, while an increased rate of surplus value is an effect of an increased productivity in the case of the factory workers).

Comment to the figure: (1) At given levels of productivity, putting-out is superior to factories as a system of exploitation when productivity is low (Y/L)'; while factories are superior as a system of exploitation, when the level of productivity is high (Y/L)''. (2) At given rates of exploitation, the productivity of putting-out is higher than that of factories when the rate of exploitation is low (s/Y)'; while the productivity of factories is superior to that of putting-out, when the rate of exploitation is high (s/Y)''. At (Y/L)* the two systems are in equilibrium (equally competitive). To the left of (Y/L)* putting-out is superior to factories as a system of exploitation, while the opposite holds for levels of productivity to the right of (Y/L)*. The argument may be primitive. But the point I want to make is that we should strive to capture both efficiency and power aspects in (integrate them into) our analysis.

Maybe it would be possible to list “merits” and “drawbacks” of the putting-out sys-tem and the factory system respectively, from the point of view of surplus production and/or productivity. Would a systematic investigation of such a balance and its devel-opment over time, industry for industry, be a worth-while approach?

�𝑠𝑠𝑌𝑌�

�𝑠𝑠𝑌𝑌�"

1Factory

Putting-out

�𝑠𝑠𝑌𝑌�'

�𝑌𝑌𝐿𝐿�' �𝑌𝑌𝐿𝐿�

"�𝑌𝑌𝐿𝐿�*

�𝑌𝑌𝐿𝐿�

136

Bo Gustafsson

CHARACTERISTICS PUTTING-OUT FACTORIES

Merits Draw-backs Merits Draw-backs

Objective function: X XRisk of investment X XLevel of investment: X XLabour costs X(?) XCapital costs: X XLevel of stocks X XAssembling costs: X X Length of production period: X XDegree of specialization: X XQuality control: X XTransaction costs: X XSecurity of property rights: X XTechnical progress: X XEfficiency of decision-making: X XRegularity of production: X XTurnover time of capital: X X

In passing one may note that Sombart thought that the putting-out system had a disadvantage vis-à-vis factories, since factories made collective action possible.

But this presupposes on the one hand, that labour in fact was organized in the early factories while not organized in domestic industries. And should not on the other hand the existence of some property-owning have increased the bargaining power of domestic workers compared to factory proletarians?

137

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

Wid

enin

g m

arke

ts

Incr

easin

g di

visio

n of

labo

ur

Mec

hani

zatio

n (o

f the

labo

ur p

roce

ss a

nd o

f ene

rgy

inpu

t)

Savi

ng o

n ca

pita

l

Mor

e ra

pid

turn

-ove

r of c

apita

l (tim

e of

pr

oduc

tion

& sa

les

decr

ease

d)

Decr

ease

d co

sts o

f tra

nspo

rtat

ion

of m

ater

ial

inpu

ts, t

houg

h-pu

ts a

nd o

ut-p

uts

Fact

ory

syst

em

Incr

ease

d po

ssib

ilitie

s of

con

trol

and

util

izatio

n of

labo

ur p

ower

Redr

istrib

utio

n of

net

-pro

duct

from

labo

ur to

cap

ital (

high

ter p

rofit

abili

ty o

f cap

ital

A hi

gher

rate

of i

nves

tmet

A hi

gher

rate

of g

row

th o

f pro

duct

ion

Desk

illin

g of

labo

ur

(Sav

ing

on h

uman

cap

ital)

Incr

easin

g pr

oduc

tivity

of l

abou

r

Decl

inin

g w

age

shar

e

Not

e: T

his

pict

ure

is in

tend

ed a

s a s

impl

istic

pie

ce o

f pro

voca

tion

and

disr

egar

ds w

holly

any

pos

sible

mer

its o

f the

put

ting-

out s

yste

m. F

urth

er, i

t has

not

hing

to s

ay o

n al

l tho

se c

ases

whe

n pu

ttin

g-ou

t sys

tem

s lin

gere

d on

or a

rose

in in

dust

ries

with

sta

gnan

t dem

and.

SOM

E PO

SSIB

LE F

ACTO

RS IN

THE

TR

ANSI

TIO

N FR

OM

THE

PU

TTIN

G-SY

STEM

TO

FAC

TORI

ES

138

Bo Gustafsson

Appendix 2: A note on the concept of factory and on factory employment in England 1840.

1. Firstly, is it suitable to define “factory” preliminarily as I have done in my paper (as a relation of production; as a specific form of organization; and as a technological entity with the main emphasis on the first mentioned aspect); and also to see the factory as a process successively taking on its attributes until we are met with the full-fledged factory? If so it should be possible to define certain stages in the rise of the factories (forms of proto-factories). But how do we treat those centralized forms of production, which existed very early, e.g. iron-works. When does an iron-work become a factory? It starts out as a unit with centralized production and wage-labour (in paternalistic forms). Do the iron-works become factories, when machinery replacing hand labour enters? Does this also apply to potteries, which in England utilized mainly hand labour as late as in the 1840’s?

2. Secondly, if you consider that the factories were superior in productivity and profitability compared to domestic industries (with or without a putting-out superstructure) in so many respects (labour utilization, labour costs, capi-tal costs, capital turnover, control of labour, product quality and what not) it seems to be that we are confronted with two problems: a) the explanation on efficiency considerations becomes over-determined (we have more explana-tory variables than we really need) and b) how should we relate the different explanatory variables to each other?

3. Thirdly, an early empirical work on the factory system in England by Hsien-Ting Fang, “The triumph of the factory system in England” (1930, reprint Porcupine Press Philadelphia 1978), has canvassed an enormous mate-rial mainly pertaining to the 1840’s.

Fang divides manufacturing industry into Factory System (FS), Merchant Employment System (MES, equivalent to Putting-Out System) and Craftsman System (CS). I have tried to systematize his findings on a separate sheet (see below). He also makes a number of different interesting points, for example:

1) In cotton factories profitability was more influenced by capital/output ratios than by profit shares, i.e. while profit shares did not vary much, cap-ital/output ratios did. 2) Hand-loom factories actually increased in numbers around 1840. 3) Centralization + supervision in hand-loom manufacturing could increase the productivity of labour by 100–300 per cent. 4) The causes of the late mechanization in the woollen industries were: a) the resistance of the weavers, b) rapid changes in demand and in fashion, c) the necessity of

139

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

having loosely spun yarn in fulling, and d) the acceptance of wage cutting on the part of the weavers. 5) Hand-loom factories in woollen manufacture were concentrated to the West Countries (especially Gloustershire), where the merchant employer system was strongly entrenched, in contradistinction to Yorkshire, were the craftsman system was strong. The craftsmen in Yorkshire responded to the advent of factories by founding cooperative joint-stock mills. 6) Embezzlement is always the other side of the system of short wages and was frequent in the West Counties but not in Yorkshire. That is, the weaker the position of the workers, the more frequent was embezzlement. This was a powerful incentive for manufacturers to centralize labour, since this made it possible for them to control the labour share! It was precisely because of this that piece rate wages were practiced in the merchant employer system. Possibly, piece rates in factories were a complement (working on incentives) to direct control. 7) In iron and some other heavy industries the factory system is conditioned by the scale of minimum investments and technological con-siderations. 8) In consumer goods industries factory production presupposes standardization of products making large-scale production possible. This is just a sample of interesting observations in Fang’s book, which of course is not theoretical at all.

140

Bo Gustafsson

The State of the Factory System in England around 1840

Covering 50 per cent of manufacturing. Source: Fang (1930) By-employment not accounted for.Factory System (FS), Merchant Employer System (MES) and Craftsman System (CS)

I. FACTORY EMPLOYMENT OF PRIMARY IMPORTANCEIndustries Total Employment Factory Employment ShareCotton, Flax,Hemp, Silk,Worsted, Woollen,Paper, Pottery, Ca. 610 000 Ca. 432 000 70% Glass, Iron,Engine & Machines,Buttons,pins,screw etc.

II. FACTORY EMPLOYMENT SECONDARY IN IMPORTANCEIndustries Total Employment Factory Employment Share Cutlery,Anchor & Chain, Ca. 100 000 Ca. 10 000 10% Ribbon, Hosiery,Hat, Glove

III. FACTORY EMPLOYMENT OF TERTIARY IMPORTANCEIndustries Total Employment Factory Employment ShareClock & Watch, Gun, Wearingapparel, Lace, Ca. 275 000 Ca. 15 000 5%Lock & Key, Straw Plate

TOTALS Ca. 985 000 Ca. 457 000 45%

Comment: 1) In Group I, the MES is in most cases the second most important form of organization in all textiles except woollens, while the CS is next in importance in pottery, glass, engines & machines and button etc. 2) In Group II, where factories are second in importance, there is no CS except in cutlery, i.e. the MES dominates all branches, from cutlery to glove. 3) In Group III, where factories are less developed, the CS seems to dominate. The MES is the most important form of organization in clock & watch and in guns (with the craftsman system second), while the craftsman system (partly family craftsman system) dominates in wearing apparel, lace, lock & key and straw plate.

Thus there seems to be some structure in the evolution: 1) The factory system develops on the basis of putting-out systems, while factories arrive latest where the craftsman system still exists. 2) Further, factories are more developed the more mass markets in standardized products (mass demand) develop, while craftsman production mainly caters for local or non-mass demand. 3) Lastly, it is evident, if we like Fang define factories mainly by concentration of employment, that also “heavy industries” are characterized by the early arrival of factories.

141

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

Appendix 3: Why were wages lower in domestic industries than in factories?

It is generally assumed that the wage rates of factory labour were higher than in domestic industries during the industrial revolution, at least from the late 18th century (for evidence, see above). I am aware of the fact that this propo-sition is debatable on various grounds: difficulties of defining wages, lack of sufficient evidence etc.

From the point of view of neoclassical economics the proposition should perhaps be unproblematic: wage rates were higher in factories simply because the (marginal) productivity of labour was higher. The marginal and average productivity of labour were probably higher in factories than in domestic industries. But wage rates are also influenced by supply conditions.

Now, labour was difficult to recruit — in spite of the higher wage rates — and this should also have contributed to the higher wage rates. But this also in-dicates that the efficiency wage rates in factory employment, even if they were higher than in domestic industries, were not high enough after all to compensate for more intensive labour, for worse labour conditions and for the authoritarian discipline of factory labour. At least, the difference in wage rates, according to this view, is formal rather than real. Others think that the important aspect of factory wages, from the point of view of the employees, was not wage rates but family income. Since factory labour did not always imply the employment of whole families in factories, factory wage rates had to be higher than wage rates in domestic industries and, still, factory family income may have been lower than in domestic industries.6

From the point of view of traditional Marxian political economy, the proposition that wage rates in the factory were higher than in domestic in-dustries presents a problem. This is because of the following circumstance. The existence of some means of existence (property) besides industrial labour (side-line activities, plots, gardens, commons, cattle etc.) should have made the supply of labour of domestic industrialists rather inelastic compared to factory labourers, who more or less were pure proletarians. Thus, from the point of view of supply conditions the wage rates of factory labour should have been lower than in domestic industries. But they were not.6 On the other hand, some observers believe that factory labour, in spite of lower wage rates, offered more regular employment than domestic of industries and, thus, higher wage incomes. Bill Lazonick emphasizes that the higher productivity of factory labour in combination with more intensive labour (increased labour effort) made possible higher wage income (and larger profits, too), (in spite of the fact that wage rates were lowered?).

142

Bo Gustafsson

Here I will submit the assertion that the lower wage rates in domestic indus-tries might partially be explained by the fact that labour in domestic industries was an intermittently free good. The fact that labour is an intermittently free good in primary production (agriculture etc.), where labour during the year is utilized mainly during spring, summer and autumn, as in Western Europe, was pointed out long ago by Eli F. Heckscher, the Swedish economic historian. In Sweden, at least, winter time was the period of “winter sleep”. In the absence of complementary productive activities like wood-cutting, hunting etc. labour had no economic value.

Probably, this fact (guild control in the cities is another) may explain why domestic industries arose as side-line activities in the countryside. But it also made very low wage rates possible in domestic industries, especially where primary production gave insufficient subsistence. If we to begin with assume that producers of all sorts were satisfiers, i.e. that they wanted to attain a certain level of real income, e.g. traditional subsistence, only those primary producers who were too poor to reach that level were candidates for domestic industries (assuming that rich primary producers did not choose to specialize in domestic industries because their labour was more productive there). If we assume that producers of all sorts were maximisers of real income, also those primary producers who in fact gained their subsistence would have been inter-ested in supplementing this income by devoting some part of their free labour to domestic industries, up to the point where the additional utility of additional real income balanced the additional disutility of effort and reduced leisure.

In any case the result would have been that primary producers, thanks to the fact that their labour was an intermittently free good, were prepared to supply labour during the periods when their labour was a free good to wage rates that were inferior to the wage rates of those workers who were forced to make a living only on industrial labour. As suggested above the propensity to accept very low wage rates must have been especially strong for poor primary producers unable to earn minimum subsistence. For them leisure was of zero value and any additional real income from additional labour should have been a net addition to utility. The more well-off the primary producers were, the higher was the value they put on leisure and the higher the wage rates in domestic industry had to be to induce an increased labour supply.

If this conception is true, several consequences follow. In the first place, domestic industries as side-line activities in primary production would not be found in primary production, which is more or less continuous during the year, granted that domestic industries are not a result of comparative advantage. Secondly, we should expect a rough correlation between on the one hand the length of the periods of “winter sleep” in primary production and the exten-sion of domestic industrial pursuits (once again granted that the existence of domestic industries is not conditioned by comparative advantage). Thirdly, wage rates in domestic industries should, ceteris paribus, roughly vary with the conditions of existence of primary producers, i.e. the poorer they were, the

143

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

lower wage rates they would accept and vice versa. A corollary of the last two propositions is that domestic industries should be most extensive the longer the periods of “winter sleep” and the poorer the primary producers (demand condition aside).

Perhaps this mechanism may also cast light on the problem of sweating industries during the 19th century, i.e. the fact that certain branches of domestic industry could survive in spite of paying very low wages and offering very bad conditions of work. Without possessing special knowledge about sweating industries in general, I have the impression that one of its condition of existence might have been the existence of labour, e.g. married women partially “employed” in households, who accepted out-work in sweating industries because it signified additional income to the households of poor male labourers and who were thus prepared to work for very low rates. Also in this case labour was, in a sense, an intermittently free good, if household chores and child care — given the prevailing gender system — intermittently tied women to the households. Maybe this also explains why domestic industries could survive so long, side by side with factories.

Lastly, one may ask how and why this mechanism stopped operating on a general scale and in an historical perspective. We have seen that domestic industries were given basic conditions of existence as long as primary produc-ers could not earn a sufficient income in primary production and other sources of rewarding employment did not exist aside from domestic industries. With the growth and development of the factory system, based on continuously rising productivity and the growing strength of organized labour, real wages in factory production more and more left domestic industries behind. Further, the on-going industrialization increased the social division of labour and multi-plied employment opportunities outside primary production. Even pri mary production itself underwent a process of industrialization. Thereby the con-ditions of existence of low wage domestic industries eroded.

P.S. The discussion above has, of course, several limitations. In the first place, it does not refer to domestic industries, wherein the producers were mainly occupied by industrial production and had primary production as a sideline activity, although even those categories would have been prepared to accept low wage rates in view of the existence of supplementary income from the sidelines. Secondly, wage rates may have been lower in domestic industries because labour skills usually were lower. Thirdly and most import-ant, the concept of wage rate should be defined more precisely (per unit of output or per unit of time unit?) As suggested above, the distinction between wages as rates and as income is also important — the former being crucial for employers’ output decisions and the second crucial for workers’ employment decisions. While “wages” may have been higher in factories, “wage rates” may have been lower!

144

Bo Gustafsson

Appendix 4: Notes on Marx and the transition to the factory system

In his paper on “Theory and History in Marx’s Economics” (published in Alexander J. Field, The future of economic history (1987)) William Lazonick contrasts Marx’s construction of the transition to the factory system with some very important empirical facts from British historical industrial reality. Lazonick has certainly a very good point in emphasizing that Marx, firstly, overestimated the importance of manufactures and underestimated the importance of domestic industries as precursors of the factory system. Likewise, that Marx probably put a too strong emphasis on technological change in the same transition. There are, however, two major points to be elucidated somewhat more than was possible in a short article like Lazonick’s. In the first place, I think, Marx put such a strong emphasis on technical change because this was qualitatively new in the late 18th and the early 19th centuries compared to what existed before. It is a fact that Watt’s second edition of the new steam-engine was of revolutionary importance with its separate con-denser, its double-acting working and its rotary motion. Thereby was born that universal prime-mover of machinery which made the generalization of the factory principle a technical and economic possibility. The steam engine was a symbolic representation of a very general phenomenon. There was a qualitative new stage in technological development occurring at this time in very many fields and in many countries and this new qualitative stage should by no means be underestimated. A reading of Marx’s manuscripts from 1861–63 (written between Grundrisse and Capital, I) makes it clear that Marx had studied 18th and 19th technological history very carefully (as also Nathan Rosenberg noted on the basis only of Capital, I). Secondly I am not wholly convinced that Marx did not understand that the traditional manufactures were not the real point of departure for the factory system. After all he explicitly states that the manufactures furnished a too slim basis for the factory system. So why were the manufactures important? Because the division of labour and the concentration of labour-power in the manufactures from an analytical point of view were a precondition for the factory system. This way of looking at development problems is perhaps conditioned by Marx’s theory of science. He insisted on analysing history from both an abstract — logical — and a concrete — historical — point of view. The logical and the historical aspects are both necessary for a full understanding of change and development. The historical aspect shows us history in all its complexity, bifurcations and

145

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

twisted turns, while the logical aspect abstracts from all this and shows us the basic mechanics and stages of change. Since manufactures possessed two characteristics of the later factory system in undeveloped form (division of labour and concentration of workers) manufactures were logical and thus in a sense historical development forms preceding and conditioning the factories. Furthermore, even if manufacturers usually were not the empirical point of departure for factories in England they frequently were in continental and northern Europe.

II

Before I started to read Lazonick’s paper, I re-read Marx myself (Capital, I), in addition to his manuscripts from 1861–1863 (Zur Kritik der politischen Oekonomie (Manuskript 1861–63). Gesamtausgabe II:3.1 and II:3.6 (Berlin 1976 and 1982, respectively when they were published for the first time). These manuscripts contain Theories of Surplus Value (previously published), but the two volumes I refer to sandwich the Theories (to Marx the Theories were a parenthesis in his works on the next last version of Capital.) They are interesting reading because in them we may follow Marx’s way of researching in contradistinction to his way of presentation. In the following I will first summarize the analytical back-bone of what Marx has to say on the transition mechanisms (often implicit) in Capital I, since there are some subtle notions there which Lazonick probably had no space to deal with. After this I will add some material from the manuscripts. The aim is to try to reconstruct the logic of Marx’s reasoning.

Production of relative surplus value the essence of the factory systemBefore Marx starts with the chapter on Cooperation (chapter 13) in Capital, I, he has elucidated the concept of relative surplus value in the preceding chapter and the entire part IV on machinery and the factory system has as its heading “Production of relative surplus value”. Relative surplus value — this is what modern capitalism is about according to Marx. Why? Because modern capi-talism implies and effects that continuous rise of productivity that the factory system, built on machine technology, brought forth. The factory system with its machinery, according to Marx, also increased absolute surplus value, gen-erally by condensing earlier amorphous labour time and specifically, for a period, by extending the working day. But the essence was a qualitatively new emphasis on the production of relative surplus value because of a new stage of technology.

In chapter 13 on Cooperation Marx stresses the following points. 1) Since concentration of labour-power is the starting point of capitalist production one should start by analysing cooperation. Concentration of labour-power implies to begin with an evening out of product quality and also effecting economies

146

Bo Gustafsson

of constant capital. Per se this cheapens commodities and thus lowers the value of labour power but it also raises the profit rate. 2) Concentration of labour power implies also cooperation, which raises the productivity of labour by the same mechanisms which make it possible for, e.g., three persons together to perform what they cannot perform individually (Umschlag von Quantität zur Qualität) but also because of “the animal spirits” that increase the efficiency of labour. I think anybody who has worked in a factory can confirm the correctness of this observation. When several people work together they stimulate each other to performances which they do not make individually and this irrespective of other circumstances. (By the way, the same mechanism operates in a working group of intellectuals, e.g. in a seminar. If it were not for this, intellectuals would never consider working together!) Concretely Marx refers to three factors operating in this: a) a lowered time of transportation when moving objects, b) an improved perception of what is going on and c) an allocation of tasks according to capabilities. Concentration of labour, thus, implies cooperation and is, at least, a necessary condition of cooperation. (As Lazonick points out, Marx later perceived that cooperation is possible without concentration of labour — as e.g. in putting-out industries or in other forms of organization. But we may agree that far-reaching cooperation in operations tied to a specific place, e.g. with a stationary steam-engine, necessitates con-centration of labour. This before the advent of the communication in dus-tries!) 3) From these observations Marx goes on and inquires about the effects of cooperation. These are: a) any single capitalist must mobilize a larger minimum sum of capital for variable as well as for constant capital, ceteris paribur; b) the concentration and cooperation of labour further makes supervision necessary. Some supervision (monitoring) would be necessary in collective work irrespective of the prevailing relations of production, e.g. by mutual supervision against shirking (before men have become angels). But the antagonistic capital-labour relationship reinforces this necessity. Thus it is cooperation that leads to supervision, not the other way round. (That is: given the factory. If we start from decentralized domestic workers, capitalists may want to improve supervision by centralizing workers, independently of gains from cooperation). The role of the capitalist relations of production is that they increase the necessity of supervision (capital aiming at pumping out maximum surplus value from the labour power). In this respect, Marx carefully observes that the resistance (and possibilities of resistance) of labour increases with an increasing number of cooperating labourers, and the more this number increases, the more the counter-pressure of capital increases.

Division of labour and manufacture In the following chapter 14 on the division of labour and manufacture Marx makes the two points about the origins of manufacture, which Lazonick describes so neatly in his paper (via vertical and horisontal integration, re-

147

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

spectively.) Here — in the manufacture — cooperation based on the division of labour assumes its first, simple form. After having explained the two-fold origins of the manufacture Marx goes on in the next section (2) to investigate the effects of cooperation on labour productivity in the process of labour in the manufacture. They are a) saving on time, b) perfection of methods (given effect with a minimum of exertion), c) saving on time because of less move-ments of the workman’s tools. The ensuing increased productivity of labour is conditioned either by an increased intensity of labour or a decreased amount of time unproductively consumed. But, careful as always, Marx notes that this specialization also “disturbs the intensity and flow of man’s animal spirits” which works in the contrary direction.

After these preliminary observations Marx goes into the really interesting things — interesting for the logical connection between manufacture and fac-tory because the increased productivity of the labour in the manufacture not only depends upon the increased efficiency of the labourer per se but also on “the perfection of his tools”. The characteristic feature of the manufacture in this respect is the differentiation of the instruments of labour. Through this specialization of tools, the productivity of the labourer is increased. But more important: the differentiation of knives, drills, hammers etc. (Marx mentions the 500 varieties of hammers produced in Birmingham) into very specialized and simple tools paves the way for the introduction of machinery. Each specialized implement is adapted to a particular process but several together are also used for different operations in one and the same process. “The manufacturing period simplifies, improves and multiplies the implements of labour, by adapting them to the exclusively special functions of each detail labourer. It thus creates at the same time one of the material conditions for the existence of machinery, which consists of a combination of simple instruments.” This is a crucial step and a condition for the transformation to machinery. At this point one may make the following comment: Even if the manufacture as a business organization is not to be regarded as the general historical predecessor of the factory, it is clear that the technology and imple-ments utilized and developed in manufactures historically were points of departure for the technological development from the late 18th century (or one of them). The numerous technicians, artisans, mechanics and inventors of the late 18th century did not fall down from heaven but made their contributions on the basis of the preceding era (Maxine Berg, The Age of Manufactures (1985), p. 235; A.P. Wadsworth – J. de Lacy Mann, The Cotton Trade and Industrial Lancashire (1931), chapter 5.)

After having isolated “the detail labourer” and his implements as “the simplest elements of manufacture” Marx makes a characterization of manu-facture as a whole. 1. To begin with he distinguishes “two fundamental forms of manufacture”, often mixed in practice but necessary to distinguish with re-gard to the origins of machinery: a) Heterogeneous manufacture characterized by processes that fit together independently made components (like parts for

148

Bo Gustafsson

watches put together in a watch manufacture) and b) Serial manufacture like needle manufacture which transforms wires in a continuous process handled by 70–90 different detail labourers. Marx notes (and Sombart emphasized this point still more) that heterogeneous manufacture is rare, since the splitting up of work in a number of heterogeneous processes (30–40 in e.g. watchmak-ing) permits little use of common instruments of labour and the work thus may very well be performed as domestic or artisan industry. Serial manu-facture — like in needle, paper or glass manufacture — is more important. Its economic rationale is that it saves constant capital (reduces the multiplication of small premises) and shortens the time of transport for through-puts by a considerable extent, although not as much as in the future mechanical factory, where through-puts incessantly flow from station to station.

In a sense the manufacture is a kind of factory without machines, the col-lective labour and its parts making up the inter-connected living machines. Compared to the isolated artisan or the domestic worker there has arisen a certain interdependence in the direct labour process and this fact compels each detail worker “to spend on his work no more than the necessary time and thus a continuity, uniformity, regularity, order and even intensity of labour of quite a different kind”. (The manufacture also introduces what 20th century economists like Jansen and Schneider called “the law of harmony”. This law fixes certain technical relations between sets of machines in a work-shop and this necessitates a discontinuous (non-marginal) extension of scale when the scale of production must be extended).

After having noted that manufactures sometimes develop into combinations of various manufactures through backward or forward vertical integration (as when, in glass manufacture, the manufacture of earthenware melting-pots is integrated backward and the manufacture of glass-cutting or brass-founding is integrated forward), Marx sums up his characterization of the manufacture as follows: “The collective labourer, formed by the combination of a number of detail labourers, is the machinery specially characteristic of the manufac-turing period.”

One consequence of the manufacture is, lastly, the emergence of “a class of so-called unskilled labourers”, since any manufacturing process requires “certain simple manipulations, which every man is capable in doing” resulting in a fall in the value of labour-power — mainly as a consequence of the dis-appearance or the diminution of the expenses of apprenticeship — and thus an increase of surplus value.

In this analysis Marx has considered a) the origin of the manufacture, b) its simple elements, c) the detail labourer and his implements and d) the totality of the mechanism. Now he proceeds to link up the analysis of the micro-organism, i.e. the division of labour in the manufacture, with the division of labour in society, “which forms the foundation of all production of commodities”. In this section he points out that the division of labour in society develops on the one hand from within and on the other hand from without (contacts between

149

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

regions, nations etc.) and he explores the importance of the division between branches of production, between town and county, population aggregations etc. Two things are emphasized: a) the degree of division of labour in any micro-unit is conditioned by the degree of division of labour in society as a whole and vice versa; b) the Colonial system and the emergence of the world market also develop the division of labour in society.

After having once again re-iterated that “division of labour in the work-shop, as practised by the manufacture, is a special creation of the capitalist mode of production alone”, Marx in the concluding section of the chapter on the division of labour and manufacture — “the capitalist character of manufacture” — once more emphasizes that “an increased number of labourers under the control of one capitalist is the natural starting point, as well of co-operation generally, as of manufacture in particular”. He states that “the collective working mechanism is a form of existence of capital” in so far as the splitting-up of interconnected labour processes has been transformed to an appendage of capital converting the labourer “into a crippled monstrosity”. This has occurred through the “decomposition of handicrafts, by specialisation of the instruments of labour, by the formation of detail labourers and by grouping and combining the latter into a single mechanism” and in its specific capitalist form “manufacture is but a particular method of begetting relative surplus value”.

Still — and this is important — Marx clearly realizes the very limited im -portance of the manufactures as the concrete point of departure for the factory system and he devotes two pages to explain this: a) the number of unskilled labourers remained “very limited”, b) the attempt to assign women and children to specific tasks “as a whole is wrecked on the resistance of the male labourers”, c) the de-skilling of labour is met by the efforts of workers to uphold rules of apprenticeship, d) the workers refuse to be disciplined, e) capital failed to become the master of the whole disposable working-time of the manufacturing labourers, f) manufactures were short-lived and changed their locality all the time. So Marx concluded:

At the same time manufacture was unable, either to seize upon the production of society to its full extent, or to revolutionise that production to its very core. It towered up as an economical work or art, on the broad foundation of the town handcrafts, and of the rural domestic industries. At a given stage in its development, the narrow technical basis on which manufacture rested came into conflict with requirements of production that were created by manufacture itself.

These are very strong words and Marx seems to be aware of the fact that the manufactures cannot be constructed as some general development stage be-fore the factories. What, then, is the link between manufactures and factories justifying this exhaustive treatment of manufactures? One thing is clear: Marx

150

Bo Gustafsson

ends the chapter (and the whole of part III of Capital, I) by pointing out: The manufactures created

the workshop for the production of the instruments of labour themselves, in-cluding especially the complicated mechanical apparatus then already employ-ed ... This workshop, the product of the division of labour in manufacture, pro-duced in its turn — machines. It is they that sweep away the handicraftsman’s work as the regulating principle of social production and this cuts loose, on the one hand, the workmen from a detail function, and, on the other hand, the technical fetter for the domination of capital.

Thus, it seems that according to Marx there was a factual link between manufactures and factories in so far as the manufacture, first, by developing very simplified implements (tools), laid a technical basis for the development of the tools of the machines in the factories. Secondly, in so far as these implements were a product of the division of labour in the manufactures there is also an indirect link between manufactories and factories. But how to explain the other aspects of manufactories emphasized by Marx: That they were the starting point of capitalist factories in so far as they a) concentrated workers, b) condensed and intensified labour, c) cheapened constant capital (scale ef-fects), d) introduced cooperation of labour in a systematic way, e) developed the division of labour inside manufactories, f) created a collective and inter-dependent labour mechanism akin to that in the future factories, although the “machines” in the factories were the labourers themselves and g) started the process of the final subordination of labour to capital? How could these elements of the manufacturers be transferred to the factories, although the manufactories, as Marx himself emphasized, usually were not transformed into factories? At this point we have to refer to Marx’s conception of history as a process combining concrete (the historical) and abstract (logical) aspects. Even if the concrete links between manufactures and factories are weak and manufactures mainly represented a dead end in industrial development, manufactures did acquire several characteristics that later emerged in the factory system. The characteristics of manufactures pointed out by Marx (a-g above) existed in fact in manufactures as well as in factories and manufactures preceded factories. The difference was that manufactures mainly produced luxuries while factories arose and developed by adapting to the mass markets associated with domestic industries. Thus there was a connection between manufactures and factories, in some but not in all aspects.

But what then becomes of the transition from domestic industries to fac-tories? The first thing to note here is that Marx was aware of the fact that factories rose on the foundations of domestic industries. He writes in the manuscripts mentioned above (II:3.1, p. 245f.) that the domestic industries (häuslichländiche Nebenarbeit) “lack the absolute subsumtion of the worker under a wholly one-sided and simple operation. This is not his exclusive work. But then the main condition is missing. These workers work with their own

151

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

means of production. This very mode of production is in fact not capitalist, but the capitalist only steps in as a middle-man, as a merchant between these independent workers and the ultimate buyer of the commodities. This form, wherein capital has not yet taken hold of production (sich noch nicht der Pro-duction selbst bemächtigt hat), always constitutes the transition from agrarian side-line production (ländlichen Nebenindustrien) to the capitalist mode of production. The capitalist appears here for the worker, who is an owner of commodities, a producer and a seller, as buyer of the commodities (als Käufer der Waaren), not of labour. The fundamental condition of capitalist produc-tion is as yet lacking. (Es fehlt also noch die Grundlage der capitalistischen Production.)

Where that division of labour in the form of independent branches of pro-duction exists (as in the example of Blanqui) there are a lot of time-consuming unproductive mediating processes, which are conditioned by the fact that the commodities in their consecutive stages exist as independent commodities and their connection in the total production is mediated by the exchange of commodities, by buying and selling. The cooperative labour (das Füreinander Arbeiten) in the different branches is conditioned by various chance occur-rences, stoppings (Zufälligkeiten, Unregelmässigkeiten) etc. Only the forced connection in the workshop produces the simultaneousness, evenness and proportionality (Gleichzeitigkeit, Gleichmässigkeit and Proportionalität) in the mechanism of these various operations and connects them as a whole to a proportionate (gleichförmig) working mechanism.

Machinery and modern industry Marx had finished his treatment in Capital, I. of the manufacture by stating that the detailed implement created by the specialization of tools in the manufac-tories became the point of departure for the machines of the factories. While the revolution of the mode of production in the manufacture started with the labour-power, the corresponding revolution of the mode of production in the factories started with the instruments of labour, which in the factories became converted from tools to machines.

Marx starts his analysis by defining “a fully developed machinery as con -sisting of three essential parts, the motor mechanism, the transmitting mechanism and finally the tool or the working machine.” The main point here is that “the tool or the working machine is that part of the machinery with which the industrial revolution of the 18th century starts ... Either the entire machine is only a more or less altered mechanical edition of the old handcraft tool, as for instance, the power-loom; or the working parts fitted in the frame of the machine are old acquaintances, as spindles are in a mule, needles in a stocking-loom, saws in a sawing-machine, and knives in a chopping-machine.” The main point is: “From the moment that the tool proper is taken from man, and fitted into a mechanism, a machine takes the place of a mere implement.”

152

Bo Gustafsson

The test of this assertion is, according to Marx, the fact that long before the advent of the factories and even the manufactures the motor mechanism (the motive power) is transformed into machines of pumping or pounding “without creating any revolution of the mode of production”. Not even the steam-engine per se had such consequences. “The steam-engine itself, such as it was at its invention during the manufacturing period at the close of the 17th century and such as it continued to be down to 1780 (Marx refers to Watt’s first so-called simple acting engine incapable of rotation), did not give rise to any industrial revolution. It was, on the contrary, the invention of machines that made a revolution in the form of steam-engines necessary.” Our interpretation of this last assertion must hence be that technological development according to Marx is primarily endogenous to the technical economic processes: steam-engines being perfected and applied only when the need for them — dictated by the mass application of working-machines — emerges. “Increases in the size of the machine, and in the number of its working tools, call for a more massive mechanism to drive it; and this mechanism requires, in order to overcome its resistance, a mightier moving power than that of man, apart from the fact that man is a very imperfect instrument for producing uniform continuous motion.”

Horse-power was the most unreliable motive power, costly and of restrict-ed applicability in factories; wind was too inconstant and uncontrollable and the attempts to increase its effects resulted in problems with the gearing (in its turn stimulating research into the laws of friction). The problems connected with the repetitive movements of a lever (pushing and pulling) led to the appli-cation of the fly-wheel. Thus Arkwright’s throstlespinning mill was originally turned by water. But the limitations of water power were, first, that it could not be increased at will, secondly that it failed at certain seasons of the year and, thirdly and most important, it was essentially local (only overcome with the future turbines). Now enters Watt’s double-acting steam-engine:

Not till the invention of Watt’s second and so-called double-acting steam-engine, was a prime mover found, that begot its own force by the consumption of coal and water; whose power was entirely under man’s control; that was mobile and a means of locomotion; that was urban and not, like the water-wheel, rural; that permitted production to be concentrated in towns instead of, like the water-wheels, being scattered up and down the country (the steam-engine is the parent of the manufacturing towns); that was of universal technical application, and, relatively speaking, little affected in its choice of residence by local circumstances. The greatness of Watt’s genius showed itself in the specification of the patent that he took out in April, 1784. In that the specification of his steam-engine is described, not as an invention for a specific purpose, but as an agent universally applicable in Mechanical industry… One motive mechanism was now able to drive many machines at once. The motive mechanism grows with the number of the machines that are turned simultaneously, and the transmitting mechanism becomes a wide-spreading apparatus.

153

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

In the following Marx discusses different aspects of machinery, such as the emergence of an automatic system of machinery as, e.g. (in textile industries) the apparatus that stops a drawing frame, whenever a silver breaks; or the self-acting device, which stops the power-loom as soon as the shuttle bobbin is emptied of web.

He stresses that this development of machines undermines the power of skilled labour as well as the detailed workmen in manufactures; that radical changes in one sphere of industry creates pressures on other spheres, as when spinning by machines made weaving by machines a necessity and both to-gether conditioned the mechanical and chemical revolution that took place in bleaching, printing and dyeing, or mechanized cotton-spinning creating the gin for separating the seeds from the cotton fibre etc.

On a still more general level, mechanized industry calls forth the revolu-tion in the means of communication and transport (railways, ocean steamers, telegraphs). The crowning achievement of all this was when man was able to let machines produce machines by means of mechanical lathes, planing machines, iron cutting and shearing machines.

But however important technical change and machinery are for the advent of the factory system, creating new conditions for the operation of economic and social forces and directing these in specific directions, while cutting off other possible directions, Marx is no adherer of a technological interpretation of the transition. The essence of the new factory system is the new economic and social relations arising and growing upon the new technological basis. Thereby, he first observes that machinery enhances the productive power of labour in various ways. Machinery like other physical conditions of pro-duction are appropriated costless by capital and he specifically notes: a) that machinery, while always entering as a whole into the labour-process, enters into the value-begetting process only by bits; b) that “in the product of mach-inery, the value due to the instruments of labour increases relatively but decreases absolutely, its absolute amount decreases but its amount relatively to the total value of the product increases” and c) “that the productiveness of a machine is measured by the human labour-power it replaces”.

Of special importance in understanding the victory of the machine-operated factory are the effects of machinery on the workmen. These are: a) employment of labour without specific muscular power like children and women, i.e. making the employment of cheaper labour power possible; b) depreciating the value of labour-power because machinery “by throwing every member of the family on to the labour-market spreads the value of the man’s labour-power over his whole family”; c) thereby changing the contract between capitalist and worker transforming the worker to “a slave dealer” morally degrading the whole working-class; d) prolonging the working-day because machinery is a perpetuum mobile; e) increasing relative surplus value by i) depreciating the value of labour power, ii) cheapening the commodities entering into the reproduction of labour-power and iii) creating extra surplus value for the

154

Bo Gustafsson

capitalists first introducing machinery and thereby making it possible for them to reap the difference between the value of commodities determined by the socially necessary labour-time of the existing technology and the value of commodities produced by superior technology; f) lengthening the working-day because of the contradiction created by the fact that an increased relative surplus value per worker in consequence of the introduction of machines is off-set by a decreasing number of workers, forcing the capitalist to pump out more labour of the remaining workers; g) creating a surplus working population; and h) intensifying labour after the introduction of the compulsory shortening of the hours of labour by i) making labour time less porous than before, ii) by increasing the speed of the machines and iii) giving the workmen more machinery to tend.

Some points in the manuscripts of 1861–1863 Much of the material contained in the 1861/63 manuscripts returns in Capital in transformed or unchanged form. Sometimes, however, Marx is more spe-cific and precise in the manuscripts than in Capital. For example he defines here the division of labour as “a particular, specified, further developed form of cooperation” and while in “simple cooperation many making the same kind of labour are working together, in the division of labour many workers work together under the command of capital producing separate parts of the same commodity, whereby every specific part gives rise to a specific labour, a specific operation in the production of one commodity, which represents the totality of these specific moments of labour”.

In his further discussion of the division of labour he explains the concen-tration of labour under the command of a capitalist partly by a) the fact that surplus value is determined not only by its rate but also by the absolute num-ber of workers, and partly by b) a wish to effect economies of economizing on constant capital (Oekonomie der Arbeitsbedingungen). It is on this basis that the element of force is introduced, granted the rule of capital: “Die Arbeiter werden (become) der Disciplin des Kapitals unterworfen.”

Discussing the rationale of the introduction of machinery Marx holds that the general aim (Zweck) of machinery is to decrease necessary labour and increase surplus labour. Here he also stresses that the direct lowering of wages in connection with the introduction of machinery only applies to “singular cas-es” (einzelne Fälle), the employment of women and children being a special case. The wage may very well be increased; still the operation pays because of the lowering of the necessary labour time. (All this from II:3.1.)

Discussing machinery in II:3.6 he holds that the main effects of machin-ery are: 1) an increase of the absolute working time in factories, because of the contradictory effects of labour-saving (increased rate of surplus value and decreased number of workers), 2) the substitution of working tools for ma-chinery, 3) conglomeration of workers, 4) condensation of labour.

155

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

Appendix 5: Three reviews

In the following pages I will review three very different books related to the problem of the transition from domestic industries to factories.

I

The first one is really a minor classic, P. Gaskell, “The manufacturing popu-lation of England” (1833, reprint Arno Press, New York 1972). I first met his name when reading Engels’ Condition. Ure does not like Gaskell at all and I must admit that his repeated moralistic strictures, mainly aimed at the sexual habits of the new manufacturing population, are somewhat tiresome to read. But in the introduction to the book he sketches an analytical history of the rise of cotton industries in England, which is rather interesting. Below I will try to summarize his arguments:

1. It all starts with the increasing demand for cloth at the middle of the eighteenth century leading to mechanization of spinning. Before this “one half of the weaver’s time had generally to be spent in waiting for work” (p. 34).

2. When weaving could expand thanks to the increased supply of yarn “one of the first effects…was the gradual abandonment of farming as an accessary which had been very common with the more respectable portion of weavers. His labour, when employed on his loom, was more profitable, and more im-mediate in its return, than when devoted to agricultural pursuits.” (p. 35). This indicates that the value productivity as well as real incomes of the domestic textile industry was higher than in agriculture and caused a shift of labour power from agriculture to industry.

3. As long as productivity in agriculture did not increase pari passu with the drain of labour, the ex-farming weavers had to be replaced by other people specializing in agriculture. “This necessarily led to the introduction of a new order of farm tenants, men who exclusively devoted themselves to the cultiva-tion of the soil…and who in nine cases out of ten were mere holders at will.”

4. But also the status of weavers declined in spite of an increased standard of comfort, because they no longer held or possessed land.

5. Traditionally there had existed two categories of weavers. On the one hand, the above mentioned land-holding weavers, and, on the other hand, the landless weavers, “who had all along depended upon” the demand for cloth. The increase in demand for cloth brought these two categories of weavers closer to each other, since the land-holding weavers severed the connection

156

Bo Gustafsson

to the land, while the poorer proletarian weavers shared in the increased real income of the whole weaver population. Both became proletarians; the poorer ones were this before but become better paid, while the ex-land-possessing weavers were transformed to proletarians because it paid.

6. The winner of this transformation was the poor weaver. And in this con-nection Gaskell makes some observation on the privations of this class under the old system when demand was irregular:

The second, or inferior class of artisans, had at all times been great sufferers from the impossibility of supplying themselves with materials for their labour. Considerable vacations were frequently occurring in this respect, and at these periods they underwent very severe privations. This irregularity had produced its usual effects upon their industrial character rendering them improvident, devoid of forethought, and careless in their expenditure. Not being able to calculate, had they been so disposed, upon the certainty that their exertions would be invariably called for, they became indifferent, enjoyed the good whilst it lasted, and starved through the interval as they best might be. It is an indisputable fact, that irregularity in the demand for labour, from whatever cause it may arise, by occasionally throwing the workmen out of employ, and generating idle habits, is one of the most disorganizing and degrading influences which can be brought to bear upon their character. (p. 37.)

Granted that Gaskell does not only echo common prejudices, this observa-tion is really interesting, since he deduces the behaviour of poor domestic producers as to labour and leisure from the conditions of production. Since demand was so irregular, it was impossible to form rational expectations (sic!) concerning the future. The only rational behaviour was to live and work from day to day in a fatalistic way.

Gaskell continues:

The class of poor weavers were thus instantaneously elevated very considerably in world consideration. They were freed from one great cause of depression, which had hitherto prevented all improvement. They now took their stand upon the same ground with the weaver, who had hitherto been a great farmer, and who had come down one degree on the social scale, in consequence of his giving up his land for the purpose of devoting himself to the more profitable business of weaving. (This amalgamation of the two divisions…gave them a community of interests and feelings which bound them together.)

7. And now Gaskell reiterates his main point, that the increased level of comfort essentially was an effect of more continuous employment over the year:

A very material improvement, therefore, had been gradually operating in both classes of weavers, during the half century immediately preceding the application of steam power. This improvement had not arisen so much from any increase in the rate of payment for labour [although we in fact know that the rate of wages increased faster in the industrial north during the second half

157

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

of the eighteenth century — see my larger paper — BG note], as from a market generally understocked, and a constantly increasing production for yarn, which enabled them to work full hours…. (p. 38.)

8. As to spinners — “the aristocracy of manufacturers” — their condition “was undergoing changes still greater and more rapid than that of the weavers” (p. 40):

a) originally weaving and spinning were performed in the families possess-ing a loom and a distaff.

b) as a consequence of improved and more bulky and expensive spinning machines a social differentiation and a new division of labour took place. Firstly, the more well-off weavers deserted the loom and took up mechanical spinning. Secondly, the earlier spinners who could not afford to buy the more expensive spinning machines left spinning and took up weaving.

9. Parallel to this the spinners “were joined by another class of persons… and this was the yeoman — the male freeholder now nearly extinct as a part of the social confederacy” (p. 41). Why? Because the yeoman

had hitherto been surrounded by petty farmers — who had generally eked out their bad management as cultivators by being weavers, and who had served him as bulwarks or breakwaters against impending storm. These were one by one removed [because of their specialization on industrial pursuits —B G note], and their places immediately occupied by a race of men who gave a considerably increased rent, and who by improved modes of husbandry…soon drove the small proprietor from the markets which he had so long supplied. Thus…the yeoman was driven to embark some portion of his means in the purchase of spinning machines, and before very long, great quantities of yarn were produced by the inmates of old farm-houses…five-seventh of those who purchased these machines were obliged to have recourse to a loan, generally a mortgage to raise the money.” (p. 42.)

10. Gaskell, thus, puts great emphasis on the importance of the growth of new and more expensive technology as a factor differentiating social classes. “The price of the more complicated spinning machines was very consider-able, and as has been seen removed them out of reach of the inferior class of weavers. This, aided by other causes already noted, brought the small free-holder into the field.” (p. 42). But still more important was the intervention of “monied men who began to turn their attention to a branch of trade, the returns from which were very rapid. This brought a farther accession of capital into it, and led to the erection of mills containing a greater or less number of spinning machines propelled by water power, with the assistance of hu-man labour….” These mills were exclusively devoted to the first processes of manufacture, namely, carding and spinning. These mills — so Gaskell seems to imply — were vastly more productive than domestic carding and spinning production and even if the wages of the factory workers were “high, it is true”, the efficiency wages of factory workers were lower than the remuneration of

158

Bo Gustafsson

domestic labour (“yet comparatively much lower than the estimated value of home labour”).

11. The rise of the mills presented the domestic spinner and carder with a keen competition (“his profits fell”). The domestic spinner who had bought himself a jenny machine “of the best and most approved make” had to repay the debt out of the proceeds of his spinning. But these proceeds were lowered because of the competition from the spinning mills, which because of their higher productivity lowered yarn prices. This forced jenny spinners to sell off their jennies. “The number of machines which at this period were thrown back into the market, gave a strong impulse to the growth of the mills; a machine that was not sufficiently perfect for the purpose of domestic manufacture, doing well enough in a mill in conjunction with others, worked a less rate of wages, and assisted by water power…” (p. 44). This led to the proletarianiza-tion of those ex-weavers and freeholders who had earlier invested in improved jennies in domestic industry, although some of them succeeded in establishing themselves as mill-owners.

12. The continuous improvement of spinning, while weaving technology remained unchanged in the main, led to an increased disproportion between the supply of yarn and cloth respectively. Some of the yarn was sent to for-eign markets to ease the pressure on domestic yarn prices. But it also induced an expansion of handloom-weaving, the lack of technological improvement being balanced by lower input prices (of yarn). Now came the mass immigra-tion to the manufacturing districts. “Now, however, when the outcry for cloth continued, and yarn was abundant, a large body of weavers immigrated into the manufacturing districts — almost the entire mass of agricultural labourers deserted their occupations, and a new race of hand-loom weavers, which had undergone none of the transitions of the primitive manufacturers, were the product of the existing state of things.”

13. This class of hand-loom weaver “was of a still lower grade in the social scale than the original weavers…. This at once led to a great depreciation in the price of hand-loom labour, and was the beginning of that train of disasters, which has finally terminated in reducing those who have clung to it to a state of starvation.” (p. 46–47.)

So far P. Gaskell. The interesting points of his “stylized history” of the transition problem seems to me to be many and quite important, viz. the fol-lowing ones:

1. It all started with the increasing demand for textiles.2. Labour was transferred from agricultural to industry partly because in-

dustry provided higher earnings (points 2, 6, 7 and 12) and partly because labour was outcompeted and proletarianized in earlier occupations (points 8, 9, 10, 11 and even 12). To some extent push and pull worked together, as when transformations within agriculture first created (more) landless workers and new employment opportunities for these opened up with the great expansion of hand-loom weaving in the wake of the advance of factory spinning. I find

159

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

this view highly realistic and it avoids the simplicity of the two extreme po-sitions according to which industry arose only because of worsening or only because of improving conditions.

3. Two other fundamental points in Gaskell’s conceptions seems to be these: 1) Life was miserable for that class of domestic workers which was mainly dependent upon the irregular demand for their output and to this class the first phase of expansion of domestic industry implied a real advance. 2) When analysing the transformation of domestic industries it may be appropriate to assume that domestic workers — for analytical purposes — can be divided into two main categories: those equipped with considerable land holdings and those without considerable land holdings. The first mentioned group was “lured” into whole-time industrial pursuits by the higher income to be earned but undermined thereby the security of their future position (and their status declined). For the second group the expansion of domestic industries represented a pure case of material progress, since their employment became more stable and their real incomes rose considerably.

4. The increasing size and cost of spinning machines acted as a factor of economic and social differentiation but had very complicated effects. To begin with the more well-off weavers took to spinning, while their former jobs were occupied by the common ex-spinners. Also farmers (“yeomen”) took up the new mechanized spinning in domestic industries, partly because they could afford to buy the new but relatively expensive spinning machines and partly because the on-going technical and commercial transformation of agriculture gave rise to a new and more ambitious class of farmers specialising in rationa-lized forms of agriculture being able to pay the higher land rents de manded (point 9). Still more important in this regard was the introduction of factory spinning, which outcompeted the just mentioned class of more well-to-do domestic spinners and, on the one hand, increased the number of proletarianized domestic spinners, and, on the other hand, increased the supply of modernized spinning jennies etc. on the market which were bought up by the increasing section of mill owners so that these profited on both counts.

5. The great expansion of factory spinning in the last quarter of the 18th century was very important for recruiting proletarianized labour from agriculture into hand-loom weaving in the manufacturing districts. This re-sult ed in an over-establishment of hand-loom weaving, which made for the future disaster of this class of workmen, when mechanized weaving started to expand from the 1820’s. But for its time and for a period it was — and was experienced as — a blessing for the workers involved.

6. In all this I find in Gaskell two points of great interest to the conceptual-ization of the transition problematic. 1) Domestic industries develop partly in complementarity and partly in conflict with each other up to the final victory of the factory. 2) The transition period can only be understood as a sequence of sub-stages wherein the characteristics and interrelationships of one sub-stage sets the course for the ensuing sub-stage. Some kind of period analysis,

160

Bo Gustafsson

thus, seems to be appropriate. The alternative approach, viz. to start with the construction of one general model containing only information on initial and boundary conditions for the explanation of the terminal results may be highly misleading as to the causal mechanisms of the change. Such a general model should be the result rather than the starting point, I think.

II

The second book is K.D.M. Snell, “Annals of the labouring poor. Social changes and agrarian England 1660–1900” (CUP paperback 1987). As far as I can understand this book is an important contribution revising the traditional con-servative assessment of the consequences of the enclosures upon employment initiated by J. Chambers in the early 1950’s. According to this view enclo-sures were not important in creating agrarian unemployment in England as historians had long believed, especially those in the radical tradition. On the contrary enclosures rather created new employment opportunities because of the agrarian improvements. Snell’s main points are as follows.

1. Whereas the radical tradition (e.g. the Hammonds) had concluded that enclosures were fatal to three agrarian classes, the small farmer, the cottager and the squatter, the conservative revision has almost exclusively concentrat-ed on the small farmer.

2. The revision has completely relied on the tax assessment — and this explains the first point — but even Chambers in his article (Enclosure and la-bour supply in the Industrial Revolution. EHR 1953) wrote that this source is so deficient in different respects that “detailed investigation…is simply not worthwhile.” This because the country quotas have no relation to acreage; many owners did not became chargeable after 1798; the irregular use of titles; tax avoidance; defective accuracy of the returns etc. This has had as an effect that investigations of different authors into identical parishes have produced wildly different results (Davies versus Chambers, 300 per cent variation! with-out anybody understanding why….)

3. Snell’s use of settlement examinations indicates growing seasonal fluc-tuations in agrarian employment and he — to me wholly convincingly — inter-prets this as an indication of a less full and regular demand for labour after enclosure. More important, enclosure, Snell argues as many before him, hit women’s employment hard since they were cut off from their former part-time employment on the commons and the open fields.

4. Snell also notes that Chambers had taken a quite different position in his 1932 book on Nottinghamshire in the eighteenth century, emphasizing that enclosure had “disastrous” effects on the employment of labour in the Midlands and that vagabondage increased vastly.

5. Relying on Sturt’s and Davies’ “Change in the Village” (1912), Snell stresses the fact that since enclosure took away the means of subsistence for cottagers and squatters, these now had to get hold of money in order to survive

161

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

and this forced them to increase their labour supply on the market. In this connection Snell quotes the opinion of Arthur Young, according to whom the value of a cow to a family was equivalent to 5–6 shilling a week, close to the wages of a fully employed labourer. Further the labouring poor lost their rights to collect fuel and furze from the commons, wastes and nearby woods and also the right of gleaning after harvest, earlier supporting a family with bread during a third of or even for the whole year. Lastly also they lost rights to cut turves for fuel, wood for fuel, housing and fencing, rights to cut hay in common meadows, rights of finishing etc.

6. The positive employment effects of enclosure are also dubious. Hedging and ditching did not provide continuous, but rather once-and-for all employ-ment effects. Differences in technological change before and after enclo-sure were often marginal or non-existent (Havinden’s research). Enclosure increased rents, they were costly and thereby they diminished resources for improvement. Productivity increased before rather than after enclosure.

7. There is a strong correlation between enclosure and the rise of poor rates.8. The increase of population may be explained by the fact that the prole-

tarianization of labour in the countryside eroded the motive for the postpone-ment of marriage, since no saving motive any longer existed.

These, very shortly, are Snell’s arguments for a return to the standpoint that contemporaries of enclosure as well as many later historians took. But if this is true, it has important consequences for the problem of the transition to the factories, since a rural proletariat was created that had to seek employment outside agriculture. Maybe this proletariat turns up among the many rural workers who emigrated to the manufacturing districts in the last quarter of the 18th century (see Bowden quoted in my paper, as well Gaskell quoted above). This means that while in the first stage of the industrial revolution industrial employment represented a better option, it represented more of a forced one when the spinning mills started to multiply, accompanied by the increase in hand-loom weaving.

III

The third book of interest is Gay L. Gullickson’s “Spinners and Weavers of Auffay” (CUP 1986) on the rise and development of domestic industry in a French village in Normandy 1750–1850. The main point of Gullickson is that it is not poor land per se but seasonal unemployment and landlessness that were the distinguishing features of proto-industrial regions. In her case study the cottage textile industry expanded in a region of markedly commer-cial agriculture. Owners or leaseholders of very small plots (peasants or arti-sans) provided one of the major labour sources for the cottage textile industry. Gullickson further stresses that putting work out in the countryside saved the merchants money, since rural spinners and weavers were paid less than their urban counterparts. This was accepted by the rural spinners and weavers, be-

162

Bo Gustafsson

cause harvest wages and the products from garden plots in combination with the income from domestic industry supplied them with a higher standard of living.

The importance of Gullickson’s work is, so it seems, that it takes us out of the frame of earlier discussions concentrating on the physical characteristics of the land and focuses on the social characteristics of the domestic industry countryside.

Part II

Preliminary steps towards modelling of the transition

165

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

I. IntroductionIn the preceding part of this paper I presented a plausible story of how and why factories arose within the cotton industry during the second part of the 18th century in Britain (see abstract of part I). The story is, however, to a large extent intuitive and implicit. In this part I try to take some steps towards mak-ing the story more formal and explicit by defining concepts more precisely, delimiting the problem, developing explicit hypotheses and indicating some possible testable implications of the hypotheses.

II. DefinitionsBy “transition” I refer to a structural change as to the composition of the ele-ments that make up the industrial structure during this period (domestic indus-tries, putting-out systems and factories) from an initial state to a terminal state in space and time. The precise meaning of this structural change is difficult to capture. First, it contains an element of novelty and emergence (the rise of factories) and secondly it refers to the frequency and/or “dominance” of the elements involved. The number of factories, the number of people employed in factories as well as output of factory production did increase between initial and terminal states both absolutely and relatively. Still, there were probably more people employed in domestic and putting-out industries than in factories as late as in the 1830’s (according to one estimate 300,000 versus 220,000). Nonetheless we regard the 1,200 cotton mills in Britain and Ireland at this time as the element that “dominates”, because of the “weight” we — or at least contemporary observers — assign to factories. Without being quantitatively dominating (at least with respect to employment) factories represented the new, more dynamic and growing element in the industrial structure, which pointed to the future and therefore was perceived as the key element. The transition from domestic industries to factories in the cotton industries, thus, means that domestic industries were in this loose sense “dominating” at the initial state, while factories were “dominating” at the terminal state.

In this study the focus will not be on the whole period between the 1750’s and the 1830’s, when the full-fledged factory had been established. By “full-fledged factory” I refer to the classical definition first suggested by Andrew Ure (“Philosophy of Manufacture”) in the 1830’s emphasizing capitalist own-ership, centralization of labour, hierarchy and supervision of the process of pro duction by the owner or his representatives and, lastly but not least, the utilization of machinery (machines replacing manual operation, transmission machines and energy machines) in interrelated series of sub-divided processes of production. This full-fledged factory is however the end product of an his tori-cal process starting with the Arkwright factories for spinning cotton twist (warp yarn) in the 1770’s, in their turn superseded by the mule-spinning factories in

166

Bo Gustafsson

the early 19th century. As I have tried to show in part I the transition to fac-tories occurs in two distinct stages, whereby the first stage is characterized by the centralization of workers under the command and supervision of the manufacturer. This stage originates in the early 18th century in the small ware cotton industry and silk throwing and gains momentum from the 1750’s, when various processes of cotton manufacture (prepatory like slubbing, roving and carding, but also spinning, weaving and finishing) are centralized. This first stage, when the process of production is still not much mechanized, continues in weaving up to the introduction of the power-loom from the 1820’s. The factory system according to the definition of Ure starts with the Arkwright factories in spinning and also factories for printing cotton. My concern will be with the first stage of factory production from c. 1750 to c. 1770/80. The rationale for this is the assumption that centralization of labour and hierarchy/supervision were necessary conditions for the introduction of machinery replacing manual labour and acting as energy machines.

By “factory” I, thus, refer to a centralized workshop with a number of workers surpassing the number of workers in a normal household (extended or not), where the workers are performing their tasks under the command and supervision of a manufacturer, who usually owns most or all of the means of production (premises, raw materials and at least larger or more expensive equipment). Since we know from e.g. fragmentary evidence on hand-loom weaving in Manchester around 1750 (Wadsworth – de Mann) that a household could have 5–10 looms worked by household members and journeymen, we may provisionally define a factory with the above characteristics as a work-shop with at least 10–20 workers. The usefulness of this definition will show up in light of empirical evidence.

This definition of factory delimits this specific organization for producing cotton products in three respects: it is a centralized workshop, its number of workers and the character of the agent of production, who is not the head of a household but a person with only a contractual relation to the workers (although with paternalistic aspects).

By “domestic industry” I refer to an economic organization based on or consisting of household members under the command and supervision of the household head, who owns his means of production, organises production, buys his raw material, works it up into final output, sells the output and receives money income from this. In this case the direct producer makes the output and marketing decision, he controls the labour process and input resources as well as output and he can make a choice between labour and leisure. I call this organization “decentralized” because of the smallness of the labour force and the narrow limits for increasing it. In order to increase output above certain limits it is not possible to augment the number of workers. Instead the number of organizations (i.e. households) must be augmented. Usually (as was the case in the Lancashire cotton industry) the domestic producers own or rent a piece of land for subsistence production (some grain, milk, butter, cheese).

167

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

The implication of this was that the domestic producers could diversify their supply of labour — which factory workers could not — make a choice between manufacturing work and agricultural work and also use the income from agri-culture as a reservation wage in their output decisions.

By “putting-out system” I refer to an economic organization based on do-mestic production. But in this system the domestic producer (our outworker) only controls his own labour process and he is usually owner only of a limited part of the means of production, namely his working-tools. The principal is a merchant, who employs domestic workers, owns the raw materials, puts out these either directly from his warehouse or indirectly through his own salaried agents to be worked up into finished or partly finished products by the domestic producers for sale to consumers or other merchants. In this system the domestic producer is already a wage worker. This delimits the putting-out system from domestic industry, while on the other hand the out-worker in the putting-out system has not been centralized to a workshop under the command of the employer.

This is a very idealized description of the three economic organizations involved and in practice the limits between them were fuzzy and combina-tions also very frequent. In respect to the British cotton industry, which at this time was mainly concentrated to northwest England (Lancashire, Cheshire and West Riding), the putting-out system was already dominant, which means that the transition occurred from the putting-out system to factories. In the Lancashire cotton industry the limits between producing and trading are also difficult to draw. Most merchants were also manufacturers, especially with respect to prepatory and/or finishing processes (roving and carding as well as dyeing, bleaching and printing).

III. Properties of the Economic OrganizationsIn order to be able to analyse the question why factories successively arose and expanded, while putting-out industries relatively speaking stagnated, we need to make certain assumptions about the behavioural characteristics of those organizations, as well as about their environment. In point of fact the evidence at hand for making those assumptions is deficient and contradictory. As indicated in part I there is a common assumption, backed up by contem-porary sources, that e.g. domestic producers (inside or outside the putting-out system) were not maximizers but rather satisficers as to income, which should have implied that rising wage rates would have reduced labour effort and vice versa above (or below) a specific wage rate (the backward sloping supply curve of labour). But this behaviour does not mean that they were not maximizers. It only means that income was not the only argument of their uti-lity function, the other being leisure. (This behaviour was judged as perfectly rational by one contemporary observer with reference to the shortness of life

168

Bo Gustafsson

of the working people, making maximization of only income for saving for old age irrational.)

We shall assume that all agents involved were maximising some utility function (wages-leisure or profits). The implication of this is that if agents may choose between economic organizations they prefer an organization A before an organization B, if the result or the reward of activities in A are higher than in B. In practice agents may be forced by circumstances to develop their activities within B rather than A. But then the choice space includes another set of activities, which is still worse than B (e.g. C, which ultimately may be death from starvation). Another implication of the maximizing assumption is that more rewarding organizations tend to expand compared to less rewarding organizations in terms of employment, profits, wages and/or investments. This expansion may be regarded as a measure of the comparative efficiency of an organization. If we, thus, observe that one organization A grows compared to another organization B, we may infer that A is a more efficient organization than B.

Each of the set of agents involved (domestic workers — merchants and factory workers — capitalists, respectively) are further assumed, from effi-ciency considerations, to adhere to the maximizing behaviour also within a given organization, i.e. with given resources maximize reward or with given rewards minimize resource use. An implication of this is that the agents are striving to enforce efficient property rights to their resources. This means that each set of agents strives to capture as many results as possible from resources used, prevent “leakages” and internalize possible externalities of activities. This mechanism works of course also across organizations, when preferring and choosing more efficient before less efficient organizations.

The above assumptions may seem trivial but they have far-reaching con-sequences for the mode of explanation of the problem of transition from do-mestic industries (or rather putting-out industries) to factories. If we can show that one organization was more efficient than the other one with respect to specific properties, the transfer of the activities of the economic agents from one organization to the other is justified by the assumptions concerning the objective functions of these agents.

A much more complicated problem is presented by the fact that the out-come of the activities of the agents depends upon the assumptions we make concerning their respective strategies. What kind of games did domestic wor-kers and merchants and workers and capitalists, respectively, play? Much evi-dence points in the direction that the game situation in the putting-out system was reminiscent of non-cooperative zero-sum games giving rise to endless bargaining and cheating and high transaction costs (search costs, bargaining costs and enforcement costs). This should be further pursued. But what about the game situation in the early factories? The workers in the factories were more “nested” and much easier to control than domestic workers. On the other hand they could combine collectively more easily. If we assume that cen-

169

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

tralization of workers led to higher productivity — an assumption for which there is evidence — it might have occurred to both workers and capitalists that they both were situated in a game making cooperation and mutual benefits possible. It is interesting to note that both Andrew Ure and William Lazonick (the first- mentioned baptized “the Pindaros of the British factory owners” by Marx, the latter a Marxist economic historian) explain the victory and suc-cess of the full-fledged mechanized factory with reference to its profit- and wage-enhancing properties based on fixed capital and high productivity. Wage income (at least over the year) from factory work was probably higher than wage income from out-working in putting-out industries. On the other hand for a long time workers despised factory work, which to begin with had to rely on casual and migrant workers.

IV. Putting-out and Factory Organization ComparedAn economic organization may be represented as consisting of a set, E, of envi-ronment properties, e; of a set, A, of activities, a, in this case production; a set, R, of results, r, and a function, f, mapping E and A into R, so that E x A = R. This structure refers to any organization. With reference to an economic or-ganization working in a market system, we may represent it as in figure 1 (below). The economic organization is made up of the activities taking place in production (Pr). The environment is made up on the one hand of the in-put market and on the other hand the output market. The general elements of the input market are money (M), input commodities (C) consisting of labour power (LP) and physical means of production (Pm) and technology (T). The output market is made of a manufactured product (C + dC), which through sale is trans formed into money (M + dM). An economic agent starts out with a sum of money (M), buys means of production and labour (Pm and Lp), combines them together with technology (T) in the process of production (Pr) and turns out manufactured products enhanced in value by the labour process (C + dC), which are sold in the market giving rise to a sum of money (a result) that exceeds the value of the original input resources (the difference being dM). This is a simple model of a successful organization, which is growing in terms of monetary rewards. If the result only equals inputs in value, the organization is stationary and if the result is less than inputs in value, it is declining. A successful organization is dependent upon productivity growth conditioned by improved technology (human and non-human capital) or higher labour inten-sity or both. An economic organization may survive even without productivity growth, if all economic organizations are stationary. But if at least one orga-nization is growing and economic agents adhere to a maximising behaviour, only growing organizations survive. A special case is represented by predatory organizations, which may be inherently stationary or declining but which may

170

Bo Gustafsson

Figure 1. Economic organization in a market economy and its environment

Production Activities

(A) Input Markets Output Markets

M C

Lp (T) Pm

Pr C+dC M+dM

Environment (E)

Note: For an explanation of symbols, see text above. Input markets, output markets and pro-duction organization partly overlap, since inputs bought are transferred from input markets to production organization and, correspondingly, outputs produced within the production organi-zation are transferred to output markets.

survive by continuously choosing new environments. The so-called sweating industries during the 19th century may be an example of this.

In the first part of my paper I have suggested that the factory system in cot-ton industries arose and expanded primarily because of the strongly growing demand for cotton products from the middle of the 18th century. To begin with this demand was met by the putting-out system. But due to various constraints of this organization (low elasticity of labour supply, problems with quality of products, embezzlement of inputs and outputs, weak incentives for inno-vation, high transaction costs, long turnover time of capital etc.), the strong growth of demand working against these constraints led to increasing costs of production within the putting out system. In order to master this problem some putters-out centralized labour to workshops and/or factories under their command. They were thereby rewarded since the productivity of labour and profitability of capital increased. When this transition had been initiated other putters-out followed suit. This would explain the transition from putting-out industries to factories.

I also discussed that part of the environment which is made up of the input market, i.e. the availability of free labour, money capital sufficient for invest-ment, the existence of barriers of entry due to expensive machinery (e.g. big spinning jennies or carding machines). But these conditions were assigned

171

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

the role of necessary prerequisites of capitalist production in factories and no attempt was made to link those changes in the input market to the choice of organization (except noting that free labour may have been forced to take up factory employment in order to survive and that only merchants and manufac-turers with sufficient capital could afford to buy the expensive machinery) at least not systematically. The explanation suggested was to deduce effects of demand growth in the output market on the putting-out organization and since these effects were negative a new organizational solution was searched for and found, namely factory organization. Neither was any attempt made to assign critical values for the process of getting started (the initial conditions) nor did I try to explain why the putting-out organization in fact did expand in specific sections of the cotton industry (e.g. in weaving). Since both organizations co-existed for so long a time period and centralized and decentralized modes of production usually co-exist in modern economic history, it could not be so simple that factories were superior to putting-out industries with respect to all properties or to all kinds of environment. Rather we should expect some kind of trade-off in results between those two kinds of organization with respect to given kinds of environment.

In conclusion I will shortly discuss these three aspects: 1) How did changes in the input market work on the two kind of organizations and their behavioural characteristics? 2) Is it possible to assign critical values for the changes in the demand for final output leading to factory organization? 3) Which were the merits and demerits, respectively, of putting-out industries and factories in adapting to the changes in their environment?

In part I of this paper I have suggested two propositions as to the relation-ship between on the one hand changes in the input market and on the other hand changes in the organization of the cotton industry: 1) The increasing supply of labour flowing into the industrial north in general and into the cotton industry in particular was mainly an effect of an increasing demand for final output; and this applies to free (proletarianized) as well as to land-attached labour. It was suggested that this shift from agricultural to industrial employ-ment was mainly caused by increasing wages in industry relative to income from agriculture. 2) The increase in the supply of free labour due to population growth and enclosures of land may have been a necessary but not a sufficient condition for the centralization of workers to workshops and primitive fac-tories. The rationale for this proposition was the assumption that, on the one hand, centralization of labour was necessary for the organization of factory production and, on the other hand, was easier to perform for manufacturers if labour was no longer attached to land. But it was also suggested that this con-dition by itself was not sufficient for the explanation of the rise of factories, since some other change in the environment must also have occurred in order to create motives for the centralization of labour. I conjectured that this “some other change” was the increasing problems in the putting-out organization caused by the increasing demand for final output. Still, there was a loophole in

172

Bo Gustafsson

the argument. I suggested that free labour in contradistinction to out-workers attached to land were characterized by a higher elasticity of labour supply and that this circumstance per se should lead to a higher surplus generation for the centralizing manufacturers compared to the utilization of out-workers. If this is the case, manufacturers should always prefer free labour to out-workers. Thus, the assumed increase of free labour during the latter part of the 18th century might have created new and not earlier existing motives for manu-facturers to centralize labour to factories and this change might be taken as not only a necessary but also a sufficient condition for the rise of factories, (granted that also other conditions, like capital for premises and machines etc., also were fulfilled). But if this proposition is valid, it should also be pos-sible to show, firstly, that the amount of free labour existing before the rapid rise of population and the enclosures would not have been sufficient for the centralization of labour; secondly that either wage rates in the early factories were lower than among out-workers or that (in the absence of an unlimited supply of labour and hence a perfectly elastic supply of labour) the increase of the marginal productivity of labour due to centralization did not offset the lower elasticity of the supply of free labour. I am not aware of evidence that could confirm the first of these two deductions. On the one hand there existed centralized workshops in cotton manufacture already during the first part of the 18th century; on the other hand there was an increase of such workshops or factories from the middle of the century. But the question is whether this change could be said to be sufficiently large in order to connect it with the seemingly dramatic increase of free labour during the second part of the cen-tury. As to the second deduction I am not aware of evidence that could confirm that wage rates were lower in the early factories, rather it was the other way around; as to the relationship between the marginal productivity of labour and its elasticity of supply, there is no evidence that could test this relationship. We can only safely conclude that the elasticity of the supply of labour was not perfect, since the expansion of cotton industries to begin with mainly benefit-ted putting-out industries and created a shortage of labour. From this it seems reasonable to conclude that the creation of free labour during the 18th century was a necessary but not a sufficient condition for the rise of the factory system.

Another change in the input market that has been discussed is the fact that the size and cost of machinery for carding, spinning (and probably also printing) increased during the second part of the 18th century to an extent that made factory organization necessary, since this new larger and expensive machinery could either not be technically accommodated in a household (too large and/or in need of mechanical motive power like horses or water) or was too expensive for out-workers to buy. The increasing cost of machinery could explain why some (rich) and not all agents engaged in cotton manufacture switched over to factory production and, thus, contribute to the explanation of the differentiation of the cotton producers into factory owners and not-factory owners. The increasing size of machines could indeed explain the emergence

173

The Transition from Domestic Industries to Factories

of factories but this change could not alone be responsible for the pheno-menon, since, first, workers seem to have been centralized to factories also when machines were not so large (this has to be investigated more closely); secondly, since the increasing size of machines was itself a response to increa-sing demand for final output.

From this we provisionally conclude that the changes occurring in the in-put markets may have been necessary but not sufficient conditions for the rise of factories and, further, that these changes probably were induced by changes in the markets for final output.

When it comes to the second question raised above, namely to what extent it is possible to assign critical values for changes in demand for final output leading to factory organization, it seems as if we totally lack evidence for the task. We know that demand for cotton products increased very fast during the latter part of the 18th century (calicoes, muslins, velveret and earlier fustians, check and velvet); that the principal demand seems to have come from the working and middle classes thereby creating the first mass market for consumer goods; that this was due to the qualities of cotton as a textile, its cheapness and its ability to conquer markets for linen and wool products. We also know that this strong increase in demand put the putting-out organi-zation under severe pressure, leading to increasing carrying and fetching; to an increasing variation of product quality and increasing control problems; to — probably — an increasing rate of embezzlement of inputs and outputs; and to increasing labour costs due to leisure preferences among out-workers when wages rose because of the increasing demand for labour. We know this because contemporary observers have made such observations. But in order to prove it we need more and more quantitative data making it possible to com-pare variations in demand on the one hand and variations in choice of industry organization on the other hand; alternatively a number of phase studies where the transition from putting-out organization to factory organization could be studied at the firm level. In the absence of such data it might be possible to construct a conjectural history by making certain reasonable assumptions about specific variables. Assume e.g. that we could find the amount of carry-ing and fetching of products in the putting-out organization in a specific cotton industry district at two points in time and also data on demand, cost of produc-tion and profit margins. Then we might construct a schedule connecting varia-tions in demand on the one hand and variations in carrying and fetching costs and profitability on the other hand; assume further that we might construct similar schedules for e.g. degree of embezzlement and its costs on the one hand and demand and output variations on the other hand etc. Then it would be possible to construct a model on the basis of such relationships and their interrelations. The emergent results would depend upon the assumptions made but they would, at least, show us one possible world with empirical fragments.

The third question we raised above was about the merits and de-merits, respectively, of factory and putting-out organization in adapting to the obser-

174

Bo Gustafsson

ved changes in their environment. We raised this question because, first, the increasing demand for cotton products not only gave incentives to starting factory production but also expanded the putting-out organization; secondly, because the putting-out organization survived for a long time and still exists in other forms; thirdly, because factory organization and putting-out organization were frequently combined even during the time period investigated as well as later. This problem concerns in a sense the boundary conditions of these two organizations and the shape of the profitability trade-off between them and its conditions. The general observation to make is, first, that putting-out organizations in the cotton industry were more flexible than factory organiza-tion; could cater more easily for local or specific demand in contradistinction to foreign and mass demand; that there were no fixed costs for investments or labour; that inventory costs could be held low; and that risks connected with output decisions were wholly or mainly borne by the out-workers. In addi-tion one may mention that the out-workers could not combine for common interests as easily as factory workers. All this may explain why putting-out industries survived far into the 19th century, why they complement factory production at peak demand and for specific products in cotton manufacturing.

177

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

En vetenskapsmans verksamhet framgår helt opartiskt ur hans arbeten. Denna bibliografi har sammanställts av en människa som tagit del i Bo Gustafssons liv under hans sista år och som sörjer över hans för tidiga död. Jag har försökt att med hjälp av denna bibliografi följa hans väg som vetenskapsman och publicist.

Den vägen avbröts i förtid. Många vetenskapliga seminarier fick förgäves vänta på hans deltagande. Detta gäller i synnerhet det vittnesseminarium i april 2004 som tillägnades utgivningen av Kommunismens svarta bok. Boken kom att framkalla en våg av diskussioner. Ett annat seminarium, som Bo Gustafsson själv hade förberett och som handlade om Östeuropas ekonomiska utveckling under den föränderliga turbulenta tiden, fick hållas utan hans medverkan. Det ägde rum i juni 2000 på Kollegiet för samhällsforskning (SCASSS) i Uppsala. Vad Bo Gustafsson skulle ha kunnat säga, blev aldrig sagt i de publikationer som var menade att fortsätta denna bibliografi. Även hans memoarer ”Jag flög med att rött hallon i näbben” förblev oavslutade. Memoarskrivandet höll han på med så länge den plågsamma sjukdomen ännu gav honom kraft att skriva. Och just under dessa dagar föddes de dikter, med vilka Bo Gustafssons själ så småningom tog avsked av detta liv:

Solen glider Jungfru Marianed i djupet. Heliga Guds moderHavets skålar tag mig i famnenvävs till duk. vagga mig till ro.Måsar breder Bär mig i drömmen,vita vingar, för mig till hamnen skymning sveper red mig mitt hemallt till ro. där änglarna bo.

Dessa poetiska rader, som vittnar om själens ljusa uppenbarelser under sjukdomens svåra tid, föregår nu Bo Gustafssons vetenskapliga bibliografi. Han var en människa som hade en sällsynt begåvning och sällsynta själsliga egenskaper.

Larisa Oldireva GustafssonHösten 2005

178

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

Bibliografi

1955

”Synpunkter på Sovjetekonomin”. Vår tid 1955, häfte 11, s. 312–315.

1956

”Filialsverige och Tasmanien.” Ny Dag 1956-01-05, Arbetartidningen 1956-01-17.

”En klassiker.” Rec. av Marx, Karl, Till kritiken av den politiska ekonomin. Clarté 1956, häfte 2, s. 21

”De första filosoferna.” Rec. av Thomson, George, The First Philosophers. Clarté 1956, häfte 3, s. 42–43.

Rec. av Reubin, William, The Atom Spy Hoax. Ny Dag 1956-01-30, Arbetartidningen 1956-01-31.

Rec. av Aspelin, Gunnar, Tankelinjer och trosformer. Del 6. Ny Dag 1956-04-20, Arbetartidningen 1956-04-23.

1957

”Idéer inför rätta.” Clarté 1957, häfte 1, s. 8–9 .

”Marxismen omvärderar.” Clarté 1957, häfte 2, s. 2–3.

”Nuet och historien.” Rec. av Sweezy, Paul M., The Present as History. Clarté 1957, häfte 2, s. 22.

”Två åsikter om M. Djilas och hans bok. Ett antikommunistiskt missfall.” Clarté 1957, häfte 4, s. 15–22.

Rec. av Almquist, Carl Jonas Love, Dikter i landsflykt. Ny Dag 1957-02-15.

Rec. av Heckscher, Eli F., Svenskt arbete och liv. Ny Dag 1957-11-14.

1958

”Dessa de mycket fattiga.” Clarté 1958, häfte 3, s. 2–4.

”Altaret och penningpåsen som vetenskapligt problem.” Ny Dag 1958-01-15, Ar be tar -tidningen 1958-01-17.

179

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

”Thorild och tempelljuset.” Arbetartidningen 1958-10-01, 1958-10-02, Ny Dag 1958-10-01, 1958-10-02.

Rec. av Fleisher, Wilfrid, Sweden: The Welfare State. Science and Society 1958, 22 (3): 253–255.

”En annan uppfattning.” Rec. av Höglund, Zeth, Minnen i Fackelsken. Från Branting till Lenin. Revolutionernas år. Clarté 1958, häfte 1, s. 21–22.

”Kina förändras.” Rec. av China Reconstructs (Peking 1957). Clarté 1958, häfte 2, s. 22.

Rec. av Twain, Mark, The Complete Short Stories. Clarté 1958, häfte 3, s. 30.

Rec. av Villon, François, Det stora testamentet och andra ballader. Arbetartidningen 1958-05-07, Ny Dag 1958-05-07.

Teateranmälningar:

Josephson, Erland, Sällskapslek. (Uppsala, Stadsteatern). Ny Dag 1958-01-17.

Saroyan, William, Så länge vi lever. (Uppsala, Stadsteatern). Ny Dag 1958-02-01.

Feydeau, George, Fruar på vift eller Kalkontuppen. (Uppsala, Stadsteatern) Arbetar-tidningen 1958-04-12, Ny Dag 1958-04-12.

Weill, Curt och Anderson, Maxwell, Lost in the Stars. (Uppsala, Stadsteatern) Arbetar-tidningen 1958-11-08, Ny Dag 1958-11-08.

1959

”Från marxism till marginalism.” Clarté 1959, häfte 3, s. 26–27.

”Socialism i USA?” Clarté 1959, häfte 4, s. 22–23.

”Samuel Johnsons liv.” Ny Dag 1959-02-06.

”Lortvattensverige.” Arbetartidningen 1959-02-23, Ny Dag 1959-02-23.

”Henrik Bernhard Palmær.” Ny Dag 1959-02-25, Arbetartidningen 1959-02-26.

”Krigsutbrottet 1939.” Arbetartidningen 1959-08-25, 1959-08-26, 1959-08-27; Ny Dag 1959-08-25, 1959-08-26, 1959-08-27.

Inlägg med anledning av Samuelsson, Kurt, ”Sovjet och framstegen.” (Stockholms-Tidningen 1959-06-02, 1959-06-03, 1959-06-04). Arbetartidningen 1959-06-08, 1959-06-09, 1959-06-11, Ny Dag 1959-06-08, 1959-06-09, 1959-06-11.

”Ekonomi och politik.” Rec. av Strauss, Erich, Common Sense about the Common Market: Germany and Britain in Post-war Europe; Robertson, Dennis H., Lectures on Economic Principles; Wiksell, Knut, Selected Papers on Economic Theory; Arpi, Gunnar, Sveriges nutida näringsliv. Clarté 1958, häfte 1, s. 30.

180

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

”Historia.” Rec. av Stephenson, Carl, Medieval Feudalism; Haskins, Charles H., The Rise of the Universities; Neff, John U., Industry and Government in France and England 1540–1640. Clarté 1959, häfte 2, s. 30.

”Filosofi. Marxism.” Rec. av The Dictionary of Philosophy. Runes, Dagobert D. (ed.); Lewis, John, Marxism and the Irrationalists. Clarté 1959, häfte 2, s. 30–31.

”En bok om en resa.” Rec. av Takman, John, Vår vid sydkinesiska sjön. Clarté 1959, häfte 3, s. 37–38.

”Historia och filosofi.” Rec. av Nehru, Jawaharlal, Toward Freedom. Clarté 1959, häfte 3, s. 38.

”Personkulten dissekerad.” Rec. av Boffa, Giuseppe, Inside the Khrushchev Era. Clarté 1959, häfte 4, s. 14–16.

Rec. av Books on Communism. A Bibliography. Hunt, Carew R. N. (ed.). Clarté 1959, häfte 4, s. 32.

”Politisk ekonomi.” Rec. av Bljumin, I. G., Grundriss der modernen bürgerlichen politischen Ökonomie der USA; Domdey, Karl Heinz, Die deutschen Monopolie auf den äusseren Märkten, DDR – 300 Fragen 300 Antworten. Clarté 1959, häfte 4, s. 32.

Rec. av Palme, Sven, Kristendomens genombrott i Sverige. Arbetartidningen 1959-05-27, Ny Dag 1959-05-27.

Rec. av Bohr, Nils, Atomfysik och mänskligt vetande. Arbetartidningen 1959-07-31, 1959-08-01, Ny Dag 1959-07-31, 1959-08-01.

Rec. av Collinder, Björn, Språket. Arbetartidningen 1959-08-06, Ny Dag 1959-08-06.

Rec. av Lönnroth, Erik, Från svensk medeltid. Arbetartidningen 1959-09-22, Ny Dag 1959-09-22.

”Filosofernas elände.” Rec. av Wedberg, Anders, Filosofins historia och von Wright, G. H., Logik, filosofi och språk. Arbetartidningen 1959-10-05, 1959-10-06, Ny Dag 1959-10-05, 1959-10-06.

Rec. av Michailov, Nikolaj N., Rysslands nya geografi. Ny Dag 1959-10-23.

Rec. av Sigma. En matematikens kulturhistoria. Del 1. Ny Dag 1959-10-28.

Rec. av Tolstoj, Leo, Den andra epilogen till Krig och fred. Arbetartidningen 1959-12-01, Ny Dag 1959-12-01.

Teateranmälningar:

Tjechov, Anton, Tre systrar (Uppsala, Stadsteatern). Arbetartidningen 1959-03-03, Ny Dag 1959-03-02.

Shakespeare, Williams, Så tuktas en argbigga. (Uppsala, gästspel av Hälsingborgs stadsteater). Ny Dag 1959-05-29.

Sardou, Victorien, Madame Sans-Gêne (Uppsala, Stadsteatern). Ny Dag 1959-09-12.

181

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

1960

”SAP:s programförslag och socialismen.” Clarté 1960, häfte 1, s. 24–26.

”Den plundrade kontinenten. Intryck från en marxistisk konferens.” Clarté 1960, häfte 4, s. 23–25.

”Duellen Peking – Moskva. Den kubanska revolutionen.” Clarté 1960, häfte 3, s. 10–12.

”Sjustatsmarknaden och svenska näringslivets framtid.” Vår tid 1960, häfte 16, s. 41–51.

”Sociologisk omorientering. Kulturen på 60-talet.” Arbetartidningen 1960-02-29, Ny Dag 1960-02-29.

”Argument för ett socialistiskt Sverige.” Arbetartidningen 1960-03-17, 1960-03-18, Ny Dag 1960-03-17, 1960-03-18. Debattinlägg. Arbetartidningen 1960-04-25, Ny Dag 1960-04-25.

”Den privata industrins socialisering i Kina.” Arbetartidningen 1960-07-26, Ny Dag 1960-07-26.

”Den kinesiska linjen.” Arbetartidningen 1960-08-06, Ny Dag 1960-08-06.

Rec. av Schweitzer, Albert, Vördnad för livet; Gunnarson, Gunnar, Vardagsljud – evighets-ackord; Malmenström, Gunnar, Wiedenborg, Bo, 245 svenska storföretagsledare; Essays in Labour History (1886–1923). In Memory of G. D. H. Cole. Briggs, Asa and John Saville (eds.). Clarté 1960, häfte 1, s. 35–36.

”Marxism.” Rec. av Kornai, Janos, Overcentralization in Economic Administration; Engels as Military Critic (artiklar från Volunteer Journal och Manchester Guardian); Marx, Karl, Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts. Clarté 1960, häfte 1, s. 37.

Rec. av Doernberg, Steffan, Die Geburt eines neuen Deutschlands – 1945–1949; Mills, C. Wright, The Sociological Imagination; Romein, Jan, Das Jahrhundert Asiens: Geschichte des modernen asiatischen Nationalismus. Clarté 1960, häfte 2, s. 29.

Rec. av Friedrich Engels – Paul and Laura Lafargue: Correspondence, vol. I; Smelser, Neil J., Social Change in the Industrial Revolution; Stern, Bernhard J., Historical Sociology; Studies in the Industrial Revolution: Presented to T. S. Ashton. Pressnell L. S (ed.); Briggs, Asa, Chartist Studies; Hill, Christopher, Puritanism and Revolution; Robertson, Dennis, Lectures on Economic Principles, vol. III; Silverman, Jerry, Folk Blues. Clarté 1960, häfte 3, s. 45–46.

Rec. av Cole, George D. H., A History of Socialist Thought; Seton-Watson, Hugh, Neither War nor Peace; Schapiro, Leonard, The Communist Party of the Soviet Union. Clarté 1960, häfte 4, s. 37.

Rec. av Galbraith, John K., Överflödets samhälle. Arbetartidningen 1960-01-08, 1960-01-09.

Inlägg med anledning av Hedberg, Håkan, ”Håkan Hedberg besöker Kina.” (Stockholms-Tidningen 1960-12-05, 1960-12-12, 1960-12-17, 1960-12-22, 1960-12-28). Arbetar-tidningen 1960-12-02, Ny Dag 1960-12-02.

182

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

Teateranmälningar:

Tennesse, Williams, Plötsligt i somras (Uppsala och Gävle, Stadsteatern). Upsala Nya Tidning 1960-02-06.

Ostrovskij, Alexander, En skojares dagbok (Uppsala och Gävle, Stadsteatern). Svenska Dagbladet 1960-10-15.

Pirandello, Luigi, Henrik IV (Uppsala, Stadsteatern). Arbetartidningen 1960-12-06, Ny Dag 1960-12-06.

1961

“Rostow, Marx and the Theory of Economic Growth.” Science and Society1961, 25(3): 229–244.

”Svensk ekonomisk teori efter 1879.” Vår tid 1961, häfte 4, s. 119–143.

”Svensk ekonomisk teori: Knut Wicksell (1851–1926).” Vår tid 1961, häfte 6, s. 203–226.

”Sveriges planerade associering.” Clarté 1961, häfte 4, s. 19–20.

”Vad hindrar avrustning?” Arbetartidningen 1961-03-15, Ny Dag 1961-03-15.

”Sveriges försvar och kärnvapen-strategin.” Arbetartidningen 1961-06-15, Ny Dag 1961-06-15.

”Enhetspolitikens teori.” Arbetartidningen 1961-06-27, Ny Dag 1961-06-27.

”Vad är skönhet? En kinesisk debatt.” Arbetartidningen 1961-08-01, Ny Dag 1961-08-01.

”Matprofessorn som sinolog.” Arbetartidningen 1961-09-30, Ny Dag 1961-09-30.

”Berlinfrågans utveckling.” Rec. av Fleming, Denna F., The Cold War and its Origins 1917–1960. Clarté 1961, häfte 3, s. 30–32.

Diskussion av Björk, Karl, ”Läsning av partiprogram.” (Balans 1961, häfte 1, s 34–40). Clarté 1961, häfte 2, s. 12–14.

1962

”Sågverksindustrins arbetare 1890–1945.” Sågverksförbundet 1907–1957. Hildebrand, Karl-Gustaf (redaktör). s. 107–191. Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell, 1962.

”Svensk ekonomisk teori III: Gustav Cassel (1866–1944).” Vår tid 1962, häfte 3,s. 86–110.

”Kalvstek i himlens höjd?” Clarté 1962, häfte 1, s. 12–15.

”Från kapitalism till socialism: (1). Gammal kapitalism som ny.” Clarté 1962, häfte 4, s. 8–10.

183

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

”Från kapitalism till socialism: (2). Kapitalistisk ändalykt.” Clarté 1962, häfte 6, s. 26–28.

”Enhetspolitikens nödvändighet.” Arbetartidningen 1962-04-14, 1962-04-16, Ny Dag 1962-04-14, 1962-04-16.

”Löner och priser.” Rec. av Wilson, Thomas, Inflation; Fellner, William, The Problem of Rising Prices; Hanssen, Alvin H., Economic Issues of the 1960s. Clarté 1962, häfte 2, s. 18–19.

Rec. av Balassa, Bela A., The Hungarian Experience in Economic Planning. Clarté 1962, häfte 2, s. 22.

”Arbetaren i överflödssamhället.” Rec. av Zveig, Ferdynand, The Worker in an Afflu-ent Society. Clarté 1962, häfte 3, s. 28–29.

1963

Sverige och världshandeln. 55 sid. Stockholm: Arbetarkultur, 1963.

Källorna till Övre Norrlands försörjningsproblem under det moderna näringslivets genombrottsskede: rapport över arkivinventeringar oktober 1962–1963. 63 sid. Uppsala: Ekonomisk-historiska institutionen, 1963.

”Det spanska eländet i siffror.” Clarté 1963, häfte 3, s. 7–10.

”Sprickan i den socialistiska världen.” Clarté 1963, häfte 4, s. 10–12, 14.Andersson, Ingemar, ”Sprickan mellan Andersson och Gustafsson.” Clarté 1963, häfte 5, s. 8–10.

”Andersson och sprickan.” Clarté 1963, häfte 6, s. 18–21.

”Förhållandet mellan löner och priser.” Vårt tid 1963, häfte 1, s. 7–11.

”I stället för EEC.” Vår tid 1963, häfte 4, s. 113–122.

”EEC: s framtid.” Arbetartidningen 1963-02-26, 1963-02-28, Ny Dag 1963-02-26, 1963-02-28.

”Sverige och utrikeshandeln.” Arbetartidningen 1963-03-04, 1963-03-06, 1963-03-08, 1963-03-11, 1963-03-13, Ny Dag 1963-03-04, 1963-03-06, 1963-03-08, 1963-03-11, 1963-03-13.

”Kärnvapenfri zon i Skandinavien.” Arbetartidningen 1963-07-18.

[Artiklar med anledning av spionaffären.] Arbetartidningen 1963-07-04.

”Kärnvapenfri zon i Skandinavien.” Arbetartidningen 1963-07-18.

”Gamla och nya perspektiv.” Arbetartidningen 1963-08-08, Ny Dag 1963-08-08.

”Marxismen och den fredliga vägen.” Arbetartidningen 1963-09-24, Ny Dag 1963-09-24.

Rec. av Nurkse, Ragnar, Equilibrium and Growth in the World Economy. Science and Society 1963, 27 (4): 487–489.

184

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

1964

Från kolonialism till socialism. En essä om ekonomisk utveckling. 102 sid. Stockholm: Tidskriften Clarté 1964.

Rec. av: Lidman, Sara (Dagens Nyheter 1964-12-12), Mutén, Leif (Upsala Nya Tidning 1964-12-29), Wickremesinghe, B. (Svenska Dagbladet 1965-03-03), Sjöström, Hans O. (Aftonbladet 1965-04-22), Lundkvist, Arthur (Stockholmstidningen 1965-05-29), Werner, Peter (Arbetarbladet 1965-09-13).

”Den besvärlige Mr. Blackett.” Clarté 1964, häfte 1, s. 21–22.

”Sprickan tätas.” Clarté 1964, häfte 1, s. 27–28.

”Den portugisiska imperialismens nedgång och snara fall.” Clarté 1964, häfte 3, s. 25, 27, 29.

”1914: Slutet på en International, början på ett världskrig.” Clarté 1964, häfte 3, s. 33–34.

”Lokaliseringspolitik m/64.” Clarté 1964, häfte 6, s. 17–18.

Rec. av African Studies in Income and Wealth. Samuels, L. H. (ed.). Clarté 1964, häfte 1, s. 22–30.

Rec. av Inflation: Proceedings of a Conference held by the International Economic Association; Olderogge, D. A. and Potechin, I. I., Die Völker Afrikas. Clarté 1964, häfte 5, s. 20–21.

Inlägg med anledning av Gyllner, Birgitta, ”Rätten till fri abort.” (Dagens Nyheter 1964-05-10). Dagens Nyheter 1964-05-22.

1965

Den norrländska sågverksindustrins arbetare 1890–1913. Arbets­ och levnadsförhål-landen. (Ekonomisk-historiska studier 1). 217 sid. Uppsala: Svenska bokförlaget/ Norstedt.

Rec. av Ågren, Kurt (Upsala Nya Tidning 1966-08-27; Dagens Nyheter 1966-12-30), Sågvall, Kersti (Upsala Nya Tidning 1966-08-27), Svensson, Bengt (Historisk tidskrift 1966, häfte 4). Furhoff, Lars (The Scandinavian Economic History Review 1969, 17 (2)).

Från kolonialism till socialism. En essä om ekonomisk utveckling. 130 sid. Utökade uppl. med Lidman, Sara, ”Samtal över en klyfta” (förskrift). Stockholm: Tidskriften Clarté 1965.

V. I. Lenin i urval. Urval av Bo Gustafsson. 215 sid. Förord s. 5–9. W & W-serien 116. Stockholm: Wahlström & Widstrand, 1965.

Karl Marx & Friedrich Engels i urval. Urval av Bo Gustafsson. 269 sid. Förord s 5–9. W & W-serien 119. Stockholm: Wahlström & Widstrand, 1965.

”Vad kan vi lära av den kinesiska revolutionen?” Marxistiskt forum 1965, häfte 1, s. 15–17.

185

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

”Radions censur.” Clarté 1965, häfte 2, s. 21.

”Inflationen [i Latinamerika].” Clarté 1965, häfte 3, s. 19.

Rec. av Studies on Developing Countries, Sachs, Ignacy (ed.); Bettelheim, Charles, L’Inde independente; ”Gammal nazism i ny belysning.” Clarté 1965, häfte 2, s. 28–29.

1966

”Friedrich Engels and the historical role of ideologies.” Science and Society 1966, 25 (3): 257–274.

”Sågverksarbetarna i Norrland 1890–1913.” Kring industrialismens genombrott i Sve rige. Lundström, Ragnhild (redaktör). s. 208–223. Stockholm: Wahlström & Widstrand, 1966.

Fra kolonialisme til sosialisme: et essay om økonomisk utvikling. 98 s. Oslo: Elan-Bøkene, 1966.

”SKP:s stadgeförslag: en kritisk granskning.” Marxistiskt forum 1966, häfte 1, s. 50–68.

”Är detta socialism?” Marxistiskt forum 1966, häfte 2, s. 19–23.

”Det nya avtalet om företagsdemokrati.” Marxistiskt forum 1966, häfte 3, s. 20–24.

”Internationell politik.” Marxistiskt forum 1966, häfte 3, s. 56–57.

”En viktig seger för de verkliga fredsvännerna i Svenska Freds- och Skiljedoms-föreningen.” Marxistiskt forum 1966, häfte 4, s. 21–23.

”SÄPO och det svenska klassamhället.” Marxistiskt forum 1966, häfte 4, s. 50–57.

Arbete och kapital sedan 1945. 28 sid. Marxistiskt forum 1966, häfte 6.

”Versuch über den Kolonialismus.” Kursbuch 6 (1966: juli), s. 86–135.

Luxemburg, Rosa, Jag var, jag är, jag blir. Urval och förord av Bo Gustafsson. 250 sid. (Inledning ”Rosa Luxemburg och vår tids revolution.” s. 7–19). Boc-serien, Staffanstorp: Cavefors, 1966.

”Nyvänstern slår till.” Clarté 1966, häfte 5/6, s. 33–39.

”Varför Vietnam? Samhällsekonomiska orsaker till de kapitalistiska ländernas inter-vention i ‘tredje världen’.” Clarté 1966, häfte 5/6, s. 46–49.

”Reflexioner över en ideologisk pyttipanna.” Rec. av Samuelsson, Kurt, Är ideologi-erna döda? Clarté 1966, häfte 3, s. 26–28.

”Små klara himlabloss.” Rec. av Therborn, Göran, Borglid, Lars-Ola, Olofsson, Gunnar och Wiklund, Rune, En ny vänster. Clarté 1966, häfte 4, s. 5–6, 8–9.

186

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

1967

Reservation ställd till SKP:s programkommission med anledning av förslaget till ett nytt partiprogram. 16 sid. Uppsala: Tidskriften Marxistiskt forum 1967.

Vänsterpartiets ledare ‘summerar’. 15 sid. Uppsala: Tidskriften Marxistiskt forum 1967.

Mao Tse-tung, Politiska skrifter. Urval av Bo Gustafsson. 290 sid. (Inledning s. 7–17). Stockholm: Rabén & Sjögren, 1967.

Matsson, Ragnar Historia 2 (tiden efter 1789), för gymnasiets ekonomiska och tek-niska linjer. 280 sid. (under medverkan av Burgmann, Torsten, Degerman, Allan, Gustafsson, Bo och Lagerström, Herbert). Stockholm: Bokförlaget Liber, 1967.

”Sinjavskij: Brott och straff.” Clarté 1967, häfte 2, s. 29–31.

”Arbete och kapital.” Clarté 1967, häfte 3, s. 26–40.

”När Lenin talade för döva öron.” Clarté 1967, häfte 5, s. 10–12.

”Sovjetisk ekonomi 1917–1967”. Clarté 1967, häfte 5, s. 54–59.

”Leder förstatliganden till socialismen?” Marxistiskt forum 1967, häfte 1, s. 45–55.

”Gammalt vin i nya läglar.” Marxistiskt forum 1967, häfte 2, s. 48–50.

”Som i Frankrike före revolutionen.” Marxistiskt forum 1967, häfte 4, s. 46–49.

1968

Från kolonialism till socialism. En essä om ekonomisk utveckling. Med Sara Lidman ”Samtal över en klyfta” (förskrift). 130 sid. 4 uppl. Stockholm: Tidskriften Clarté 1968.

”Klassicism, marxism och marginalism.” Häften för kritiska studier 1968, häfte 1/2, s. 3–15.

Vad vill Kommunistiska förbundet? 66 sid. Uppsala: Marxistiskt forum,1968.

”USA, Dollarn och Vietnamkriget. Tal vid opinionsmöte i Uppsala 1 februari.” Clarté 1968, häfte 2, s. 34–41.

”Sovjetrevisionismen och ockupationen av Tjeckoslovakien.” Clarté 1968, häfte 5/6, s. 20–29.

”Röd front första maj.” Marxistiskt forum 1968, häfte 2, s. 37–44.

”Rösträtten under kapitalismen.” Marxistiskt forum 1968, häfte 3, s. 57–67.

187

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

1969

Marxism och revisionism. Eduard Bernsteins kritik av marxismen och dess idéhistoriska förutsättningar. Ekonomisk-historiska studier 4. 434 sid. Uppsala: Svenska bokför-laget, 1969.

Rec. av: Bromander, Lennart (Arbetarbladet 1970-02-28), Tarshys, Daniel (Expressen 1970-04-04), Gunnarsson, Gunnar (Tiden 1970, nr 5, s. 289–295), Aspelin, Kurt (Aftonbladet 1970-06-23), Runeby, Nils (Historisk Tidskrift 1970, nr 3, s. 411–427; Upsala Nya Tidning 1970-04-11).

”U-landsbiståndets politiska ekonomi.” U­hjälp i utveckling. 14 forskare och sam-hällsvetare om Sveriges u­landspolitik och utvecklingsbistånd. s. 42–60, W&W-serien 209. Stockholm: Wahlström & Widstrand, 1969.

”Stalin, Alexandersson och statistiken.” Marxistiskt forum 1969, häfte 3, s. 17–21.

”Varför är vänstern splittrad.” (osign.) Clarté 1969, häfte 2, s. 2.

”Ned med de nya tsarerna.” Clarté 1969, häfte 3, s. 26.

Förord och fackgranskning av Karl Marx, Kapitalet. Första boken. Kapitalets pro-duktionsprocess. 836 sid. Inledning s. vii–xxvi. Staffanstorp: Cavefors/Clarté, 1969.

”Jag ämnar plundra och göra det grundligt…”, ”Vilken väg…?” Tillägg i Huberman, Leo, Människans rikedomar. s. 263–287. Stockholm: Rabén & Sjögren, 1969.

”Stalin – en stor revolutionär.” Inlägg med anledning av Bengt Alexanderssons rec. av Conquest, Robert, The Great Terror i Dagens Nyheter 1969-04-03). Dagens Nyheter 1969-04-16.

Inlägg i debatten med anledning av Printz-Påhlson, Göran, ”Fem punkter om den nya vänstern.” Dagens Nyheter 1969–08–04.

1970

”Marxism och revisionism. En sammanfattning.” Nya avhandlingar. Historisk tid-skrift 1970, häfte 3, s. 411–417.

”Gunnarson, Bernstein och marxismen.” Tiden 1970, häfte 10, s. 610–615.Gunnarsson, Gunnar, ”Replik till papperstiger.” Tiden 1971, häfte 1, s. 55–56.

”30 år efter.” Efterskrift till Stalin, Josef, Om den dialektiska och historiska mate-rialismen. s. 37–60. Stockholm: Kommunistiska förbundet marxist-leninisterna, Göteborg: Haga, 1970.

”Till minnet av Ivan Bohman.” Gnistan 1970, nr 8, s. 4.

Diskussionsinlägg i debatten med anledning av Printz-Påhlson, Göran, ”Fem punkter om den nya vänstern.” Dagens Nyheter 1970-08-07.

188

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

Intervju av Uisk, Ahto med Bo Gustafsson, ”KFML – sann socialism eller kineseri?” Arbetaren 1970, nr 37, s. 5, 11.

Intervju av Kleberg, Lars med Bo Gustafsson, ”Bönder och herrar”. Ord och bild 1970, häfte 5, s. 344–349.

1971

”Ekonomisk tillväxtteori och ekonomisk historia.” Ur ekonomisk-historisk synvin-kel. Festskrift tillägnad professor Karl­Gustaf Hildebrand 25.4.1971. Ekonomisk-historiska studier 7, s. 49–82. Stockholm: Läromedelsförlagen, 1971.

”Marxistisk teori och idéhistorisk metod. En fallstudie.” Scandia 1971, band 37, nr 2, s. 340–397.

Socialkapitalismen: en kritik av sovjetekonomin. (En antologi redigerad av Bo Gustafsson). 188 sid. Inledning ”Socialkapitalism eller socialism”, s. 7-33. Stockholm: Rabén & Sjögren, 1971.

Från kolonialism till socialism. En essä om ekonomisk utveckling. Utökade uppl. med Lidman, Sara ”Samtal över en klyfta” (förskrift). 5 uppl. 130 sid. Stockholm 1971.

Förord till Lenin, V. I., Marknadsfrågan. Marxistiskt bibliotek (red. Bo Gustafsson). s. 5–26. Stockholm: Gidlunds, 1971.

Förord till Luxemburg, Rosa Socialdemokratins kris. Marxistiskt bibliotek (red. Bo Gustafsson). 191 sid. Inledning ”Rosa Luxemburg och Socialdemokratins kris. s. 5–24. Stockholm: Gidlunds, 1971.

Förord till Mehring, Franz, Karl Marx – hans livs historia. Första delen. Marxistiskt bibliotek (red. Bo Gustafsson). 386 sid. s. 5–35. Andra delen 776 sid. Stockholm: Gidlunds, 1971.

Förord till Marx, Karl, Klasstriderna i Frankrike 1848–1850. Marxistiskt bibliotek (red. Bo Gustafsson). 231 sid. s. 5– 35. Stockholm: Gidlunds, 1971.

Efterskrift till Somerville, John M., Marx’ och Engels’ samhällsvetenskapliga metod. Marxistiskt bibliotek (red. Bo Gustafsson). s. 127–129. Stockholm: Gidlunds, 1971.

Rec. av Fritz, Martin, Kirunagruvornas arbetskraft 1899–1905. The Scandinavian Economic History Review 1971, 19(1): 66–67.

1972

Marxismus und Revisionismus. Eduard Bernsteins Kritik des Marxismus und ihre ideengeschichtlichen Voraussetzungen, I-II. 491 sid. Frankfurt am Main: Europäische Verlagsanstalt, 1972.

”Sågverksarbetarna i Norrland 1890-1913.” Problem i svensk ekonomisk historia. Adamsson, Rolf & Jörberg, Lennart (redaktörer). s. 141–149. Lund: Gleerup, 1972.

189

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

“A perennial of doctrinal history: Keynes and ‘the Stockholm School’.” Economy and History1972, 16: 114–128.

”Den marxistiska teorin för samhällsförändringar.” Studier i historisk metod, 1972, häfte 8, s. 48–64.

”VPK:s nya programförslag.” Marxistiskt forum 1972, häfte 2, s. 13– 19.

”Röd front, VPK och KFML.” Marxistiskt forum 1972, häfte 4, s. 34– 36.

”Ett halvfärdigt program. Till kritiken av VPK:s programförslag.” Marxistiskt forum 1972, häfte 5, s. 10– 20.

”KFML 5 år?” (medförfattare Nils Holmberg) Gnistan 1972, nr 6/7, s. 18.

”Detta lär oss EEC-valet: Norge: Ett enat folk starkare är storkapitalet.” Gnistan 1972, nr 7, s. 6.

Förord till Marx K. – Engels F., Brev i urval. 252 sid. s. 5–7. Stockholm: Gidlunds, 1972.

Inledning till Varga, Eugen, Den ryska vägen till socialismen: ett politiskt testamente. s. 7–27. Stockholm: Rabén & Sjögren, 1971.

1973

”Det monopolkapitalistiska Sverige efter 1945. Välfärd med förhinder.” Historia i centrum och periferi. Graninger, Göran & Tägil, Sven (redaktörer). s. 291–299. Stockholm: Esselte studium, 1973.

”Det nya ekonomiska systemet i Ungern.” Marxistiskt forum 1973, häfte 4, s. 8–16.

”SKP:s första kongress – en seger för enhetspolitiken.” Marxistiskt forum 1973, häfte 5, s. 1–7.

”Centern på arbetsplatsen.” Marxistiskt forum 1973, häfte 6, s. 5–9.

”Rösträtten under kapitalismen.” Marxistiskt forum 1973, häfte 6, s. 28–33.

Stemmeretten under kapitalismen. Det kommunistiske parti. s. 26. Oslo: Marxistisk-leninistisk forlag, 1973 (övers. från Marxistiskt forum 1968, häfte 3).

”Så föddes VPK: Socialism via ‘strukturreformer’.” Gnistan 1973, nr 12, s. 10.

”1967 års kongress: Det var då VPK slopade Lenin.” Gnistan 1973, nr 14, s. 10.

”VPKs nya program oduglig vägledning till socialismen.” Gnistan 1973, nr 18, s. 10.

”Revolutionen som kom bort.” Gnistan 1973, nr 19, s. 10.

”För ett socialistiskt Sverige!” Gnistan 1973, nr 33, s. 14.

”Klasstriderna i Chile.” Gnistan 1973, nr 38, s. 10.

”Klasstriderna i Chile II. Folkfronten: programmet, valsegern och reformerna.” Gnistan 1973, nr 39, s. 10.

”Klasstriderna i Chile III. Vägen till nederlaget.” Gnistan 1973, nr 40, s. 10.

190

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

”Klasstriderna i Chile IV. Några lärdomar.” Gnistan 1973, nr 41, s. 10.

Rec. av Therborn, Göran, Klasser och ekonomiska system. Sociologisk forskning 1973, band 10, nr 3, s. 60–62.

Rec. av Steiger, Otto, Studien zur Enstehung der neuen Wirtschaftslehre in Schweden. The Scandinavian Economic History Review 1973, 21(1):126–127.

1974

”Capitalismo e socialismo nel pensiero di Bernstein.” Storia del marxismo contempo-raneo, Annali. Vol. XV, 1973. pag. 107–114. Milano, 1974.

”Perspektiv på den offentliga sektorn under 1930-talet” (under medverkan av Pihkala, Erkki, Tönnesson, Kåre D.) s.105–153. Kriser och krispolitik i Norden under mel-lankrigstiden. Mötesrapport. Nordiska historikermötet i Uppsala 1974. Uppsala: Almqvist & Wiksell, 1974.

Sydow, Björn von, ”Perspektiv på källor.” Historisk tidskrift 1975, häfte 3, s. 289–304.

Tal om revisionismen. 40 sid. Lund: Lunds Clartésektion, 1974.

”Idéer inför rätta.” Clarté 1974, häfte 1, s. 16–17.

Klasstriderna i Chile. 21 sid. Göteborg: Oktober, Stockholm: Ordfront, 1974.

”Fakta om socialimperialismen: Politisk opposition i Sovjetunionen, 1.” Marxistiskt Forum 1974, häfte 1, s. 28–35.

”Fakta om socialimperialismen. Den politiska oppositionen i Sovjetunionen.” Marxistiskt forum 1974, häfte 4, s. 6–14.

Ljunggren, Magnus, ”Hur stark är oppositionen i Sovjet? En kritisk granskning av SKP:s syn.” Liberal debatt 1974, häfte 4 s.14–16.

”För ett nytt kommunistiskt partiprogram.” Marxistiskt forum 1974, häfte 7/8, s. 4–12.

”Demokratin och socialismen: Infanteri, artilleri, kavalleri!” Gnistan 1974, nr 10, s. 10.

”Demokratin och socialismen: Proletariatets diktatur förutsättningar för folkets demo-krati.” Gnistan 1974, nr 13, s. 10.

”Kapitalexporten skapar arbetslöshet i Sverige.” Gnistan 1974, nr 13, s. 10.

Intervju av Lindgren, Stefan med Bo Gustafsson, ”Kapitalismen kan inte dräpas i köket”. Gnistan 1974, nr 33, s. 10.

1975

Marxismo y Revisionismo. La critica bernsteiniana del marxismo y sus premisas histórico-ideológicas. 439 pp. Collección Teoría y Realidad, 9. Barcelona, Buenos Aires, Mexico: Grijalbo, 1975.

191

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

”Perspektiv på en kritisk metod.” Historisk tidskrift 1975, häfte 4, s. 417–428.

”C. H. Hermansons politiska testamente.” Marxistiskt forum 1975, häfte 1, s. 2–7.

”Hur mogen måste tiden bli?” Marxistiskt forum 1975, häfte 2, s. 18–22.

”Hur mogen måste tiden bli? II.” Marxistiskt forum 1975, häfte 3, s. 11–16.

”Vad är kommunistisk kommunalpolitik?” Marxistiskt forum 1975, häfte 6, s. 12–14.

”De tyska kommunisterna, huvudmotsättningen och fascismens seger 1933.” Marxistiskt forum 1975, häfte 8, s. 15–19.

”Inflationen – är den nödvändig?” Förr och nu 1975, häfte 1, s. 33–48.

”USA:s ekonomi – ett korthus.” Gnistan 1975, nr 11, s. 14.

”Ett nytt 30-tal? När kommer krisen hit?” Gnistan 1975, nr 13, s. 14.

”Handen på hjärtat. Rudolf Meidner: Är det makten det gäller?” Gnistan 1975, nr 34, s. 14.

Furhoff, Lars, ”Bo Gustafsson är kommunist.” Dagens Nyheter 1975-02-05. Diskussion: Karl-Gustaf Hildebrand, Dagens Nyheter 1975-02-12; Lars Furhoff, Dagens Nyheter 1975-02-14; Per Sörbom, Dagens Nyheter 1975-02-20 [lärartillsätt-ningar].

1976

”Den ’nya’ ekonomisk-historiska forskningen och de kontrafaktiska förklaringarna. Några synpunkter.” Historisk tidskrift 1976, häfte 3, s. 273–288.

”Hur fysiokratisk var den svenska fysiokratismen?” Scandia 1976, band 42, nr 1, s. 60–91.

“Inside or Outside the Ivory Tower? Some Reflections on Social Science and Political Commitment.” Uppsala University 500 years 7. s. 15–26. Faculty of Social Sciences at Uppsala University. Uppsala: Acta Universitatis Upsaliensis, 1976.

”Modeller som tvångströja. Repliker.” (medförfattare: Odén, Birgitta, Ohlsson, Rolf, Olsson, Carl-Axel). Scandia 1976, band 42, nr 2, s. 88–108.

”Trotskismen som socialimperialismens försvarare.” (I) Marxistiskt forum 1976, häfte 1, s. 6–9.

”Trotskismen som socialimperialismens försvarare.” (II) Marxistiskt forum 1976, häfte 2, s. 12–15.

”Vad är en huvudmotsättning? (I).” Marxistiskt forum 1976, häfte 2, s. 16–20.

”Huvudmotsättning? (II).” Marxistiskt forum 1976, häfte 3, s. 9–11.

”Är KPD:s historia ‘främst en fråga om negativa erfarenheter’?” Marxistiskt forum, 1976, häfte 3, s. 12–17.

192

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

”Rösträtten under kapitalismen.” Marxistiskt forum 1976, häfte 4/5, s. 22–29.

”Lenin om klasser och partier.” Marxistiskt forum 1976, häfte 7/8, s. 66–72.

”30 år efter.” Stalin, Josef, Om dialektisk og historisk materialism. s. 29–42. København: Oktober, 1976.

”Behöver arbetarklassen bundsförvanter?” Gnistan 1976, nr 4, s. 18.

Rec. av Lundström, Ragnhild Alfred Nobel som internationell företagare. Den no-belska sprängämnesindustrin 1864–1886. (Uppsala Studies in Economic History 10. Östervåla, 1974). Historisk tidskrift 1976, häfte 1, s. 98–106 .

1977

Den offentliga sektorns expansion. Teori­ och metodproblem. Gustafsson, Bo (redak-tör). Bidrag från ett tvärvetenskapligt symposium i Uppsala 9–12 mars 1976. Uppsala Studies in Economic History 16. Acta Universitatis Upsaliensis. 269 sid. Inledning. s. 9–22. Uppsala: University, Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell international, 1977.

”Det som skapat tveksamhet är ytterst Lin-Biao-affären.” Ord och bild 1977, häfte 5/6, s. 65–68.

”Modeller som tvångströja.” (Replik på Krantz, Olle och Nilson, Carl-Axel, ”Mo dell-er från ekonomisk teori i historisk forskning”, Scandia 1976). Scandia 1977, band 43, häfte 1, s. 88–96.

”Vänstern måste delta i kampen för löntagarfonder.” Socialistisk debatt 1977, häfte 5, s. 20–29.

”Den offentliga sektorns expansion.” Saco/SR-tidningen 1977, nr 3, s. 24–25.

”Tre sätt att rädda Sverige.” Aftonbladet 1977-09-04.Bogården, Greger, ”Bo Gustafsson löper över till klassfienden: I SKP har hans idéer besegrats i öppen åsiktskamp.” Gnistan 1977, nr 26, s. 18.Lansman, Arvid, ”Bo Gustafsson rycker ut för att rädda kapitalismen.” Gnistan 1977, nr 35, s. 11.

1978

“A new look at Bernstein: some reflections on reformism and history.” Scandinavian Journal of History 1978, 3: 275–296.

”Imperialismen, tredje världen och historiens list.” Ekonomisk debatt 1978, häfte 5, s. 333–340; Aktuellt om historia 1979, häfte 1/2, s. 63–71.

”Den offentliga sektorns historia.” Arkivet för folkets historia 6, 1978, häfte 4, s. 10–21.

Rec. Adler-Karlsson, Gunnar, Dagens Nyheter 1978-01-10.

”Kapitalismens kris och vägen framåt.” Socionomen 1978, nr 17, s. 12–13.

193

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

”Kan vi lita på politikerna?” Medförfattare: Lindström, Ulla och Ditmark, Åke (med anledning av Björn von Sydows avhandling). Arbetaren 1978, nr 38, s. 8–9.

Rec. av Krantz, Olle och Nilsson, Carl-Axel, Swedish National Product 1861–1970: New Aspects on Methods and Measurement (1975). Statistisk tidskrift 1978, häfte 1, s. 71–76.

Rec. av Unga, Nils, Socialdemokratin och arbetslöshetsfrågan, 1912–1934: Fram­växten av den ’nya’ arbetslöshetspolitiken. The Economic History Review 1978, 31 (2): 333–335.

Rec. av Gamby, Erik, Per Götrek och 1800­talets svenska arbetarrörelse. Förr och nu 1972, häfte 2, s. 72.

”Hur Marx ’Kapitalet’ kom till.” Rec. av Rosdolsky, Roman, ’Kapitalets’ tillkomst-historia. Dagens Nyheter 1978-08-04.

Intervju av Norlin, Bo och Sahlén, Tom med Bo Gustafsson, ”Som helhet är SKP ett parti som går på tomgång och lever huvudsakligen för sin egen skull.” Zenit 1978, nr 58, s. 41–51. Replik av Borell, Klas i Zenit 1979, nr 59, s. 55–56.

1979

Post­industrial Society. Proceedings of an International Symposium Held in Uppsala from 22 to 25 March 1977 to Mark the Occasion of the 500th Anniversary of Uppsala University. Gustafsson, Bo (editor). 238 sid. Introduction pp. 7–16; ”Comment on Bettelheim, Charles, Economic Politics and Political Economy in China.” pp. 169–183. London: Croom Helm, 1979.

”Missvisande om mirakelperioder.” Ekonomisk debatt 1979, häfte 2, s. 85–94.Diskussion: Rydenfelt, Sven. Ekonomisk debatt 1979, häfte 4, s. 297–299.

”Västtyskland och kärnkraften: demonstranter knäcks med straffavgifter.” Dagens Nyheter 1979-04-10.

”80-talets Sverige som jag vill se det.” Dagens Industri 1979-05-08.

”Möte med marxismens världsbild. En sommar i lejonets kula.” Dagens Nyheter 1979-08-17

”Facklig aktivitet och lönebildning.” Rec. av Björklund, Jörgen, Strejk–förhandling–avtal. Historisk tidskrift 1979, häfte 99, s. 346–348.

”Trade unions in the Swedish sawmills.” Review of Björklund, Jörgen, Strejk–för-handling–avtal. The Scandinavian Economic History Review 1979, 27 (2): 190.

”Att skriva historia.” Rec. av Odén, B. (red.), Att skriva historia. Dagens Nyheter 1979-07-19.

194

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

”Vad är barn och vad är badvatten? En kommentar till ‘Alternativens möjlighe-ter’.” Diskussionsinlägg med anledning av Anderstig, Christer och Wibe, Sören, ”Alternativens möjligheter.” (Zenit 1979, häfte 2, s. 1–10). Zenit 1979, häfte 2, s. 11–14.

Höög, Victoria, ”Bo Gustafsson, vetenskap & politik.” Tekla 1979, häfte 7, s. 4–23.

1980

”Hur arbetet skapade människan – arbetet i marxismens perspektiv.” Arbetets värde och mening. Sörbom, Per (redaktör), s. 57–65. Stockholm: Liber förlag, 1980.

”Arbetslösheten i historiskt och ekonomiskt perspektiv.” Socialmedicinsk tidskrift 1980, häfte 3, s. 180–189.

”Finns det ekonomiska drivkrafter för Sovjetunionens expansionism?” Ekonomisk debatt 1980, häfte 7, s. 512–521.

”Industrihistorisk forskning.” Daedalus: Tekniska museets årsbok 49, s. 51–52. Stockholm: Tekniska museet, 1980.

”Som självmord i rädsla för döden.” Folket i bild 1980, häfte 3, s. 6.

”Vilket program kan få fart på Sverige?” SAF-tidningen 1980, nr 34, s. 16–17.

”Vägen ut ur krisen.” Tiden 1980, häfte 8, s. 531–541.

”Arbetarrörelsen försummade ideologin och strategin. Efter valet.” LO-tidningen 1980, nr 5, s. 8–9.

”Dra igång ekonomin och lägg in en högre växel.” LO-tidningen 1980, nr 51/52, s. 12–13.

Diskussion med anledning av ”3 x 300 olika sektorer!” (LO-tidningen 1980, nr 37, s. 1–12). LO-tidningen 1980, nr 38, s. 8–9.

”Meddelanden och aktstycken: den svenska arbetarklassen och reformismen.” Rec. av Hentilä, Seppo, Den svenska arbetarklassen och reformismens genombrott inom SAP före 1914: arbetarklassens ställning, strategi och ideologi. Historisk tidskrift för Finland 1980, häfte 2, 165–183.

Intervju av Bernhardsson, Bo med Bo Gustafsson, ”I det här samhället är det faktiskt socialdemokraterna som representerar arbetarklassen.” Socialistiskt forum 1980, häfte 1, s. 16–19.

Intervju av Köll, Anu Mai med Bo Gustafsson, ”Vart tog marxismen vägen? Kring den svenska universitetsvänstern.” Ord och bild1980, häfte 5, s. 3–27.

195

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

1981

I övermorgon socialism. 202 sid. Stockholm: Gidlunds, 1981.Rec. av Abrahamsson, Sten-Erik (Hufvudstadsbladet 1982-01-28), Augustsson, Lars Åke (SIA 1981, häfte 17, s. 10–11), Moelv, Bjarne (Folket 1981-06-04), Herrström, Thorleif (Ny Dag 1981-06-05), Engqvist, Lars (Arbetet 1981-06-11), Nycander, Svante (Dagens Nyheter 1981-06-11), Ehnmark, Anders (Expressen 1981-06-11), Nycander, Svante och Gustafsson, Bo (Dagens Nyheter 1981-06-13), Lundh, Christer (Sydsvenska Dagbladet Snällposten 1981-06-16), Fredriksson, Gunnar (Aftonbladet 1981-06-17), Persson, Anders (Helsingborgs Dagblad 1981-06-23), Lidström, Gill (Göteborgs­Posten 1981-06-27), Therborn, Göran (Svenska Dagbladet 1981-06-30), Sörlin, Sverker (Västerbottens Folkblad 1981-97-29), Jonsgården, Kenneth (Arbetarbladet 1981-07-29), Kumm, Evert (Västgöta­Demokraten 1981-11-24), Gustafsson, Bo (Västgöta­Demokraten 1981-12-17, diskussion).

”Den ekonomiska krisen och den offentliga sektorn – några synpunkter.” Statens bud-getunderskott och upplåningspolitik. Förutsättningar och konsekvenser i hushåll och företag. s. 9–32. Stockholm: Sparfrämjandet, 1981.

”John Maynard Keynes viktigaste tes: sänkta löner fel medicin mot arbetslöshet.” LO-tidningen 1981, nr 21, s. 16, nr 22/23, s. 12.

”Vi måste få i gång investeringsprocessen.” Dagens Nyheter 1981-03-21.

”En vithårig tornado på Grange Road.” (Robinson, Joan). Dagens Nyheter 1981-11-01.

Diskussion av Sandberg, Nils-Eric, ”Om socialism.” (Dagens Nyheter 1981-07-25). Dagens Nyheter 1981-11-08.

”Löntagarfonder i Pariskommunens efterföljd.” (Med anledning av Liljestrand, Lars-Gunnar, diskussion i Clarté 1980, häfte 4/5.) Clarté 1981, häfte 1, s. 42–43.

Diskussion: Liljestrand, Lars-Gunnar i Clarté 1981, häfte 2, s. 32–35.

”Ny startpunkt i löntagarfondsfrågan.” (Med anledning av Hedborg, Anna och Edin, Per-Olof, Det nya uppdraget.) LO-tidningen 1981, nr 17/18, s. 8–10.

”Tanken och makten.” Debattinlägg. Expressen 1981-07-23.

”Allvarligt om Grassman tigs ihjäl.” (Med anledning av Grassman, Sven Det tysta riket.) LO-tidningen 1981, nr 43, s. 9.

Diskussion: Grassman, Sven, LO-tidningen 1981, nr 46, s. 12.

Diskussion med anledning av Reberg, Arne, ”Loskor på folkhemsfönstret.” (Fönstret 1981, nr 16, s. 12–13). Fönstret 1981, nr 16, s. 18.

Intervju av Larsson, Stefan med Bo Gustafsson, ”Löntagarfonder – hopp eller flopp.” Nerikes Allehanda 1981-09-15.

Intervju av Svensson, Tommy med Bo Gustafsson, ”SKPs grundare som blev social-demokrat: respekten för människor viktigare än tolkningen av Marx.” Metallarbetaren 1981, nr 35, s. 20–22.

196

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

1982

“Beyond welfare capitalism. Issues, actors and forces in societal change. Review sym-posium.” (co-authors: Himmelstrand, Ulf, Ahrne, Göran, Lundberg, Leif, Lundberg, Lars). Acta Sociologica 1982, 25 (3): 301–317.

”Löntagarfonder – demokrati och effektivitet.” Tiden 1982, häfte 6, s. 365–385.

”Forskarutbildningens mål.” Tiden 1982, häfte 10, s. 609–620.Diskussion: Eriksson, Olof, Tiden 1983, häfte 2, s. 109–113.

”Med nya besparingar körs svenskt näringsliv i botten.” LO-tidningen 1982, nr 7, s. 13.

”Löntagarfonder och marknadsekonomi: Jämför fondsystemet med verkligheten – inte med läroböckernas värld.” LO-tidningen 1982, nr 17, s. 16; nr 18, s. 16; nr 19, s. 16.

”Bakgrunden till KFML:s bildande – några personliga anteckningar. Kommunistisk ideologi. Programdebatt och idéutveckling. Kommunismen i Sverige.” Med delanden från Arbetarrörelsens arkiv och bibliotek 1982, häfte 24/25, s. 81–85.

”Fondmotståndet är taktiskt betingat.” Dagens Nyheter 1982-08-20.

Diskussionsinlägg ”Välfärdsforskning och industriell återhämtning.” Tiden 1982, häfte 4, s. 244–248.

Diskussion med anledning av Ingelstam, Lars, ”Varför har vi inte råd med tjänster?” (Stockholms Tidningen 1982-06-02). Stockholms Tidningen 1982-06-09.

Diskussionsinlägg. [Devalveringen.] Svenska Dagbladet 1982-10-18.

”Rådgivare Eklunds ’bistra sanning’ har betänklig slagsida: Inte ett ord om arbetslös-heten.” Rec. av Eklund, Klas, Den bistra sanningen. LO-tidningen 1982, nr 43, s. 9.

Intervju av Zetterberg, Leif med Bo Gustafsson och Håkan Arvidson, ”Leninismens kris…syndikalismens möjlighet?” Arbetaren 1982, nr 5, s. 6–7.

1983

Marx och marxismen. 179 sid. Stockholm: Gidlunds/Verdandi, 1983. Rec. av: Lindblom, Paul (Arbetet 1983-03-11), Anderberg, Rolf (Göteborgs­Posten 1983-03-14): Rec. Nr 85 (Svenska Dagbladet 1983-03-14), Myrdal, Jan (Dagens Nyheter 1983-03-14), Annerstedt, Jan (Östersunds-Posten 1983-03-23), Höög, Lars (Östersunds-Posten 1983-03-23), Kumm, Evert (Östersunds-Posten 1983-03-23), Schwartz, Nils (Östersunds-Posten 1983-03-23), Swedenmark, Peter (Östersunds-Posten 1983-03-23), Östrand, Thomas (Östersunds-Posten 1983-03-23), Eriksson, Birger (Dala-Demokraten 1983-03-24), Forser, Tomas (Dagens Nyheter 1983-03-30), Myrdal, Jan (Dagens Nyheter 1983-03-30).

197

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

”Imperialismen, tredje världen och historiens list.” U-landsekonomi. Jonung, Lars (redaktör). s. 21–29. Malmö: LiberFörlag, 1983.

”The causes of the expansion of the public sector in Sweden during the 20th cen-tury.” Annales Societatis Litterarum Humaniorum Regiae Upsaliensis. Kungliga Humanistiska vetenskapssamfundets i Uppsala årsbok 1981–1982. s. 11–42. Uppsala: Almquist & Wiksell, 1983.

The causes of the expansion of the public sector in Sweden during the 20th century. Uppsala Papers in Economic History. Research report 1. 42 p. Uppsala: Department of Economic History, 1983.

”Nedgången kan åter vändas till uppgång: Om likheterna med 30-talskrisen.” LO-tidningen 1983, nr 1/2, s. 14–15.

”Mer om 1984 års forskningspolitiska proposition.” Tiden 1983, häfte 4, s. 244–248.

”En omöjlig tusenlapp? Marx och ekonomisk kris.” Fönstret 1983, häfte 5, s. 10–12.

”Vi kan inte spara oss ur krisen om vi inte ökar investeringarna.” LO-tidningen 1983, nr 11, s. 10–11.

”Första steget på väg till löntagarägande: Fond-debatten.” LO-tidningen 1983, nr 33, s. 6.

”Bakgrunden till KFML: några personliga anteckningar.” Arbetarhistoria 1983, häfte 23/25, s. 81–85.

”Är konservatismen död?” Svenska Dagbladet 1983-10-28.

Diskussion med anledning av Jakobsson, Ulf, ”Ekonomisk utveckling i länder med stora offentliga underskott.” (Skandinaviska Enskilda bankens kvartalsskrift, 1983, nr 1, s. 18–27). LO-tidningen 1983, nr 23/24, s. 13, nr 35, s. 13.

Intervju av Silverberg, Bo med Bo Gustafsson, ”Utan löneföljsamhet: risk för sämre resultat i offentliga sektorn.” Fackläraren 1983, nr 6, s. 8–9.

1984

”Exporten ensam kan inte dra Sverige ur krisen.” LO-tidningen 1984, nr 1/2, s. 12–13.

”Keynesianismen vidareutvecklad.” Tiden 1984, häfte 2, s. 100–110.

”En bra början…: Modell eller parentes?” Rec. av Hedborg, Anna och Meidner, Rudolf, Folkhemsmodellen. LO-tidningen 1984, nr 25, s. 18.

”Feldts felaktiga funderingar: Samtal med Feldt.” LO-tidningen 1984, nr 35, s. 8–9.

198

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

Diskussion med anledning av Lindqvist, Sven, ”Ryssarna vill fram till Indiska ocea-nen!” (Nya Wermlands-Tidningen 1984-09-22) och ”Vad händer i Afghanistan?” (Dagens Nyheter från 1984-04-21 till 1984-06-24). Dagens Nyheter 1984-07-24.

Intervju av Sten, Göran med Bo Gustafsson och Gunnar Heckscher, ”Bo Gustafsson och Gunnar Heckscher: självständiga ämbetsmän problem för demokratin.” SACO/SR tidningen, 1984, nr 3, s. 4–5.

1985

Det antika slaveriets nedgång: En ekonomisk teori. Uppsala Papers in Economic His-tory. Research report No 10. 91 sid. Uppsala: Department of Economic History, 1985.

”L’esperienza svedese della cogestione e die fondi dei lavoratori.” I Limiti della Democrazia, Baldassare, A. (ed.), pag. 110–143. Bari: Laterza, 1985.

”Det antika slaveriets nedgång: En ekonomisk teori.” Aktuellt om historia 1985, häfte 1/2, s. 70–88.

”Missvisande om mirakelperioder.” Ekonomisk historia. Jörberg, Lennart (redaktör). s. 37–46. Stockholm: Liber förlag, 1985.

”Nog är vi överens? Replik.” Tiden 1985, häfte 1, s. 48–50.

”Från överhetsstat till välfärdssamhälle.” Tiden 1985, häfte 5/6, s. 267–275.

”Industrin kan producera 5 proc mer utan kostnader!” LO-tidningen 1985, nr 9, s. 8–9.

”Skyll inte bara på lönerna – inflationen är en onyttighet som antingen tillverkas eller importeras”. LO-tidningen 1985, nr 27/33, s. 6–7.

”Speglas hela verkligheten? (Samhälle och mediebild).” Upsala Nya Tidning 1985-01-19.

”Varför historisk arbetsmiljöforskning.” Arbetslivets historia. s. 11–13. Stockholm: Arbetarskyddsfonden, 1986.

1986

“Conflict, confrontation and consensus in modern Swedish history.” Economics and Values. Arvidson, Lennart, Hägg, Ingemund, Lönnroth, Måns & Rydén, Bengt (edi-tors). pp. 16–50. Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell, 1986.

“Co-determination and wage earners’ funds.” Towards a Democratic Rationality: Making the Case for Swedish Labour. Fry, John Allan (ed.), pp. 86–109. Aldershot: Gower, 1986.

”Mellan socialistiskt ideal och kapitalistisk verklighet.” Arbetarhistoria. Meddelanden från Arbetarrörelsens arkiv och bibliotek 1986, häfte 1/2, s. 16–27.

”Öppet brev till kulturministern: dynga i TV.” Dagens Nyheter 1986-08-12.

”Sociologiprofessuren i Lund.” Sydsvenska Dagbladet 1986-09-12.

199

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

Diskussion med anledning av Tännsjö, Torbjörn, ”Demokrati till salu!” (Dagens Nyheter 1986-11-22). Dagens Nyheter 1986-12-13.

”Låt Hemläkarjouren leva!” Diskussion med anledning av Åkesson, Åke, ”Skall Hemläkarjouren stoppas?” (Upsala Nya Tidning 1986-10-02). Upsala Nya Tidning 1986-11-12.

Intervju av Sundling, Janne med Bo Gustafsson, ”Högre löner är bra ekonomisk poli-tik”. Kommunalarbetaren 1986, nr 27, s. 12–14.

1987

Cassel, Gustav. The New Palgrave Dictionary: A Dictionary of Economics. Vol. I. pp. 375–377. London: The Macmillan Press, 1987.

“The rise and economic behaviour of the medieval craft guilds. An economic-theoret-ical interpretation.” The Scandinavian Economic History Review 1987, 25 (1): 1–40.

”Hur vägarna blev en kollektiv nyttighet.” Över gränsen. Festskrift till Birgitta Odén. Norrlid, Ingemar (redaktör). s. 83–103. Lund: Historiska institutionen, 1987.

Intervju av Andersson, Mats J. med Bo Gustafsson, ”Professor i Uppsala: offentliga sek-torn kan visst växa! Men den måste bli bättre.” Statsanställd 1987, nr 2, s. 12–13.

Intervju av Linder, Bengt-Olof med Bo Gustafsson, ”Arbetarrörelsen är svag: Vägval – visioner.” LO-tidningen 1987, nr 39, s. 6–7.

”Risk för på-stället-marsch (Bo Gustafsson svarar Feldt).” Med anledning av en in-tervju med Bo Gustafsson om SAP:s ekonomiska politik. Kommunalarbetaren 1987, nr 1, s. 15.

1988

Den tysta revolutionen. Det lokala välfärdssamhällets framväxt: exemplet Örebro 1945–1982. 237 sid. Hedemora: Gidlunds, 1988.

Rec. av Andersson, Kerstin (Nerikes Allehanda 1988-09-10), Lenander, Anne-Marie (Nerikes Allehanda 1989-02-22), Mundebo, Ingemar (Upsala Nya Tidning 1989-04-29).

Den ekonomiska vetenskapens utveckling. Del 1: Från Aristoteles till Adam Smith. Uppsala Papers in Economic History. Basic reading No 4 (1976). 137 sid. Uppsala: Department of Economic History, 1988.

”Regeringskapitalism eller socialism?” Clarté 1988, häfte 1960–1985 (Axplock), s. 16–19. Tidigare införd i Clarté 1961, häfte 2.

”Sprickan i den socialistiska världen.” Clarté 1988, häfte 1960–1985 (Axplock), s. 22–27. Tidigare införd i Clarté 1963, häfte 4. Diskussion i Clarté 1988, häfte 3/4, s. 27–32.

200

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

”Andersson och sprickan.” Clarté 1988, häfte 1960–1985 (Axplock), s. 27–32. Tidigare införd i Clarté 1963, häfte 6.

”Sprickan tätas.” Clarté 1988, häfte 1960–1985 (Axplock), s. 34–35. Tidigare införd i Clarté 1964, häfte 1.

”Små klara himlabloss.” Clarté 1988, häfte 1960–1985 (Axplock), s. 48–55. Tidigare införd i Clarté 1966, häfte 4.

”Varför Vietnam?” Clarté 1988, häfte 1960–1985 (Axplock), s. 80–84. Tidigare in-förd i Clarté 1966, häfte 5/6.

”Höj landstingsskatten!” Upsala Nya Tidning 1988-09-09.

1989

”Från gåva till tribut. Om klassamhällets uppkomst.” Kungl. vitterhets historie och antikvitets akademiens årsbok, 1989. s. 93–111. Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell, 1989.

Myrdal, Karl Gunnar. Svenskt biografiskt lexikon. Nilzén, Göran (redaktör). Band 26, s. 144–160. Stockholm, 1987–1989.

”Socialism och kapitalism i samexistens.” Arbetarhistoria 1989, häfte 4, s. 6–8.

”Karl Marx återupplivad.” LO-tidningen 1989, nr 34, s. 22–23.

”Slå tillbaka nyliberalism i arbetarrörelsen: SAP 100 år.” Kommunalarbetaren 1989, nr 11, s. 24–25.

Diskussion med anledning av Heyman, Ulf, ”Högskolorna måste ta initiativet!” (Upsala Nya Tidning 1989-07-05). Upsala Nya Tidning 1989-07-19, 1989-07-20.

1990

Gunnar Myrdal 1898–1987: Liv och verk. Uppsala Papers in Economic History. Research Report No 25. 29 sid. Uppsala, 1990 (ett särtryck ur Svenskt biografiskt lexikon, band 26, 1989).

The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties. Aoki, Masahiko, Gustafsson, Bo and Williamson, Oliver (editors). 385 p. London: Sage, 1990.

”Den offentliga sektorns expansion.” Forskning i ett föränderligt samhälle. Härnqvist, Kjell & Svensson, Nils-Eric (redaktörer). Stiftelsen Riksbankens Jubileumsfond 1965–1990. s. 102–124. Hedemora: Gidlunds, 1990.

Introduction. (co-author Fridjonsdottir, Katrin). The Scandinavian Economic History Review 1990, 38 (2): 3.

”Marxismens motsägelser.” Svenska Dagbladet 1990-02-15.

201

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

1991

Människa, miljö, samhälle: ett antal uppsatser författade av forskare inom sam-hällsvetenskapliga fakulteten och utgivna i anslutning till fakultetens jubileumsår 1989–1990. Gustafsson, Bo (redaktör). Inledning s. 7–21. 251 sid. Uppsala: Samhällsvetenskapliga fakulteten, 1991.

”The rise and economic behaviour of medieval craft guilds.” Power and Economic Insti-tutions: Reinterpretations in Economic History. Gustafsson, Bo (ed.), pp. 69–106. Introduction, pp. 1–50. Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 1991.

Rec. av Clark, Gregory. Business, History, Review 1992, 66 (3): 606–608.

”Ägande, makt och marknad – den marxistiska traditionen och dess framtid.” Makten över företagen. Eidem, Rolf & Skog, Rolf (redaktörer) Serie: Maktutredningens pu-blikationer. s. 245–275. Stockholm: Carlsson, 1991.

1992

Intervju av Bratt, Peter med Bo Gustafsson, ”Politiken offrad för marknaden.” Dagens Nyheter 1992-09-05.

Diskussion med anledning av Lagerlöf, Karl-Erik, ”Ekonomer förstår inte ekonomi.” (Dagens Nyheter 1992-02-24). Dagens Nyheter 1992-05-14.

1993

Rationality, Institutions and Economic Methodology. Mäki, Uskali, Gustafsson, Bo, Knudsen, Christian, (eds.). Economics as social theory (serie). Preface, pp. ix–xi. 312 p. London and New York: Routledge, 1993.

Rec. av Cowen, Tyler, Journal of Economic Methodology 1995, 2 (1): 154–157.

Markets and democracy: participation, accountability and efficiency. Bowles, Samuel, Gintis, Herbert, Gustafsson, Bo (eds.). Preface, pp. xv–xviii. 340 p. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1993

Rec. av Dugger, William M., Journal of Economic Issues 1994, 28 (3): 946–948; Dorman, Peter, Journal of Economic Literature 1995, 28 (1): 227–228.

”Läror, läromästare och lärogångar.” De lärdas bibliotek. Trettio uppsalaprofessorer om betydelsefulla böcker, s. 117–128. Stockholm: Atlantis, 1993.

”Sverige och EG: Anmärkningar.” Häften för kritiska studier 1993, häfte 1/2, s. 130–134.

”Marknad och sjukvård.” Upsala Nya Tidning 1993-02-03.

Diskussion med anledning av Ehrenberg, Måns, ”De kvinnliga forskarna försvinner.” (Upsala Nya Tidning 1993-04-07). Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-06-03.

Diskussion med anledning av Spång, Torgny, ”Premietandvård ger problem.” (Upsala Nya Tidning 1993-05-21). Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-06-23.

202

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

1994

”Arbetet skapar människan.” Årsbok för kristen humanism 1994, s. 71–80.

”Den tysta revolutionen.” Den svenska modellen. Thullberg, Per & Östberg, Kjell (redaktörer). s. 142–160. Lund: Studentlitteratur, 1994.

”Kön går före kompetens.” Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-02-02.

”Klar majoritet behövs i EU-frågan.” Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-09-23.

”EU hotar demokratin!” Diskussion med anledning av Elvander, Nils, ”Argument för ja till EU.” (Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-09-28). Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-10-07.

”EU bäddar för arbetslöshet.” Diskussion med anledning av Nils Elvanders replik i Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-10-26. Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-11-10.

”Toppstyrd hantering av EU-frågan.” Replik på Brolund, Åke, ”Tätortsfinland sade JA!” Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-10-18.

Diskussion med anledning av Strömholm, Stig, ”En studietid med många viktiga val.” (Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-09-01). Upsala Nya Tidning 1994-09-21.

Intervju av Neuman, Ricki med Bo Gustafsson, ”Begreppet jämlikhet var politisk ledstjärna – men den liberala traditionen hotades aldrig hävdar akademiker apropå 1968 års vänsters väg.” Svenska Dagbladet 1994-04-11.

1995

”Foundations of the Swedish model.” The Nordic Journal of Political Economy 1995, 22: 5–26.

”Marknadens möjligheter och begränsningar.” Filosofi och specialvetenskap: sju uppsatser utgivna med anledning av föreningens sextioåriga tillvaro. s. 125–152. Uppsala: Förening för filosofi och specialvetenskap (Uppsala: Wikström), 1995.

”Kön går före kompetens.” Upsala Nya Tidning 1995-02-02. Diskussionsinlägg Upsala Nya Tidning 1995-02-11.

Intervju av Hansson, Tom, ”Lika mycket livsstil som ideologi: professor Bo Gustafsson justerar protokollet efter sextiotalet, vänstern och maoismen.” Svenska Dagbladet 1995-10-11.

1996

“The industrial revolution in Sweden.” The industrial revolution in national con-text: Europe and the USA. Teich, Mikulás, Porter, Roy and Bo Gustafsson (editors), pp. 201–225. 413 p. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1996.

203

Bo Gustafsson – bibliografi 1931–2000

”Ekonomisk effektivitet och rättvisa.” Årsbok för kristen humanism 1996, s. 8–34.

”Offentliga åtaganden: Teori och historia.” Det offentliga åtagandet – en antologi. s. 45–65. Riksrevisionsverket, häfte 41. Stockholm, 1996.

”SCASSS – origins and rationale. Reflections of the first ten years.” Annual Report 1995–1996, pp. 47–57. Uppsala: Kollegiet för Samhällsforskning, 1996.

”Arvet har länge stoppat ny ekonomisk historia.” Rec. av Magnusson, Lars, Sveriges ekonomiska historia. LO-tidningen 1996, nr 25, s. 26.

”Mannen som gick till historien medan han levde.” Rec. av Forser, Tomas, Jag har speglat århundradet. LO-tidningen 1996, nr 31, s. 15.

”Leta efter sambandet mellan kunskap och kön!” Debattinlägg med anledning av Rothstein, Bo, ”Instängda i sitt kloster: öppet brev om feminismen.” (Dagens Nyheter 1996-01-12). Dagens Nyheter 1996-01-22.

Diskussion. Jonsson, Stefan, ”Sextiotalet bortom gott och ont: när kommer berät-telsen om hur 60-talets optimism vändes till 90-talets pessimism?” (Dagens Nyheter 1996-01-16). Dagens Nyheter 1996-02-02.

1997

“Nature and economy.” Nature and Society in Historical Context. Teich, Mikuláš, Porter, Roy and Bo Gustafsson (editors), pp. 347–363. Introduction, pp. 1–8. 400 p. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997.

Rec. av Stoll, Mark, Journal of the History of the Behavioral Sciences 2000, 36 (2): 176–177.

Scope and limits of the market. Uppsala Papers in Economic History. Research report, 43. Uppsala, 1997. Reprinted from Der Markt im Mitteleuropa der Zwischenkriegszeit, Teichová, Alice, Mosser, Alois, Pátek, Jaroslav (editors). pp. 19–52. Prague: Univerzitá Karlová, Vydavatelství Karolinum, 1997.

”Den ekonomisk-historiska bakgrunden till den svenska arbetarlitteraturen.” Arbetar–historia 1997, häfte 3/4, s. 20–24.

”Bulgakov överlevde Sovjetmakten: en gruvlig litterär hämnd.” Upsala Nya Tidning 1997-04-28.

1998

“Scope and limits of the market mechanism in environmental management.” Ecological Economics 1998, 24: 259–274.

“Some theoretical problems of institutional economic history.” Scandinavian Economic History Review 1998, 46 (2): 5–31.

204

Larisa Oldireva Gustafsson

”Ekonomporträttet: Gunnar Myrdal (1898–1987).” Ekonomisk debatt 1998, häfte 8, s. 617–627.

”Den svårfångade konservatismen.” (Inlägg med anledning av Stig Strömholms ar-tikel om konservatismen i Tidskrift för politisk filosofi 1997, häfte 3). Tidskrift för politisk filosofi 1998, häfte 1, s. 32–34.

Diskussion med anledning av Frängsmyr, Tore, ”Filosofen vid helvetets portar.” (Svenska Dagbladet 1998-08-09). Svenska Dagbladet 1998-08-16.

Diskussion med anledning av Gustavsson, Sverker, ”I valet mellan pest och kolera.” (Upsala Nya Tidning 1998-05-18). Upsala Nya Tidning 1998-06-13.

1999

Utvärdering av FRNs program för genusforskning 1991–1997. Medförfattare: Ve, Hildur, Saarinen, Aaino. 36 sid. Stockholm: Forskningsrådsnämnden, 1999.

”Kommunism som moderniseringsprojekt. Med anledning av boken Kommunismens svarta bok.” Upsala Nya Tidning 1999-05-04, 1999-05-05.

Rec. av Reputation. Studies in the Voluntary Elicitation of Good Conduct. Klein, Daniel B. (ed.). Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 1999, 155 (4): 785–786.

”Missvisande om Keynes.” Debattinlägg med anledning av Clarke, Peter, The Keynesian Revolution and Its Economic Consequences. Svenska Dagbladet 1999-03-25.

Acta Universitatis Upsaliensis UPPSALA STUDIES IN ECONOMIC HISTORY

Editors: Maths Isacson & Lars Magnusson Volumes 1–9 are part of the series Ekonomisk-historiska studier, Scandinavian Uni-versity Books, which were published in 1965–1973 by Esselte Studium, Stockholm.

Under its new title, the series is included in the publication group Acta Universitatis Upsaliensis and is distributed in the same way as the other series of that group.

1. Bo Gustafsson, Den norrländska sågverksindustrins arbetare 1890–1913.

Arbets- och levndsförhållanden. 1965. Lic avhandl. 2. Nils Gruvberger, Svensk utrikessjöfart 1865–1885. Företagsformer och ägande-

struktur. 1965. Lic.avhandl. 3. Lars Furhoff. Upplagespiralen. 1967. 4. Bo Gustafsson, Marxism och revisionism. Eduard Bernsteins kritik av marxis-

men och dess idéhistoriska förutsättningar. 1969. 5. Kersti Sågvall-Ullenhag, AB Åtvidabergs förenade industrier med föregångare.

1970. 6. Jörgen Ullenhag, Den solidariska lönepolitiken i Sverige. Debatt och verklig-

het. 1971. 7. Ur ekonomisk-historisk synvinkel. Festskrift tillägnad professor Karl-Gustaf

Hildebrand 25.4.1971. 8. Hans Modig, Järnvägarnas efterfrågan och den svenska industrin 1860–1914.

1971. 9. Staffan Sjöberg, Arbetare vid Surahammars järnverk. Löne- och anställnings-

förhållanden 1936–1969. 1973. 10. Ragnhild Lundström, Alfred Nobel som internationell företagare. Den nobelska

sprängämnesindustrin 1864–1886. 1974. 11. Göran Dyverfeldt, Norrbottnisk sågverksindustri 1900–1925. AB Ytterstfors-

Munksund och dess föregångare. 1974. 12. Britta Jonell Ericsson, Skinnare i Malung. Från hemarbete till fabriksindustri.

1975. 13. Karsten Lundequist, Socialhjälpstagande – utveckling och orsaker 1945–1965.

Med en intensivundersökning av hjälptagandet i Uppsala. 1976. 14. Eskil Ekstedt, Utbildningsexpansion. En studie över den högre utbildningens

expansion och ekonomins strukturella omvandling i Sverige under efterkrigs-tiden. 1976.

15. Bertil Jakobsson, Företaget, kommunen och individen. En studie i relationerna mellan Söderfors bruk AB och Söderfors kommun och dess invånare 1895–1925. 1976.

16. Bo Gustafsson (utg.), Den offentliga sektorns expansion. Teori och metod-problem. Bidrag från ett tvärvetenskapligt symposium i Uppsala 9–12 mars 1976 anordnat med stöd av Statens Råd för Samhällsforskning. 1977.

17. Alf Johansson, Den effektiva arbetstiden. Verkstäderna och arbetsintensitetens problem 1900–1920. 1977.

18. Maths Isacson, Ekonomisk tillväxt och social differentiering 1680–1860. Bondeklassen i By socken, Kopparbergslän. 1979.

19. Franklin Chinna Swamy Vivekananda, Unemployment in Karnataka, South India. 1979.

20. Lars Magnusson, Ty som ingenting angelägnare är än mina bönders conserva-tion ... – Godsekonomi i östra Mellansverige vid mitten av 1700-talet. 1980.

21. Howard Simson, The Social Origins of Afrikaner Fascism and its Apartheid Policy. 1980.

22. Anders Forsman, En teori om staten och de offentliga utgifterna. 1980. 23. Kurt Wickman, Makro-ekonomisk planering– orsaker och utveckling. 1980. 24. Jan-Erik Pettersson, Kristidsekonomi och företagsutveckling. Industrin i Upp-

sala län 1939–49. 1980. 25. Lars Magnusson, Kapitalbildning i Sverige 1750–1860: Godsen. 1983. 26. Mats Larsson, Arbete och lön vid Bredsjö bruk. En studie av löneprinciper och

lönenivåer för olika yrkeskategorier vid Bredsjö bruk 1828–1905. 1986. 27. Bob Engelbertsson, Industriarbete i förindustriell arbetsmiljö. Sala gruva och

silververk under 1800-talet. 1987. 28. Peter Gårestad, Industrialisering och beskattning i Sverige 1861–1914. 1987. 29. Mats Morell, Studier i den svenska livsmedelskonsumtionens historia. Hospital-

hjonens livsmedelskonsumtion 1621–1872. 1989. 30. Mats Essemyr, Bruksarbetarnas livsmedelskonsumtion. Forsmarks bruk 1730–1880.

1989. 31. Une Sahlgren, Från mekanisk verkstad till internationell industrikoncern. AB

Scania Vabis 1939–1960. 1989. 32. Irma Irlinger, TCO och kvinnorna. Tidsperioden 1944–1974. Studie av TCOs

och SIFs arbetsmarknadspolitik och behandling av principen lika lön för lika arbete. 1990.

33. Kersti Ullenhag (ed.), “Hundred Flowers Bloom”, Essays in Honour of Bo Gustafsson. 1991.

34. Paulina de los Reyes, The Rural Poor. Agrarian Changes and Survival Strate-gies in Chile 1973–1989. 1992.

35. Inger Jonsson, Linodlare, väverskor och köpmän. Linne som handelsvara och försörjningsmöjlighet i det tidiga 1800-talets Hälsingland. 1994.

36. Bo Hännestrand, Människan, samhälle och ledarhunden. Studier i ledar-hundsarbetets historia. 1995.

37. Torbjörn Lundqvist, Den stora ölkartellen. Branschorganisering och kartell-bildning i bryggeriindustrin 1885–1914. 1995.

38. Ulf Magnusson, Från arbetare till arbetarklass. Klassformering och klass-relationer i Fagersta – ett mellansvenskt brukssamhälle ca 1870–1909. 1996.

39. Lars-Olov Johansson, Levebrödet. Den informella ekonomin i 1930-talets Dalarna. 1996.

40. Juan Bergdahl, Den gemensamma transportpolitiken. Elimineringen av hinder för gränsöverskridande vägtransporter inom den Europeiska Gemenskapen 1958–1992. 1996.

41. Göran Salmonsson, Den förståndiga viljan. Svenska Järn- och metall-arbetareförbundet 1888–1902. 1998.

42. Nighisty Ghezae, Irrigation Water Management. A Performance Study of the Rahad Scheme in Sudan, 1977–1996. 1998.

43. Annika Åkerblom, Arbetarskydd för kvinnor. Kvinnlig yrkesinspektion i Sverige 1913–1948. 1998.

44. Klas Nyberg, Kommersiell kompetens och industrialisering. Norrköpings ylle-industriella tillväxt på Stockholms bekostnad 1780–1846. 1999.

45. Richard Ringmar, Gästriklands bergsmän, Kronan och handelskapitalet. Aktö-rer och institutionella spelregler i bergsmansbruket, 1650–1870. 1999.

46. Mikael Lönnborg, Internationalisering av svenska försäkringsbolag. Driv-krafter, organisering och utveckling 1855–1913. 1999.

47. Fredrik Sandgren, Åt var och en efter behov? En studie av lanthandeln i Rev-sundsregionen i östra Jämtland 1870–1890. 1999.

48. Torbjörn Engdahl, The Exchange of Cotton. Ugandan Peasants, Colonial Market Regulations and the Organisation of the International Cotton Trade, 1904–1918. 1999.

49. Mikael Olsson, Ownership Reform and Corporate Governance. The Slovak Privatisation Process in 1990–1996. 1999.

50. Pernilla Jonsson, Marknadens väv. Svenska mekaniserade bomullsväverier i distribution och försäljning 1850–75. 2000.

51. Alejandro González Arriagada, Surviving in the City. The Urban Poor of Santi-ago de Chile 1930–1970. 2000.

52. Lars Fälting, Småhusfinansiering. En studie av kommunens, statens och en-skilda aktörers riskhantering i Nyköping 1904–1948. 2001.

53. Magnus Carlsson, Det regionala särintresset och staten. En studie av besluts-processerna kring Mälarbanan och Svealandsbanan 1983–1992. 2001.

54. Erik Lindberg, Borgarskap och burskap. Om näringsprivilegier och borger-skapets institutioner i Stockholm 1820–1846. 2001.

55. Carl Jeding, Co-ordination, Co-operation, Competition. The Creation of Com-mon Institutions for Telecommunications. 2001.

56. Tom Petersson, Framväxten av ett lokalt banksystem. Oppunda sparbank, Södermanlands enskilda bank och stationssamhället Katrineholm 1850–1916. 2001.

57. Christer Petersson, Lanthandeln. En studie av den fasta handelns regionala utveckling i Västmanlands län 1864–1890. 2001.

58. Rikard Skårfors, Stockholms trafikledsutbyggnad. Förändrade förutsättningar för beslut och implementering 1960–1975. 2001.

59. Kersti Ullenhag, Delen och helheten. Företags- och industrihistorisk forskning under fyra årtionden. 2001.

60. Henrik Lindberg, Att möte krisen. Politikbyte på lokal nivå under industrikrisen i Söderhamn 1975–1985. 2002.

61. Anna Eriksson-Trenter, Anspråk och argumentation. En studie av användning och uttolkning av lag vid naturresurskonflikter i nordvästra Hälsingland ca 1830–1879. 2002.

62. Annette H. K. Son, Social Policy and Health Insurance in South Korea and Taiwan. A Comparative Historical Approach. 2002.

63. Anders Sjölander, Den naturliga ordningen. Makt och intressen i de svenska sparbankerna 1882–1968. 2003.

64. Peter Hedberg, Handeln och betalningarna mellan Sverige och Tyskland 1934-1945. Den svensk-tyska clearingepoken ur ett kontraktsekonomiskt per-spektiv. 2003.

65. Ylva Hasselberg och Peter Hedberg (red.), I samma båt. Uppsatser i finans- och företagshistoria tillägnade Mats Larsson. 2003.

66. Hilda Hellgren, Fasta förbindelser. En studie av låntagare hos sparbanken och informella kreditgivare i Sala 1860–1910. 2003.

67. Jenny Andersson, Mellan tillväxt och trygghet. Idéer om produktiv socialpolitik i socialdemokratisk socialpolitisk ideologi under efterkrigstiden. 2003.

68. Sofia Murhem, Turning to Europe. A New Swedish Industrial Relations Regime in the 1990s. 2003.

69. Branka Likić Brborić, Democratic Governance in the Transition from Yugoslav Self-Management to a Market Economy. The Case of the Slovenian Priva-tization Debates 1990–1992. 2003.

70. Rebecca Svensson, När järnarbetare hanterar spaden och målaren knackar makadam. Om arbetslöshetspolitik i en arbetarstyrd kommun, Västerås, under 1920-talets krisår. 2004.

71. Kristina Lilja, Marknad och hushåll. Sparande och krediter i Falun 1820–1910 utifrån ett livscykelperspektiv. 2004.

72. Malin Junestav, Arbetslinjer i svensk socialpolitisk debatt och lagstiftning 1930–2001. 2004.

73. Johan Samuelsson, Kommunen gör historia. Museer, identitet och berättelser i Eskilstuna 1959–2000. 2005.

74. Berit Bengtsson, Kampen mot § 23. Facklig makt vid anställning och avsked i Sverige före 1940. 2006.

75. Tomas Matti, Professionella patriarker. Svenska storföretagsledares ideal, praktik och professionaliseringsprocess 1910–1945. 2006.

76. Maria Axelsson, Ifrågasatta företagare. Konkursförvaltares syn på kvinnor och män som företagsgäldenärer under 1900-talet. 2006.

77. Malin Jonsson, Kvinnors arbete och hushållens försörjning. Vävinkomsternas betydelse för hushållsekonomin i Siljansbygden 1938–1955. 2006.

78. Julia Peralta Prieto, Den sjuka arbetslösheten – svensk arbetsmarknadspolitik och dess praxis 1978–2004. 2006.

79. Sara Flygare, The Cooperative Challenge. Farmer Cooperation and the Politics of Agricultural Modernisation in 21st century Uganda. 2006.

80. Pernilla Jonsson, Silke Neunsinger and Joan Sangster (eds.), Crossing Bound-aries: Women’s Organizing in Europe and the Americas, 1880s–1940s. 2007.

81. Magnus Eklund, Adoption of the Innovation System Concept in Sweden. 2007. 82. Karin Ågren, Köpmannen i Stockholm. Grosshandlares ekonomiska och sociala

strategier under 1700-talet. 2007. 83. Anna Brismark, Mellan producent och konsument. Köpmän, kommissionärer

och krediter i det tidiga 1800-talets Hälsingland. 2008. 84. Christopher Lagerqvist, Kvarboende vid vägs ände. Människors försörjning i

det inre av södra Norrland under svensk efterkrigstid. 2008. 85. Lili-Annè Aldman, En merkantilistisk början: Stockholms textila import

1720–1738. 2008. 86. Anders Houltz, Brita Lundström, Lars Magnusson, Mats Morell, Marie Nisser,

Eva Silvén (redaktörer), Arbete pågår – i tankens mönster och kroppens miljöer. 2008.

87. Andreas Dahlkvist, Conflicting Contexts. The Implementation of European Works Councils in Sweden. 2009.

88. Erik Magnusson, Den egna vägen. Sverige och den europeiska integrationen 1961–1971. 2009.

89. Göran Bergström, Från svensk malmexport till utländsk etablering Grängesbergs-bolagets internationalisering 1953–1980. 2009.

90. Maurits Nyström, Att ta spjärn mot glömskan. 2010. 91. Lars Fälting, Mats Larsson, Tom Petersson, Karin Ågren (redaktörer), Aktörer

och marknader i omvandling. Studier i företagandets historia tillägnade Kersti Ullenhag. 2011.

92. Marie Nisser, Maths Isacson, Anders Lundgren, Andis Cinis (eds.), Industrial Heritage Around the Baltic Sea. 2012.

93. Mikael Karlsson, Filantropi under konstruktion. En undersökning av Sällskapet DBW:s samhällsengagemang 1814–1876. 2012.

94. Jan Ottosson, Ylva Hasselberg, Maths Isacson, Mats Larsson och Klas Nyberg (redaktörer), Till ämnets gagn. En festskrift till professor Lars Magnusson i samband med 60-årsdagen. 2012.

95. Lars Magnusson, Klas Nyberg, och Lynn Karlsson (redaktörer), Vetenskap och politik. Bo Gustafsson 1931–2000, en minnesskrift på 80-årsdagan av hans födelse. 2012.


Recommended