+ All Categories
Home > Documents > REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust...

REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust...

Date post: 07-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: charlton-butler
View: 219 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 16

Transcript
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    1/16

    RegulatorGlobal News oF ReleVaNCe To eNTiTies & iNdiViduals aFFeCTed by aNTiTRusT issues wiNTeR 2009, V. ii,

    IN THIS ISSUE:n International UpdatePage 2

    nChina: InBev/Anheuser-Busch Merger Gets the Go-Ahead, but With ConditionsPage 2

    n European Competition Law UpdatePage 2

    n Enhanced Pace o International Cartel EnorcementPage 4

    n EU Commission Targets Pharma IndustryPage 5

    n Reed Smith Comments on the Application o the EC Merger RegimePage 6

    n Germany Proposes New Merger Control ThresholdPage 7

    n Latest European Court Ruling Fails to Resolve Parallel Trade UncertaintyPage 8

    n United States UpdatePage 9

    n The Election o President Obama and Antitrust EnorcementPage 9

    n Implications o the Supreme Court Decision Rejecting Reliance as a Requirement in a

    Civil RICO ClaimPage 10

    n Make Way For Class Certifcation TrialsPage 11

    n Federal Circuit Applies Rule o Reason and Validates Reverse Payment Patent

    Settlements in In re Ciprofoxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust LitigationPage 12

    n Federal Court Allows Joint Bidding Suit to ProceedPage 14

    n Regulatory Update In BriePage 15

    n Reed Smith At The PodiumAnd On PaperPage 13

    http://www.reedsmith.com/
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    2/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 2

    In its irst public ruling since the adoption o the new Anti-Monopoly Law

    (AML), the Chinese Ministry o Commerce (MOFCOM) has allowed InBevs

    US$52 billion purchase o Anheuser-Busch, creating the worlds largest brewer.

    The conditions imposed to secure clearance may,

    however, leave a bitter atertaste.

    The new competition law regime in China has

    attracted a lot o attention since its adoption

    last year and entry into orce Aug. 1, 2008. The

    AML itsel is rather vague and only provides

    or general principles. With most implementing

    rules not yet ready and a near complete lack o

    previous enorcement experience by the Chinese

    authorities, the irst decisions were eagerly

    awaited.

    MOFCOM has approved a number o concentrations since the entry into orce

    o the AML. However, this is the irst decision to be made public, and MOFCOM

    has clariied it will usually only publish conditional approvals or prohibitions o

    concentrations. The decision, together with some guidance on merger review

    published by MOFCOM on its website, will allow companies and their advisers

    to get a eel or the enorcement o merger control in China and the procedure

    involved.

    MOFCOM set out its decision in a one-page document briely stating the

    conditions imposed on the parties. InBev is required:

    n Not to increase Anheuser-Buschs existing 27 percent shareholding inTsingtao Brewery

    n To inorm MOFCOM i there is any change to its controlling shareholders in a

    timely manner

    n Not to increase InBevs existing 28.56 percent shareholding in Zhujiang

    Brewery

    n Not to acquire shares in China Resources Snow Brewery and Beijing Yanjing

    Brewery

    Imposing conditions or merger clearance is nothing new. The paradox, however,

    lies with the act that MOFCOMs assessment ound that the acquisition will not

    distort competition in the beer market in China. The conditions were justiied

    to ensure that no urther acquisitions take place that may deteriorate the

    competitive structure o the market in the uture.

    MOFCOM has indicated that its approach to merger control is not only

    to contribute to the normal operation o markets, but also to the healthy

    development o enterprises. Preserving a competitive market structure has

    always been a concern to competition law enorcers, but imposing conditions on

    uture acquisitions or unproblematic transactions appears little, i at all, justiied

    on competition grounds. Businesses trying to acquire companies in China will

    now have to plan their uture acquisition strategy careully, including the potential

    impact on other business activities in China.

    Although MOFCOM has been conscious o the timeline provided or in the AML,

    it took several submissions o supplemental inormation beore the preliminary

    review could be commenced or InBev. MOFCOM has stated it is currently

    working on detailed implementation rules to clariy the material required to

    be submitted to it or merger review. In the meantime, it is possible to submit

    questions in writing to MOFCOM or clariication, or reer to the notiication

    guidelines under the older Rules o Foreign Investors Acquisition o Domestic

    Enterprises.

    Another point that emerged rom the InBev decision was the role that

    competitors and other industry players may play in the competition assessment

    process. During the review, MOFCOM engaged in extensive consultations with

    other government departments, beer industry associations, domestic beer

    manuacturers, manuacturers o beer ingredients, and beer distributors. This is

    not uncommon practice, but it remains to be seen how important an involvement

    and inluence third parties may have in the merger review process in China.

    The AML and merger control enorcement in China are still at a very early stage.

    The InBev decision is, however, sending worrying signals o competition law

    serving as a guise or industrial policy planning and national protectionism,

    and it is hoped that this will not become a generalized trend o competition law

    enorcement in China.

    Thomas Karalis

    Trainee Solicitor London

    I N T E R N A T I O N A L U P D A T E

    China: inBev/anheuser-BusCh merger gets the go-ahead, But with Conditions

    European State-aid measures to combat the global financial crisis

    The global inancial crisis that has taken hold in the latter hal o 2008 has given

    rise to a lurry o activity in the State-aid ield as a number o inancial packages

    have been put in place in order to save struggling European banks and to ensure

    the stability o the inancial systems o various EU Member States. These

    packages necessarily need prior EC clearance as State aid to ensure that the aid

    does not coner on the beneiciary undertakings, an unair advantage over their

    competitors within the EU.

    In order to protect inancial stability and avoid spill-over eects on the rest o

    the economy, new temporary arrangements were put in place by the European

    Commission Oct. 1 to allow quicker approval decisions on proposed emergency

    rescue measures in avor o inancial institutions. This has seen, or example, the

    recent approval o rescue aid to Hypo Real Estate in Germany within a couple o

    days o notiication, and the approval o aid to Bradord & Bingley in the UK within

    just 24 hours o ormal notiication ollowing urgent inormal discussions with UK

    authorities on how to structure the package to limit distortions o competition.

    european Competition Law update

    (continued on page 3

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=16404http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=16404http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=16404
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    3/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 3

    (continued on page 4

    The European Commission has also published guidance (in the orm o a

    Communication) to EU Member States as to how they can structure support

    schemes, such as guarantees or recapitalization schemes, in a way that would

    be compatible with EU State-aid rules. The Communication considers that

    Article 87(3)(b), under which the Commission may allow State aid to remedy aserious disturbance in the economy o a Member State, is available as a legal

    basis or aid measures undertaken to address the

    inancial crisis in light o the level o seriousness

    that the current crisis in the inancial markets

    has reached, and o its possible impact on the

    overall economy o EU Member States. The

    Commission has recently approved a number o

    support schemes under Article 87(3)(b) in the UK

    and other EU Member States.

    The Commissions recent activity in this

    ield shows its willingness to adapt its usualprocedures in exceptional circumstances. While

    the above measures have helped a number o

    struggling inancial institutions, struggling irms in other sectors are unlikely to

    have support approved on the same basis in the absence o a comparable risk to

    the wider economy.

    Creation of a new public interest consideration in UK merger control

    Following the Sept. 18, 2008 announcement by Lloyds o its intention to merge

    with HBOS, the Secretary o State issued an intervention Notice to the UK Oice

    o Fair Trading (OFT) (the body responsible or irst phase review o mergers in

    the UK), stating that he believed the stability o the UK inancial system ought tobe speciied as a public interest consideration under the Enterprise Act, and that

    this may be relevant to the consideration o the Lloyds/HBOS merger situation.

    An order was subsequently laid beore Parliament introducing this new public

    interest consideration into the Act. As with the State-aid measures described

    above, the intention was to ensure that the regulatory process did not prevent

    rapid action rom being taken to address issues arising rom the global inancial

    crisis.

    The UK merger regime provides limited powers or the Secretary o State to

    intervene in mergers in order to protect legitimate public interest considerations.

    Previously, the only speciied public interest considerations had been national

    security and plurality o media ownership. However, it was elt that the new publicinterest consideration was necessary as the inancial services sector was vital

    to the economy, and the ailure o a bank would leave individuals and businesses

    unable to access savings, raise inance or meet day-to-day inancial obligations,

    with potential knock-on eects in other parts o the inancial system.

    Following its review o the transaction, the OFT concluded that there was a

    realistic prospect that the anticipated merger would result in a substantial

    lessening o competition in relation to personal current accounts, banking

    services or small and medium-sized enterprises in Scotland, and mortgages. It

    was elt that it would not be appropriate to deal with the competition concerns by

    way o undertakings in lieu o reerence to the Competition Commission (CC).

    The Secretary o State (with whom the inal decision rested), however, considered

    that the stability o the UK inancial system outweighed the competition concerns

    identiied by the OFT and thereore decided not to reer the merger to the CC or a

    more in-depth investigation.

    This is an exceptional case and is the irst time a public interest consideration

    has been created in order speciically to acilitate a particular merger. As many

    commentators have noted, the merged entity will, o course, be subject to the

    ordinary competition rules in its daily operations.

    BSkyB/ITV

    A recent judgment o the UK Competition Appeal Tribunal (CAT), dismissing an

    appeal by BSkyB (the UKs largest pay TV provider), has upheld a decision o the

    Secretary o State o January 2008 (implementing a Report rom the Competition

    Commission) that BSkyBs acquisition o a 17.9 percent shareholding in ITV (a

    UK national terrestrial television broadcaster) would give rise to adverse eects

    on competition. The CAT held that the CC had been entitled to ind in its Report

    that the acquisition constituted a relevant merger situation, on the basis that

    it granted BSkyB the ability to exert material inluence over the policy o ITV,

    and that it would lead to a substantial lessening o competition. The judgment

    supported the CCs approach to the consideration o material inluence, inding

    that BSkyB had identiied no deect that would render the indings perverse or

    irrational.

    The CAT did, however, ind that the CC had incorrectly applied the plurality o

    the media public-interest consideration in inding, in this regard only, that the

    acquisition would not be expected to operate against the public interest. The

    judgment provides interesting analysis o the media plurality public interest

    consideration, this being the irst time that the Secretary o State has intervened

    in a merger on this (or any other) ground since the Enterprise Act gave decision-

    making authority to the OFT and CC. The CAT held that the Commission ought to

    have treated BSkyB and ITV as wholly controlled by only one person, and treated

    the act that, in practice, BSkyB shares control over ITV with others as irrelevant

    or the purpose o the plurality assessment.

    This case is also noteworthy or the act that the CAT went on to consider

    separately in a second judgment whether to remit the media plurality question

    back to the CC and Secretary o State. It held that the remedy imposed (requiring

    BSkyB to reduce its shareholding to 7.5 percent) was not undermined by the

    Reports deiciency in relation to the plurality issue, and that remitting the

    plurality issue to the CC and Secretary o State would thereore serve no useul

    purpose: it could not result in any lesser remedy being considered appropriate as

    the reduction in shareholding was still necessary to remove the adverse eect on

    competition; urther, there was no realistic prospect o any additional or dierent

    remedy being imposed, as the existing remedy would also be suicient to remove

    the eects o the transaction on the plurality o media owners. The CAT has

    reused BSkyB permission to appeal its decision, but leave to appeal may still be

    sought directly rom the Court o Appeal.

    Richard J. WaiteAssociate London

    European & Middle East Corporate

    e C L uc 2

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=11073http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=11073http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=11073http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=11073
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    4/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 4

    e C L uc 3

    New European liner consortia block exemption

    On Oct. 21, the European Commission published a preliminary drat block

    exemption Regulation or liner shipping companies participating in consortia

    arrangements. Liner shipping essentially involves the provision o regular

    services on which cargo is transported by container; consortia are deined as

    arrangements between two or more carriers that provide international liner

    shipping services exclusively or the carriage o cargo, chiely by container,

    and the object o which is to bring about cooperation in the joint operation o a

    maritime transport service.

    Consortia arrangements have beneited rom a block exemption since 1995, and

    the European Commission recently held a consultation period, inviting comments

    on a drat Regulation revising the existing block exemption that is due to expire

    April 25, 2010 (the submitted comments are now available on the European

    Commissions website at: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/legislation/

    maritime/). I adopted, the revised Regulation will remain in orce until 2015.

    An accompanying technical paper published by the European Commission

    explains that consortia generally help to improve the productivity and quality o

    liner shipping services through the economies o scale and eiciency they allow

    in the operation o vessels and utilization o port acilities; customers beneit

    rom the improvements in service quality and the global coverage that such

    arrangements bring about.

    This review comes at a time when the European Commission has been phasing

    out other sector-speciic block exemptions, such as the aviation block exemption

    and the liner conerence block exemption, and when the only other sectoral block

    exemption regulations in orce (the Insurance Block Exemption and the Motor

    Vehicle Block Exemption) are undergoing review, with the possibility that they will

    not be renewed. This could thereore be the last sector-speciic block exemption

    adopted by the European Commission.

    European Commission imposes highest ever cartel fine

    On Nov. 12, the European Commission announced that it had imposed ines

    totaling 1.38 billion (roughly US$1.97 billion) on our European producers o car

    glass involved in cartel activity between 1998 and 2003. (For more details, see

    article on Enhanced Pace o International Cartel Enorcement in this issue o

    theAntitrust Regulator.) This groundbreaking ine comes hot on the heels o a

    676 million (US$965m) ine imposed by the European Commission Oct. 1 on

    participants in a parain wax cartel. These are the irst signiicant ines imposedsince early 2007 and act as a clear and stark reminder to companies engaged

    in cartel activity in Europe, that the Commission remains intent on sending out a

    strong message that such activity will result in severe penalties. The European

    Commissions press release notes the right o injured parties to seek damages or

    loss arising rom the operation o the cartel.

    enhanCed paCe of internationaL CarteL enforCement

    In recent months, we have seen a signiicant increase in antitrust enorcementagainst international cartels. This increased activity in international cartel

    enorcement is worth noting since it relects a greater emphasis on eradicating

    price-ixing cartels by enorcement agencies

    worldwide. The ollowing recent examples are

    discussed here: (1) the imposition o the highest

    ine against a cartel ever, where the European

    Commission ined car glass producers more

    than 1.3 billion or a market sharing cartel; (2)

    LG, Sharp and Chunghwas agreement to plead

    guilty and pay a total o $585 million in ines or

    participating in price-ixing conspiracies; and

    (3) the Eastern District o New Yorks reusal to

    dismiss a class action against various Chinese

    Vitamin C manuacturers.

    The European Commissions Imposition of the Highest Fine Ever

    On Nov. 12, 2008, the European Commission imposed ines totaling

    1,383,896,000 again Asahi Glass, Pilkington, Saint-Gobain and Soliver or illegal

    market sharing and exchange o commercially sensitive inormation regarding

    deliveries o car glass in the European Economic Area (EEA), in violation o the

    EC Treatys and the EEA Agreements ban on cartels and restrictive business

    practices. Asahi, Pilkington and Saint-Gobain are the three major players in

    Europes car glass manuacturing industry. Between early 1998 and early 2003,these companies discussed target prices, market sharing and customer allocation

    through a series o meetings and other illicit contacts. The Belgian company

    Solivar also took part in these discussions. These our companies controlled

    about 90 percent o the glass used in the EEA in new cars and or original

    branded replacement glass or cars, a market worth about 2 billion in the last

    ull year o the inringement. The Commission started the cartel investigation on

    its own initiative ollowing a tip rom an anonymous

    source. The Commission increased the ines against

    Saint-Gobain by 60 percent because it was a repeat

    oender. Asahi provided additional inormation

    to help expose the inringement, and its ine was

    reduced by 50 percent under the Leniency Notice.

    These are the highest cartel ines the Commission

    has ever imposed, both or an individual company

    (896 million against Saint-Gobain) and or a cartel

    as a whole.

    The ines in this case are based on the 2006

    Guidelines on Fines. Under these Guidelines, ines

    relect the overall economic signiicance o the inringement as well as the share

    o each company involved. The cartel constitutes a very serious inringement

    o the EC Treatys antitrust rules. In setting the ines, the Commission took into

    (continued on page 5

    Lawrence Kill

    Partner New York

    Commercial Litigation Eastern

    Rizwan A. Qureshi

    Associate New York

    Commercial Litigation Eastern

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=17899http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=17899http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=17899http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=18249http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=18249http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=18249http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=18249http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=17899
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    5/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 5

    account the respective aected sales o the companies involved, as well as the

    combined market share and the geographical scope o the cartel agreements.

    Prctice Tip:Similar to the United States, the concepts o amnesty and leniency

    are important actors in the Commissions determination o the amount o theines imposed. Here, Asahis cooperation reduced its original ine by 50 percent

    rom 227 million to 113.5 million. The Commissions imposition o the highest

    ine ever against a cartel is relective o its increasing emphasis on disbanding

    price-ixing cartels, and highlights the importance o a deendants early

    cooperation.

    Second-Highest Criminal Fine Ever Imposed by the Department of

    Justices Antitrust Division

    Three leading electronics manuacturersLG Display Co. Ltd., Sharp Corp. and

    Chunghwa Picture Tubes Ltd.have agreed to plead guilty and pay a total o

    $585 million in criminal ines or their roles in conspiracies to ix prices in the

    sale o liquid crystal display (LCD) panels. O the $585 million in ines, LG, a

    South Korean corporation, will pay $400 million, the second-highest criminal ine

    ever imposed by the Departments Antitrust Division. Sharp Corp., a Japanese

    consumer electronics manuacturer, has agreed to pay a $120 million ine or

    its participation in separate conspiracies to ix prices or LCD panels sold to

    Dell Inc., Motorola Inc. and Apple Computer Inc. Chunghwa, a Taiwanese LCD

    manuacturer, has agreed to pay a $65 million ine or its participation with LG

    and others in a price-ixing conspiracy.

    The three companies, which were charged with violating the Sherman Antitrust

    Act, allegedly held crystal meetings and engaged in communications about

    setting prices on the LCD displays. They agreed to charge predetermined prices

    or the displays, issued price quotas based on those agreements, and exchanged

    eu Commission targets pharma industry

    Last January, the Commission spectacularly launched an investigation into the pharma sector by carrying out dawn raids on Europes major pharma groups. This

    was the irst time a sector inquiry had been commenced by unannounced inspections.

    The Commission published a 400-page preliminary report on its investigation, which was launched at a press conerence given by EU Competition Commissioner

    Neelie Kroes in Brussels Nov. 28, 2008.

    The Commissions preliminary view, on which it will now consult, is that competition in the European pharma industry is not

    working as well as it should. The Commission cites certain practices o the large pharma groups that the Commission believes

    restrict competition and artiicially keep the prices o drugs high.

    The practices that concern the Commission are: registering lots o patentsapparently 1300 in one caseor the same drug

    (patent clusters) in order to make it more diicult or other companies to produce competing (generic) versions o the same

    drug; a policy o initiating litigation to keep the generic companies out o the market or delay their entry; settling these cases by

    agreements that typically keep the generic competitor out o the market or a time; giving the generic competitor a license o the

    patent holders drug or the right to sell it, so removing the possibility o a new generic drug entering the market; and/or including a

    so called reverse payment to the generic company.

    The truth is that there is really nothing new in any o these allegations or practices, many o which have already been extensively

    litigated by competition authorities and industry players in the United States. The debate turns on the tension between antitrust

    legislation that is aimed at promoting competition, and other laws that saeguard intellectual property rights, which by their very

    nature coner an unchallengeable monopoly on the holder. Patents and other intellectual property rights are in the public interest

    because they incentivize innovation by allowing innovators the exclusive right to exploit the ruits o their work during a deined period. It is natural that powerul

    companies will wish to use the law in order to delay the entry o competitors and will vigorously deend any challenges to their intellectual property rights. European

    law recognizes the importance o intellectual property rights, and also recognizes that it is not a breach o competition law just to be big and powerul.

    So the Commission will have its work cut out i it is going to mount legal challenges to the practices it has identiied. O course, registration and vigorous deense o

    patents restricts competition. That is the whole point o having a patent. When does this activity go so ar as to become something that the law should sanction?

    In this connection, the Commission will take little comort rom the more recent developments across the Atlantic. Last month, a U.S. Federal Appeals Court upheld

    a decision in avor o drug companies Bayer, Hoechst and Barr in a challenge by a group o health plan providers that patent settlement agreements between the

    three companies had artiicially kept up the price o the drug Ciproexactly the same argument raised by the Commission in its report. See article on Bayer/Barr in

    this issue o theAntitrust Regulator.

    So we will wait and see what enorcement action eventually results rom this enquiry as it now goes to consultation. Consultation will inish at the end o January,

    and the inal report is expected next spring. In the meantime, the Commission is keeping busy with another series o raids on the pharma sector. This, the

    Commission says, is unconnected with the current enquiry, and speculation is that these raids relate to distribution o drugs, rather than preventing or delaying

    generic entry. Neelie Kroes has picked a big ight with the pharma companies. It certainly promises to keep her busy.

    Edward S. Miller

    Partner London

    European & Middle East Corporate

    ec pc il Cl ecc 4

    (continued on page 6

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1609http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1609http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1609http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1609
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    6/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 6

    reed smith Comments on the appLiCation of the eC merger regime

    At the end o October, the European Commission (the Commission) launched a

    three-month public consultation on the unctioning o the EC Merger Regulation

    (the ECMR), which sets out the rules or merger control in the European

    Economic Area (EEA, consisting o 27 EU Member States plus Norway, Iceland

    and Leichtenstein).

    When the ECMR came into eect May 1, 2004,

    it introduced reerral mechanisms that gave

    the merging parties the right to request the

    Commission to examine a transaction that was

    notiiable in at least three Member States, even

    when the turnover thresholds or Commission

    review were not met. Conversely, the notiying

    parties can request a reerral to a Member

    State when the transaction signiicantly aects

    competition in a distinct market in that Member

    State. The Commissions consultation ocuses on

    the eectiveness o these reerral mechanisms.

    The Competition and EU Group at Reed Smith submitted comments to the

    Commissions consultation at the beginning o December. Reed Smith noted

    that, at the European level, there is a need or a reerral mechanism that allows

    the parties to request that the Commission reviews a transaction that triggers

    notiication in a number o EU Member States. Such a mechanism allows parties

    to concentrate their resources on making one iling and managing one timetable,

    without incurring iling.

    However, Reed Smith noted that, while there are beneits to using the reerral

    mechanism, parties will still tend to opt to make multiple ilings in dierent

    Member States, especially when the transaction does not raise any competition

    concerns. Parties can be deterred rom using the reerral mechanism because

    the procedure lengthens the decision-making timetable and places an additional

    burden on the parties to provide detailed inormation to the Commission beore

    ormal notiication is made.

    The reerral mechanism requires a period o 15 working days to be added to

    the decision-making timetable, to allow or the reerral request to be approved

    or vetoed by the Member States. Given that a notiied transaction cannot be

    completed until it is approved by the Commission, this additional period candeter parties rom requesting a reerral. This is particularly the case where the

    transaction does not raise competition concerns and clearance can be expected

    without a detailed investigation being initiated. In such circumstances, parties wil

    oten preer to coordinate notiications across a number o jurisdictions to ensure

    clearance as quickly as possible so as not to delay the transactional timetable.

    Reed Smith has thereore proposed the introduction o an expedited reerral

    procedure under the ECMR in those circumstances where the transaction does

    not raise any competition concerns, and a technical notiication requirement

    has only been triggered because turnover thresholds have been met.

    Lesley A. Davey

    Partner London

    European & Middle East Corporate

    sales inormation on the display panels, in order to monitor and enorce the

    agreement.

    Prctice Tip:This is yet another example o antitrust enorcement agencies

    clamping down on international cartels. The ine imposed on LG is signiicantas it is the second-highest ever imposed by the Antitrust Division, and puts into

    perspective the crippling eect such a ine could have on a violating entity.

    Antitrust Suit Proceeds Against Chinese Vitamin C Manufacturers

    Despite an amicusbrie submitted by the Chinese Ministry o Commerce, Eastern

    District o New York Judge David Trager rejected a motion to dismiss and allowed

    an antitrust action to proceed against Chinese Vitamin C makers. The Chinese

    companies, Hebei Welcome, Jiangsu Jiangshan, Northeast Pharmaceutical

    Group and Weisheng Pharmaceutical Co., claim they were compelled by their

    government to ix the price o vitamin C in violation o U.S. law. The plaintis,

    Ranis Co. and Animal Science Research Inc., are American manuacturers

    who alleged in their complaint that the ormation o the alleged cartel led to an

    increase in the price o vitamin C in the United States rom $2.50 per kilogram to

    $7 per kilogram between December 2001 and December 2002. In their motion

    to dismiss, the deendants did not deny the allegations, but invoked the acts o

    state, oreign sovereign compulsion and international comity doctrines.

    Here, Judge Trager concluded that there was not enough evidence to determine

    that any o these doctrines applied to the deendants price-ixing action, despite

    the arguments made by the Chinese government. The Chinese Ministry o

    Commerce in its brie identiied the trade association that allegedly acilitated

    the cartel as the Chamber o Commerce o Medicines and Health Products

    Importers & Exporters. The brie argued that such chambers, in contrast to their

    voluntary nongovernmental U.S. cousins, have played a central role in Chinas

    shit rom a command economy to a market economy. Although the ministry

    noted that it did not decide the speciic prices, the deendants and the ministry

    insisted the companies could not have exported vitamin C without conorming

    to the agreed-upon price. Judge Trager said the Chinese position was owed

    deerence but was not conclusive. Further, he said it was contradicted by other

    documents in the case, which suggested a complex interplay between the

    deendants and the Chamber that made it diicult to determine the degree o

    deendants independence in setting prices. Judge Trager denied deendants

    motion to dismiss and has allowed the antitrust suit to proceed.

    Prctice Tip:This case is indicative o the act that U.S. courts are taking a

    more stringent stance against international cartels. Even despite the arguments

    asserted by a oreign government, U.S. courts appear poised to enorce U.S.

    antitrust violations by oreign cartels.

    ec pc il Cl ecc 5

    (continued on page 7

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=11031http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=11031http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=11031http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=11031
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    7/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 7

    Reed Smith also noted that the detailed inormation that has to be provided to the

    Commission when making a request acts as a deterrent rom using the reerral

    mechanism. This is especially the case where the transaction obviously does

    not raise competition concerns at either a Member State or Community level.

    Reed Smith suggested that this inormation, which includes details o customers,

    competitors, suppliers and changes to the market over a ive-year period, is

    overly burdensome or parties to a transaction that maniestly do not raise any

    competition concerns. Reed Smith thereore suggested that a shortened request

    orm be introduced or these types o transactions.

    The Commission is due to complete its consultation Jan. 30, 2009. It will then

    prepare a report to the EU Council o Minister setting out its views on howeectively the reerral mechanism is working and whether any amendments to

    the ECMR are needed.

    r s C alc eC m rc 6

    germany proposes new merger ControL threshoLd

    German merger control laws prevent parties rom entering into M&A

    transactions beore obtaining clearance o the proposed transaction with the

    Bundeskartellamt, the German Federal Cartel

    Oice. Entering into an M&A transaction

    without obtaining clearance jeopardizes the

    legal eectiveness o the proposed transaction,

    at least with regard to any German element,

    and bears the risks o substantial ines or any

    individual violating German law.

    In determining whether a proposed transaction

    needs to be notiied to the Bundeskartellamt,

    German law sets up two thresholds (assuming

    the de minimis exception and the trile market

    provision do not apply):

    n First, the combined aggregate worldwide turnover o all companies involved

    with the proposed transaction needs to exceed an amount o 500 million.

    n Second, the German turnover o at least one participating company needs to

    exceed 25 million.

    These requirements do not necessarily take into account whether there is

    an actual competitive impact in Germany. In most cases, merger ilings are

    submitted or non-German M&A transactions or precautionary reasons because

    one party alone exceeds the 25 million domestic threshold. I, or example, a

    company headquartered in the United States intends to acquire all the shares

    in another U.S. or other non-German company, a German merger iling will be

    required i the acquiring party (including all ailiated companies) has worldwide

    sales exceeding 500 million and the sales in Germany exceed 25 million.

    The question o market impact and relevance o the transaction rom a German

    merger control perspective will then (in principal) only be examined on a second

    level once the notiication to the Bundeskartellamthas been submitted.

    The current German laws result in a actual duty to notiy proposed transactions

    to the Bundeskartellamt, even i there are obviously no concerns rom a merger

    control perspective. This results in respective costs but, more important, can

    also cause considerable delay i a transaction cannot close because the merger

    clearance is outstanding.

    On July 23, 2008, the German Federal Government took the decision to introduce

    a new drat bill that, i implemented, would signiicantly reduce the number

    o merger ilings. The drat o the so-called Third Small Business Relie Act

    (Drittes Mittelstandsentlastungsgesetz)intends to disburden small and medium-

    sized businesses (Mittelstand)in Germany rom bureaucratic constraints. The

    competitiveness o the domestic medium-sized businesses, as well as the

    attractiveness o the business location in Germany, shall be improved.

    With regard to German merger control laws, the

    drat bill proposes to introduce a new turnover

    threshold o 5 million that has to be exceeded by

    one o the parties, in addition to the existing turnover

    threshold o 25 million that has to be exceeded by

    one party only according to the current provisions. I

    neither o these two thresholds is met, there would

    be no requirement to notiy a proposed transaction

    in Germany.

    I implemented, the number o merger control

    procedures would be signiicantly decreased, which

    would relieve the companies concerned, may they

    be in Germany or abroad. The drat bill would thereore make a contribution that

    proposed transactions do not have to be notiied to the FCO i they constitute only

    little or obviously no risks to the local markets.

    The implementation would also align the current German laws to international

    merger control regimes. Compared with the current German regulations, in

    many other jurisdictions and even in the European Regulation EG/139/2004 (EC

    Merger Control Regulation), the aggregate turnover o more than one company

    involved in the merger has to exceed a certain domestic turnover threshold. Thus,

    compared with other jurisdictions, a considerably high number o cases, including

    cases in which the target is not even located in Germany, are brought beore the

    FCO or merger control purposes each year at the moment.

    The German antitrust authority has not yet commented on the proposed

    amendments. At this stage, it remains unclear whether and when this amendmen

    will be adopted by the German parliament.

    Constantin F. Conrads

    Associate Munich

    European & Middle East Corporate

    Robert A. Heym

    Partner Munich

    European & Middle East Corporate

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=2216http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=2216http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=2216http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=938http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=938http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=938http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=938http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=2216
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    8/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 8

    The European Court o Justice has again reused to set down clear guidance on

    the legality o reusal by pharma companies to ill export orders rom parallel

    traders. The ongoing legal battle between drug wholesalers and pharma

    companies about restrictions on parallel trade

    enters a new phase o uncertainty ollowing

    the most recent ruling by the European Court o

    Justice in a case brought against pharma giant

    GSK by a group o Greek wholesalers.

    Parallel trade comes about where wholesalers

    take advantage o dierent reimbursement prices

    or the same drugs prevailing in dierent EU

    Member States by buying drugs and shipping

    them rom low price countries to high price

    countries.

    The most recent ruling (itsel in a case that has

    kept the parties in litigation or eight years already) is the latest episode in a

    continuing soap opera o cases zigzagging between national European courts

    and competition regulators, the European Commission and the European Court

    o Justice. Unortunately, the implication o the ruling is that this particular series

    still has a long time to run.

    In his earlier advisory opinion to the Court in this case, the European Advocate

    General had clearly not been impressed with the string o amiliar arguments

    that GSK had dutiully trotted out. These are essentially that drug companies

    reusal to supply parallel traders or export is justiied by dierential national

    reimbursement prices imposed on the drug companies by state social security

    authorities, rather than set by the drug companies; that parallel trade unairly

    impinges on a air return on the substantial R&D required to bring a drug to

    market; that restrictions on drug exports were needed to ensure adequacy o

    national supply in each country; and that parallel trade serves only to line the

    pockets o the parallel traders rather than serving the interests o consumers.

    As expected, the European Court did not dissent rom the views o its Advocate

    General. To do otherwise would have been to open up a new exception to the

    much-promoted imperative o completing the European internal ree market by

    vigorously attacking any obstacle placed in the way o interstate trade. It would

    have taken a very brave court indeed to do this.

    However, in a signiicant move toward the position advanced by the pharma

    companies, the Court held that pharma companies can reuse to supply unusual

    orders rom wholesalers. But to prevent the drug companies rom jumping to the

    conclusion that any export order at all could be unusual, the Court also made it

    clear that a reusal to supply based only on the act that the order was or export

    rather than domestic sale would be unlawul. It was or the national courts to

    decide what was unusual in the light o previous regular commercial practice.

    The Court raked up two previous cases, both more than 30 years old, as authority

    or this idea. One admittedly is one o the leading cases in the area o abusive

    reusal to supply. However, in a judgment in that case running to more than 300

    paragraphs, you really need to look hard to identiy the two sentences the Court

    relied on in the GSK case. The other case cited by the Court concerned a reusal

    to supply petrol in a uel shortage, where it was held to be not abusive or BP to

    supply less uel to an occasional customer than to a regular customer. Hardly a

    compelling analogy to GSKs case.

    One might speculate that the Court elt that it was caught between a rock and

    a hard place. The Court did not want to make the pharma industryamong the

    most vibrant sectors in the EUa new wide exception to its crusade to complete

    the internal market. However, perhaps a degree o sympathy or the act that

    the national pricing dierentials at the root o the problem are not the pharma

    companies ault, let the Court with a desire to leave the door open just a crack.

    So where does all this leave us? With about 4 billion o parallel trade annually,

    one might think that there is an awul lot o regular commercial practice that

    parallel traders can use to justiy their export orders. One might also ask whether

    it would still be normal commercial practice or a parallel trader to request an

    increase in supplies o 5 percent, or 10 percent, or 20 percentmeasured over a

    month, a year or perhaps the history o the traders relationship with the relevant

    drug manuacturer. What about the case o a parallel trader who currently trades

    in one drug but, seeing dierentials alling away, switches his request or supply

    to similar volumes o another drug manuactured by the same supplier? Such

    questions will all provide irst rate opportunities to grow the practices o the drug

    companies and parallel traders lawyers.

    The truth is that although pharma companies are likely to hail the judgment a

    major step orward, it may in practice be diicult to convince national courts

    that large orders or export rom existing traders are unusual within the meaning

    o todays judgment, given the already widespread nature o parallel trade. The

    judgment will, however, at the same time provide support to those national courts

    and competition authoritiessuch as the French Competition Councilwho

    have shown sympathy with the more undamental arguments raised by the

    pharma companies.

    Likely reaction by pharma companies will be to pursue their existing progression

    down the supply chain. As the Courts continue to ail to resolve the uncertainty

    about how the law regulates drug distribution, pharma companies are likely to

    attempt to gain more security by acquiring more and more direct ownership and

    control o distribution. Even this, however, is not a complete answer. A reusal to

    supply a third-party distributor can still be abusive even where the supplier has

    established its own internal distribution systemparticularly where the supplier

    was previously trading with the third-party distributor. This diiculty or the drug

    companies may also then lead to a temptation to leverage the existing legal ob-

    ligation to satisy demand in each national market by canny planning o creation

    and utilization o production capacity so as to ensure that in a given geography,

    available supply does not exceed local demand. So we might see some cases

    where drug manuacturers argue that they simply dont have suicient production

    capacity to be in a position to guarantee supply in the various EU member states,

    while at the same time eeding demand or export orders.

    Overall, this case unortunately looks like another piece o rather inelegant

    sidestepping o this key issue by the European Court. The result will be more

    litigation and more uncertainty in the market as to the permissible scope o

    parallel trade. In shortbusiness as usual.

    Edward S. Miller

    Partner London

    European & Middle East Corporate

    Latest european Court ruLing faiLs to resoLve paraLLeL trade unCertainty

    * This article was irst published in International Clinical Trials, October 2008.

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1609http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1609http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1609http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1609
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    9/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 9

    U N I T E D S T A T E S U P D A T E

    the eLeCtion of president oBama and antitrust enforCement

    There can be no doubt that antitrust enorcement will be invigorated under the

    new administration. Traditionally, presidential candidates seldom spend a lot o

    time discussing their antitrust policies. President-elect Obama, however, madehimsel clear about antitrust enorcement while on the campaign trail.

    In a statement by President-elect Obama to the American Antitrust Institute,

    Obama explained his belie that Antitrust is the American way to make

    capitalism work or consumers. Most undamentally, it insists that

    customersnot government bureaucrats, and

    not monopoly CEOsare the judges o what best

    serves their needs. Obama urther emphasized

    that as president, I will direct my administration

    to reinvigorate antitrust enorcement. It will step

    up review o merger activity and take eective

    action to stop or restructure those mergersthat are likely to harm consumer welare, while

    quickly clearing those that do not. President-

    elect Obama, in particular, pointed a inger at

    the huge numbers o health care and health

    insurance mergers over the past 10 years, noting

    that these had not made the industry more

    eicient but rather had resulted in insurance premiums skyrocketing. In other

    public statements during his campaign, President-elect Obama similarly targeted

    the telecommunications, media and pharmaceutical sectors as industries that

    require stricter antitrust scrutiny and more enorcement.

    So, what can we expect over the next our years in the United States?

    n Eric Holder, Obamas choice or Attorney General, has not expressed any

    antitrust positions. Obama next will appoint assistant attorneys general under

    Holder, including an assistant attorney general or the Antitrust Division. It is

    expected that this appointee will take a harder look at proposed mergers and

    dominant irm cases.

    n President-elect Obama will also appoint a new commissioner to the FTC

    and name a new chairman. Because the FTC is seen as currently promoting

    aggressive antitrust enorcement, it is unlikely that these appointees will

    deter the FTC rom its current course o action, but instead will help bridge a

    growing rit between the current FTC and DOJ.

    n The Obama administration is likely to continue the current administrations

    vigorous enorcement eorts against international cartels.

    n The Obama administration can be expected to target the health care and

    health insurance industries, including closer scrutiny o proposed mergers and

    dominant market shares in these industries. In act, in an article published in

    the Wall Street JournalDec. 17, 2008, FTC Commissioner Jon Leibowitz was

    quoted as saying that the FTCs case against Ovation Pharmaceuticals (see

    in-depth discussion in theAntitrust Regulator, at p. 15), is an example o how

    aggressive we are going to be on health care issues going orward.

    n Additionally, the Obama administration will ocus on agreements that retard

    the entry o generic pharmaceuticals into the market, though he intends to

    preserve the pharmaceutical companies incentives to continue to developcritical new drugs.

    n The Obama administration is expected to support open competition on the

    Internet and would seek to promote many providers o network services

    through network-neutrality. Accordingly, one would expect that the proposed

    telecommunications and media consolidations will have a harder time passing

    muster under the new administration.

    Obviously, it will take a while or the eects o Obamas policies to be elt.

    Nonetheless, in the ace o what is sure to be much stricter antitrust scrutiny,

    companies would be advised to consult counsel at the earliest point possible

    when contemplating a reportable merger or consolidation under the antitrustregulations.

    Natalie C. Moritz

    Partner Pittsburgh

    Commercial Litigation Midwestern

    Further, dominant irms, with signiicant market share, particularly

    in the health care, pharmaceutical, health insurance, media and

    telecommunications industries, would be well-advised to assume tighter

    application o antitrust law to mergers, and may wish to revisit with counsel

    the ollowing types o activities:

    n Any type o tying arrangement, i.e., a requirement that one product or

    service be purchased in order to be able to purchase another product or

    service

    n Any decision to stop dealing, or any reusal to deal, with a vendor or

    distributor

    n Any new pricing structure, including volume discounts, rebates or

    dierential pricing

    n Any proposed restrictions on resale pricing or other resale restrictions

    n Any intellectual property licenses

    n Any agreements or joint ventures with competitors

    In short, antitrust enorcement in the United States seems destined to showrenewed vigor.

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1103http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1103http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1103http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1103
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    10/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 10

    On June 9, 2008, the U.S. Supreme Court issued its opinion in Bridge v. Phoenix

    Bond & Indemnity Co., a unanimous decision explicitly rejecting the notion that

    a plainti must directly rely on the misrepresentations in a mail raud scheme in

    order to bring a civil RICO claim. As recently as 2006, the Court inAnza v. Ideal

    Steel Supply Corp. indicated that recovery under civil RICO was limited to the

    immediate victims o misrepresentation. Under the prevailing interpretation o

    Anza, even i a party suered a loss proximately caused by a raudulent scheme,

    it could not bring a claim unless it directly relied upon the misrepresentations

    alleged. The ruling in Bridgehas enhanced plaintis ability to bring claims under

    civil RICO, but has not rendered reliance irrelevant: reliance may no longer be a

    ormal element o a plaintis claim, but it remains an important consideration in

    determining whether the plainti was injured by

    reason o the raud alleged. It also remains a

    potentially relevant actor in determining whether

    class certiication is appropriate.

    Fct:Cook County, Ill. holds auctions to sell

    tax liens on deaulted properties. The county

    imposes a penalty on top o the amount o unpaid

    taxes and awards liens to the bidder willing to

    accept the lowest penalty. The county solved

    the problem o selecting among equal bids by

    imposing an allocation system and limiting

    each entity to a single bid. This requirement is

    enorced via a Single, Simultaneous Bidder Rule requiring bidders to submit an

    aidavit stating that no agent o the entity has also submitted a bid. Phoenix Bond

    brought suit against Sabre Group LLC, alleging that Sabre violated the county

    rule by arranging or its ailiates to place concurrent bids. Phoenix Bond brought

    its claim as a civil RICO action since Sabre used the mail to submit raudulent

    aidavits to the county. The district court held that Phoenix Bond lacked standing

    since it was only indirectly injured by Sabres misrepresentation. While Sabres

    raudulent scheme injured Phoenix Bond by preventing it rom winning additional

    tax liens in the auction, the district court held that Cook County was the only

    party to directly rely on the alse aidavits.

    The Seventh Circuit reversed, holding that Phoenix Bonds lossthe opportunity

    to acquire additional tax lienswas real and actionable. The Court o Appeals

    held that a plainti who did not directly rely on an alleged misrepresentationmay nonetheless recover damages under civil RICO, provided that the

    misrepresentation was the proximate cause o the plaintis injury. Citing a circuit

    split on the issue o reliance, the Supreme Court granted certiorari to resolve

    whether raudulent statements made to a neutral third-party constitute suicient

    grounds to sue under civil RICO.

    The New Re:In a unanimous ruling written by Justice Thomas, the Supreme

    Court airmed the Seventh Circuit Court o Appeals, and explicitly rejected the

    existence o a direct reliance requirement. The Courts decision in Bridgedoes

    not completely eliminate the role o reliance in a civil RICO action, however;

    it simply departs rom prior case law in holding that irst-party reliance is not

    a required element. The Court is clear that its new rule does not mean that

    a civil RICO plainti can prevail without showing that someonerelied on the

    misrepresentation. Indeed, in order to have standing to bring a civil RICO suit,

    a plainti must both suer an injury and demonstrate that the injury was

    proximately caused by the deendants raudulent scheme. A plainti cannot

    sustain an injury proximately caused by raudulent statements upon which no

    one relied. But by allowing claims rom third-party plaintisthose who are

    injured as a result o someone else relying on a misrepresentationthe Court

    has increased the number o plaintis who can bring a civil RICO action.

    Reliance in Civil RICO Prior to Bridge

    Lower courts considering RICO claims have long employed dierent standards

    regarding the required relationship between a deendants raudulent act and a

    plaintis injury. Some courts required direct injury while others permitted both

    direct and indirect injury. One complicating actor was that reliance has long been

    an element in the common law tort o misrepresentationa point that several

    circuits cited as justiication or reading it into civil RICO. The Supreme Court

    initially sought to resolve the issue in Holmes v. Securities Investor Protection

    (1992) by articulating a proximate cause standard based on the directness o

    the relationship between the parties. Following Holmes, only plaintis who could

    demonstrate an injury directly arising rom another partys raudulent use o

    the mail could bring suit. Lower courts struggled to apply the Holmesproximate

    cause standard, and, once again, a circuit split ormed regarding whether reliance

    was a required element o a civil RICO actionat least two circuits held that

    direct reliance was required while our (including the Seventh Circuit in Bridge)

    allowed a third-party plainti to bring a successul claim.

    In 2006, inAnza v. Ideal Steel Supply Corp. , the Supreme Court reined the

    Holmesproximate cause standard to limit recovery to immediate victims o

    the alleged mail raud. InAnza, the plainti alleged that its competitor unairly

    increased its market share by illegally reraining rom charging state sales tax on

    cash purchases and concealing this conduct via tax raud. The Court held that

    the plainti (a competitor) was an indirect victim o the tax raud and lacked

    standing to bring a civil RICO action. Consequently, the Court did not reach

    the question o whether direct reliance by the plainti was a required element.

    In dissent, Justice Thomas argued that the majority misinterpreted Holmes.

    impLiCations of the supreme Court deCision rejeCting reLianCe as a requirement

    in a CiviL riCo CLaim

    Civil cases brought under the RICO (Racketeer Inluenced and Corrupt

    Organizations) statute are close cousins o antitrust cases. Although civil

    RICO cases are usually based on an underlying allegation o raud, proo

    o a conspiracy among dierent economic actors is oten at the core o

    the plaintis case, just as it is in cases brought under Section 1 o the

    Sherman Act. RICO claims are also similar to antitrust claims because they

    permit prevailing plaintis to recover treble damages plus attorneys ees.

    This causes the Plaintis Bar to preer RICO claims to common law raud

    claims.

    Jeremy D. Feinstein

    Partner Pittsburgh

    Global Regulatory Enforcement

    (continued on page 11

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1929http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1929http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1929http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=1929
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    11/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 11

    Thomas stated that the Court should ocus on the purpose behind the alleged

    misrepresentationgaining a competitive advantage through unair competition.

    Furthermore, he noted that reliance is not ound in the language o RICO. Two

    years later, Bridgeprovided the opportunity to revisit the issue.

    Implications

    n Epnion of efennt ibiit:By adopting a less restrictive view o the

    elements o a RICO claim, the Bridgedecision has increased the number o

    plaintis who may recover damages based on an injury resulting rom a raud

    scheme. The universe o potential civil RICO plaintis has expanded to include

    entities who neither relied upon nor were even aware o the deendants

    misrepresentation.

    n Reince p iminihe, bt ti inificnt, roe in civi RICO: As

    noted above, the Court in Bridgeheld that while the plainti need not rely on

    the misrepresentation, someonemust rely on it. Indeed, Cook County relied

    upon Sabres misrepresentations in the sense that the county processed the

    raudulent bids and corresponding aidavits. Without such reliance, no harm

    could have been suered by Bridge by reason o the misrepresentations.

    Thus, reliance remains a part o a civil RICO claim by virtue o the causation

    inquiry. Because it is not a ormal element o a plaintis claim, however,

    it may be more diicult to prevail on a motion to dismiss based on lack o

    reliance. For instance, one post-Bridgecase reversed a dismissal based on

    lack o reliance with the simple statement that ater Bridgeit is no longer

    necessary to plead or prove reliance. Brown v. Cassens Transport Co., 546

    F.3d 347, 357 (6th Cir. 2008). On the other hand, another post- Bridgecourt

    ruled that while prescription drug users could in theory bring RICO claims

    based on misrepresentations allegedly made to their doctors, and on which

    they did not directly rely, the deendants motion to dismiss must be granted

    because o plaintis ailure to properly allege proximate cause. Ironworkers

    Local No. 68 v. AstraZeneca Pharms. LP, No. 6:07-cv-5000-Orl-22-DAB, at

    *8-*12 (M.D. Fla. Nov. 3, 2008).

    n The cope of RICO contine to epn:The Court in Bridgeexplicitlyrejected the argument that anything short o requiring direct reliance would

    lead to the over-ederalization o traditional state law claims. The Court

    held that i their decision results in the undue prolieration o civil RICO suits,

    then Congress must correct the error with more narrowly crated statutory

    language.

    n Importnce of intervenin ce:Deendants accused o a civil RICO

    oense by a third-party plainti are well advised to examine whether an

    intervening cause broke the requisite chain o causation between the

    alleged misrepresentation and the plaintis injury. For example, Justice

    Thomas notes that had Sabre been able to prove that Cook County knew

    Sabres aidavits were alse (yet permitted them to participate in the auction),

    then the county would have broken the causal chain, thereby eliminating

    proximate cause and precluding third-party liability.

    n Inrnce compnie m hve tnin to brin vibe civi RICO cim

    thir-prt pintiff:In a multi-billion dollar class action against Eli Lilly

    or overcharging or its drug Zyprexa, U.S. District Court Judge Jack Weinstein

    certiied a class o third-party insurance company payors who claim injury

    derived rom misrepresentations that physicians relied upon. The plaintis

    case has survived motions to dismiss, though an interlocutory appeal appears

    likely.

    Jeremy wishes to acknowledge the contributions o Justin Ehrenwerth to this

    article.

    ilc s C dc rc rlc r Cl riCo Clc 10

    maKe way for CLass CertifiCation triaLs

    In a signiicant year-end decision aecting all class actions, but particularly antitrust cases, the U.S. Court o Appeals or the Third

    Circuit decided that trial courts must make bench-trial-like actual indings on all issues o act essential to a class certiication

    decision, even i it means deciding merits issues. In re Hydrogen Peroxide Antitrust Litigation, No. 07-1689 (3d Cir, Dec. 30, 2008).

    It may make class action deense lawyers into trial lawyers again. And in one area where class certiication was nearly automatic

    antitrust cartel casesplaintis will ind it harder to certi y a class because it eliminates any presumption o injury in act. The

    unanimous decision, authored by Chie Judge Scirica and marked PRECEDENTIAL by the court, reversed a trial courts class

    certiication in an antitrust class action that ollowed on U.S. DoJ criminal enorcement action against manuacturers o the primary

    bleaching agent in paper manuacturing. The court summarized its decision as ollows:

    In this appeal, we clariy three key aspects o class certiication procedure. First, the decision to certiy a class calls or indings by

    the court, not merely a threshold showing by a party, that each requirement o Rule 23 is met. Factual determinations supporting

    Rule 23 indings must be made by a preponderance o the evidence. Second, the court must resolve all actual or legal disputes

    relevant to class certiication, even i they overlap with the meritsincluding disputes touching on elements o the cause o action.

    Third, the courts obligation to consider all relevant evidence and arguments extends to expert testimony, whether oered by a party seeking class certiication or by

    a party opposing it.

    The court also made clear that any indings on merits issues made by the trial court in connection with class certiication will not be binding on the inder o act in

    any trial on the merits.

    Daniel I. Booker

    Partner Pittsburgh

    Global Regulatory Enforcement

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=908http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=908http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=908http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=908
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    12/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 12

    federaL CirCuit appLies ruLe of reason and vaLidates reverse payment patent settLements

    in IN RE CIPROFlOxaCIN HydROCHlORIdE aNTITRusT lITIgaTION

    It is an increasingly common case that tests the inherent conlicts between

    antitrust and patent law. On Oct. 15, 2008, the Court o Appeals or the Federal

    Circuit took a position consistent with the Second and Eleventh Circuits and

    rejected the antitrust claims o a group o direct and indirect purchasers

    contesting the legality o reverse payments made by a pharmaceutical patent-

    holder to a generic manuacturer to settle patent litigation. The Federal Circuit,

    airming the district courts grant o summary judgment or the deendants, held

    that such agreements do not violate the antitrust

    laws so long as the patent was not procured

    through raud, the underlying patent suit was

    not a sham, and the anti-competitive eects o

    the settlement agreements are not outside the

    exclusionary zone o the patent.

    Challenges to the Patent and the Settlement

    Agreements

    Bayer Corporation owns a patent or the active

    ingredient in its brand-name drug Cipro. In

    1991, Barr Labs, Inc. sought to manuacture a

    generic version o the drug during the 180-day exclusivity period available to Barr

    as a irst challenger under the Hatch-Waxman Act. Barr challenged the validity

    and enorceability o Bayers patent and, in response, Bayer sued Barr or patent

    inringement. In settling these claims just beore trial in 1996, Bayer and Barr

    entered into a series o agreements designed to resolve both Barrs challenge to

    Bayers patent, and Bayers corresponding inringement suit. On one end, Barr

    agreed to delay its entry into the Cipro market until ater Bayers patent expired.Barr agreed not to manuacture its generic version o Cipro in the United

    States, to amend its Hatch-Waxman certiication to the FDA, airm the validity o

    Bayers patent, admit inringement, and thereby relinquish its 180-day exclusivity

    entitlement. In return, Bayer agreed to pay Barr $49.1 million up ront, and

    either supply Barr with limited quantities o Cipro or resale, or alternatively,

    make additional quarterly payments to Barr, bringing the total reverse payment

    to approximately $398 million. Bayer also agreed to allow Barr to sell a generic

    version o Cipro approximately six months beore the patent expired in 2003.

    Ater the settlement agreements, our other generic manuacturersRanbaxy,

    Mylan, Schein and Carlsbadiled certiications with the FDA challenging the

    validity o Bayers patent and seeking to manuacture their own generic versionso Cipro. Bayer sued all our companies or patent inringement and deeated

    Schein and Mylan on summary judgment. Bayer also won the Carlsbadcase

    in a bench trial, again airming the validity o its patent. A court dismissed the

    Ranbaxycase when Ranbaxy withdrew its certiication to the FDA.

    Resolution of One Dispute Leads to AnotherThe Antitrust Litigation

    In 2000 and 2001, direct and indirect purchasers o Cipro and advocacy

    groups iled several antitrust actions against Bayer and Barr, challenging the

    reverse payment settlements. Speciically, plaintis alleged that the settlement

    agreements constituted an illegal market allocation in violation o Sections 1 and

    2 o the Sherman Act as well as state antitrust laws, and that Bayer unlawully

    monopolized the ciproloxacin market by enorcing a patent obtained by raud

    on the PTO. In 2003, the United States District Court or the Eastern District o

    New York denied plaintis motion or partial summary judgment, inding that the

    settlement agreements were not per se illegal. In 2005, the district court granted

    summary judgment or deendants Bayer and Barr, holding that the settlement

    agreements could not be challenged under antitrust laws because they had no

    anticompetitive eect beyond the exclusionary zone o Bayers patent.

    The appellants alleged numerous errors on the part o the district court and

    appealed to the Federal Circuit. On appeal, appellants contended that the

    settlement agreements were per se illegal because they allowed Bayer to exclude

    a horizontal competitor, not by enorcing its patent rights in court, but by making

    reverse settlement payments to Barr o $398 million. The Federal Circuit panel

    held that, in reviewing the settlement agreements, the district court could not

    conidently predict the pernicious anticompetitive eects necessary to ind the

    agreements per se illegal. Consequently, the district court properly analyzed the

    agreements under the rule o reason.

    Absent Fraud or Sham Litigation, Analysis of Patent Validity is

    Inappropriate as Part of a Rule of Reason Analysis

    Appellants also argued that the district court erred by ailing to embrace the

    position o the FTC, the Solicitor General and the Court o Appeals or the Sixth

    Circuit, which appellants contended requires application o a modiied rule

    o reason analysis, taking into account the validity and strength o the patent

    in evaluating the legality o reverse payment

    settlements. The Federal Circuit again disagreed

    and took a position consistent with the Second and

    Eleventh Circuits, noting that pursuant to statute,

    a patent possesses a presumption o validity. The

    court conirmed that the proper approach in reverse

    payment cases is two-part: (1) The district court

    must determine i there is any evidence that the

    patent was procured by raud on the PTO, or that

    the inringement suit was a sham or objectively

    baseless; (2) i no such evidence exists, the only

    remaining question is whether the agreements

    restricted competition beyond the exclusionary zone o the patent. The FederalCircuit upheld the district courts indings that Bayer properly procured its patent

    and that Bayers inringement suit had merit. The district court also correctly

    noted that Bayer had prevailed in several subsequent inringement suits. As a

    result, the Federal Circuit agreed that there is no legal basis or restricting Bayers

    preerred means o enorcing its patent rights.

    Only Anticompetitive Effects Beyond the Exclusionary Zone of the Paten

    May be Redressed by Antitrust Law

    The Federal Circuit noted that a patent is an exception to the general rule against

    monopolies and that, by its very nature, a patent is anticompetitive. As a result,

    P. Gavin Eastgate

    Partner Pittsburgh

    Global Regulatory Enforcement

    Jerey M. Weimer

    Associate Pittsburgh

    Commercial Litigation Midwestern

    (continued on page 13

    http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=964http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=964http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=964http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=21977http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=21977http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=21977http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=21977http://www.reedsmith.com/our_people.cfm?widCall1=customWidgets.content_view_1&cit_id=964
  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    13/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 13

    the Federal Circuit agreed with the district court that beore antitrust law may be

    invoked to redress a claim, it must be determined whether the anticompetitive

    eects all beyond the exclusionary zone o the patent. The Federal Circuit airmed

    that the essence o the Bayer-Barr settlements was simply to exclude a genericmanuacturer rom proiting rom Bayers inventionan action well within

    Bayers rights as a patentee. However, had the Bayer-Barr settlements included,

    in addition to reverse payments, a provision by which Barr maintained its 180-day

    exclusivity period (barring entry o competitors) or an agreement that Barr would

    not manuacture even non-inringing versions o its generic drug, such agreements

    likely would have exceeded the exclusionary zone o the patent and triggered

    potential antitrust liability, as was the case in a recent Sixth Circuit decision. The

    Federal Circuit noted, however, that the Bayer-Barr settlements contained no such

    provisions. As a result, when considering the scope o the settlement agreements,

    and the well-established judicial policy avoring settlements, the Federal Circuit

    agreed that the settlements were not violative o the Sherman Act, even though

    they may have some adverse eects on competition.

    The Settlement Agreements Did Not Create a Bottleneck or Prevent

    Other Patent Challenges

    The Federal Circuit rejected appellants argument that the settlement agreements

    were anticompetitive because, in the pharmaceutical patent context o the Hatch-

    Waxman Act, a brand-name manuacturer can protect its monopoly or years

    simply by paying o the irst challenger. Appellants argued this is the case because

    the irst challenger is entitled to a 180-day period o exclusivity, which creates

    a bottleneck and reduces the incentive or any other generic manuacturers to

    undertake the time and expense o bringing subsequent challenges to the brand-

    name patent. In this case, the Federal Circuit a irmed the district courts reasoning

    that while the Hatch-Waxman Act may create burdens or generic manuacturers,

    it also oers signiicant beneitsnamely the ability to get approval or a genericversion o a patented drug without having to endure the rigorous FDA new drug

    application process, and also the ability to challenge the validity o a patent withou

    incurring the costs o market entry or the risks o damages rom inringement. The

    Federal Circuit ound these incentives clearly at work in this case, as evidenced by

    the act that our other generic manuacturers challenged Bayers patent aterthe

    Bayer-Barr settlements.

    In addition, the Federal Circuit ound no bottleneck eect because as part o the

    settlement agreements, Barr admitted inringement o Bayers patent and amended

    its certiication with the FDA, thereby relinquishing its rights to the 180-day exclusivity

    periodan issue that the Federal Circuit held was properly decided in 2003 by the

    district court in denying plaintis motion or partial summary judgment.

    Consult Counsel

    Pharmaceutical patent inringement litigants may ind reassurance in the Federal

    Circuits decision validating the Bayer-Barr reverse payment settlements, particularly

    because the decision joins recent and similar decisions o the Second and Eleventh

    Circuits. However, the legality o such settlement agreements is contingent upon the

    parties awareness o the need to limit the anticompetitive eects o their settlements

    to the exclusionary zone o the underlying patent. Pharmaceutical companies would

    be well-served to consult with experienced counsel to avoid running aoul o antitrust

    laws when structuring such reverse payment settlement agreements.

    reed smith at the podium

    Dec. 1, 2008: AC L rbl was held in Reed Smiths London oice. Larry Kill and Peter Roth, QC o Monckton Chambers, were the

    keynote speakers. The discussion ocused on comparing the environment or competition litigation in the UK and the United States. Please contact Larry Kill or

    more inormation.

    Dec. 2, 2008: The CEU group held its 17th Annual Competition Forum. Peter Freeman, Chairman o the UKs Competition Commission, addressed the topic,

    C plc i t - rl C C. Approximately 80 people attended the program, mostly clients. Please

    contact Lesley Davey or more inormation.

    Dec. 5, 2008: Fred Houwen and Richard Neville o Warner Brothers gave a presentation entitled rk B: C Cll rl

    b C L C, at a conerence held at the Competition Commission in London. Please contact Fred Houwen or more inormation.

    Dec. 4 - 5, 2008, Competition Law and Shipping Contracts, Marjorie Holmes conducted the ollowing seminar: Reviewing and Understanding InternationalShipping Contracts, London. Please contact Marjorie Holmes or more inormation.

    Marjorie Holmes will be involved in the ollowing speaking engagements: February 2009, C gl, BIMCO Competition Workshop, Athens;

    March 26, 2009, C Ll, Lloyds Maritime Academy EU Competition Law and the Shipping Industry, London. Please contact Marjorie Holmes

    or more inormation.

    and on paper

    Richard Waite published a C L u in the Nov. 18, 2008 edition o Solicitors Journal. Please contact Richard Waite or more inormation.

    Marjorie Holmes edited and co-authored Competition Law and Practice: A Review o Major Jurisdictions, published by Cameron May International Law & Policy. The

    book is now available or purchase. Please contact Marjorie Holmes or more inormation.

    fl Cc al rl r a vl r p p sl In re Ciprofocin Hrochorie

    antitrt lititionc 12

  • 8/4/2019 REGULATOR Magazine Global News OF RELE VANCE TO Ent ities & In dividuals aff ect ed by ant itr ust issues Wint

    14/16

    ANTITRUST REGULATOR WINTER 2009 14

    federaL distriCt Court aLLows joint Bidding suit to proCeed

    On Dec. 15, 2008, a ederal district court judge in Massachusetts denied the

    motion to dismiss iled by several private equity irms alleged to have engaged

    in joint-bidding or leveraged buyout (LBO) target companies. The deendants

    in this case, Dahl, et al. v. Bain Capital Partners,

    et al., proceeded on two grounds in their motionto dismiss the suit: (1) The antitrust laws did not

    apply to the allegedly illegal conduct because

    they are preempted by Securities and Exchange

    Commission (SEC) regulation; (2) The plaintis

    ailed to state a claim under 1 o the Sherman

    Act. Both were rejected by the court.

    The plaintis in this class action antitrust suit

    are shareholders in companies purchased by

    the deendants, which include The Carlyle

    Group, Goldman Sachs, Kohlberg Kravis Roberts

    and Co., and The Blackstone Group. While joint-bidding by private equity irms

    conducting an LBO is legal (such transactions are known as club deals), the

    plaintis allege that deendant private equity irms engaged in additional, illegal

    agreements to bid below air value or companies and to illegally allocate the LBO

    market. According to the plaintis, the conspiracy was eectuated by, among

    other things, the submission o sham bids and agreements not to bid.

    In evaluating the motion to dismiss, the court was unconvinced that SEC

    regulation o this area preempted application o antitrust laws. Under the

    standard set orth in Credit Suisse Securities (USA) LLC v. Billing, 127 S.Ct. 2383

    (2007), the securities laws and antitrust laws must be clearly incompatible

    in order or the doctrine o preemption to apply. Applying the test established

    in Billingto determine whether clear incompatibility existed with respect to

    the challenged conduct, the court ound that securities laws do not govern

    private equity LBOs, and, as such, the SEC is not empowered to regulate this

    conduct. Furthermore, rejecting an argument made by the deendants, the court

    determined that regulatory ilings related to an LBO do not constitute substantial

    regulation within the meaning o Billing. In sum, because the SEC has no

    substantive authority to regulate private equity LBOs, the securities laws do not

    preempt the antitrust laws.

    Next, the court considered whether the plaintis ailed to properly plead their

    claim under 1 o the Sherman Act. Applying the standard set orth in Bell Atlantic

    Corp. v. Twombly, 127 S.Ct. 1955 (2007), the court concluded that the plaintis

    had plausibly suggested an illegal agreement. The court was convinced largely

    because plaintis complaint included nine speciic transactions and because the

    allegations tie[d] theirms together by alleging an overlap in irms bidding

    in multiple transactions.

    Finding no grounds on which to dismiss the case, the court has ordered discovery

    regarding the transactions speciied in the complaint to proceed.

    Importantly, this is the second signiicant private equity joint-bidding case

    ruled on by a ederal court in the past year. In February, the U.S. District Court

    or the Western District o Washington dismissed an antitrust suit brought by

    shareholders o an acquired company against two private equity irms that

    initially bid separately or the target company beore one irm withdrew its bid.

    See Pennsylvania Avenue Funds v. Borey, 569 F.Supp.2d 1126 (W.D. Wash. 2008)

    Ater the remaining irms bid was acceptedat a price lower than the original

    joint bidthe withdrawing irm acquired hal o the successul bidders interestin the target company. Ultimately, the court concluded that the plaintis could not

    adequately allege that the deendants had market power and thus ailed to state

    an antitrust claim.

    The contrasting results in these cases are perhaps

    attributable to the diering levels o speciicity o

    the two claims. While Boreychallenged joint-bidding

    practices in a particular transaction involving only

    two private equity irms, Dahlis a broader attack

    on private equity club deals and alleges nine

    transactions as examples o the illicit conduct. These

    results might provide guidance to uture plaintis

    seeking to challenge joint-bidding practices, insoar

    as they demonstrate that when the court must

    accept actual allegations as true, it is beneicial

    to rame those actual allegations as broadly as possible. O course, it is also

    possible that these cases simply illustrate the divergent approaches to reviewing

    motions to dismiss under the standards set orth in Twombly.

    Private equity irms should take note o the challenged conduct in these two

    cases when deciding to engage in joint-bidding with other irms.

    William J. Sheridan

    Associate Pittsburgh

    Commercial Litigation Midwestern

    Natalie C. Moritz

    Partner Pittsburgh

    Commercial Litigation Midwestern


Recommended