+ All Categories
Home > Technology > VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

Date post: 06-Sep-2014
Category:
Upload: asia-pacific-intellectual-capital-centre-apicc
View: 390 times
Download: 2 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
Academic paper on YOZMA -- the support programme credited to kick-start Israel Venture Capital Industry
Popular Tags:
23
Paper to be presented at the Summer Conference 2009 on CBS - Copenhagen Business School Solbjerg Plads 3 DK2000 Frederiksberg DENMARK, June 17 - 19, 2009 VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE Gil Avnimelech UNC at Chapel Hill [email protected] Abstract: This paper deals with a policy instrument supporting the emergence of VC industries. It is based on the Israeli experience with the Yozma program, which triggered the creation of the VC industry. This program dealt with specific system failures of the entrepreneurship process the early stage equity gap and the lack of complementary assets and skills in entrepreneurial firms. VC emergence in Israel was a policy-enhanced process in the sense that a targeted government policy directed to this goal (Yozma Program, 1993-1998) triggered it. Accompanying the process of VC emergence was the transformation of Israel's high tech sector toward a startup-intensive ICT cluster. We suggest that the feasibility of building a dynamic and innovative cluster, which exploits the ICT revolution, may be depended on the emergence of a capable domestic VC industry. Therefore, understanding the specific characteristics of Yozma program and the process it triggered could generate significant policy implication related to the process of VC industries and high tech clusters development in other countries. Therefore, the paper present a full case study of Yozma program 15 years after its implementation. JEL - codes: C, E, -
Transcript
Page 1: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

Paper to be presented at the Summer Conference 2009

on

CBS - Copenhagen Business SchoolSolbjerg Plads 3

DK2000 FrederiksbergDENMARK, June 17 - 19, 2009

VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

Gil AvnimelechUNC at Chapel [email protected]

Abstract:This paper deals with a policy instrument supporting the emergence of VC industries. It is based on the Israeliexperience with the Yozma program, which triggered the creation of the VC industry. This program dealt withspecific system failures of the entrepreneurship process the early stage equity gap and the lack of complementaryassets and skills in entrepreneurial firms.VC emergence in Israel was a policy-enhanced process in the sense that a targeted government policy directedto this goal (Yozma Program, 1993-1998) triggered it. Accompanying the process of VC emergence was thetransformation of Israel's high tech sector toward a startup-intensive ICT cluster. We suggest that the feasibilityof building a dynamic and innovative cluster, which exploits the ICT revolution, may be depended on theemergence of a capable domestic VC industry. Therefore, understanding the specific characteristics of Yozmaprogram and the process it triggered could generate significant policy implication related to the process of VCindustries and high tech clusters development in other countries. Therefore, the paper present a full case studyof Yozma program 15 years after its implementation.

JEL - codes: C, E, -

Page 2: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

VC Policy: Yozma Program 15-Years perspective

1. Introduction

This paper deals with a policy instrument supporting the emergence of VC

industries. It is based on the Israeli experience with the Yozma program, which

triggered the creation of the VC industry. This program dealt with specific system

failures of the entrepreneurship process – the early stage equity gap and the lack of

complementary assets and skills in entrepreneurial firms.

Israel’s high tech cluster development was strongly related to the development of a

local VC industry (Avnimelech & Teubal 2004a, 2004b, 2004c). VC emergence in

Israel was a policy-enhanced process in the sense that a targeted government policy

directed to this goal (Yozma Program, 1993-1998) triggered it. Accompanying the

process of VC emergence was the transformation of Israel's high tech sector toward a

startup-intensive ICT cluster. We suggest that the feasibility of building a dynamic and

innovative cluster, which exploits the ICT revolution, may be depended on the

emergence of a capable domestic VC industry. Therefore, understanding the specific

characteristics of Yozma program and the process it triggered could generate significant

policy implication related to the process of VC industries and high tech clusters

development in other countries.

1.1 The Role of Venture Capital in Cluster Emergence

The identification of new forms of intermediation lies at the heart of the creation

of new industries. Gompers and Lerner (1999) have been very clear that VC (a new

‘supply agent’) mediates between capital and startups in ways that the traditional

banking system (old "supply agent") did not, thereby overcoming "market failures"

with startup and innovation financing. Thus, the VC industry has an important role in

creation of new industries and clusters. According to Florida and Kenney (1988), the

VC industry plays a central role in coordinating various high-tech agents: entrepreneurs

and managers; professional employees; specialized suppliers; investors and capital

markets; and product markets. Therefore, we can conceptualize the role the VC

industry as both providing direct value to startups through direct interaction with their

portfolio companies (Gompers & Lerner, 1999, 2001) and as providing indirect value to

the innovation process within the cluster.

Page 3: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

2. The Development of the Israeli ICT Cluster

Chapter 5 described the development of the Israeli ICT cluster in five phases. We

will briefly describe the second and the third phases of development.

At the Pre-Emergence (phase 2, 1986-1992) there were first signs of regional

high tech industrial concentration. A central feature of this phase is the appearance of

significant startup activity and the gradual acceptance of technological

entrepreneurship. Some startup financing took place. However, a VC industry did not

exist yet. A critical mass of startups accumulated towards the end of this phase and,

correspondingly, a measure of ‘demand’ for the VC services. As a result significant

startup and VC-related experimentation and learning took place.

Two major conditions for transition to the Pre-Emergence phase were: the

ongoing technological revolution that made the pool of technological opportunities

continuously renewable1, and the significant diffusion of R&D and innovation

capabilities throughout the Israeli business sector. This is necessary for the country to

transform a pool of technological opportunities into a stream of potential business

opportunities.

The Emergence process (phase 3, 1993-2000) presented rapid quantitative growth

of startup and VC activities and the eventual emergence both of the startup-intensive

ICT cluster and of the VC industry. Israel's VC industry was triggered by a government

targeted-program – the Yozma program. The rapid growth of the cluster was an

outcome of the VC industry emergence and of a few early successful startups (many of

them backed by VCs) that were the source of spin-off and imitation by many new

agents. This enhanced a critical mass that created cluster externalities. Emergence

began with a fluid sub-phase (1993-1995) followed by rapid growth (1996-1998) that

eventually led to the bubble (1999-2000).

During the fluid sub-phase significant experimentation and collective learning

took place both with respect to startup and VC strategies and with respect to their form

of organization. During the rapid growth sub-phase an accelerated entry of startups and

VC companies occurred. A domestic VC industry was created. It is then that the cluster

attained a size, which enabled it to sustain a large number of supporting services. This

induces entry of additional leading multinational companies and of additional domestic

and foreign VCs, rapid creation of startups and rapid growth in the IPOs and acquisition

1 Such conditions occurred in Israel at the mid-80s (the creation of the software industry and the PC industry, and the change in the business model in the semiconductor industry toward the fables model).

Page 4: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

activities. As long as external and internal conditions remain unchanged, the process of

creation of large numbers of startups continued and the cluster continue to grow.

3. VC Emergence

VC emergence involves two groups of conditions: first, those underpinning

demands for VC services; second, those underpinning rapid growths of VC supply. The

existence of an adequate demand for VC services in Israel depends on a prior

appearance of a critical mass of startups in the pre-emergence phase. The supply-side

pre-conditions for VC emergence include liberalization of capital markets, other

institutional changes, restructuring of defense industries, the appearance of the startup

business model, experimentation with VC-related activities since the late 1980s, and the

implementation of the Yozma program (1993-1998).

3.1 Triggers for VC Emergence

In the late 1980s a new phase in the globalization process began: foreign high tech

startups could more easily float in NASDAQ, provided the economy had adapted to the

new opportunities. Part of Israel’s adaptation involved new government programs,

which complemented the existing R&D support program. These included Targeted

programs supporting VC (Inbal and Yozma), and complementary programs raising the

demand for VC-services (e.g. the Technology Incubators’ Program, and the extension

of the regular R&D program).

The actual trigger was implementation of Yozma in 1993. This provided the

critical mass for the cumulative, self-reinforcing process of growth of VCs and startups.

Yozma funds raised 263M$ up to 1998 and significant amounts were invested. In

addition, significant imitation by other private VCs occurred during this period. This

triggered strong collective learning processes, which contributed to attain the critical

mass, which made this process effective and self-sustaining. This further stimulated

entry of new VC companies, and accelerated creation of second and third funds by

existing Yozma VC companies and other VC companies. The cumulative process was

also fueled by favorable changes in the external environment in particular the rise of the

NASDAQ Index, and deregulation of communications markets. Additional internal

factors were the Oslo peace agreements, the highly educated Russian immigration to

Israel, Israeli highly experienced returnees from the U.S. during the early 1990s, and

domestic regulatory changes favoring VC investment and entrepreneurship.

Page 5: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

ITP in Israel

The Israeli Government’s ITP towards the business sector began in 1969 with the

implementation of the industrial R&D support program. The new “R&D legislation” of

1984 further consolidated Israel's support of business sector R&D. This program was

the first of the set of programs comprising Israel’s Program Portfolio; and it was the

backbone of Israel’s innovation and technology strategy. This R&D support program

was widely regarded as having been a success in terms of stimulating R&D in the

business sector, in stimulating exports resulting from R&D, and in contributing to the

creation of a high tech sector during the 1980s (Justman & Zuscovitch 1999).

Moreover, the dynamic processes unleashed by its successful implementation led to the

other programs comprising Israel’s ITP of the 1990s (see Box C1).

Box C1: New ITP Programs in Israel during the 1990s 1) Inbal (1992-1998) - a Government owned Insurance company, which gave partial (70%) guarantees to traded VC funds. Four VC companies were established under Inbal regulations.

2) Yozma (1993-1998)—a 100M$ Government owned VC company, which invested in 10 private early-phase oriented VC Funds which operated in Israel (8M$ per fund).

3) Magnet Program (1992--)—a Horizontal Program supporting cooperative, generic R&D involving group of firms and at least one University (annual budget 40-60M$).

4) Technological Incubators’ Program (1992--)—a program supporting startups during the first three years of their operation. The incubators are privately managed (since 2001 they became also privately owned). Both they and the projects approved get financial support from the Government (annual total program budget 25-30M$).

Table C1: OCS Grants and VC Investments 1970-2008 (in M$) 1970 1980 1985 1990 1995 1997 2000 2005 2008

OCS Budget 3 39 107 136 346 397 440 263 349

VC Investments 0 0 0 ~20 ~250 436 3,092 1,337 2,076

Sources: OCS (2009) and IVC (2009).

4. VC Targeted Policies

New national priorities emerged with the beginnings of the massive immigration

from the former Soviet Union during the early 1990s. The government of Israel began

searching for means to employ the thousands of engineers that came to this country.

Simultaneously the military industries had laid-off hundreds of engineers; and there

were many attempts to create startup companies, which largely failed.

One of the main targets was enhancement of startup formation, survival, and

growth. Till the 1990s, the percentage of successful young companies was extremely

low and the accepted view was that this resulted from weak management abilities.

Experts in the field realized that despite massive government support for R&D there

Page 6: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

still was a clear 'market failure', which blocked the successful creation and development

of startup companies. The head of OCS at the time, Yigal Erlich, pondered about how

to make OCS support more effective. The basic problem was lack of capability to grow

after the product development phase. He thought that the missing link was marketing

and management skills; and that the way to get it was to foster VC activity. At the time,

there were only 2-3 VCs in Israel, and it was clear that the total capital available and

the scope of VC activity were inadequate for the task at hand.

4.1 Inbal

It is important to consider not only programs like Yozma, which were successful

but also precursor programs like Inbal, which, even though they failed to generate a VC

industry, indirectly promoted the successful program. The Inbal Program was the first

attempt at implementing a targeted ITP directed to the VC industry. It was launched in

1991, 1-2 years before the implementation of Yozma. Its central idea was to stimulate

VC funds by guaranteeing the downside of their investments. The mechanism used was

a Government insurance company ("Inbal") that provided a 70% guarantee to VC funds

traded in Israeli stock market (TASE). The program imposed certain restrictions on the

investments of the 'protected' funds. Four funds were established. They and the Inbal

program, as a whole was not a great success. Fund valuations in the stock market were

low and the funds encountered bureaucratic problems. In addition, publicly traded VCs

has greater difficulty in exploiting reputation earned from early exits to increase the

capital invested (in LP form of VC organization it would be easy to rapidly raise a

second fund); and they absence of incentives relevant to the upside. Eventually all of

Inbal funds attempted to leave the program, which they eventually succeeded in doing -

all the (former) Inbal Funds were merged into other investment/holding companies.

4.1.1 Lessons from Inbal failed VC program

Inbal supported publicly traded VCs with guarantees to the downside. There was

no mechanism for drawing professional VC agents into the program; it did not generate

VC investors and partners with adding value capabilities; and it was exposed to 'stock

market sicknesses' and short-term thinking. Other Israeli VC agents did not imitate this

form of VC organization. However, our interviews reveal that policymakers and

businessmen alike learned from Inbal's weak impact: the difficulty in publicly traded

VCs of having investors contribute to the operation of the fund; greater difficulty to

Page 7: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

rapidly exploits the reputation earned from early successful exits in order to raise new

capital, limits on decisions making flexibility and on management compensation; and

the absence of incentives for the “upside” (an important factor in attracting professional

VC partners and investors). We conclude that the indirect contribution of Inbal to the

eventual design (see Box C2 and C3) and implementation of a successful VC policy in

Israel was quite high (such as influencing Yozma’s selection of Limited Partnership as

the form of VC organization and the selection of the early stage investment focus).

4.2 Yozma Program2

There is wide consensus that one of the major factors triggering emergence of

Israeli VCs was Yozma. Four sets of factors seem to have been responsible for Yozma

to become an effective trigger of Israel's ICT Cluster: a) favorable background

conditions; b) policy and market forces’ experimentation during the pre-emergence

period; c) timing - the time overlap between Yozma implementation on the one hand

and the rising Nasdaq index and expanding market for ICT on the other; and d) the

successful design and implementation of the Yozma program.

Let us recall some of the background conditions, which were operating at the

time, that transformed Yozma into an effective trigger of Israel's ICT cluster: the

industrial R&D support Program; the restructuring of the military industries, the

massive highly educated immigration for the former Soviet Union, and new global

innovation opportunities opened by the ICT revolution. These, together with a cultural

shift where entrepreneurship were increasingly being considered prestigious in Israeli

society, generated a spurt of startup activity during the early 1990s. More specifically,

we argue that at the beginning of operation of Yozma, there was a clear demand for VC

services. The pool of startups included also some very high quality ones (such as RAD

Group, Checkpoint, Ornet, Galileo, and M-systems) who made a significant direct and

indirect contribution to emergence (see also Ellies at el., 2008). In addition, we should

not underestimate the specifics of the design and of the implementation of Yozma.

4.2.1 Yozma Design

The program began operating in late 1992 and the first fund was created in 1993.

The explicit objective was to create a solid base for a competitive VC industry with

2 Most of the material below was obtained from two interviews (01/1998 and 05/2000) with Yigal Erlich the CEO of Yozma and one of the most important architects of the Program. Additional material was obtained from joint work with him at the UFISE and ESTER research programs during the years 2001-2006.

Page 8: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

critical mass of capital and activity; to learn from foreign limited partners; and to

acquire a network of international contacts. It was based on a 100M$ Government

owned VC fund (with the same name) oriented to two functions: a) investment in ten

private VC funds ('Yozma Funds'-80M$); and b) direct investments in high tech

companies-20M$. The basic thrust was to promote the establishment of domestic LP

VC funds that invested in very young Israeli high tech startups with the support of

government and with the involvement of reputable foreign VC investors. Each ‘Yozma

Fund’ had to engage as LPs one such foreign institution together with a well-

established Israeli financial institution. However, the VC Company itself had to be a

completely new organization not own by any existing financial institution (this was

made to assure a competitive industry, which is not lacked-in to the old financial

system’s routines). When a fund fulfilled these conditions, the Government would

invest (through Yozma) 40% (up to 8M$) of the funds raised. Thus the $100M of

Government funds would draw at least $150M of private sector funds (domestic and

foreign). Each Yozma fund had a call option on Government shares, at cost (plus

interest) for a period of five years. Thus, Yozma did not simply provide supply, risk

sharing incentives to investors, but it also provided an upside incentive (the private

investors could leverage their profits through acquisition of the government shares).

The incentives to the 'upside' also stimulated entry of professional VC firms and

managers (when you have higher returns the government incentive becomes more

significant). The program also assured the realization of learning through the

compulsory participation of foreign financial institutions (most of them were well-

experienced foreign VC companies – See table C2).

Table C2: Yozma Funds – capital, foreign investors and portfolio

Name Est. Capital Foreign LP LP Orion Portfolio Exits

Eurofund 1994 $20M Daimler-Benz, DEG Germany 14 7 (50%)

Gemini 1993 $36M Advent USA 25 13 (52%)

Inventech 1993 $20M Van Leer Group Netherlands 33 16 (48%)

JVP 1993 $20M Oxton USA 12 10 (83%)

Medica 1995 $15M MVP USA 10 5 (50%)

Nitzanim 1994 $20M AVX, Kyocera Japan, Japan 13 7 (54%)

Polaris (Pitango) 1993 $20M CMS USA 19 13 (68%)

Star 1993 $20M TVM Siemmens Germany 27 15 (56%)

Vertex 1996 $39M Vertex Int., Singapore tech USA , Singapore 29 16 (55%)

Walden 1993 $33M Walden International USA 21 10 (48%)

Yozma 1993 $20M None IL Gov. 16 10 (63%)

Total $263M 217 122 (56%)

Page 9: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

Box C2: Critical Dimensions of Yozma Program Design Yozma Funds were Independent Israeli Limited Partnership VC Companies A focus on early stage investments in high tech startup companies

Target level of capital aimed at $250M (Government Support $100M)- an assumed Critical Mass

A multiplicity of privately-owned Israeli VC funds (10), each one managed by a local management

company and involving a reputable foreign VC company (and one domestic financial institution)

Government Participation in each Fund $8M (representing 40% of the capital raised)

Strong incentive to the “upside” – the possibility, within a 5-year period, of purchasing government’s share at cost (all funds except two made use of this option).

Planned ‘Privatization’ of Yozma Venture Fund and its Hybrid Funds: has taken place since 1998. These previous features assured that the Yozma program was a Catalytic Program.

Box C3: Factors explaining the differential Yozma-Inbal impact YOZMA Design INBAL Design The program was promoted by the OCS and structured as Fund of Funds (equity investments in the hybrid funds without intervention in the operation of the funds)

The program was promoted by the treasury and structured, as a government Insurance company (guarantees to the funds)

Single Objective: Creating a competitive domestic VC industry in Israel

Dual objective: Promoting the Israeli local stock exchange and promoting VC activity in Israel.

A targeted level of capital aimed at $250M (government support of $100M) � created a critical mass of capital

No targeted level of capital � did not lead to a critical mass of capital

A clear objective to create a competitive market – aiming at creating 10

No clear objective regarding the competition in the VC market � only 4 funds were created

LP form of VC organization - the ideal form of organization according to U.S. experience

Publicly traded form of VC- hard to leverage current success to fundraising and bureaucracy

Investments focused on early stages – Focus Investments also in later stages and non-high tech

Strong incentive to collective learning and to 'learning from others' (through requirement of having a reputable foreign financial institution)

No incentive to collective learning, to learning from others or to VC cooperation. Did not attract any global financial nor strategic investor into Israel

The Government owned fund started to invest immediately - encouraged VCs to invest fast.

No mechanism to encourage VC firms to invest immediately

Managers’ abilities were also an important criterion for selection of 'Yozma Funds'

Administrative and financial criteria figured prominently in selection of Inbal VCs

Limited number of Yozma funds- created an incentive to join fast, and a clear way out of the program � pre-planed privatization.

No explicit limit to the number & timing of funds that could enjoy the INBAL benefit; and a complex way out of the program.

Leveraged incentives to the upside - a 5-year option to buy the government’s share at cost � Attracting professional VC teams.

Downside guarantees, which favor entry of non-professional VC firms

YOZMA - Impact INBAL - Impact Created a critical mass of VC investment Critical mass of VC activity was not achieved

Most 'Yozma fund' are among the 20 leading VCs in Israel

Non of the INBAL funds are among the 20 leading VCs in Israel

Very high private VC performance Low private VC performance

Follow up funds & strong growth of capital Very few secondary issues

Yozma Funds were models for the design of many other VC companies in Israel

Very few other public traded VC were established in Israel

5. Yozma Impact

In total the Yozma Program created ten private VC funds (and the Yozma fund

itself that was eventually privatized in 1998). Six funds were founded in 1993: Gemini,

Star, Pitango, Walden, Invantech, and JVP; two in 1994: Nitzanim and Eurofund; one

Page 10: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

in 1995: Medica; and one in 1996: Vertex. The total capital raised by Yozma funds was

$263 million (100M$ out of it government capital) and they invested in 164 startup

companies (the aggregate number of portfolio companies in table C2 is 217, however

there were syndications between various Yozma funds in a few investments).

Eventually, these funds had an Exit (IPO or M&A) rate of 56%, which is much above

the “regular VC Exit rate”3 (in table C3 we can see that the Exit rate in the entire Israeli

VC industry during 1993-2000 is 27%; and the exit rate of the entire population of

Israeli startup is 14% compared with exit rate of the Yozma funds funds in the same

period was 48%). These very high rates of return of the Yozma funds4 suggest both the

very supportive environment that existed when the program was implemented and the

successful design and application of the program.

Table C3: Yozma Initial Funds and Follow-up Funds 1993-2000

Name Funds Total Capital Portfolio Active Exits Closed

Eurofund 2 $72M 25 7 (28%) 11 (44%) 7 (28%)

Gemini 3 $346M 83 15 (18%) 45 (54%) 23 (28%)

Inventech** 2 $40M 33 3 (9%) 17 (52%) 13 (39%)

JVP 3 $278M 43 6 (14%) 25 (58%) 12 (28%)

Medica 2 $70M 23 6 (26%) 11 (48%) 6 (26%)

Nitzanim (Infinity, Concord)

3 $191M 62 12 (19%) 31 (50%) 19 (31%)

Polaris (Pitango) 5 $655M 109 41 (38%) 49 (45%) 19 (17%)

Star 14 $987M 113 40 (35%) 55 (48%) 19 (17%)

Vertex 3 $246M 73 22 (30%) 33 (45%) 18 (25%)

Walden 3 $184M 47 14 (30%) 17 (36%) 16 (34%)

Yozma 3 $100M 45 8 (18%) 22 (49%) 15 (33%)

Average 3.9 $288M 59.6 15.8 (27%) 28.7 (48%) 15.2 (25%)

Entire IL VC-backed 104 $5,919M 779 209 (27%) 212 (27%) 358 (46%)

Entire IL SU 2,672 890 (33%) 357 (14%) 1,425 (53%)

Table C4 visualizes the emergence of the Israeli VC industry during 1993-2000,

in which period the private-VC fundraising average annual growth rate was 85%. At

the same time, the other PE agents experienced moderate growth rates. The time trends

of VC/PE fundraising growth rates within sub-phases during 1991-2000 suggest that

while capital market trends (mostly NASDAQ) influences both VC and PE, Yozma

program, which triggered VC emergence, crowd out PE activity for a while.

The big jump in Israeli VC activity occurred in 1993 when Yozma and Private

3 The VC literature (such as Gompars & Lerner, 1999) usually suggests an average exit rate of 20%-40%. 4 Out of the 10 Yozma funds 6 had over 100% IRR.

Page 11: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

VCs raised 162M$ compared to 27M$ the year before5. Thereafter, there was a rapid

growth of the Israeli VC industry both in terms of capital raised and in terms of number

of funds. Total capital raised per year by Israeli VCs grew rapidly during the 1990s.

During the second half of the 1990’s, the Israeli VC industry became a significant

industry. It was then that the first foreign VC companies began to invest directly in

Israeli startups. Later on, a few of them (e.g. Benchmark, Sequoia, Intel Capital and

others) established Israeli offices. To sum up, the Yozma funds initiated a dynamic,

cumulative process involving: learning by doing and learning from foreigners. It was a

collective learning process, which also contributed to exploitation of economies of

scale and specialization.

Table C4: Capital raised by PE organization in Israel 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Private VCs 40 49 27 33 82 93 287 595 653 1,160 2,712

Yozma VC 0 0 0 149 40 15 30 19 0 0 0

Inbal VC 0 0 54 22 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

Other PE 5 9 79 168 262 25 620 134 33 258 66

Total PE 45 58 160 372 384 133 937 777 686 1,418 2,778

These observations sustain our presumption that Yozma’s 250M$ raised in 1993-

1996 (the remaining 13M$ were raised after 1996 only from the private investors)

significantly contributed to create a critical mass which triggered a cumulative process

of growth in the VC industry during the second half of the 1990s, and that the Inbal

Program did not directly generate a cumulative process of growth (although it did have

some important indirect learning effects). This and the insights received during our

interviews are the basis for our inference that Yozma triggered VC emergence.

Another indication of Yozma Funds’ success in triggering growth of the industry

is their expansion, which took the form of Yozma ‘follow up’ funds (see table C5).

Most Yozma funds were followed by three or more additional funds managed by an

expanding core of managers. The total sums managed by this group was 3.2B$ at the

end of 2000 - 54% of the total capital raised by the entire VC industry during the years

1993-2000 (the total sums managed by this group is currently 5.9B$ - 48% of the total

capital raised by the entire VC industry). Table C6, shows that 4-5 former Yozma funds

are among the top-10 VC companies in Israel during the years 1996-2008.

5 Note that during 1992 publicly traded VCs and PE funds played a dominant role in total capital raised—133M$

compared to 27M$ capital raised by LP VCs. This in part reflects the Inbal incentives on Public VC; but capital were also raised by the other two categories of financial institutions-PE Funds, and Investment Companies.

Page 12: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

Table C5 Yozma Initial Funds and Follow-up Funds 1993-2008

Name Funds T. Capital Portfolio Active Exits Closed

Eurofund 2 $72M 25 6 (24%) 12 (48%) 7 (28%)

Gemini 5 $686M 105 38 (36%) 41 (39%) 26 (25%)

Inventech** 2** $40M 33 3 (9%) 17 (52%) 13 (39%)

JVP 4 $783M 85 34 (44%) 33 (38%) 18 (20%)

Medica 3 $195M 33 14 (43%) 13 (39%) 6 (18%)

Nitzanim (Infinity, Concord)

3+5 $896M 132 44 (33%) 52 (40%) 36 (27%)

Polaris (Pitango) 5 $1,342M 140 62 (44%) 57 (41%) 21 (15%)

Star 14 $987M 113 36 (32%) 55 (49%) 20 (19%)

Vertex 6 $640M 94 42 (45%) 34 (36%) 18 (22%)

Walden 3 $184M 47 12 (26%) 19 (40%) 16 (34%)

Yozma 3 $150M 55 14 (25%) 24 (44%) 17 (31%)

Average 5 $543M 78 28 (36%) 31 (40%) 19 (24%)

Entire IL VC-backed 171 $12,243M 1,193 520 (44%) 244 (20%) 429 (36%)

Entire IL SU 6,107 3272 (53%) 477 (8%) 2358 (39%)

Table C6: Top-10 VC Management Companies in Israel 1996-2008

Top10 - 1996 Capital Top10 - 2000 Capital Top10 - 2004 Capital Top10 - 2008 Capital

Star 172 Star 650 Pitango 800 Pitango 630

Evergreen 112 Pitango 625 Star 630 Infinity 450

Etgar 80 Genesis 362 JVP 588 Carmel 407

SFK 64 Evergreen 361 Evergreen 478 Gemini 340

Denali 50 Gemini 310 Gemini 400 Evergreen 335

Vertex 47 Giza 271 Giza 361 Giza 270

Giza 46 ISP 262 Genesis 262 Benchmark 250

Gemini 36 Concord 260 Vertex 260 Neurone 200

Walden 33 JVP 258 Benchmark 240 Sequoia 200

Star 26 EVP 205 ISP 200 Vertex 175

5 Yozma Funds 5 Yozma Funds 5 Yozma Funds 4 Yozma Funds

* The Capital row present the total capital (M$) raised by the management company in the last 5 years. 5.1 Indirect Impact

The VC ‘emergence state’ materialized during the second sub-phase of the cluster

emergence (1996-1998). This phase was characterized by accelerated growth of VC

activity; by entry of large numbers of players both on the supply side (VCs) and on the

demand side (startups); and by ‘selection/reproduction’ of critical features of the

industry. Table C8 shows figures on VC fundraising and investment, on startup

creation, VC-backed startups and exits (IPOs and tradesales). The number of new

startups created in the three years prior to the implementation of Yozma is

approximately 200 companies. Significant increases during 1993-1995 (approximately

440 companies) and sharp increases year by year after that (up to 2000). This reflects

the impact of implementation of the Yozma Program and the increased availability of

VC. While the direct impact of Yozma is reflected in 164 backed companies, the

indirect impact also includes the acceleration of startup formation in the cluster.

Page 13: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

Another indirect impact is the rapid entry of non-Yozma related funds, something

triggered by the handsome profits obtained by Yozma Funds (see table C7). In 1993,

eight new VC management companies were created (six of them were Yozma funds)

and in 1997 a new wave of VC management companies creation began as a result of the

early successful exits of Yozma funds. Thus, while during 1990-1992 VC-backed

startups represented only 10% of startup creation, during 1993-1996, VC-backed

startups represented 55% of startup creation.

Table C7: The Development of the Israeli VC Industry

Year New MC Closed MC* T. Active MC New Funds Closed Funds T. Active Funds

1990 1 0 2 1 0 2

1991 2 0 4 2 0 4

1992 3 0 7 4 0 8

1993 8 0 15 11 0 19

1994 3 0 18 4 0 23

1995 3 0 21 5 0 28

1996 4 0 25 9 0 37

1997 7 0 32 14 1 50

1998 7 0 39 15 1 64

1999 9 0 48 19 2 81

2000 14 0 62 27 4 104

2001 7 4 65 18 13 109

2002 3 8 60 6 7 108

2003 1 0 61 1 5 104

2004 2 0 63 5 8 101

2005 1 3 61 7 15 93

2006 3 9 55 10 15 88

2007 6 11 50 12 18 82

2008 2 6 46 8 22 68

* We define a closed management company either one that was actually closed or one that did not raised a new fund at least 7 years. An active fund is a fund raised at the last 7 years (the investment period of a fund).

VC Exits :IPOs and M&As

Only small numbers of Israeli companies undertook an IPO in NASDAQ (or in

other markets) till the late 80s. Today Israeli (or Israeli-related) companies traded in the

U.S. are the third largest group behind only the U.S. and Canada. Moreover, many

Israeli (or Israeli-related) high tech companies are also traded European stock market

such as the London-based AIM stock market.

The number of Israeli high tech companies IPOs jumped in 1993 and then again

in 1996 with the first exits of firms backed by Yozma funds. This led to the indirect

impact of Yozma program, which was expressed by acceleration of startups formation

and exits (IPOs and M&As) and other networking and reputation effects. The picture,

which emerges, is one of increasing maturity of Israel’s ICT cluster and VC industry

(due to learning), a process that is accompanied by the increase in the NASDAQ

Page 14: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

index6. The number of IPOs increased considerably during 1995-2000 compared to

1990-1994, as well as the share of VC-backed issues. Moreover, Yozma funds exits had

a significant effect during the years 1998-2001 with over 50% of the Israeli IPOs in

Nasdaq (see table C8). The picture which emerges is one of increasing maturity of

Israel’s ICT cluster on the one hand (due to learning and other cluster effects such as

the creation of the VC industry itself), a process which accompanied the increase in the

Nasdaq index (which by itself would also induce an increase in IPOs). There is no

doubt that within this process Yozma funds had a significant role. We cannot avoid

noting also that prior to 1993, there was already a non-insignificant number of IPOs (12

during 1991-2 alone) all of whom excepting one being non VC-backed issues. This in

part reflects the fact that very good; high quality startup began populating the scene in

the early 1990s.

Table C8: VC invested and high tech startups foundation, IPOs* and M&As**

Year VC Raised

(VC Invested)

IL Startups Foundation

(VC Backed)

IL IPOs in The U.S.

(VC back)

IL IPOs in Europe

(VC back)

IL IPOs in Israel

(VC back)

Significant IL M&As

(VC back)

1990 5 (NA) 53 (4) 1 (1) 0 (0) 1 (0) 1 (0)

1991 49 (NA) 51 (5) 4 (1) 0 (0) 7 (0) 0 (0)

1992 81 (NA) 94 (12) 9 (1) 0 (0) 7 (0) 1 (0)

1993 204 (NA) 124 (73) 11 (4) 0 (0) 9 (0) 1 (0)

1994 122 (NA) 140 (85) 8 (4) 1 (0) 7 (0) 2 (2)

1995 108 (NA) 175 (87) 9 (4) 2 (0) 3 (0) 7 (3)

1996 317 (293) 231 (117) 16 (10) 3 (1) 0 (0) 11 (3)

1997 643 (440) 263 (119) 12 (3) 0 (0) 2 (1) 7 (3)

1998 653 (589) 332 (152) 7 (4) 6 (1) 2 (0) 16 (6)

1999 1,160 (1,011) 587 (208) 12 (9) 6 (1) 4 (0) 15 (9)

2000 2,712 (3,233) 665 (372) 19 (12) 13 (3) 10 (3) 32 (11)

2001 1,319 (1,985) 371 (159) 2 (1) 0 (0) 0 (0) 8 (6)

2002 497 (1,138) 355 (76) 1 (0) 0 (0) 0 (0) 5 (3)

2003 6 (1,011) 410 (113) 0 (0) 0 (0) 0 (0) 9 (8)

2004 589 (1,465) 580 (141) 6 (2) 1 (0) 3 (2) 15 (7)

2005 1,644 (1,337) 511 (117) 4 (2) 11 (1) 4 (3) 16 (9)

2006 903 (1,620) 521 (121) 2 (2) 4 (2) 10 (3) 28 (23)

2007 1,096 (1,759) 596 (119) 6 (4) 1 (0) 20 (5) 26 (16)

2008 967 (2,076) 580 (177) 0 (0) 0 (0) 0 (0) 21 (15) Source: IVC (2008), OCS (2007), VentureOne (1997) and authors calculations. * Only of high tech startups; ** not including fire sales (at least $20M or at least $5M with annual ROI above 25%).

The picture about the emerging ICT cluster will not be complete without

considering the phenomenon of M&A—one of the main mechanisms of exit for VC

investors and for startup entrepreneurs. There is no clear ‘market place’ where M&A

transactions (which are ‘private’ capital market transactions) are negotiated and

implemented. It follows that the conditions for an emerging cluster to facilitate M&A

activity on a continuous basis differ from those required to provide access to public

6 Both factors were at work here - NASDAQ index growth, it did not induce other countries’ firms to float more

Page 15: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

capital markets. Clear reputation effects are required in order to trigger MNEs to

undertake a costly search for technological opportunities in a specific cluster. The

Israeli case suggests that a critical mass of IPOs might play a crucial role in creating the

conditions for cluster emergence and that M&A only come in increasingly large

numbers later on, probably starting in 1994 (became significant in only since 1996 –

see table C7). The link could be as follows: public capital market links early in the

game generate conditions for the emergence (given a suitable Government program like

Yozma) of a distinctive VC industry. The new industry develops a capability for M&A

and in fact, many VCs become oriented towards the M&A form of exiting rather than

to the IPO strategy7 (see table C8). With the onset of cluster maturity and with

enhanced cluster reputation, MNEs start coming and this creates a very strong wave of

new M&A. Table C7 show that during 1996-7 the number of significant VC backed

M&A was still 20% lower than IPO numbers for the period; but that the former

exceeded the latter by about the same percentage during 1998-2000.

Table C9: Yozma Funds Exits by Years

Year IPOs in the U.S.

(% of Total) IPOs in Europe

(% of Total) IPOs in Israel (% of Total)

Acquired firms (% of Total)

Total Successful Exits

1993 0 0 0 1 (100%) 1 (4%)

1994 0 0 1 (14%) 1 (50%) 2 (16%)

1995 1 (11%) 0 0 3 (43%) 4 (21%)

1996 5 (31%) 1 (33%) 0 3 (27%) 8 (29%)

1997 2 (17%) 0 0 3 (43%) 6 (26%)

1998 4 (57%) 0 0 3 (19%) 7 (21%)

1999 6 (50%) 3 (50%) 0 6 (40%) 15 (34%)

2000 8 (42%) 3 (23%) 1 (10%) 10 (31%) 22 (30%)

2001 1 (50%) 0 0 3 (38%) 4 (36%)

2002 0 0 0 5 (100%) 5 (63%)

2003 0 0 0 1 (11%) 1 (11%)

2004 1 (17%) 0 1 (33%) 2 (13%) 4 (14%)

2005 1 (25%) 0 0 2 (13%) 3 (5%)

2006 1 (50%) 0 0 6 (21%) 7 (16%)

2007 0 0 0 2 (8%) 2 (4%)

2008 0 0 0 6 (30%) 6 (29%)

Total 29 (25%) 7 (15%) 3 (4%) 51 (26%) 97* Source: IVC (2009), OCS (2008), VentureOne (1997) and authors calculations. * Excluding Firesales and an exit backed by few Yozma funds is count only once – this explains the gap with table C2.

6. Cumulativeness and VC Emergence

VC emergence in Israel is closely related to the onset of a cumulative process

where VC activity and profits led, at least till the end of the decade to more VC activity

and profits. Cumulativeness involves four main sub-processes, which interact; and a

7 The ‘simple’ types of M&A seem to be easier to learn during early phase of the VC industry development compared to ‘preparing a company for IPO’. The latter requires paying attention to management, financial and marketing capabilities since, for floating, a company needs a selling product (although it need not be profitable). In contrast, most M&A are based on the technology and technological excellence of SU and of its staff.

Page 16: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

fifth (VC-startup Co-evolution), which integrates some of these and comprises a central

part of the overall process. The four component sub-processes are: Entry, Collective

Learning, Exploitation of Economies of Scale, and Reputation and Networks Effects.

Strong collective learning took place during five years of Yozma operation (1993-

1998) and beyond, triggered by Yozma, who contributed to attain the critical mass of

activity for an effective and self-sustaining process. Learning pertained to screening

deal flow, due diligence, investing in startups, monitoring startups, providing value

added, and in the exiting. Collective learning of VCs together with some very good

‘early exits’ (through demonstration, networking and reputation effects) stimulated

entry of new VC companies, and accelerated creation of second/third funds by the

existing Yozma management companies. Yozma, by creating a quantum jump in VC

activity accelerated individual and collective learning8 by VC and startups, and

interactive VC-startup learning. Moreover the learning process involved a significant

component of learning from foreign agents in particular from the foreign ‘limited’

partners of Yozma Funds9.

The enhanced VC and high tech activity enabled a better Exploitation of

Economies of Scale in the domestic generation of non-traded (or partially non-traded)

inputs to high tech e.g. accountants, lawyers, investment bankers, consultants, providers

of knowledge inputs, and independent suppliers of production inputs. This factor,

together with the existence of networks of personal links, presumably contributed to

reductions in Transactions Costs and through this, facilitated deal making in the VC

industry. Through time after 1993 Israel’s high tech cluster became better integrated

and increasingly capable of providing effective services to new startups, both through

VC and through a gamma of other input and service suppliers. The cumulative process

was also fueled by favorable changes in the External and internal Environment (which

were mentioned in section 3).

6.1 VC-startup Co-evolution

VC-startup co-evolution is a central axes in the cumulative process leading to VC

emergence and beyond. The interaction between the two types of agents of the business

sector is both direct and indirect. Direct interactions parallel supply-demand effects and

8 Yozma Funds were connected in a network by the fact of a common OCS board member. 9 Yozma was instrumental in bringing to Israel important financial institutions (see table C2). These companies became a source of know-how, networking and reputation for the young VC industry. They presumably were instrumental in triggering new elementary dynamic processes, which directly and indirectly contributed to the overall high tech momentum of the period.

Page 17: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

user-producer links in young markets e.g. VC and startup entry; and interactive

learning. Indirect links also occur through the wider cluster via one or more sub-

processes of cumulativeness10.

In Israel the starting point of VC-startup co-evolution can be found in the early

1980s when new opportunities in Software induced the foundation of a group of

startups and emergence of the startup business models. These were linked to new forms

of finance including the financing of startups by investment companies; and the first

formal VC—Atena (created in 1985). A more rapid process of startups creation began

in the early 1990s fueled by the ongoing ICT revolution, by the globalization of capital

markets for technology companies, and by the growth of the NASDAQ index. By 1993

more than 300 startups were operating in the country and seeking for capital. Thus,

prior to Yozma, an excess demand for VC services arose. However, this excess demand

and the other background conditions probably could not by themselves trigger VC

emergence without the help of a program like Yozma. System failures prevented the

un-aided emergence of a domestic VC industry. These included lack of market-tested

VC reputation and a critical mass of VC activities that would enable partnering with

foreign VCs; and coordination problems between startups, VC firms and risk capital

(see Gilson, 2003). Yozma program assured a highly dynamic response to the excess

demand for VC services generated during the pre-emergence11. This led to very high

profits of early VC entrance and high expectations regarding future VC performances,

which stimulated VC entry and expansion.

The new VC supply was directed to existing startups and to a new wave of

startups, which expressed the entrepreneurial response to the increase in VC activity.

The number of startup creation vs. VC-backed startups for the years 1989-1992

reflected the excess demand for VC financing (only 10% of startups were financed by

10 There were three steps in the VC-SU co-evolution: Pre-Emergence: the numbers of startups operating and the small share of those, which were VC-backed, suggests the existence of ‘unsatisfied demand for VC services’; Emergence: The rapid policy response (through Yozma) to such a deficit led to a quantum jump in VC raised and, due to the availability of a pool of skilled potential VC entrepreneurs, to a corresponding increase in VC activity. This in turn led to a ‘temporary excess supply of VC services’. As a result we observe not only an increased share of startups that were VC-backed but also significant increases in gross additions to startups during 1995-1996. These were either a reaction to the ‘excess supply of VC services’ or to the expectation that new startup foundations would easily find new VC sources of finance if required. Increasingly Synchronous Growth: Starting in 1996 startup demand for VC services and VC ‘supply’ become increasingly synchronous i.e. rapid mutual adjustment. During the rest of the decade, the share of startup which are VC-backed increases. 11 The rapid VC supply response would seem to contradict the assertion that there is supply inelasticity in the VC industry (Gompers & Lerner 1999). However, we argue that the real bottleneck to expansion is not risk capital but experienced VC managers. This inelasticity was not present in Israel during VC emergence, due to the accumulation of VC-related experience in the pre-emergence phase, and due to returnee of experience Israelis from Silicon Valley and elsewhere. Thus, Yozma's addition to capital translated immediately into sharp increases in VC activity-although a strong process of individual and collective learning was still required for the VC industry to become efficient.

Page 18: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

VC) prior to Yozma, the figures for the years 1993-1994 reflect the impact of

implementation of the Yozma Program and the increased availability of VC (60% of

startups were financed by VCs), and the figure for the years 1995-2000 (49% of the

startups were financed by VCs) and the years 2001-2006 (33% of the startups were

financed by VCs) represents the entry of new type of financing agents.

Box C4: Sub-processes operating during VC emergence 1. Yozma Funds and other VCs founded prior to 1996 created follow-up funds.

2. Entry of non-Yozma VCs during 1996-1998 and follow-up funds of these organizations.

3. Successful Exits of these early entrants enhanced their reputation and led to more VC fundraising both by the successful VCs themselves and by other new Israeli VCs. During the process, foreign investment banks set up offices in Israel. This further facilitates the creation and growth of high tech startups.

4. Since 1996 strategic partners e.g. IBM, Cisco, Intel, etc. became limited partners of Israeli VCs. This in turn led to further reputation and networking of portfolio companies, which strengthened their activity and performance. It also led to enhance direct investments by such partners and to enhance reputation and networking benefiting the high tech cluster as a whole. Collective learning of the VC industry and interactive learning involving Israeli VCs, Israeli startups, and foreign strategic partners.

5. “Cluster Effects” from the higher scale of activity which enhanced the local production of inputs and services for the high tech sector (e.g. accounting, consulting, legal, patents offices, etc)

6. Increase in the M&A activities of multinational companies in Israel. Leading both to a new significant exit channel for Israeli startups and to an increase in R&D activity of multinational companies in Israel

7. Significant direct foreign VC activity in Israel, starting in 1997 (represent 50-60% of the VC investments in Israel). Some foreign VCs established domestic offices is Israel, starting in 1999

8. A comprehensive cluster - the structural hole in the innovation process in Israel’s ICT cluster was closed and the VC industry became one of its central coordinating agents.

Cumulative self-reinforcing process of growth

The infusion of VC supply by Yozma program triggered a cumulative process

with positive feedback in which more profitable VC activity at present spurred even

more profitable VC activity in the future12. At the center of this process was VC-startup

co-evolution. The sub-processes mentioned in Box C4 have both direct and indirect

effects on startup and VC development. For example, the ‘cluster effects’ mentioned in

Box C4 would enhance the efficiency of startups and thereby also indirectly affect the

growth of VC activity. Similarly, the reputation resulting from successful exits would

both enhance foreign resources invested in Israeli VCs and the possibility that startups

would gain access to the global product and capital markets. Overall, each new sub-

12 Because of these cumulative effects and the growth of NASDAQ index during the relevant period – Government VC equity did not ‘crowd out’ private VC investments. In fact the opposite was the case: by triggering a cumulative process of growth, it led to the creation of new business opportunities, which the private VC sector exploited.

Page 19: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

process increased the set already in operation thereby reinforcing the cumulativeness of

VC emergence.

Interactive learning and creation of strong user-producer links

In young markets users learn from producers and vice versa - a phenomenon

called interactive learning (Lundvall 1988). The reason why interactive learning is

relevant for the dynamics of VC emergence is that it involved creation of a new

industry/market. Interactive learning represents one component in the process of

creation of user-producer networks—a widespread phenomenon in clusters and also

very relevant for VC. In the VC industry, these networks enable VCs to have access to

deal flow, to a wide variety of ‘added value services’, and to global capital markets.

The high impact of these networks is also related to other events and processes such as:

startup entrepreneurs becoming VC partners; VC strategic investors becoming direct

investors in startups; VCs sponsoring “home entrepreneurs” or founding startups, and

VC partners becoming entrepreneurs.

Class A market forces

Yozma’s success also derived from the strength of the market forces operating in

the area prior to implementation of the program or who entered the industry shortly

after its implementation. This factor seemed to have contributed to spark a self-

sustained cumulative process of VC emergence. The high quality and strong

capabilities of ‘early entrants’ to the VC industry were ascertained through a

microeconomic analysis of 40 leading VC companies (Avnimelech & Teubal, 2004b).

We found that those companies indeed possessed strong capabilities, were eventually

highly profitable and had a significant indirect impact on the subsequent growth and

development both of VC and of the high tech cluster as a whole. Prevalence of such

conditions explains both the rapid process of growth during VC emergence and the high

impact of the targeted policy implemented for this purpose.

Class A Market Forces and Industry Emergence

We argue that under the uncertain and harsh global selection environment,

existence of sophisticated and even profitable domestic market forces operating prior to

industry emergence may actually enhance, rather than diminish, both the justification

for implementing targeted policies and the probability that such policies will lead to

Page 20: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

industry emergence. Our empirical work has demonstrated this link between the Class

A market conditions that prevailed in the Israeli VC industry in the early 1990s and the

strength of the subsequent policy-enhanced VC emergence process. Under Class A

market conditions and with the enhancement of targeted policy we should anticipate a

faster emergence process with a stronger economic impact. While, the unaided

operation of (even) Class A market forces, might generate a cumulative process which

is ‘too little and too late’. This is due to our observation that in order to efficiently

translate private firm success into positive externalities and cluster emergence, a certain

critical mass should be reached.

We argue that there are a number of reasons for believing that despite the

presence of Class A market conditions during the early 1990s, Yozma was critical for

Israel’s successful VC emergence13. The previous chapters suggest that in addition to

Class A market conditions, VC emergence required: (1) accessing reputable foreign

partners14; (2) a complex coordination process linking the reputable foreign agents with

highly skilled domestic VC entrants; (3) assuring that a significant part of the domestic

VC agents adopt an early stage investment strategy, the LP form of organization and of

other aspects of VC activities (this would enable the exploitation of increasing returns

to scale in VC activities); (4) assuring that a cumulative process with positive feedback

would be initiated and completed within a short period of time; and (5)

‘country/government signaling’ (the substitute for lack of VC market-tested reputation).

In our opinion most of the above were system failures that unaided market forces

by themselves (even if they were Class A) could not overcome. This is even more so

once we recognize the relatively narrow window of opportunity for high tech

transformation (i.e. both VC emergence and a significant economic impact could not

have taken place prior to the next downturn in the global VC industry without the

trigger and acceleration induced by Yozma). It meant that even if unaided market

forces could have led to VC emergence by themselves it would have been a much

slower process (with the risk of not attaining sustainability) and presumably one with a

much lower economic impact. There is also sufficient evidence to support our view that

the design and mode of implementation of Yozma succeeded in overcoming each one

of the specific system failures causes mentioned above (see chapter 6).

13 The failure of the Inbal Program, which began operating only one year before Yozma strengthens our argument that Yozma was critical for the emergence of Israel's VC industry. The requirements below and the associated system failures should be dated at 1993. For additional details of Yozma and Inbal Programs see chapter 6. 14 This was difficult without Yozma due to the lack of market-tested reputation at the level of the VC industry.

Page 21: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

The upshot is that within a certain range, an increase in the sophistication of local

VC capabilities could enhance the justification and the expected impact from

implementing a targeted policy15. However, beyond a certain level of capabilities,

policy would not be justified since a high impact VC emergence would occur without

government intervention. Similarly, when conditions are not Class A, policy may not be

justified since even the best policy design might not trigger VC emergence. The role of

government could be different in such Class B conditions (early entrants to an infant

VC industry have low private profitability levels and/or low Pp-Ps correlation). Rather

than targeting the industry itself the role of government under these conditions could be

directed to stimulate favorable pre-emergence conditions such as fostering high tech

startups, supporting business experiments, or ascertaining other ‘functional

requirements’. The upshot is that targeting should be withheld, at least for the time

being, or should focus on other industries where Class A conditions prevail.

We argue that Class A market forces should be considered as pre-condition for

the implementation of targeted policy due to the fact that a necessary condition for the

first VC funds created to trigger entry of subsequent funds is that the former be highly

profitable. Such a performance would generate what we termed market-tested

reputation, which would considerably facilitate the raising of additional capital and the

participation of a wider set of foreign partners. In Israel, the strong early profitability

was due to very good exits (during 96-97) from early investments (during 1993-1994);

and this led immediately to venture capitalists worldwide to consider investing in

Israeli VCs and startups, hence the onset of cumulativeness16. The Israeli experience

shows that, once several Yozma funds had high returns, the individual reputation

effects spilled-over to the VC industry and high tech cluster as a whole; and that this

led not only to expansion of existing VCs but also to entry of new VCs. By the same

token, early funds and early investments, which are not highly profitable, risk

truncating the subsequent process of industry emergence17. This pattern of “early

success leads to initial reputation that leads to additional capital and added value

networks” may lead to a self-sustained cumulative process of growth. In addition, the

early reputation enhanced new high potential entrepreneurs to establish startups, which

15 This contradicts both the theory of infant industries support where the prior existence of strong market forces would seem to pre-empt the need for policy (Stoneman, 1987; Bell at el., 1984) and the underpinnings of a simple ‘market failure’ justification for policy according to the neoclassical perspective (Arrow, 1962). 16 This effect has been analyzed by Gompers (1996) who focuses on how early ‘exit’ successes of young, unknown VCs enhanced the flow of capital to follow up funds of these organizations. 17 A weak Reputation effect could lock–in VC into a low-level 'equilibrium' trap.

Page 22: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

increase the potential deal flow and therefore lead to additional increase in potential

future success.

7. Imitation of Yozma Program in Other Countries

Since 1999, as the tremendous success of the Israeli VC industry and the related

Yozma program became famous around the world many countries tried to adopt the

model of Yozma. Some countries had a formal process of learning from the Yozam

program (meetings with policy makers in Israel and with Israeli researchers that

analyzed the Yozma experience) these include: New Zealand, Latvia, and Russia. Other

countries started some formal or informal processes of learning from the Yozam

program, but did not implement a similar program eventually. It is still too early to

assess the success of these policies. However, the significant imitation of the program is

by itself a signal for it high reputation.

8. Conclusions

We now summarize and complete our argument concerning the role of Yozma.

First, Class A Market Forces in the VC area were necessary but probably not sufficient

for industry emergence - additional capabilities and other elements were also required;

Second, these would not automatically be generated to the extent and the speed

required without Yozma; Third, either Yozma caused emergence, or it only accelerated

emergence, our assessment is that Yozma was a successful policy with a significant

impact. Due to the narrow window of opportunity even if Yozma only accelerated

emergence its economic value was significant i.e. unaided market forces would have

created a smaller VC sector and a slower growth of high tech cluster as a whole18.

It is important to mention that the Israeli experience cannot be easily repeated in

other countries. However there still may be valuable lessons, which could be learned

from that experience. Also a dynamic interpretation of that experience which also

integrates others’ experiences could contribute, through an evolutionary process, to a

broader framework for analyzing VC policies in a variety of countries/contexts.

The analysis of Yozma also suggests that in some cases of clear system failure

in the market a targeted temporal government intervention could have significant value.

18 David (1985, 2001) has emphasized that effective policies implemented under conditions of strong ‘path

dependence’ enjoy only a narrow window of opportunity a statement which fits our view of the impact of Yozma.

Page 23: VC POLICY: YOZMA PROGRAM 15-YEARS PERSPECTIVE

Bibliography

Avnimelech, G. and M. Teubal 2004a. Venture Capital – Start Up Co-evolution and the Emergence and Development of Israel’s New High Tech Cluster—Part 1: Macroeconomic & Industry Analysis. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 13(1), pp. 33-60.

Avnimelech, G. and M. Teubal 2004b. Strength of Market Forces and the Successful Emergence of Israel’s Venture Capital Industry: Insights from a Policy-led Case of Structural Change. Revue Economique, 55(8), pp. 1265-1300.

Avnimelech, G. and M. Teubal, 2004c. Venture Capital Policy in Israel: A Comparative Analysis and Lessons for Other Countries, in Sunil, M. and Bartzokas, A. (ed.) Financial System, Corporate Investment in Innovation and Venture Capital, Edward Elger

Avnimelech, G. and M. Teubal 2005. Evolutionary Innovation and High Tech Policies: What can we learn from the Israel's targeting of Venture Capital?. Science, Technology and Economy Program (STE) Working Paper Series WP-25-2005, Neaman Institute, Technion-Israel Institute of Technology.

Black, B and R. Gilson 1998. Venture Capital and the Structure of Capital Markets: Banks versus Stock Markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 47, pp. 243-277.

Bresnahan, T. and A. Gambardella 2004. Building High Tech Clusters: Silicon Valley and Beyond. Cambridge University Press.

CBS 2009. Central Bureau of Statistics, Israel, Available at <http:// www.cbs.gov.il>

Gilson, R 2003. Engineering a Venture Capital Market: Lessons from the American Experience. Stanford Law Review, 55(4), April, pp. 1067-1104

Gompers P. and J. Lerner 2001. The Venture Capital Revolution. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(2), pp. 145-168

Gompers, P. 1994. The Rise and Fall of Venture Capital. Business and Economic History 23(2), pp. 1-26

Gompers, P. and J. Lerner 1999. The Venture Capital Cycle. The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, London, England.

Lerner, J. 2002. When Bureaucrats Meet Entrepreneurs: the Design of Effective ‘Public Venture Capital’ Programs. The Economic Journal, 112, February, pp. F73-F84.

Lundvall, B. 1992. National Systems of Innovation: Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning. Pinter Publishers, London

Metcalfe, S. 1994. Evolutionary Economics and Technology Policy. The Economic Journal, 104(425), pp. 931-944.

Metcalfe, S. 1995. Technology Systems and technology Policy in an Evolutionary Framework. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19(1), pp. 25-46.

Metcalfe, S. 1996. The economics foundations of technology policy: equilibrium and evolutionary perspective. Ch. 11 in Stoneman, P. (ed) Handbook of economics of innovation and technological change, Blackwell: Oxford UK and Cambridge USA.

Nelson, R. 1993. National Systems of Innovation. Oxford University Press

Nelson, R. 1994. The Co-evolution of Technology, Industrial Structure and Supporting Institutions. Industrial and Corporate Change, 3(1), pp. 47-63.

OECD 1996. Venture Capital and Innovation. OCDE/GD(96)168, Paris

OECD 1997. Government Venture Capital for Technology Based Firms. OCDE/GD(97)201, Paris

OECD 2000. The Internationalization of Venture Capital Activity in OECD Countries: Implications for Measurement and Policy. DSTI/DOC(2000), December

OECD 2002. A Comparison of Venture Capital Policies and Programs in Selected OECD Countries. DSTI/DOC(2002), STI Working Paper 2002, Industry Issues.

OECD 2003. Venture Capital Policy Reviews. DSTI/DOC(2003), STI Working Paper 2003, Industry Issues.


Recommended