+ All Categories
Home > Documents > CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA -...

CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA -...

Date post: 06-Feb-2018
Category:
Upload: trinhkhanh
View: 218 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
24
63 CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA 3.1 Introduction This chapter looks at the aspects of textiles in India and tries to locate the status of the Khadi in the entire textile industry. First we look at the history of textiles in India in section 3.2. Next we move on to analyse the outcome of textile policy adopted in India after independence for the growth of the textile industry and how it has impacted the Khadi sector in section 3.3. Further we look at role of technological choices made in the five-year plans and its impact on the different sectoral outcomes of textile Industry in section 3.3.7. Finally we look at the Khadi and its current position visa-a-vie other small scale and textile industries in terms of production contribution, employment absorption etc. in section 3.4. Summary and conclusions are presented in section 3.5. 3.2 A Brief History Of Textiles In India The cotton handloom industry of India is one of the great manufacturing institutions of the world. Beginning with fragments of woven cotton material found in the ruins of Mohenjo-Daro, going on to supply the world with cotton fabrics from at least the time of the Roman Empire, and from then up to the end of the 18th century. Archaeological evidence from Mohenjo-Daro, establishes that the complex technology of mordant dyeing had been known in the subcontinent from at least the second millennium B.C. The use of printing blocks in India may go as far back as 3000 B.C., and some historians are of the view that India may have been the original home of textile printing. The export of printed fabrics to China can be dated to the fourth century B.C, where they were much used and admired, and later, imitated. There are testaments to the quantity, quality and variety of Indian cotton fabrics scattered through written records. Pliny, the Roman historian of the 1st century A.D. calculates the value of the cotton fabric trade between India and Rome at 100 million sesterces (equal then to 15 million rupees) every year, and complains that India is draining Rome of her gold. The thirteenth-century A.D. Chinese traveller Chau Ju-kua refers to Gujarat as a source of cotton fabrics of every colour and mentions that every year these were shipped to the Arab countries for sale. The discovery at Broach of a hoard of gold and
Transcript
Page 1: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

63

CHAPTER 3

TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA

3.1 Introduction

This chapter looks at the aspects of textiles in India and tries to locate the

status of the Khadi in the entire textile industry. First we look at the history of textiles

in India in section 3.2. Next we move on to analyse the outcome of textile policy

adopted in India after independence for the growth of the textile industry and how it

has impacted the Khadi sector in section 3.3. Further we look at role of technological

choices made in the five-year plans and its impact on the different sectoral outcomes

of textile Industry in section 3.3.7. Finally we look at the Khadi and its current

position visa-a-vie other small scale and textile industries in terms of production

contribution, employment absorption etc. in section 3.4. Summary and conclusions

are presented in section 3.5.

3.2 A Brief History Of Textiles In India

The cotton handloom industry of India is one of the great manufacturing

institutions of the world. Beginning with fragments of woven cotton material found in

the ruins of Mohenjo-Daro, going on to supply the world with cotton fabrics from at

least the time of the Roman Empire, and from then up to the end of the 18th century.

Archaeological evidence from Mohenjo-Daro, establishes that the complex

technology of mordant dyeing had been known in the subcontinent from at least the

second millennium B.C. The use of printing blocks in India may go as far back as

3000 B.C., and some historians are of the view that India may have been the original

home of textile printing. The export of printed fabrics to China can be dated to the

fourth century B.C, where they were much used and admired, and later, imitated.

There are testaments to the quantity, quality and variety of Indian cotton fabrics

scattered through written records. Pliny, the Roman historian of the 1st century A.D.

calculates the value of the cotton fabric trade between India and Rome at 100 million

sesterces (equal then to 15 million rupees) every year, and complains that India is

draining Rome of her gold.

The thirteenth-century A.D. Chinese traveller Chau Ju-kua refers to Gujarat as

a source of cotton fabrics of every colour and mentions that every year these were

shipped to the Arab countries for sale. The discovery at Broach of a hoard of gold and

Page 2: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

64

silver coins, mostly fourteenth-century and belonging to the Mamluk kingdom of

Egypt and Syria, suggests the maintenance of the advantageous trading system

recorded since Roman times whereby Indian textiles and other renewable resources

were traded for precious metals. Also in the thirteenth century A.D., Marco Polo

recorded the exports of Indian textiles to China and South East Asia from the

Masulipattinam (Andhra) and Coromandel (Tamil) coasts in the ‘largest ships’ then

known. It is conjectured that the initial development of this trade accompanied the

spread of Indian cultural influence in South-East Asia. Many spectacular Indian trade

cloths, most now two or three centuries old, have been treasured as heirlooms

throughout Southeast Asia into the twentieth century, making only rare appearances at

important ceremonies or at times of crisis. Prestige trade textiles such as Patola

(double ikat silk in natural dyes) from Patan and Ahmedabad, and decorative cottons

in brilliant colour-fast dyes from Gujarat and the Coromandel coast were sought after

by the Malaysian royalty and wealthy traders of the Phillipines. The port city of Surat

(in Gujarat) emerged as the major distribution point for patola destined for South-East

Asia, and was frequented by the ships of the Dutch East India Company. Textiles also

comprised a significant portion of the Portuguese trade with India. These included

embroidered bedspreads and wall hangings possibly produced at Satgaon, the old

mercantile capital of Bengal, (near modern Calcutta). Quilts of embroidered wild silk

(tassar, munga or eri) on a cotton or jute ground, combining European and Indian

motifs were comissioned by the Portuguese who had been attracted to Bengal, (as

traders had been since the early centuries A.D.), by the quality of the region's textiles.

J.H. van Linschoten, who was based in Goa as secretary to the archbishop in the

1580s A.D., observed that Cambay also produced silk embroidered quilts. Textiles

from Golconda and further south also found favour in Europe and South East Asia. In

the early 1600s, Dutch and English trading settlements were established in Golconda

territory. Produced in the Golconda hinterland, kalamkaris - i.e. finely painted cotton

fabrics were bought or commissioned from the port city of Masulipattinam. Buying at

source enabled the Dutch and English merchants to procure these textiles at rates

thirty per cent lower. 'Palampores' - painted fabrics based on the ‘tree of life’ motif

that had become popular in the Mughal and Deccan courts were also highly regarded.

The attractiveness of fast dyed, multi-coloured Indian prints on cotton (i.e. chintz) in

Europe led to the formation of the London East India Company in 1600 A.D.,

followed by Dutch and French counterparts. By the late 1600s, there was such

overwhelming demand for Indian chintz (whether from Chittagong in Bengal, or

Page 3: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

65

Patna or Surat, that ultimately French and English wool and silk merchants prevailed

on their Governments to ban the importation of these imported cottons from India.

The French ban came in 1686, while the English followed in 1701. Not all textile

producing centres were associated with ports. Several textile producing centres that

catered to the internal market, and to the overland international trade were located in

Northern and Central India, in the kingdoms of the Rajputs and the Mughals, each

with their own unique specialization. While Kashmir was well known for its woollen

weaves and embroidery, cities like Benaras, Ujjain, Indore and Paithan (near

Aurangabad) were known for their fine silks and brocades. Rajasthan specialized in

all manner of patterned prints and dyed cloths. Fine collections of Indian Textiles can

be seen in the Calico Museum in Ahmedabad and in the Crafts Museum in Delhi

(South Asian History, 2001). India's manually operated textile machines were

amongst the best in the world and the early textile machines produced in newly

industrialized Britain and Germany were modelled on the basis of these machines.

Cotton industry at one time employed millions of people at each stage, from

the growing of the plant through the ginning, carding and spinning, the warping,

sizing and weaving up to the dyeing, bleaching, printing, finishing and finally the

trading of the cloth. Today handloom industry is dispersed in villages and towns,

avoiding the pollution and ghettoisation of concentrated production that we see in

powerloom centres. Many of the producer regions are closely linked to their local

markets. At the dawn of the 21st century, handloom production is still the largest

employer in the country after agriculture, employing twelve and a half million

weaving families, not including the loom and reed makers, dyers, warp-winders,

sizers and other specialists who supply ancillary support. Weaving is not confined

solely to traditional weaving castes: when the industry thrives in one region, many

other non-weaving castes take it up (Uzramma, 2003).

Apart from its formidable size, the other great strengths of the handloom

industry in common with other craft industries are its low overheads and capital

needs, its variety and regional specialization, its versatility and adaptability, its

independence of generated power and of imports, and its smooth skill transfer

mechanisms. Analysis of handicrafts by Liebl and Tirthankar (2003) revealed that

market for handicrafts have gained significantly (the only exception is handloom)

contrary to the expectation of handicrafts to be substituted by modern manufacturing

industries under freer markets after 1990. The study also clearly shows the lack and

Page 4: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

66

weakness also common to artisanal industries: an absence of institutional support for

credit, research, technology, management and market development. What the

handloom industry has is a domestic market cutting across the social and economic

spectrum and the urban/ rural divide: cotton handloom fabric is still worn and used by

Indian people of all kinds and classes. This tenacious preference accounts for the

increase in handloom production over the years. Though the percentage of handloom

as a part of textile production has dropped from 24% in 1980-81 to 20% in 1999-

2000, the actual production has gone up from 3109 to 7352 million square meters

(Liebl and Tirthankar, 2003).

Geographical trends in the production of textiles and garments show a clear

pattern of the continuing relative (and, in some cases, absolute) decline of developed

country producers and a geographical shift of production to certain developing

countries, notably in East Asia and, to a lesser extent, in Mexico, the Caribbean,

Eastern Europe and some parts of the Mediterranean rim. In terms of exports only the

United States and Italy, of the industrialized countries, retained their shares of the

total world exports between 1980 and 2000. China dramatically increased its share of

world exports from 4.6 per cent in 1980 to 10.2 per cent in 2000. Both Korea and

Taiwan also doubled their shares of the world exports from 27 per cent in 1980 to 39

per cent in 2000 (Dicken, 2003).

World textiles exports are dominated by Asia (primarily East Asia) and

Western Europe. Together these account for more than 80 per cent of the total. In

terms of garments imports, the most striking feature is the over-whelming dominance

of the United States as the destination for almost one-third of the total. Second,

Japan’s share of garments imports almost tripled between 1980 and 2000 to be on a

par with Germany’s at around 9 per cent of the total. As in textiles, Western Europe

and Asia dominate garments exports (with around 75 per cent of the world total).

However, Asia is overwhelmingly the leading producer region (Dicken, 2003). Not

only are textiles and garments two of the most labour-intensive industries in modern

economies but also labour costs are the most geographically variable of the

production costs of the industries. There is a wide labour cost gap between different

countries. The spread is enormous, from over $10 per hour in the United States to 22

cents per hour in Vietnam, India around 33 cents (Dicken, 2003). Therefore it is

imperative for India to look at capturing some Global share in textile and garments

given its cost of labour and other advantages. It seems important to remember this

Page 5: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

67

history of quality and quantity when today Indian fabrics hold a mere 2.5% of world

textile trade, behind China, Pakistan and Turkey, and the main item of export is the

cheapest ‘grey sheeting’, made on powerlooms, and in which we are competitive only

on account of the low wages we pay (Uzramma, 2003). Further, we have the only

substantial household-based cotton textile industry in the world, and as part of that we

have a huge skill-bank in the millions of people capable of weaving and of making the

looms and accessories. We grow our own cotton and make our own yarn (Liebl and

Roy, 2003). Therefore it is imperative to enquire further into contribution of the

textile policy pursued in India after independence and what were its limitations which

contributed for such gloomy conditions in that sector.

3.3 Textile Policy In India

Study of textile Policy by Mishra (1993) in historical perspective reveals at least

five salient concerns that have motivated policy although their relative importance has

varied at different points in time. These are:

1. Regulation of inter-sectoral competition;

2. Provision of cheap cloth;

3. Fibre policy;

4. Modernisation; and

5. Sickness and Rehabilitation of mills.

3.3.1 Regulating Inter-Sectoral Competition And Its Impact

In the initial flush of Independence and the considerable influence of

Gandhian ideology at that time, the dominant opinion on the choice of `technology for

cloth manufacture was that the promotion of handlooms could achieve at one stroke

the twin objectives of generation of employment and the production of cloth for mass

consumption.

In 1950, the Government reserved certain areas of production, comprising a

wide variety of items of common use, for exclusive manufacture by the handlooms –

mills being legally prohibited from producing these items. This was followed up with

a cess on all mill-made cloth in 1952 to fund the subsidies for the handloom and

Khadi sectors.

The Kanungo Committee of 1954 was of the opinion that with the exception

of those textile items which required an ‘intricate body pattern’ there seemed ‘to be no

variety of fabric which the handloom industry could produce in a better quality or at a

lower price (consistent with a reasonable wage being paid to the handloom weaver

Page 6: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

68

and his assistants) as compared to the mill or the powerloom industry’. The committee

recommended a progressive conversion of handlooms into powerlooms through

organized effort over a period of fifteen to twenty years.

These views were sharply opposed by another official committee – the Karve

Committee, 1955, which was concerned with the role of the village and small

industries in the Second Five Year Plan. Not only did this Committee recommend the

freezing of both mill and powerloom output at existing levels (so that the entire

incremental demand for cotton cloth during the second plan period was to be met by

handlooms), it also recommended deferring any proposals for additional spinning

capacity in the mill sector, in order to promote the hand spinning sector. The

recommendations of the Karve Committee represent perhaps the most extreme

ideological position in favour of small, hand-operated techonology vis-à-vis power-

aided production.

In 1964, the report of the Asoka Mehta Committee resurrected the views of the

Kanungo Committee in recommending that the ‘powerloom sector be allowed to

acquire a paramount position in the decentralized sector of the textile industry.

Questioning the long-term viability of handlooms, it further urged that the regulatory

provisions regarding acquisition and installation of powelooms should be done away

with since they had not only proved ineffective but also given scope for serious

malpractices’.

With the unabated growth of powerlooms and its inherent conflict with

handlooms, it was only a matter of time before serious concern began to be voiced

about the survival of the handloom sector. In July 1974, B.Sivaraman Committee

pointed out that Government support for the handlooms had been inadequate and that

product reservation meant for the protection of the handloom sector had, in fact,

benefited the powerloom sector. Apart from institutional framework for the promotion

of handlooms, it also urged a set of wide-ranging fiscal measures to narrow down the

considerable cost advantages that the powerlooms had over the handlooms.

Towards this end, it envisaged the introduction of a legislation to statutorily

prevent the growth of powerlooms. The proposed legislation never saw the light of

day. In 1981, the Government announced a fresh textile policy which allowed a

marginal expansion of the powerloom sector, limited to Handloom Cooperative

Societies wishing to install powerlooms.

Notwithstanding these policy proclamations, the number of powerlooms grew

from an estimated figure of around six lakhs in 1981-82 to an estimated 8.36 lakhs

Page 7: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

69

(authorized as well as unauthorized) as on 1 January 1985. It was becoming

increasingly apparent that the growth of the powerloom sector could not be checked

through administrative fiat.

The 1985 textile policy made yet another major break from the past – it did

away with the virtual freeze on weaving capacity of the mills that had existed since

1956, although replacements of looms had been permitted for purposes of

modernization since 1978. It was a belated recognition of the fact that this freeze had

served only to inhibit the infusion of new entrepreneurship, consequently limiting

competition within the mill sector itself. It had been evident for quite some time that

the powerlooms required no protection from the mills and that the greater threat to the

existence of the handlooms came from the former, rather than the latter.

3.3.2 Cheap Cloth

Since the sixties, an important concern of textile policy has been the provision

of cheap cloth for the weaker sections of society. All the composite mills were

required to produce, at least, the stipulated minimum amounts of such cloth, fixed at

45 percent and later raised to 50percent in 1965 (commonly referred to as controlled

cloth), which was to be sold at prices fixed by the Government. The mills were

permitted to sell the non-controlled varieties in the open market.

As a result of repeated representations from the mill, which were obviously,

adversely affected by this measure, the scheme underwent several modifications. In

May 1968, the stipulated obligation was reduced to 25 percent. Subsequently, the

facility of transfer of obligation between mills was allowed and, in 1971, obligation

for individual mills was replaced by an industry-wide obligation.

The fact that the controlled cloth scheme was a major contributory factor in

the spread of sickness, in the organized mill sector, was officially recognized in the

textile policy statement of 1978. Apart from discontinuing the imposition of

obligation on the mills, the policy also envisaged a gradual transfer of the production

of such cloth to the handloom sector, so that the employment objective could also be

served. Till such time that such transfer was affected, the nationalized mills under the

National Textile Corporation (NTC) were to shoulder the major responsibility of

producing such cloth.

Page 8: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

70

3.3.3 Fiber Policy

Given the large area under cotton cultivation (the largest in the world) and the

millions of farmers whose livelihood depends on this crop, it is hardly surprising that

one of the major planks of India’s textile policy has been to ensure the predominant

use of cotton in textile manufacture and to limit the competition posed by man-made

fibres and yarns, particularly synthetics.

The use of non-cotton fibres in textile manufacture was sought to be curbed

both by fiscal as well as administrative measures. The Industries (Development and

Regulation) Act of 1951 introduced a fibre-based compartmentalisation between

different sectors of the textile industry. This not only prevented the cotton textile

mills from manufacturing pure non-cotton clothe, but also from using non-cotton

fibres and yarns in blends with cotton beyond a certain proportion.

More important than the administrative curbs on the use of man-made fibres

and yarns (which primarily affected the mills), has been the high ‘incidence of fiscal

levies’ on these items (especially on synthetic fibres and filaments) in limiting the

growth in consumption.

In the wake of the more liberal approach towards the use of man-made fibres

envisaged in the 1978 and 1981 textile policies, considerable additional capacities for

the production of synthetic fibres and filament yarns were sanctioned in the late 1970s

and early 1980s. This trend was maintained in the 1985 policy. With domestic

production rising rapidly, imports of man-made fibres and yarns have shown a sharp

decline in late eighties. On account of the marked consumer preference for non-

cotton and blended cloth, the consumption of synthetic fibres and yarn has grown

rapidly in spite of their high prices vis-à-vis cotton.

The Cotton Corporation of India (CCI) was set up in 1970 as a major public

sector trading agency to cushion the growers from a steep crash in prices and to

stabilize prices for the industry. The 1978 textile policy explicitly envisaged a price

stabilizing role for the CCI, so that prices were not allowed to fall below a prescribed

minimum or to rise above a predetermined ceiling through buffer stock operations.

On account of the logistical problems of operating a buffer stock in a commodity that

degenerates rapidly with time and the substantial costs involved, the buffer stock

concept was abandoned in the 1981 policy. The textile policy of 1985, therefore

envisaged ‘that the CCI, in addition to its traditional role of ensuring remunerative

prices for the growers, would also function as a price stabilization agency through

appropriate import-export interventions.

Page 9: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

71

3.3.4 Modernisation

Modernisation schemes have included the promotion of frame looms and

jacquard looms, training to weavers in new techniques. Several drawbacks with frame

looms that weavers have identified themselves such as less flexibility, having to

weave in worksheds as opposed to in the house, more physically difficult, and

substantial additional investment expenses which weavers cannot afford have limited

the use of modern technology.

3.3.5 Sickness And Rehabilitation

While some degree of sickness in the form of poorly performing units had

always existed in the industry, it did not become a serious policy issue till the

National Textile Corporation (NTC) was incorporated in 1968 with the primary

objective of managing sixteen sick mills taken over by the Government. The

Accumulated cash losses of the NTC mills alone had reached a staggering Rs. 800

crores approximately by 1984-85. Taking cognisance of this, the 1985 policy, for the

first time, came out explicit against nationalization or takeover of sick mills by the

Government. As a logical corollary, it envisaged the eventual closure of nonviable

units with adequate safeguard for workers’ interests. A Nodal Agency was to be set

up for the preparation and management of rehabilitation packages for sick mills that

were found to be potentially viable on careful screening. Further, a rehabilitation

fund was to be set up to provide interim relief to workers affected by the permanent

closure of nonviable units.

Mishra (1993) identifies four major factors that have crucially affected policy

outcomes:

1. Ideology

2. The issue of equity

3. The operation of pressure groups

4. Meta-policy

Planners in India had opted for an autarkic development strategy which gave

emphasis to investments in heavy industry for achieving growth objectives and small-

scale, labour-intensive manufacture of essential consumer goods for providing

employment to the rapidly growing labour force. What came to be known as the

Mahalanobis model, curiously attempted to combine essentially antithetical elements

of the Soviet model of development with its emphasis on comprehensive state

Page 10: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

72

planning and rapid industrialization with Gandhian economic beliefs in the efficacy of

essentially pre-industrial, non-mechanised techniques for the manufacture of yarn and

cloth.

Some of the major prescriptive elements emanating from such thinking were: (a) a

preference for direct, discretionary, physical controls over indirect, market-mediated

ones, operating through the price mechanism, (b) strong ‘export pessimism’ combined

with an open-ended commitment towards import substitution, and (c) the promotion

of equity commitment towards import substitution, and (c) the promotion of equity

through direct state interventions in favour of traditional labour intensive modes of

production and price controls. Such postulates naturally exercised considerable

influence on the evolution of textile policy.

These regulations, which came to be ‘embodied in the Cotton Textiles Control

Order of 1948 (CTCO), vested the state with wide-ranging powers to regulate prices,

distribution and production of textile products, including the installation of capacity to

produce them. In fact its ambit was progressively widened to encompass newly

emerging sectors (for example, man-made textiles) and to deal with changing

contours of policy. Once introduced, these controls, with the passage of time,

acquired an existence of their own-creating in the process powerful constituencies and

strong justifications in favour of their perpetuation.

Although the strait-jacket regime implied by the CTCO encompassed all

mechanized production of textiles, their actual impact did not extend much beyond

the formal sector due to the sheer administrative non-feasibility of enforcing these

controls over a large number of tiny units spread across a number of locations all over

the country. This stranglehold of controls was undoubtedly an important contributory

factor in the decline in competitiveness of the formal textile weaving sector. As a

logical corollary, the power looms which, at least de facto, were largely outside their

pale were able to thrive and flourish.

The issue of equity has always been on the forefront of the Indian economic

policy agenda. Thus the policy tilt in favour of traditional non-mechanised

production of cloth, although initially deriving its impulse from Gandhian beliefs, was

subsequently justified as an instrument for providing income and employment for the

economically weak sections of the population. In a similar vein, the concern for

meeting the clothing needs of the poor was the raison d’etre of the controlled cloth

scheme.

Page 11: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

73

Whether any equity objectives were indeed served by these measures is

another matter. What is significant is that the costs of meeting these distributional

objectives were imposed on other mechanized sectors of the industry (through fiscal

instruments as well as physical controls) instead of the society at large. The fact that

crucial trade-offs are involved between equity and efficiency and equally, between

expansion of short and long run employment, was not adequately appreciated until the

1985 policy.

Pressure from the large and vocal body of cotton growers has been a major

factor in the manifest policy bias against synthetic fibres. Similarly, pressure from

organized labour groups has prevented a rational policy on the closure of nonviable

mills and has provided the primary impetus for the takeover and nationalization of

such mills by the Government. Although the freeze in the weaving capacity in the

organized mill sector seemingly goes against mill interests.

To circumvent capacity restrictions and to take advantage of the substantially

lower wages as well as lower excise levies, the mills have, over time, forged strong

links with the powerlooms. There is good reason to suspect that a good part of the

powerloom sector is run by the mills by proxy.

Policy-making in this sector has, as a consequence, come to acquire most of

the classical attributes associated with what is commonly referred to as

‘incrementalism’. First, with the exception of the 1985 policy, textile policies have

shifted only marginally from the existing position over the years. Thus, changes have

never moved far from the status quo ante. Second, these policies have largely been

means-oriented- the means available at hand (in terms of financial and administrative

resources) have been more crucial in determining policy outcomes than the objectives

to be achieved. Third, textile policies have been largely remedial or reactive, dealing

with problems as they arose instead of anticipating them. The focus inevitably has

been on short-term goals without much regard for longer-term consequences. A good

example is the controlled cloth scheme making mills sick, which in turn had to be

nationalized to keep them operational. Finally, policies have, as a rule, been

fragmentary, in that they have viewed the policy arena as being comprised of a

number of largely independent segments rather than as an interconnected whole.

Thus, the likely cross-sectoral impact of policies has usually been overlooked; leading

often, to wholly unintended consequences. The most obvious example being the rapid

proliferation of power looms resulting from the restraints on mill capacity.

Page 12: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

74

3.3.6 Textile Policy Of 1985.

The accent in economic policy at that time was on liberalization, deregulation,

technological up gradation and increased competition. The 1985 policy statement

marks a major break from the past. It intended largely at the competition and

efficiency. It aimed at removing the barriers to entry and exit, flexibility in the use of

cotton and man-made fibers, equal treatment of the mills and powerlooms for fiscal

purposes, closure of non-viable units both private and public etc. Although its thrust

on some of the more contentious issues has been greatly diluted at the implementation

stage. This brings into focus the fundamental dilemma that policy-makers are

invariably confronted with – a policy that is technically and economically rational, is

often not politically so. A realistic policy must necessarily involve difficult trade-offs

between political and economic objectives.

3.3.7 Technological Choice And Decline Of Handlooms

The observations of Mishra and Srivastava (2004) are highly relevant here.

They observed that the issue of choice of technique was a matter of great debate in

India in 1950s and 1960s. The central issue, which was not settled at the time, and

one which still remains a great challenge for Indian policy makers is, what is to be

maximized – output or employment. The ambiguity was not strikingly reflected in the

textile policy. The textile policy attempted to promote mills and handlooms

simultaneously and consequently, ended up in contributing to sickness of mills and

decimation of handlooms. A third sector, namely powerlooms, came up to push both

sectors on the back foot and ran away with all incremental demand of textiles. It can

be debated how far the ascendancy of powerlooms was policy induced or an outcome

of gradual development of a different pattern of industrial organisations. But then is

no denying of the fact that more than half of cloth production in India originates from

powerloom sector. Here an intermediate technology (powerloom) is out competing

capital-intensive technique (mill sector) as well as a labour-intensive technique

(handloom) (Mishra and Srivastava, 2004).

The paper of Mishra and Srivastava (2004) examines the inter-sectoral

competition in textile industry, especially between handloom and powerloom, within

the choice of technique framework in an old textile city, namely Kanpur. This study

of inter-sectoral competition and ‘choice of technique’ in informal textile industry of

Kanpur shows that the conventional ‘choice of technique’ model fails to explain

Page 13: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

75

satisfactorily the continued proliferation of powerloom and gradual decimation of

handloom. Neither is the capital-intensive technique (powerloom) always growth

stimulating nor is the labour-intensive technique (handloom) always employment

maximizing. It appears that factor prices, i.e., high wage rate and low interest rate,

are among the principal reasons for the continued proliferation of powerlooms.

Moreover, the capital-intensive technique (powerloom) is also not always surplus

maximizing and thus growth stimulating. Rather, it emerges from their study that

there is a greater likelihood of the rate of reinvestible surplus going down with

increase in capital-intensity. One possible explanation of this observed anomaly

between empirical fact and theoretical propositions could be that choice of technique

is made in a particular socio-economic environment where exogenous factors are as

important as endogenous ones in determining this choice. The conventional model

excludes these exogenous variables (like policy regime and political economy

considerations) and focuses on output-employment trade off only. Consequently, its

results are tentative and causal relationships are tenuous. This study demonstrates

that raising of capital-intensity is no guarantee of higher surplus generation. The

proliferation of powerlooms in recent times is not explained by surplus maximization

motive. Therefore, we need to look beyond the narrow model of choice of technique

and due caution needs to be exercised in application of the model explaining the

dichotomous relationship between growth and employment.

3.4 Khadi In The Textile Industry

Next we look at the characteristics of Khadi in the overall small-scale industry

and textile sector to get a better view of its historical transit after Independence. Table

3.1 shows the changing relative importance of individual segments of the VSI sector

(Cols. 2 to 11, both in Sub- Tables 3.1.a and 3.1.b). As is expected, the modern sector

accounts for a lion’s share of out put while the bulk of employment is offered by the

traditional sector. In the modern sector, both output and employment shares have

expanded while the opposite has happened with the traditional sector. It seems that the

traditional sector is being pushed to a corner as its share in output is concerned; in

1996-97, it had contend with mere 8.36 percent share in out put against as high as

60.36 percent share in employment. Over time, the traditional rural industries have

steadily lost their ground to modern small-scale industries (like powerloom), whether

located in the rural or urban areas.

Page 14: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

76

An especially distressing picture emerges for the handloom sector where in

1996-97; a mere 2 percent share in out put was accompanied by as high as a 25.90

percent share in VSI employment. This sub-sector seems to serve as a dumping

ground for a lot of additional labour force, presumably because alternative

employment opportunities are not available to those already engaged in it, especially

to those weavers who have been in the craft for a long time and primarily due to lack

of education and alternative skills, cannot shift to other jobs. What explains the

weakening of this sub-sector during the past decade or so? Chadha (2000) observes

that while the inherent weaknesses of the handloom sector cannot be wished away, the

economic tug of war incessantly going on since the 1960s between the handloom and

powerloom sectors has played a decisive role in the secular decline of the former. The

house of Khadi thus poses questions about its future survivability, especially in the

context of the liberalized market regime that has been operating since 1991.

Page 15: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

77

Table 3.1.a: Output Expansion in Village and Small Industries (VSI) in India: 1973-74/1996-97 (Rs. In Crores). TRADITIONAL SECTOR (TS) MODERN SECTOR (MS) Year Khadi Village

Industries Hand-loom

Seri culture

Handi- Crafts

Coir Total TS

Small Scale Industries

Power loom

Total MS

Total VSI Sector

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Series - 1(1979-80 Prices) 1973-74 50.7 187.4 1290.2 96.8 1635.8 92.2 3353.1 11059.2 3041.3 14100.5 17453.6 1979-80 92.0 348.0 1740.0 131.0 2050.0 86.0 4447.0 21635.0 3250.0 24885.0 29332.0 1984-85 115.9 517.3 1964.2 215.9 2387.0 68.5 5268.9 34454.6 4244.1 38698.7 43967.5 Series - 11 (1984-85 Prices) 1984-85 170.0 758.6 2880.0 316.6 3500.0 100.5 7725.7 50520.0 6423.0 56943.0 64668.7 1985-86 164.6 900.4 2589.0 370.0 4100.0 139.5 8263.5 57100.0 7668.0 64768.5 73032.0 1986-87 167.0 1034.0 2759.2 417.0 5100.0 141.0 9618.2 64500.0 8106.3 72606.3 82224.5 1987-88 178.3 1265.2 2806.0 445.0 6150.0 148.7 10993.2 72880.0 8394.0 81274.0 92267.2 1988-89 187.0 1473.8 2773.1 490.0 8250.0 153.2 13327.1 73125.0 9092.0 82217.0 95544.1 1989-90 203.0 1101.0 3377.0 493.0 7067.0 128.0 12369.0 92080.0 9865.0 101945.0 114314.0 Series - 111 (1990-91 Prices) 1990-91 286.0 1994.0 3633.0 868.0 11325.0 161.0 18267.0 155340.0 12337.0 167677.0 185944.0 1991-92 290.8 1993.0 3298.4 804.2 11668.8 167.9 18223.1 140775.4 20964.0 161739.4 179962.5 1992-93 298.7 2077.0 3404.0 952.2 12440.0 177.0 19348.9 134632.8 21670.0 156302.8 175651.7 1993-94 307.2 2399.0 3519.1 1041.0 14599.6 185.5 22051.4 191827.9 22467.5 214295.8 236346.8 1994-95 369.2 2199.0 3719.6 1130.3 15999.6 201.0 23618.7 209092.4 24434.4 233526.8 257145.5 1995-96 323.7 2243.0 4204.8 952.7 20159.5 199.5 28083.2 281486.8 20910.2 302397.0 330480.2 1996-97 385.4 2331.0 4528.2 981.3 23695.6 209.5 32131.0 330994.1 21030.6 352024.7 384155.7 Note: Out figures under Series 1, Series-11 and Series-111 are at constant prices with Base 1979-80, 1984-85 and 1990-91, Respectively.

Source : (Chadha, 2000, Table 1.1A, p.8)

Page 16: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

78

Table 3.1.b: Employment and Productivity Expansion in Village and Small Industries (VSI) in India: 1973/1996-97. TRADITIONAL SECTOR (TS) MODERN SECTOR (MS) Seri- Culture

Handi-crafts

Village Indus- Tries

Hand- loom

Seri culture

Handi- crafts

Coir Total TS

Small Scale Industries

Power-loom

Total MS

Total VSI Sector

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Series - 1 (1979-80 Prices) 1973-74 E 8.8 9.3 52.1 12.0 15.0 5.0 102.2 39.7 10.0 49.7 151.9 P 576.1 2015.1 2476.4 806.7 10905.3 1844.0 3280.9 27857.0 30413.0 28371.2 11490.2 1979-80 E 11.2 16.1 61.5 16.0 20.3 5.6 130.7 67.0 11.0 78.0 208.7 P 821.4 2161.5 2829.3 818.8 10098.5 1538.5 3402.5 32291.0 29545.5 31903.8 14054.6

1984-85 E 14.6 22.4 74.7 20.0 27.4 5.9 165.0 90.0 32.2 122.2 287.1 P 793. 2309.4 2629.5 1079.5 8711.7 1161.0 3193.3 38282.9 13180.4 31668.3 15314.4 Series - 11 (1984-85 Prices) 1984-85 E 14.6 22.4 74.7 43.2 27.4 5.9 165.0 90.0 32.2 122.2 287.1 P 1164.4 3386.6 3855.4 732.9 12733.7 1703.4 4682.2 56133.3 19947.2 46598.2 22524.8 1987-88 E 14.0 27.8 74.8 57.7 34.9 5.5 214.7 107.0 42.1 149.1 363.8 P 1273.6 4551.1 3751.3 771.2 17621.8 2703.6 5120.3 68112.1 19938.2 54509.7 25362.1 1989-90 E 14.1 32.1 76.0 50.0 42.2 5.5 216.9 119.6 45.0 164.6 381.5 P 1439.7 3430.0 4443.4 986.0 16746.4 2327.3 5702.6 76990.0 21922.2 61935.0 29964.4 Series - 111 (1990-91 Prices) 1990-91 E 14.2 34.4 96.9 52.0 43.8 5.5 246.7 124.3 55.0 179.3 426.0 P 2014.1 5796.5 3749.2 1669.2 25856.2 2927.3 7404.5 124971.8 22430.9 93517.6 43648.8 1991-92 E 14.3 35.4 106.0 54.8 53.1 5.5 263.9 126.0 55.0 181.0 444.9 P 2033.6 5629.9 3111.7 1475.6 24159.0 3052.7 6905.3 111726.5 38116.4 89358.8 40450.1 1992-93 E 14.5 36.6 106.0 54.8 53.1 5.5 270.4 128.3 60.0 185.3 458.7 P 2060.0 5674.9 3211.3 1737.6 23427.5 3218.2 7155.7 104935.9 36116.7 83007.3 38293.4 1993-94 E 14.5 39.4 110.0 56.0 58.3 5.0 283.2 139.4 56.0 195.4 478.6 P 2118.6 6088.8 3199.2 1858.9 25042.2 3710.0 7786.5 137609.7 40120.5 109670.1 49383.0 1994-95 E 15.5 42.0 112.0 60.0 64.0 5.0 298.5 145.0 65.0 210.0 508.5

Page 17: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

79

P 2381.9 5235.7 3321.1 1883.8 24999.4 4020.0 7912.5 144201.7 37591.4 111203.2 50569.4 1995-96 E 16.7 40.3 128.0 60.0 66.0 5.5 316.1 153.0 68.6 221.0 537.1 P 1938.3 5565.8 3285.0 1587.8 30544.7 3627.3 8884.3 183978.3 30481.3 136831.2 61530.5 1996-97 E 16.0 45.0 149.0 59.6 70.8 5.5 347.2 160.0 70.8 228.0 575.2 P 2408.8 5180.0 303.9.1 1646.5 33468.4 3809.1 9254.3 206871.3 29704.2 154396.8 66786.5 Compound Growth Rate 1973-85 O 7.8 9.7 3.9 7.6 3.5 -2.7 4.2 10.9 3.1 9.6 8.8 E 4.7 8.3 3.3 4.8 5.6 1.5 4.5 7.7 11.2 8.5 6.0 P 3.0 1.2 0.5 2.7 -2.0 -4.1 -0.2 2.9 -7.3 1.0 2.6 1984-90 O 3.6 7.7 3.2 9.3 15.1 5.0 9.9 12.8 9.0 12.4 12.1 E -0.7 7.5 0.3 3.0 9.0 -1.4 5.6 5.9 6.9 6.1 5.9 P 4.3 0.3 2.9 6.1 5.6 6.4 4.0 6.5 1.9 5.9 5.9 199097*O 5.3 2.8 4.8 4.0 14.0 4.8 10.7 17.5 4.8 16.3 15.7 2.9 4.6 5.9 2.7 8.4 -0.8 5.3 4.9 4.7 4.7 5.1 2.3 -1.7 -1.1 1.2 4.9 5.6 5.0 11.9 0.3 10.9 10.0 Note : O = Value of Output (Rs. In crores at constant prices). E = Employment (Persons in Lakhs); P = Labour Productivity (Rs. at constant prices) * = Growth Rate has been computed through semi-log curve. Source : (Chadha, 2000, Table 1.1B, p.9)

Page 18: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

80

Chadha (2000) further observes (see Table 3.2) that Mill sector has witnessed a

continuous decline during the nineties. On the contrary, powerlooms and handlooms

sectors have grown fairly impressively since 1991-92; a growth rate of fabric production

to the tune of 9-10 per cent per annum, for the nineties, is not a trivial development.

Table 3.2: Production of Fabrics in India: 1991-92 / 97-98 (Production in million sq.

mts.).

Year Mills Powerlooms Handlooms Khadi Others Total

1 2 3 4 5 6 7

1991-92 2367 16089 4123 109 320 23008

1992-93 2000 17826 5219 105 325 25475

1993-94 1990 19631 5851 98 328 27898

1994-95 2271 19724 6180 91 340 28606

1995-96 2019 22239 7202 105 393 31958

1996-97 1967 24885 7456 112 428 34848

1997-98 1948 27344 7604 104 436 37436

Growth Rate (%)

1991-92/97-

98*

-2.03 9.02 10.10 0.25 5.93 8.04

Share in Output (%)

1991-92 10.29 69.93 17.92 0.47 1.39 100.00

1992-93 7.85 69.97 20.49 0.41 1.28 100.00

1993-94 7.13 70.37 20.97 0.35 1.18 100.00

1994-95 7.94 68.95 21.60 0.32 1.19 100.00

1995-96 6.32 69.59 22.54 0.33 1.23 100.00

1996-97 5.64 71.41 21.40 0.32 1.23 100.00

1997-98 5.20 73.04 20.31 0.28 1.16 100.00 Note. * Growth rate has been computed through semi-log curve. Source: (Chadha, 2000, Table 3.1, p.19) 1. Govt. of India, Economic Survey, Ministry of finance, 1998-99, p109 2. KVIC, Statistical Abstract, Directorate of Economic Research of Mumbai, 1998, p.84-85

But then, the Khadi sector has hardly witnessed any progress in its production; its

production grew merely by 0.25 per cent per annum during 1991-92/1997-98. By all

reckoning, it has been a dismal performance. The disturbing trend of Khadi’s steeply

Page 19: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

81

declining share in total production of fabrics; it had a mere 0.47 per cent share in 1991-92

which got reduced to 0.28 per cent only 1997-98.

In plain terms, it is interesting to see that while the Khadi’s share in output, in

total textile production or in sector-wise production, has been declining steadily (Table

3.2) its share in employment has been improving steadily over time (Table 3.3.). The

Khadi sector almost looks like a residual sector. However, a preponderant majority of

Khadi workers are engaged on part-time basis only, and accordingly, to their share, a

very small proportion of the industry-wise earnings would accrue. Poverty and low-level

of living are thus the endemic characteristics of their existence (Chadha, 2000.)

Table 3.3: Employment in Cotton, Wool and Silk Textiles by Production Sector:

1971/93 (Persons in Lakhs). Cotton Textiles Wool Textiles

Year Mill

Sector

Khadi Sector K:M Raito Mill Sector Khadi Sector K:M

Ratio

1 2 3 4 5 6 7

1971 9.44 7.94 0.84 1.47 1.48 1.00

1981 11.88 9.72 0.82 1.92 2.34 1.22

1991 10.75 10.65 0.99 2.53 2.81 1.11

1992 10.75 10.67 0.99 2.74 2.85 1.04

1993 10.66 10.76 1.01 2.75 3.00 1.09

Annual Compound Growth Rate (%)

1971-81 2.33 2.04 2.71 4.69

1981-93 -0.99 0.92 2.80 1.85

1971-93 0.00 0.02 0.80 0.14

Note. K= Khadi Sector, M= Mill Sector Source: (Chadha, 2000, Table 3.3, p.23) 1.Govt. of India, Statistical Abstract India, CSO 1997, Dec. 1997, p.389-90 2. KVIC, Statistical Abstract Directorate of Economic Research, July 1998, p.170-176

The study of Chadha (2000) further observes that (see Table 3.4), while sector-

wise output figures are available right from 1953-54, onwards, employment figures are

available for cotton, wool and silk together till 1966-67 where after these are published

separately for each product line. Then, to have a more firm (and stable) view of the

changing composition, three-yearly averages have been taken for various time-points,

beginning with 1953-54 and ending with 1998-99.

Page 20: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

82

Table 3.4 throws up two interesting features. First, cotton-Khadi was summarily

the beginning and the end of the Khadi sector in total, during the fifties. Gradually, silk-

Khadi gained more eminence in the Khadi sector. Among the newly emerging areas for

Khadi, the major locales were Rajasthan, Uttar Pradesh, Punjab, Jammu-Kashmir and

Maharashtra, while for the silk-Khadi, such major locales were West Bengal, Tamil

Nadu, Bihar, Karnataka and Assam. Of course, Cotton-Khadi continued to dominate in

each area. Consequently, Cotton-Khadi is still the most dominant component, both from

production and employment points of view.

Table 3.4: Share of Each Sector on the Basis of Value of Production and

Employment (%).

Period Cotton Woollen Silk Muslin Total Khadi

1 2 3 4 5 6

1953-56 O 94.73 3.77 1.63 100.00

E - - - - -

1959-62 O 91.77 6.15 2.08 - 100.00

E - - - - -

1969-72 O 87.04 10.01 2.95 - 100.00

E 85.49 11.45 2.16 - 100.00

1979-82 O 86.22 10.35 3.42 - 100.00

E 78.47 17.14 4.39 - 100.00

1989-92 O 81.96 9.94 4.73 3.37 100.00

E 75.14 17.78 4.87 2.21 100.00

1996-99 O 80.42 9.77 6.90 2.19 100.00

E 75.56 16.71 5.72. 1.94 100.00 Note: O= Output, E= Employment Source: (Chadha, 2000, Table 4.1, p.26); KVIC, Statistical Abstract Directorate of Economic Research, Mumbai, 1998.

Table 3.5 gives a few important insights about the composition of employment in

the Khadi sector as pointed out by the above study. First, in each of the four segments,

the share of the part-time workers is fairly substantial. In Woollen-Khadi, the proportion

of part-time workers was as high as 85.1 per cent in 1998-99, followed by 68.1 per cent

in cotton Khadi and 57.6 per cent in silk-Khadi; in muslin-Khadi, part-time workers are

totally absent. The very high incidence of part-time employment is the real hall-mark of

Page 21: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

83

the Khadi sector where people are encouraged to take up specific production tasks to their

living abodes, on contract or piece wage rate basis, so that some bit of supplementary

employment and earnings accrue to them.

Table 3.5: Composition of Employment in Khadi Sector: 1998-99.

Production Sector Item Description

Cotton Muslin Woollen Silk Total

1 2 3 4 5 6

1. Employment

( Persons in Lakhs )

3.33 0.27 0.34 0.36 4.30 a) Full-Time

(31.9) (100.0) (14.9) (42.4) (31.0)

7.12 - 1.94 0.49 9.55 b) Part-Time

(68.1) - (85.1) (57.6) (69.0)

10.45 0.27 2.28 0.85 13.85 c) Total

(100.00) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0) (100.0)

2. % of Scheduled Caste /

Tribes Employed

24.67

7.40

30.10

22.37

25.12

3. % of Women Employees

(in Spinning)

75.14

63.0

39.47

58.47

70.16 Note: Figures in parentheses are percentage share. Source: (Chadha, 2000, Table 4.2, p.27); KVIC, Annual Report 1998-99, directorate of Economic Research, p.9-14.

3.5 Summary And Conclusions

This chapter looks at the aspects of textiles in India and tries to locate the status of the

Khadi in the entire textile industry. The cotton handloom industry of India is one of the

great manufacturing institutions of the world. Beginning with fragments of woven cotton

material found in the ruins of Mohenjo-Daro, going on to supply the world with cotton

fabrics from at least the time of the Roman Empire, and from then up to the end of the

18th century A.D.. Archaeological evidence from Mohenjo-Daro, establishes that the

complex technology of mordant dyeing had been known in the subcontinent from at least the

second millennium B.C.

The attractiveness of fast dyed, multi-colored Indian prints on cotton (i.e. chintz) in

Europe led to the formation of the London East India Company in 1600 A.D., followed by

Page 22: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

84

Dutch and French counterparts. By the late 1600s, there was such overwhelming demand for

Indian chintz (whether from Chittagong in Bengal, or Patna or Surat, that ultimately French

and English wool and silk merchants prevailed on their Governments to ban the importation

of these imported cottons from India. Cotton industry at one time employed millions of

people at each stage, from the growing of the plant through the ginning, carding and

spinning, the warping, sizing and weaving up to the dyeing, bleaching, printing, finishing

and finally the trading of the cloth. Today handloom industry is dispersed in villages and

towns, avoiding the pollution and ghettoization of concentrated production that we see in

powerloom centres. Many of the producer regions are closely linked to their local

markets. At the dawn of the 21st century, handloom production is still the largest

employer in the country after agriculture, employing twelve and a half million weaving

families, not including the loom and reed makers, dyers, warp-winders, sizers and other

specialists who supply ancillary support. Weaving is not confined solely to traditional

weaving castes: when the industry thrives in one region, many other non-weaving castes

take it up.

Geographical trends in the production of textiles and garments show a clear pattern of

the continuing relative (and, in some cases, absolute) decline of developed country

producers and a geographical shift of production to certain developing countries, notably

in East Asia and, to a lesser extent, in Mexico, the Caribbean, Eastern Europe and some

parts of the Mediterranean rim. In terms of exports only the United States and Italy, of the

industrialized countries, retained their shares of the total world exports between 1980 and

2000. China dramatically increased its share of world exports from 4.6 per cent in 1980

to 10.2 per cent in 2000. Both Korea and Taiwan also doubled their shares of the world

exports from 27 per cent in 1980 to 39 per cent in 2000.

It seems important to remember this history of quality and quantity when today

Indian fabrics hold a mere 2.5% of world textile trade, behind China, Pakistan and

Turkey. Further, we have the only substantial household-based cotton textile industry in

the world, and as part of that we have a huge skill-bank in the millions of people capable

of weaving and of making the looms and accessories. We grow our own cotton and make

our own yarn. Therefore we enquired further into contribution of the textile policy

pursued in India after independence and what were its limitations which contributed for

such gloomy conditions in that sector.

Page 23: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

85

Study of textile Policy in historical perspective reveals at least five salient concerns

that have motivated policy although their relative importance has varied at different

points in time. These are regulation of inter-sectoral competition, provision of cheap

cloth, fibre policy, modernisation and sickness and rehabilitation of mills.

In the initial flush of Independence and the considerable influence of Gandhian

ideology at that time, the dominant opinion on the choice of `technology for cloth

manufacture was that the promotion of handlooms could achieve at one stroke the twin

objectives of generation of employment and the production of cloth for mass

consumption. The issue of choice of technique was a matter of great debate in India in

1950s and 1960s. The central issue, which was not settled at the time, and one which still

remains a great challenge for Indian policy makers is, what is to be maximized – output

or employment.

The ambiguity was not strikingly reflected in the textile policy. The textile policy

attempted to promote mills and handlooms simultaneously and consequently, ended up in

contributing to sickness of mills and decimation of handlooms. A third sector, namely

powerlooms, came up to push both sectors on the back foot and ran away with all

incremental demand of textiles. It can be debated how far the ascendancy of powerlooms

was policy induced or an outcome of gradual development of a different pattern of

industrial organisations. Here an intermediate technology (powerloom) is out competing

capital-intensive technique (mill sector) as well as a labour-intensive technique

(handloom). However a recent study of informal textile industry of Kanpur shows that the

conventional ‘choice of technique’ model fails to explain satisfactorily the continued

proliferation of powerloom and gradual decimation of handloom. Neither is the capital-

intensive technique (powerloom) always growth stimulating nor is the labour-intensive

technique (handloom) always employment maximizing. Therefore the debate on what to

maximise, output or employment is still afresh among the policy makers.

This brings into focus the fundamental dilemma that policy-makers are invariably

confronted with – a policy that is technically and economically rational, is often not

politically so. A realistic policy must necessarily involve difficult trade-offs between

political and economic objectives.

Review of significance of Khadi among other traditional sectors revealed that that the

traditional sector is being pushed to a corner as its share in output is concerned; in 1996-

97, it had contend with mere 8.36 percent share in out put against as high as 60.36

Page 24: CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA - Shodhgangashodhganga.inflibnet.ac.in/bitstream/10603/2719/10/10_chapter 3.pdf · CHAPTER 3 TEXTILES AND KHADI IN INDIA ... status of the Khadi

86

percent share in employment. Over time, the traditional rural industries have steadily lost

their ground to modern small-scale industries, whether located in the rural or urban areas.

Interestingly, the powerloom sub-sector seems to have been an absorber of many

additional working hands even while losing tremendously in its share in output. it is

interesting to see that while the Khadi’s share in output, in total textile production or in

sector-wise production, has been declining steadily its share in employment has been

improving steadily over time. The Khadi sector almost looks like a residual sector.

However, a preponderant majority of Khadi workers are engaged on part-time basis only,

and accordingly, to their share, a very small proportion of the industry-wise earnings

would accrue. Poverty and low-level of living are thus the endemic characteristics of their

existence.


Recommended