+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Economic Impact of Migration on a Rural Area in...

Economic Impact of Migration on a Rural Area in...

Date post: 28-Jan-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
23
Economic Impact of Migration on a Rural Area in Bangladesh Pierre Yves Beaudouin * February 2, 2006 Abstract The main objective of the paper is to analyze the effects of migration on sending countries. The objectives are to analyze the direct and indirect effects of migration on the migrant household income, to measure the opposed effects and to discuss the policy implication of our results. The study is based on a Three Stage Least Squares estimator to determine and mea- sure the net impact of migration on the household income. The empirical study show a negative effect of the loss of labor on the total income. However, this effect is compensate by remittances sent home by migrants. When we decompose the income in three sources of income (farm, self-employed and wage), we find these two opposed effects for the farm income, but no effect of remittances on wage in- come and only a negative effect of migration for self-employed income earned by the household. Keywords: Migration, Remittances, NEML, Bangladesh JEL Classification: O15, R23, D13 * Centre d’ ´ Economie de la Sorbonne, Universit´ e Paris 1 Panth´ eon-Sorbonne, CNRS, 106-112 boulevard de l’Hopital, 75647 Paris Cedex 13, France. T´ el: +(33)144078243. Fax: +(33)144078337. Email: pierre. [email protected], Homepage:http://team.univ-paris1.fr/teamperso/beaudouin. I thank participants of the AFSE seminar “Economic Development and Transition” on 19-20 May 2005 for helpful comments. 1
Transcript
  • Economic Impact of Migration on a Rural Area in

    Bangladesh

    Pierre Yves Beaudouin∗

    February 2, 2006

    Abstract

    The main objective of the paper is to analyze the effects of migration on sending

    countries. The objectives are to analyze the direct and indirect effects of migration

    on the migrant household income, to measure the opposed effects and to discuss

    the policy implication of our results.

    The study is based on a Three Stage Least Squares estimator to determine and mea-

    sure the net impact of migration on the household income. The empirical study

    show a negative effect of the loss of labor on the total income. However, this effect

    is compensate by remittances sent home by migrants. When we decompose the

    income in three sources of income (farm, self-employed and wage), we find these

    two opposed effects for the farm income, but no effect of remittances on wage in-

    come and only a negative effect of migration for self-employed income earned by

    the household.

    Keywords: Migration, Remittances, NEML, Bangladesh

    JEL Classification: O15, R23, D13

    ∗Centre d’Économie de la Sorbonne, Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, CNRS, 106-112 boulevardde l’Hopital, 75647 Paris Cedex 13, France. Tél: +(33)144078243. Fax: +(33)144078337. Email: [email protected], Homepage:http://team.univ-paris1.fr/teamperso/beaudouin. Ithank participants of the AFSE seminar “Economic Development and Transition” on 19-20 May 2005 forhelpful comments.

    1

  • 1 Introduction

    The United Nations estimates the stock of international migrants about 175 million in

    20001. The proportion of migrants in the world is growing, international migrants repre-

    sented 2.5 per cent of the world population in 1960 and 2.9 per cent in 2000. This trend

    should not change in the next decades despite migration laws, institutional structures and

    tightening of procedures. Despite these small figures, migration may have some important

    developmental effects on developping countries. One of the main canal of transmission of

    migration on sending countries is remittances flow sent back home by migrants to their

    family.

    Remittances are now view as a possible source to finance development. Dilip Ratha

    estimated that remittances going to developing countries represents $150 billion in 2004.

    This amount is bigger than foreign aid and is the first source of foreign capital for many

    countries. This flow of formal remittances2 from migrants to their relatives in their

    country of birth has exhibited a high rate of growth. The doubling of remittances flow3

    during the last decade has increase the study of remittances.

    The literature on the impact of migration is biased on the receiving countries. Most

    of the studies on migration are on the receiving countries’ economies and the effect on

    sending countries has been neglected. One of the reason is the absence of data on migra-

    tion. But the increase of remittance flows last years, which is one of the most important

    channel of the impact of migration on sending countries, has developed a recent growing

    literature on the effects of migration on sending countries. If non poor household partic-

    ipate to the migration process, like it seems to happen, a study without controlling for

    selectivity bias will overestimates the impacts of migration.

    Most of the literature study the effects of migration only on one part and the effects

    of remittances in another part. Most of the time, migration studies does not take into

    account the effects of remittances when studying the effects of migration on sending

    countries. Likewise a lot of papers on the effects of remittances does not take into account

    the real or potential selectivity of migrant. As migrants may represent a non randomly

    chosen subset of the overall sample, an econometric estimation by Ordinary Least Squares

    (OLS) becomes problematic if migrant and non migrant individuals differ systematically

    in their productive capabilities (individuals characteristics like education, experience,

    1Figures are from the World Migration Report (IOM, 2005, p.379)2Official statistics only take into account remittances flows transiting by formal channels (bank or

    wire transfer companies like Western union or Money gram). As some surveys found that the part ofremittances transiting by informal ways is important, remittance flows seems to be underestimate. An-other limit of recorded remittance flow is that because these figures comes from the balance of payments,by definition they only take into account remittances send by overseas migrants.

    3This increase of remittances flow is more the consequence of a improvment of the statistics than areal increase of money send back to family.

    2

  • gender. . . ).

    But there is few studies which take into account the linkages between migration and

    remittances. The size of remittance flows do not allow us, for the study of the effects

    of migration, to use the classical migration theories (Lewis, Harris and Todaro) as these

    theories did not take into account remittances in the migration strategy. Analysis on

    remittances does not take into account the determinants of migration. The only way

    to take into account in the analysis the migration decision and remittances effects is to

    use the NELM framework. This paper is based on the framework developed by the new

    economics of labor migration (NELM) which analyzes migration as part of a strategy to

    diversify the sources of income of the household in presence of market failures (Stark 1991;

    Stark and Bloom 1986). Futur remittance flows are taken into account in the decision of

    migration. And migration is viewed as an allocation of labor like non-farm labor or crop

    production.

    Another particularity of this paper is to analyze the effects of migration on all the

    economic activities of the household and not only on a particular sector, like it is done

    in the previous literature. For example, Azam and Gubert (2002) study the impact of

    migration on the agricultural sector. There is also some empirical study on the question

    of the links between migration, remittances and business creation. Amuedo-Dorantes and

    Pozo (2002) showed that remittances has no statistically significant impact on business

    investment in the Dominican Republic

    Using a particularly rich household survey on Bangladesh, the objective of this paper

    is to test the impact of migration on rural communities. Does migration reduce crop

    income and/or crop yield ? Does migration have an impact on other sources of income ?

    If yes, is it the same effects than for crop production ? Finally, are the NELM hypothesis

    validate ?

    The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the framework of the NELM.

    Section 3 presents the data used in this paper and describe some descriptive statistics

    of our household survey. Section 4 presents the empirical strategy to test our model.

    Section 5 presents the results and section 6 concludes the paper.

    2 Theoretical background

    The literature on migration is not new. Already in 1889, Ravenstein presents some

    “laws of migration”. The analysis based on the work of Lewis (1954) and Harris and

    Todaro (1970) have permit the study of some aspects of migration like the determinants

    of migration, the effects of migration on the receiving countries or the impact of migration

    on the labor market of the sending countries. But unfortunately theses models are not

    3

  • relevant to analyze the effects of migration on sending countries.

    The trademark of the NELM is that migration decisions are taken by larger units of

    related people - typically the househould, in the contrary to neoclassical theories who

    take the migrant as the unit of decision(Stark, 1991) not only to maximize the expected

    income, but also to minimize risks and loosen constraints created by a variety of market

    failures, including missing or incomplete capital, insurance, and labor markets.

    The persisting bounds between migrants and their households of origin lead to a re-

    ject of the individual-level migration decision model (like the implicit migration model of

    Lewis (1954) or Harris and Todaro (1970)) and to opt for a household model. The house-

    hold provides the funds to finance the cost of migration (transportation, fees charged by

    recruitment agencies, fees to obtain a visa and work permit, maintenance while searching

    for work. . . ) and in return, once migrants become established, the migrant share a part

    of its income by sending back some money and goods. These repeated interactions lead

    us to prefer household model to explain the decisions of migration Taylor and Martin

    (2001).

    So NELM focuses on a particular kind of migration: the short-term labor migration,

    with migrants keeping strong tie with their family of origin and who are expecting to

    return rather than settle in the host country (Sana and Massey, 2005).

    Taking the household as the unit of analysis is a mean to understand migration as a

    risk minimisation strategy.

    The migration of labor is analyzes as an exportation of a part of the labor factor

    of the household. Migration is now an element of the diversification of the sources of

    income of the household. In rural area of developping countries, crop is still the first

    income generating activity. But crop production suffers from many hazards (aléas de la

    production et fluctuation des cours des produits agricoles).

    The migration decision is no more view only as an income maximisation but also as

    a risk minimisation. In presence of market failures or missing of credit and insurance

    markets, household members should find an informal method to insure against risk. Ac-

    cording to the NELM, the migration of labor could be a method to insure against risk.

    An informal contracts are conclude between migrants and their households of origin.

    The second role of the migrant is to be a financial intermediary. Remittances could

    help to relax the liquidity constraint of the household by increasing investment in new

    technologies of production, for example by introducing high yield varieties or by develop-

    ing non-farm business (Massey et al., 1993). Migration by generating some income can

    help to increase the agricultural productivity.

    For the NELM framework, income differential is no more a necessary condition to the

    migration contrary to the standard approach initiated by Lewis (Stark and Katz, 1986).

    4

  • The theoretical model developed in this section is based on the NEMT framework de-

    veloped par Oded Stark. The analysis below is based on the works of Rozelle et al. (1999).

    The role of financial intermediaries play by the migrants can be illustrated by the figure 1.

    For simplification, we will use a unitary model of household. In this model, the

    household head is the only decision taker of the household. Consider a household who

    could invest a fix sum T̄ , such as agricultural land, labour or factory. The household can

    invest in two possible production activities with a difference in returns; such Qi, with

    i = 0, 1, the production of the low and high-return activity, respectively.

    The production of each activities depend on the investment and of the individual

    characteristics Z (for example education or age), Qi = f(Ti, Z). The total income is

    Y = g(Q0 + Q1). We can draw a production possibility frontier (PPF) in a graph with

    x-axis Q0 and y-axisQ1. For example, for a relative price of P =P1P0

    , the household will

    invest all the sum T̄ in the high-return activity. The output will be Q∗ = f1(T̄ , Zy) and

    the household income will be Y ∗ = g(Q∗).

    What are the effects of migration and remittances in this framework ? In an envi-

    ronment of perfect market, remittances have no effect on the household production. The

    household model in the case of perfect markets is separable (Singh et al., 1986). The de-

    cisions of production are independent of the dotations and preferences of the household.

    On a theoretical point of view, production and consumption decisions can be analyzed

    as being taken successively. Firstly the household decides its production level, and after

    it deduce its consumption level from the production level decided before. The negative

    effects of migration can imply a negative impact on production (decrease of the labour

    force has for consequences the decrease of the production). But in this model, remittances

    have no effect because as an simple income transfer

    Remittances have an effect on the consumption of the household by allevitaing the

    budget constraint but have no effect on the production level of the household4.

    One of the main determinant of migtration for NELM is the presence of market

    imperfections. In presence of imperfections, the household is credit constraint and can

    only invest T̄ , with T1 < T̄ . For exemple, the household owns an arable land. To cultivate

    this land, the household needs to spend some money ex ante. The credit constraint is

    relaxed by the migration process. If the household could not spend this amount because

    of a lack of savings or imperfections of the credit market, then the household production

    would be constraint. The production constraint will be Qc1 and Qc0. Migration could

    4The remittances do not change the profit maximisation condition which determine the level of pro-duction.

    5

  • Figure 1: Migration effects on production

    6

  • help to relax this constraint. In the presence of market imperfections, migration could

    be a solution. The model is non separable in presence of market imperfections. Shadow

    prices are evaluated for non-market activities. These prices linked the production and

    the consumption spheres. Remittances could have now some effects on the household

    production sphere.

    The relaxation of the credit constraint could be represented by a shift upward of the

    resource constraint line Qc1. However the net effect of migration is may be not positive.

    The constrained output is Qc1 = f1(T1, Z) for the high-return technology and Qc0 =

    f0(T̄−T1, Z) for the technology with low productivity. The constrained household incomeis so: Y c = g(Qc1 + Q

    c0) with Y

    c < Y ∗ the non-constrained income.

    The overall effect is ambiguous as the partial effects of migration and remitttances,

    c(M) and c(R), are undetermine. However, we can make a hypothesis on the value of the

    coeeficients. The non-separability of the model involve the non nullity of the coefficients

    c(M) and c(R). Test if these coefficient are statisticalley significant than zero would

    be a support or an unfirmation of NELM. Few tests exist of the NELM hypothesis.

    However we can cite Lucas (1987); Taylor (1992); Taylor and Wyatt (1996); Rozelle et al.

    (1999); Taylor et al. (2003). This paper will test the NELM hypothesis by developping

    an estimator.

    3 Empirical Methodology

    As mentioned below, migration is a strategy to increase the income of the household or to

    insure the household against risks. But the household can also diversify its production by

    developing non-farm activities or taking an employment. Migration is in competition with

    other strategies to attract assets. But migration could alleviate constraints on production.

    In developing countries, household are usually constrained by imperfection of markets like

    a labor constraint, a lack of liquidity or or a credit constraint. Remittances could have a

    positive effect on the household by alleviating these constraints. Migration can extend the

    investment realize by the household. Migration can also help the household to diversify

    its activities.

    Migration has a potential negative effect. The lost of labor can decreases the pro-

    duction of the household if the productivity do not increases. Agricultural activities still

    represents the major part of the income of the household. However this activity can

    particularly suffer from migration. This negative impact of migration on crop production

    has been found by Azam and Gubert (2004) in their study on the Soninke migration and

    also by Mochebelele and Winter-Nelson (2000) in their analysis of migration in Lesotho.

    Both papers conclude of a larger farm technical efficiency of non-migrant household.

    7

  • Previous literature testing the effect of migration on sending countries suffer from

    some limitations. An approach used in the literature is based on descriptive statistics.

    Authors use the answer to the question of the use of how do the household use remittances.

    Surveys usually find remittances are used in housing construction. However, remittances

    can free up other sources of income that may be used for other means. A survey which

    find that the principal use of remittances is in the housing construction can conclude of

    an unproductive use of remittances. But because remittances are fungible, The presence

    of fungibility of the resources prevent us using this method.

    Another approach is to examine an outcome of interest by comparing households

    who receive remittances with households that do not. We can estimate the impact of

    remittances on an outcome of interest and controlling for a set of migrant, household and

    community characteristics through ordinary least squares (OLS) regression.

    Outcomei = δ + φ ∗Remittancesi + γ ∗Xi + �iHowever, this approach could suffer from omitted variable bias. If the only effect of

    migration on the outcome of interest is through remittances, the results are not biased.

    But if migration has other impacts on the outcome in addition to its effect through

    remittances, then the error terms contains omitted variable that are correlated with

    remittances and with the outcome. This will result in a bias of the results.

    That is why we replace in the previous equation the remittances variable by a variable

    of migration, to test the overall impact of migration.

    Outcomei = α + β ∗Migrationi + χ ∗Remittancesi + η ∗Xi + �iThe coefficient β then captures the joint impact of remittances and of other conse-

    quences of migration through the migrant variable.

    The production is constrain because of the presence of market imperfections. This

    as for result that (Y c) depends on migration (M) and remittances (R). A vector of

    individual, household and village characteristics may also affect the income. In order to

    test if migration and remittances have different effects according to the source of income,

    the empirical analysis will distinguish three distinct sources of income: crop production

    Yc, self-employed income Ys and wage Yw5.

    (1) Y ck = α0k + α1kM + α2kR + α3kZk + �Yk ; k = a, s, w

    As mentioned before a potential bias of endogeneity is possible. We control for this

    bias by the instrumental variable method6.

    5The total income is the sum of the three sources of income and the remittances, Y = Ya+Ys+Yw +R6A test of endogeneity has been completed. A joint test that the coefficient of the residual are statically

    different from zero

    8

  • Migration depends of the individual, household and village characteristics, (ZM):

    (2) M = β0 + β1ZM + �M

    The dependent variable is the number of migrants.

    Remittances are a function of migration, individual and household characteristics

    (ZR):

    (3) R = γ0 + γ1M + γ2ZR + �R

    After the presentation of the theoretical model and our empirical method to test the

    model, the next section will present the specification of the system of equation.

    3.1 Variable specification

    The survey use the following definition to define a member of a household. A householder

    is a person who has been living in the household for at least 6 months or less than 6 months

    but plans to stay in the household for more than half a year. So a person who has been

    living at least 6 months outside the household7 or who moved out of the household for

    marriage of migrated overseas will be defined as a migrant. Remittances include cash and

    in-kind transfers8

    Following the NELM theory, migration and remittances variables are linked with the

    household income. To control this endogeneity bias, we choose the instrumental variable

    method. The migration network is an instrument in the migration equation(Taylor and

    Wyatt, 1996). Village migration network is approximate by the number of migrants by

    village. We postulate that the variable have a positive effect on the number of migrants

    but have no effect on the income nor on the remittances (minus the number of migrants

    of the household). In our preferred specification, we decompose the network variable into

    an internal migrant network composed by migrants living in Bangladesh and external

    migrant network composed by migrants living outside the country.

    In the remittances equation, the norm of the village to remit is an instrument. We

    use the annual amount of remittances received by a household of the village to proxy the

    norm of the village. This instrument is proposed by Taylor et al. (2003). This variable

    should affect the level of remittances received by the household but has no effect on the

    income of the household.

    7without plans to stay more longer in the household8whatever the method of transfer. The great advantage of using a survey is that remittances include

    transfer transiting by banks or money trabsfer firms like Western Union or Money gram (formal transfer)and money transiting by hand, hundi (informal transfer).

    9

  • 3.2 Functional form

    Equations (1) through (3) constitute an equation system. Error terms �i, i = Y,R,M are

    normally and identically distributed with variance σ2i . A correlation of the error terms

    is likely to occur between the income equations and remittances. An exogene shock can

    have an effect on the five equations. To account for contemporaneous correlation, we

    choose to estimate our model by the three-stage least squares. This estimation method

    consist of an estimation of each equation by the two-stage least squares and a correction

    of the error terms to take into account the possible correlation of the error terms.

    4 Data

    The data use in this paper, Matlab Health and Socio-Economic Survey (MHSS), have

    been collected by RAND Corporation in 1996. In spite of the goal of the survey was not

    migration, this survey includes a lot of information on our subject. The dataset contains

    informations on non-resident household members9 (their relationship with the household

    head, age, marital status, education level, location, occupation, remittances send back to

    home. . . ). The dataset includes four separate surveys with different samples. The main

    survey consists of household- and individual-level information on 4,364 households. The

    second survey is on the determinants of natural fertility survey. The third survey is on

    internal migrants and the last survey consists of a community survey. This paper use the

    main survey which consists of 4,364 households distributed on 140 villages.

    Matlab is a rural area in the south-west part of Bangladesh. Since 1966, a pro-

    gram of demographic surveillance under the Centre for Health and Population Research

    (ICDDR’B, formerly known as International Centre for Diarrhoeal Disease Research,

    Bangladesh) is in place in this area. The sample of MHSS benefit from this program as

    the sample is based on previous surveys and census realized by ICCDR’B. Moreover the

    9We have information on the spouse, children, parents or sibling of the household head who aremigrants.

    Table 1: Number of household migrating

    Status Household Percentage

    Number of household with at least one migrant 1,992 45.65%Number of household with at least one migrant abroad 609 13.96%Any migrant 2,372 54.35%Total 4,364 100%Source: MHSS (1996)

    10

  • Table 2: Distribution of migrants by relationship and remitting status

    Relationship Number of migrants RemitTotal Internal External Total Percentage

    Spouses 353 203 158 284 80.45%Children 3,883 3,572 1,332 2,143 55.19%Parents 1,015 950 91 83 8.18%Siblings 15,164 12,954 2,210 2,620 17.28%Total 20,415 5,130 25.13%Source: MHSS (1996)

    experienced field organization and the respondent population accustomed answering to

    surveys lead to very low attrition rates

    Matlab is located about 55 kilometers Dhaka, the country’s capital and one of the

    city with the highest growth rate of the world10. In spite of this geographical proximity,

    a trip between Matlab and Dhaka takes six hours preventing return trips. This is a cause

    of urban migration (Kuhn, 2001). Destinations of overseas migrants11 can be basically

    separate in three groups: Developing countries, Persian Gulf and Southeast Asian coun-

    tries. These destination countries for migrants have changed over the years. The first

    destination was Great Britain. The second destination was Middle east countries (Saudi

    Arabia, Kuwait, UAE. . . ) in the seventies. The last destination is southeast countries

    (Malaysia, Brunei. . . ). In contrast to the migration to developing countries, migration to

    the Middle East and South East Asia has been characterised by short term employment,

    with specific job contracts and migrants returning home after completion of the contract

    period IOM (2005). Informal migration is so very difficult, the main way to become an

    illegal migrant is to stay in the country after the end of the labor contract.

    This survey collected data on such diverse topics as income, expenditures, education,

    employment, food consumption, health and nutrition, landownings, assets, migration and

    rural credit. . . . The particularity of the dataset that is interesting for us is the information

    on migrants: education, remittances, employment, location . . . . The survey also include

    a village survey.

    4.1 Descriptive statistics

    A little bit less than half of households in the survey have at least one migrant, and 13.96%

    have at least one migrant abroad (table 1). The data does not allow us to know precisely

    in which country resided migrants, but in general Bangladeshis migrate to Middle East

    10The population of Dhaka was 1.3 million before the independance (1971) and 8.5 million in 1997.11Figures are available on the SAMReN website http://www.samren.org/FactsandF igures/bangladesh/1.1.htm

    11

  • Table 3: Remittances

    Internal External Total

    Spouses 4395.733 30002.18 12921.53Children 2412.394 6106.651 9109.04Parents 21.910 7.412 110.735Siblings 569.027 104.573 939.772Total 2541.451 12531.9 7166.73Source: MHSS (1996)

    countries (Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, Oman, Qatar. . . ) and more recently to South East

    Asian countries (Malaysia, Singapore. . . ).

    The dataset included information on different type of migrant: spouse of the household

    head, its children, parents and siblings. Table 2 shows statistics on remittances received

    by surveyed households. The incidence of remittances vary a lot. 80% of household head

    spouses send money to their spouse. More than half of the children of the household head

    remit. This figure fall to 17.28% and 8.18% for parents and siblings of the household

    head. This lead us to restrict our analysis to spouse and children migrants. A migrant

    household is defined, in the following of the paper, as a household having at least one

    person (the spouse of the household head or its children) who was previously a member

    of the household has left for more than six months to live or work elsewhere, either in

    Bangladesh or abroad.

    The average respondent received tk7,166.733 per year from migrants (Table 3). But

    this figure vary a lot between the destination of migration and the relationship of the

    migrant. International migrants send more money back home as they earn more abroad.

    Also, the spouse of the household head or these children send more money than parents

    or siblings. A household who actually had a migrant son or a migrant spouse received

    tk4,395.733 from internal migrant and tk30,0002.18 from international migrants. In con-

    trast, siblings living outside the district or the country account for a very little sum of

    transfer.

    Table 4 shows the number of migrants per household. On average a household count

    4.68 migrants, with a minimum of 1 and a maximum of 29.

    Table 5 presents the means of variables used in the regression analysis, broken down

    by migration status. The household size and the composition of the household are not sig-

    nificantly different between migrant household and non-migrant household. The human

    capital is more important in migrant household as non farm assets, but it is not the case

    for farm assets and the agricultural land per capita own by the household. A significant

    difference comes out from comparing the two sub-samples regarding the amount of remit-

    12

  • Table 4: Number of migrants and amount of remittances received per house-hold

    Number of Mean Number Mean Numbermigrants amount of of amount of ofwithin remittances households remittances householdsthe household received received

    0 0 422 0 3,7551 499 1686 24,221 4272 538 2749 35,223 1233 516 4612 62,335 404 468 5569 63,884 165 418 5715 26,866 3>5 1503 10674 - -Total 5898 4,364 4,186 4,364Source: MHSS (1996)

    tances received by the household. This is not a surprising figure, because children and

    spouses have the higher propensity to send remittances and they send a larger amount

    of money than siblings. The fact that we restrict our analysis to overseas migration is

    also an explanation of this high amount of remittances send back home by migrants.

    Households with migrants abroad get in general about 83% more income than the others.

    But this figure is not sufficient to answer the question of the impact of migration. That is

    why in the following sections we develop an econometric analysis to answer this question.

    A p-value of less than 0.05 means that the null-hypothesis of equal means for both groups can be

    rejected at an error level of less than 5 percent [H0: Differences in means = 0].

    13

  • Table 5: Descriptive statistics

    Variable Non migrant Migrant t P>|t|household household(N=3755) (N=609) (*)

    Household size 5.516 5.84 -3.187 0.0014Dependence ratio 0.403 0.381 2.269 0.0233Education 2.901 3.804 -5.522 0.0000Experience 38.922 43.656 -7.563 0.0000Non productive assets 10206.81 27970.1 -7.663 0.0000Land per capita 0.091 0.152 -1.516 0.1295Number of cows 0.069 0.080 -1.023 0.1889Farm assets, lagged 501.039 789.557 -1.349 0.1774Non farm assets, lagged 8843.42 38660.83 -4.008 0.0001Remittances 2238.482 32587.45 -23.812 0.0000Total income 40967.45 81102.68 -11.1164 0.0000N 4364

    Source: MHSS (1996)

    5 Results

    5.1 Migration

    Estimations of the determinants of migration are presented in table 6. Results are consis-

    tent with previous empirical findings. Results are quiet similar between each specification.

    The first specification is a simple OLS, the others are Poisson estimations12. Specifica-

    tions 2 and 3 only change in the variable that we belive can act as instruments to identify

    migration.

    The first set of regressors are household demographic characteristics. One would

    expect that the number of migrants would rose as the size of the household rose and

    fall as the the number of dependents rose. The coefficient of the household size has a

    statistically significant impact on the number of migrants. However, the dependance ratio

    has no statistically significant impact. Education and experience variables have both a

    statistically significant and positive impact on the number of migrants. The coefficient

    of land per capita is not statistically significant. But the proxy variable for wealth, the

    value of non-productive assets, has a positive effect on migration. This could reflect the

    fact that migration has a cost.

    The migration networks variables include in the regression have a statistically sig-

    nificant impact on the number of migrants. More precisely, the coefficient of the total

    12The OLS estimator is biased, because the migration variable is non-negative and there is a lot ofnull observation.

    14

  • number of migrants of the village is positive. But when we break down this figure between

    the number of migrants living in the country and the number of migrants living abroad,

    we found a different effect between these two variables. The external migration networks

    has a positive effect on the number of migrants, but contrary to Mendola (2005) who

    found a positive but smaller effect, we cannot conclude to a effect different from zero of

    the internal migration networks on the migration variable.

    The final set of regressors are village characteristics. The negative coefficient of this

    dummy reflect the fact that a better environment decrease the incitation to migrate. The

    coefficient of the village size is negative. The presence of markets in the village have no

    significant impact on the number of migrants.

    5.2 Three Stage Least Squares

    5.2.1 Remittances

    Estimations of the Three Stage Least Squares are presented in table 7. The first column

    represents the remittances equation. Only few coefficients are statistically significant.

    Wealthier households (measured by the value of the value of the nonproductive assets

    owned by the household) receive more remittances. The village norms to remit has a

    positive coefficient. Only for the specification with the different source of income, the

    coefficient of the dependence ratio is statistically significant and positive. A household

    living in a village with a stronger norm to remit will receive more remittances than a

    household staying in a village with a less strong norm. The coefficient of the migration

    variable is positive. Each additional migrant increase remittance by Taka 17,892. This

    support the descriptive statistics presented in the previous section.

    5.2.2 Total income and sources of income

    Results are quite similar between total income regression and sources income regression

    (table 7 and 8). Remittances have a positive effect on income, except on the wage income.

    Migration do not have any significant effect on the total income. However, crop income

    falls when migrants leave the household. This negative effect is even bigger on wage

    income. With the departure of a household member, the labor force of the household

    decreases, and the income also decreases.

    Coefficients for the other exogenous variables affect income in ways that are consistent

    with findings by other researchers. The household siez has a positive effect on both total

    income and income by sources. It is also the same with the number of years of education

    of the household head, except for the wage income where its impact is non statistically

    15

  • significant. Stock of capital (farm and non-farm) positive effects on income, like the

    amount of land per capita.

    Although the coefficients of the village size are generally insignificant, the population

    of the village negatively affects crop income. This is the same for large and small markets

    which negatively affects respectively crop and self-employed income.

    16

  • Table 6: Determinants of migration

    Explanatory variables Number of migrants(1) (2) (3)

    Household characteristicsHousehold size 0.013∗∗∗ 0.060∗∗∗ 0.062∗∗∗

    (0.001) (0.000) (0.000)Dependance ratio 0.440 0.104 0.121

    (0.281) (0.524) (0.460)Education 0.011∗∗∗ 0.073∗∗∗ 0.069∗∗∗

    (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Experience 0.056∗∗∗ 0.028∗∗∗ 0.028∗∗∗

    (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Non productive assets 0.000∗∗∗ 0.000∗∗∗ 0.000∗∗∗

    (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Land per capita 0.002 0.006 0.006

    (0.833) (0.850) (0.847)Village characteristicsVillage size -0.000∗∗∗ -0.001∗∗∗ -0.000∗∗∗

    (0.003) (0.000) (0.006)Large market 0.017 0.098 0.014

    (0.396) (0.354) (0.899)Small market 0.009 0.058 0.071

    (0.732) (0.472) (0.389)Total Migrant -0.005 -0.008

    (0.871) (0.946)Internal migrant 0.093

    (0.542)External migrant 1.255∗∗∗

    (0.001)

    N 4236Significativity levels : ∗ : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗ ∗ ∗ : 1%

    17

  • Table 7: Estimated effects of migration and remittances on total income

    Explanatory variables Number of migrants Remittances Total incomeNumber of migrants 17892.79∗∗∗ -7200.424

    (0.000) (0.109)Remittances 1.245∗∗∗

    (0.000)Household characteristicsHousehold size 0.062∗∗∗ 4702.144∗∗∗

    (0.000) (0.000)Dependance ratio 0.119 -1494.178

    (0.467) (0.362)Education 0.069∗∗∗ 1480.925∗∗∗

    (0.000) (0.000)Experience 0.028∗∗∗ 2.967

    (0.000) (0.966)Non productive assets 0.000∗∗∗ 0.077∗∗∗ 0.311∗∗∗

    (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Land per capita 0.006 -157.568 1327.261

    (0.833) (0.679) (0.038)Farm assets, lagged 0.910∗∗∗

    (0.000)Non farm assets, lagged 0.089∗∗∗

    (0.000)Village characteristicsVillage size -0.000∗∗∗ 0.982 -4.963∗∗∗

    (0.005) (0.502) (0.204)Large market 0.025∗∗∗ –543.444 265.778

    (0.817) (0.670) (0.946)Small market 0.082∗∗∗ 1064.253 -9177.352

    (.307) (0.248) (0.000)Number of industries

    Industry 481.722∗∗

    (0.038)External migrant 1.271∗∗∗

    (0.000)Village remittances 0.822∗∗∗

    (0.000)Remittance facilities -1386.039

    (0.274)Mills ratio 1154.361

    (0.531)

    N 4236Significativity levels : ∗ : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗ ∗ ∗ : 1%

    18

  • Tab

    le8:

    Est

    imat

    edeff

    ects

    ofm

    igra

    tion

    and

    rem

    itta

    nce

    son

    tota

    lin

    com

    eExpla

    nato

    ry

    varia

    ble

    sN

    um

    ber

    ofm

    igrants

    Rem

    itta

    nces

    Agric

    ulturalin

    com

    eW

    age

    incom

    eSelf-e

    mplo

    yed

    incom

    eN

    um

    ber

    ofm

    igra

    nts

    17969.6∗∗∗

    -4130.6

    01∗∗∗

    -7755.1

    91∗∗

    245.4

    60

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.0

    15)

    (0.8

    92)

    Rem

    itta

    nce

    s0.2

    89∗∗∗

    0.0

    68

    0.1

    51∗∗

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.6

    69

    (0.0

    47)

    House

    hold

    characte

    ris

    tics

    House

    hold

    size

    0.0

    62∗∗∗

    903.4

    61∗∗∗

    3079.0

    52∗∗∗

    380.8

    50∗∗

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.0

    28)

    Dep

    endance

    ratio

    0.1

    19

    -13696.8

    19∗∗

    (0.4

    67)

    (0.0

    11)

    Educa

    tion

    0.0

    69∗∗∗

    199.9

    11∗∗∗

    1066.3

    57

    25.2

    44

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.8

    25)

    Exper

    ience

    0.0

    28∗∗∗

    28.8

    02∗∗

    -79.1

    13

    -65.3

    64∗∗

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.0

    34)

    (0.1

    30)

    (0.0

    21)

    Non

    pro

    duct

    ive

    ass

    ets

    0.0

    00∗∗∗

    0.0

    78∗∗∗

    -0.0

    16∗∗∗

    0.2

    10∗∗∗

    0.0

    16

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.0

    09)

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.2

    66)

    Land

    per

    capita

    0.0

    06

    -163.1

    33

    2036.2

    53∗∗∗

    940.3

    65

    -159.3

    20

    (0.8

    33)

    (0.6

    69)

    (0.0

    02)

    (0.2

    17)

    (0.7

    00)

    Farm

    ass

    ets,

    lagged

    0.2

    16∗∗∗

    (0.0

    00)

    Non

    farm

    ass

    ets,

    lagged

    0.0

    29

    (0.0

    00)

    Liv

    esto

    ck-0

    .030

    (0.5

    80)

    Villa

    ge

    characte

    ris

    tics

    Villa

    ge

    size

    -0.0

    00∗∗∗

    0.6

    51

    -1.2

    56∗∗

    -3.4

    68

    -1.2

    02

    (0.0

    05)

    (0.6

    56)

    (0.0

    86)

    (0.2

    17)

    (0.4

    29)

    Larg

    em

    ark

    et0.0

    25

    -846.6

    49

    -1129.9

    21∗

    -703.3

    46

    867.4

    80

    (0.8

    17)

    (0.4

    96)

    (0.0

    56)

    (0.8

    12)

    (0.5

    90)

    Sm

    all

    mark

    et0.0

    82

    880.0

    57

    -190.5

    90∗

    -8099.8

    59∗∗∗

    -1116.0

    84

    (.307)

    (0.3

    29)

    (0.6

    65)

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.2

    47)

    Num

    ber

    ofin

    dust

    ries

    703.7

    66

    (175.0

    52)

    Indust

    ry722.2

    95∗∗∗

    -32.1

    71

    (0.0

    00)

    (0.7

    36)

    Exte

    rnalm

    igra

    nt

    1.2

    71∗∗∗

    (0.0

    00)

    Villa

    ge

    rem

    itta

    nce

    s0.7

    58∗∗∗

    (0.0

    00)

    Rem

    itta

    nce

    faci

    lities

    -619.1

    80

    (0.5

    81)

    Mills

    ratio

    1644.2

    84

    (0.3

    68)

    N4236

    Sign

    ifica

    tivi

    tyle

    vels

    :∗

    :10

    %∗

    :5%

    ∗∗∗

    :1%

    19

  • 6 Conclusion

    This study used a rich dataset from rural Bangladesh to examine the different effects of

    overseas migration and remittances on the different sources of income of the household.

    Three conclusions emerge from it. First, our results supports the NELM framework that

    remittances are an element of a household strategy to alleviate market failures. Secondly

    the loss of labor affect negatively the household income. Finally the impact of migration

    is complex. It should be break down into two different effect: the lost of labor and the

    amount of remittances received. Effects also differ from income sources. Migration have

    no effect on self-employed income and remittances have no statistical impact on wage

    income.

    20

  • Annex 1. Variable definition

    Household characteristics

    Number of migrants: a person (the spouse of the household head or its children) who was

    previously a member of the household has left for more than six months to live or work

    elsewhere

    Remittances : value of remittances send by migrants

    Household size: size of the household

    Dependence ratio: (children 0-14 years + adults > 65 years)/persons 15-64 years

    Education: number of years of education of the household head

    Experience: number of years of experience (Experience=Age-Education-16 based on work

    of Jacob Mincer, Schooling, Experience, and Earnings (New York: Columbia University

    Press, 1974)

    Non productive assets : value of non productive assets

    Land per capita: agricultural land owned by the household per capita

    Farm assets, lagged : value of farm assets owned by the household in 1995

    Non farm assets, lagged : value of non farm assets owned by the household in 1995

    Village characteristics

    Village size: size of the village

    Large market : dummy variable, 1 if a large market is present in the village

    Small market : dummy variable, 1 if a small market is present in the village

    Number of industries : number of industries in the village

    Total migrant : number of migrant in the village minus the number of migrants of the

    household

    Internal migrant : number of internal migrant in the village minus the number of migrants

    of the household

    External migrant : number of external migrant in the village minus the number of mi-

    grants of the household

    Village remittances : mean value of remittances received by the village minus the amount

    of remittances received by the household

    Remitances facilities : dummy variable, 1 if there is a bank or a post in the village

    21

  • References

    Amuedo-Dorantes, C. and S. Pozo (2002). “Workers’ Remittances and the Real Exchange

    Rate: A Paradox of Gifts.” mimeo.

    Azam, J. P. and F. Gubert (2002). “Those in Kayes. The Impact of Remittances on their

    Recipients in Africa.” Document de Travail 11, DIAL.

    IOM (2005). “World Migration Report.” Technical Report, IOM.

    Kuhn, R. (2001). “Never Far from Home: Parental Assets and Migrant Transfers in

    Matlab, Bangladesh.” RAND Labor and Population Working Papers 01–12.

    Lucas, R. E. (1987). “Emigration to South Africa’s mines.” American Economic Review.

    77 (3), 313–330.

    Massey, D. S., J. Arango, G. Hugo, A. Kouaouci, A. Pellegrino, and J. E. Taylor (1993).

    “Theories of International Migration: a Review and Appraisal.” Population and Devel-

    opment Review. 19 (3), 431–466.

    Mendola, M. (2005). “Migration and Technological Change in Rural Households: Com-

    plement or Substitutes ?” Working Paper 2005-15.

    Rozelle, S., E. J. Taylor, and A. de Brauw (1999). “Migration, Remittances and Agricul-

    tural Productivity in China.” American Economic Review. 89 (2), 287–291.

    Sana, M. and D. S. Massey (2005).“Household Composition, Family Migration, and Com-

    munity Context: Migrant Remittances in Four Countries.” Social Science Quaterly.

    June 86 (2), 509–528.

    Singh, L. Squire, and J. Strauss (1986). Agricultural household models, extensions, aplli-

    cations, and policy,

    Stark, O. (1991). The Migration of Labor, Basil Blackwell, Cambridge, U.K.

    and E. Katz (1986). “Labor Migration and Risk Aversion in Less Developed

    Countries.” Journal of Labor Economics. 4 (1), 134–149.

    Taylor, J. and T. Wyatt (1996). “The Shadow Value of Migrant Remittances, Income and

    Inequality in a Household–Farm Economy.” Journal of Development Studies. 32 (6),

    899–912.

    Taylor, J. E. (1992). “Remittances and Inequality Reconsidered: Direct, Indirect and

    Intertemporal effects.” Journal of Policy Modeling. 14 (2), 187–208.

    22

  • and P. L. Martin (2001). “Human Capital: Migration and Rural Population

    Change.” in B. L. Gardner and G. C. Rausser, eds., Handbook of Agricultural Eco-

    nomics, Elsevier.

    , S. Rozelle, and S. de Brauw (2003).“Migration and Incomes in Source Communi-

    ties: A new Economics of Migration Perspective from China.” Economic Development

    and Cultural Change. Octobre 52 (1), 75–101.

    23


Recommended