+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva*eco_hkn/j.1467-9361.2011.00645.x.pdf · Hiranya K. Nath and...

Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva*eco_hkn/j.1467-9361.2011.00645.x.pdf · Hiranya K. Nath and...

Date post: 18-Oct-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
17
Remittances and Relative PricesHiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva* Abstract Using Mexican data, this article analyzes the impact of the workers’ remittances on the cross-section distribution of prices as well as on the evolution of individual relative prices over time for 272 consumer items. The results suggest that there are important differences in the responses of relative prices to remit- tances according to various categories of these items. While the relative prices of a number of nontradable service items such as housing consistently rise, the relative prices of several durable items such as furniture tend to fall in response to the remittance shock. Furthermore, remittances explain substantial variation in prices for a large number of consumer durables and services at various time horizons. The relative price responses are more volatile over time for most food items and less volatile for nonfood and service items reflecting different degrees of price flexibility. 1. Introduction The economic impact of immigration on the migrant-sending countries has been the focus of much discussion in the recent literature. One of the most well-known con- sequences of out-migration is the monetary sums sent by migrants to their families and friends back home. Usually the amount of the individual transfers is not large. However, the total amount of these flows can reach an enormous dimension. Current recorded workers’ remittance inflows into Latin America have surpassed the inflows of foreign direct investment and official development assistance. The money that the migrants send home has become an important source of income for receiving families. If we treat remittances as a source of household income, other things being equal, an increase in remittances shifts the receiving household’s budget constraint outward by the amount of the transfer and therefore has a positive impact on household consumption. However, the potential increase in consumption is not likely to be equal across the spectrum of all goods and services. Previous microeconomic studies have presented mixed evidence about the uses of remittances. While some studies argue that families receiving remittances from abroad typically spend the money on daily needs such as food and clothing (Orozco, 2003), others argue that the remit- tance receiving households tend to spend more on investment goods like education, health, and housing, and less on food than their non-remittance receiving counter- parts (Adams and Cuecuecha, 2010; Taylor and Mora, 2006). Overall, these potential changes in demand for various consumption items may have an impact on the dis- tribution of relative prices. In this article, we study the impact of remittances on the cross-section distribution of consumer prices in Mexico, the largest recipient of remittances in Latin America. The *Vargas-Silva: Centre on Migration, Policy and Society, University of Oxford, 58 Banbury Road, Oxford, OX2 6QS, UK. Tel: +44-1865-274711; Fax: +44-1865-274718; Email: [email protected]. Nath: Sam Houston State University, Huntsville,TX 77341-2118, USA.Tel: +1-936-294-4760; Fax: +1-936-294- 3488. Review of Development Economics, 16(1), 45–61, 2012 DOI:10.1111/j.1467-9361.2011.00645.x © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd Author's copy
Transcript
  • Remittances and Relative Pricesrode_645 45..61

    Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva*

    AbstractUsing Mexican data, this article analyzes the impact of the workers’ remittances on the cross-sectiondistribution of prices as well as on the evolution of individual relative prices over time for 272 consumeritems. The results suggest that there are important differences in the responses of relative prices to remit-tances according to various categories of these items. While the relative prices of a number of nontradableservice items such as housing consistently rise, the relative prices of several durable items such as furnituretend to fall in response to the remittance shock. Furthermore, remittances explain substantial variation inprices for a large number of consumer durables and services at various time horizons. The relative priceresponses are more volatile over time for most food items and less volatile for nonfood and service itemsreflecting different degrees of price flexibility.

    1. Introduction

    The economic impact of immigration on the migrant-sending countries has been thefocus of much discussion in the recent literature. One of the most well-known con-sequences of out-migration is the monetary sums sent by migrants to their familiesand friends back home. Usually the amount of the individual transfers is not large.However, the total amount of these flows can reach an enormous dimension. Currentrecorded workers’ remittance inflows into Latin America have surpassed the inflowsof foreign direct investment and official development assistance. The money thatthe migrants send home has become an important source of income for receivingfamilies.

    If we treat remittances as a source of household income, other things being equal,an increase in remittances shifts the receiving household’s budget constraint outwardby the amount of the transfer and therefore has a positive impact on householdconsumption. However, the potential increase in consumption is not likely to beequal across the spectrum of all goods and services. Previous microeconomic studieshave presented mixed evidence about the uses of remittances. While some studiesargue that families receiving remittances from abroad typically spend the money ondaily needs such as food and clothing (Orozco, 2003), others argue that the remit-tance receiving households tend to spend more on investment goods like education,health, and housing, and less on food than their non-remittance receiving counter-parts (Adams and Cuecuecha, 2010; Taylor and Mora, 2006). Overall, these potentialchanges in demand for various consumption items may have an impact on the dis-tribution of relative prices.

    In this article, we study the impact of remittances on the cross-section distribution ofconsumer prices in Mexico, the largest recipient of remittances in Latin America. The

    * Vargas-Silva: Centre on Migration, Policy and Society, University of Oxford, 58 Banbury Road, Oxford,OX2 6QS, UK. Tel: +44-1865-274711; Fax: +44-1865-274718; Email: [email protected]: Sam Houston State University, Huntsville,TX 77341-2118, USA.Tel: +1-936-294-4760; Fax: +1-936-294-3488.

    Review of Development Economics, 16(1), 45–61, 2012DOI:10.1111/j.1467-9361.2011.00645.x

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • study of the impact of remittances on the relative prices of the receiving country isimportant because relative prices play a pivotal role in decision making by millions ofeconomic agents about consumption and production in the economy. Excessive vari-ability in relative prices leads to an inefficient allocation of resources across differentsectors of the economy and involves substantial welfare cost to the society. Thus,studying the effects of remittances on relative prices is important for understandingtheir macroeconomic consequences.

    Our results also contribute to the understanding of the widely documentedpositive relation between inflation and standard deviation of relative price changes,particularly for the case of developing countries. Furthermore, information on theimpact of remittances on relative prices can be useful for the formulation of appro-priate fiscal and monetary policy in countries with large remittance inflows such asMexico.

    In this study, we seek answers to the following questions about the impact of remit-tances in the receiving countries. Do remittances have any impact on the cross-sectiondistribution of prices? In particular, what are the effects of remittances on variousmoments of the price distribution? Which products or services relative prices are mostaffected by remittances? Is it possible to discern identifiable patterns in responses ofrelative prices to remittances according to various categories of consumer items such asdurable and non-durable goods, and services? To the best of our knowledge, our paperis the first study that fully analyzes the impact of remittances on the relative prices ofthe receiving country.

    2. Relevant Literature and Theoretical Background

    Remittances have the potential to impact a large number of variables in the recipientcountry. Therefore, the literature that tries to assess the macroeconomic impact ofremittances is varied in its scope and at times controversial in its conclusions.1 Broadly,remittances may have both beneficial as well as detrimental effects. While effects likeaugmentation of the capital stock through financing investment are conducive togrowth, other impacts such as a decrease in labor supply, may have adverse con-sequences for macroeconomic performances.

    From the microeconomic perspective, some studies (especially earlier studies) con-clude that remittance transfers are spent mostly on food. For example, Orozco (2003)showed that up to three quarters of the remittance transfers are spent on food inMexico. However, some other recent studies suggest otherwise. Adams andCuecuecha (2010), using data for Guatemala, found that the remittance receivinghouseholds spend more on education and housing, and less on food than do otherhouseholds. Similarly, Taylor and Mora (2006), in a study using household level datafrom Mexico, concluded that the propensity to invest appears to be considerablylarger for households with migrants. Zarate-Hoyos (2004) showed that the Mexicanremittance receiving households devote a larger proportion of current expendituresto investment and savings and have lower income elasticities for current consumptionand for durable goods.

    Do these microeconomic impacts have any implications at the macroeconomic level?At the macroeconomic level, remittances may impact a series of variables includingprices and the exchange rate. Amuedo-Dorantes and Pozo (2004), using data for 13Latin American and Caribbean countries, found that remittances cause appreciation ofthe real exchange rate. Vargas-Silva (2009) provided further evidence of real exchange

    46 Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • rate appreciation for the specific case of Mexico. The impact of remittances on prices,however, has remained largely unexplored.

    Our paper complements the previous literature on the macroeconomic impactof remittances in the recipient country by providing, for the first time, a detailedanalysis of the impact of remittances on relative prices. By studying the impact ofremittances on relative prices of various consumption items we not only improve ourunderstanding of the household behavior as regards to the potential uses of remit-tances but also can learn a great deal about the macroeconomic consequences ofremittances.

    This line of research is also important in the context of the existing literatureon the relation between inflation and the distribution of relative price changes. Itis widely documented that there is a positive relation between inflation and thedispersion of relative price changes. However, the theoretical exposition has notbeen conclusive in regards to the causal mechanism that generates the observed rela-tionships. According to one theory propounded to explain this relationship, bothinflation and relative price variability are generated by some exogenous factor.Remittances may fit very well as that exogenous factor explaining the relationbetween inflation and various moments of relative price distribution for severaldeveloping countries.

    This literature also indicates that there may be distinct patterns in responses ofthe relative prices to aggregate factors according to some identifiable commoncharacteristics. For example, Golob and Bishop (1997) reported that there are import-ant differences in the behavior of prices of durables, non-durables and services.Nath (2004) further suggested that intermediate and investment goods may responddifferently than do consumption goods to changes in aggregate factors. These studies,however, do not provide a good explanation as to why these differences exist. Aswe have argued above, remittances may have differential effects on items withgenerally identifiable characteristics such as durable goods, non-durable goods, andservices.

    Some Intuition on the Effects of Remittances on Relative Prices

    A recapitulation of our discussion and the findings of the existing microeconomicstudies suggest that remittances, by changing household demand for various items, willhave an impact on their prices. That the remittance income elasticity of demand variesacross consumption items is an important finding of the literature and provides theintuitive basis for the expected results of our investigation. It is, therefore, conceivablethat remittances may cause disproportionate changes in prices of various consumptionitems and that will have implications for relative prices.

    If as Orozco (2003) suggested remittances are mainly spent on food, then after anincrease in remittances we may see an increase in the price of food items relative toother items. However, if remittance money is mostly spent on services such as educa-tion, health, and housing then we may observe an increase in the price of these servicesrelative to other items. This should be especially the case if, as Adams and Cuecuecha(2010) argued, remittance receiving households also decrease their spending on foodcompared to other households. Similarly, Zarate-Hoyos (2004) argued that remittancereceiving households have lower income elasticities for consumption of durable goods.If this holds true, then we can expect remittances shocks to decrease the relative priceof durable goods.

    REMITTANCES AND RELATIVE PRICES 47

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • This intuition about changes in relative prices is further reinforced by the fact thatremittance transfers are often targeted towards a specific household consumption. Forexample, some studies (e.g. Amuedo-Dorantes et al., 2007) suggested that remittancesare targeted towards healthcare expenditures. This type of targeted transfers willchange the consumption patterns of the remittance receiving households and, in aggre-gate, may have implications for relative prices.

    The above discussion is based on the implicit assumption that prices are fully flex-ible, but as it is a well known, most prices are not fully flexible. Thus, even ifremittances increase demand for various consumption items proportionately, theremay be disproportionate changes in prices with implications for relative prices.Hence, although it is intuitively clear that remittances will cause changes in relativeprices, it is not clear a priori how they will affect relative prices of individual items.Therefore, we now turn to an empirical investigation of the effects of remittances onprices in Mexico.

    3. Methodology and Data

    Methodology

    As it is standard in most macroeconomic studies of this type, we use a vector auto-regressive (VAR) model. We estimate a seven variable system that includes industrialproduction (IP), remittance inflows (REM), the overall consumer price index (CPI)(P), CPI of individual consumption item (PICI), the interest rate (I), M2 measureof money (M), and the exchange rate (X). All variables, but the interest rate, areused in natural logarithms.2 Since the data are of monthly frequency, we include12 lags of each variable as well as a constant in each equation of the VAR. In orderto compute impulse response functions and variance decompositions, we use conven-tional Cholesky decomposition to obtain orthogonal residuals. We use the followingordering of the variables in the model: IP, REM, P, PICI, I, M, and X. In this case,we assume that output is not contemporaneously affected by shocks to the othervariables, while the exchange rate is contemporaneously affected by shocks to allthe other variables. We further assume that shocks to remittances have contempor-aneous effects on individual prices, while shocks to prices affect remittances with alag.3

    We estimate the VAR model recursively including one individual consumer itemprice at a time. Thus, for each of the 272 individual prices, we estimate an equationrelating that price series with the macroeconomic variables in the VAR.That is, for eachprice index we estimate an equation of the following form:

    p A B L p D L Xit i i it i t it= + ( ) + ( ) + ε , (1)

    where pit is the log of price index of good i, Ai is the constant term, Xt is the vector ofmacroeconomic variables, and Bi and Di are lag polynomials.

    It is very important to recognize that because we include the general price level(measured by overall CPI) in the VAR model, the impulse responses represent neteffects of the remittance shock on individual prices. That is, these responses are to beinterpreted as effects of remittances on individual prices over and above their effects onthe general price level. Thus, the price of an individual item can be thought of as a“relative price”, relative to the overall price level.

    This methodology has been used by several other studies on relative prices. Forexample, Balke and Wynne (2007) and Lastrapes (2006) used VARs to estimate the

    48 Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • impact of shocks to variables like money supply, interest rates and productivity onrelative prices using data for the USA. Both papers include commodity prices andoverall CPI in the VARs in order to see the impact of these shocks on relative prices.As with the current study, Balke and Wynne (2007) used short-run restrictions andinclude the commodity prices one at a time, while Lastrapes (2006) preferred long-runrestrictions to identify the shocks.

    The inclusion of standard macro variables such as output, money supply, interest rate,and exchange rate is primarily motivated by a desire to control for the effects of thesevariables on individual markets through well known channels.As we mentioned above,aggregate factors such as output, money supply and interest rates have been shown onprevious studies to have an important impact on relative prices (Lastrapes, 2006; Nath,2004). Moreover, the exchange rate with its possible impact on the prices of tradableand nontradable goods also has important implications for relative prices (Betts andKehoe, 2008).

    In this structure of the model, for each individual price series we assume no feedbackto or from other individual price series.4 We estimate impulse responses of all individualprices for one through 24 months to a shock to remittances and generate the cross-section distributions at various time horizons after the shock. We also calculate variousmoments of these cross-section distributions at different time horizons. Finally, weestimate variance decompositions of individual prices to identify items for which vari-ations in prices are explained by remittances.

    Data

    We use monthly CPI data for 272 consumption items for the period 1996:01–2007:06.Alist of these individual price series is included in the Appendix (Table A1). The baseyear for the price series is June 2002. Seasonal adjustments have been made to theprices using the Census X-11 method. The choice of the sample period is dictated bytwo considerations. First, although data on remittances are available before 1996, theyare more reliable only for recent years. Second, we want to avoid the years of theMexican financial crisis, particularly 1994 and its immediate aftermath.

    In addition to disaggregate prices, we also obtain data on overall CPI; industrialproduction that represents output; monetary aggregate, M2; short-term interest rate;and the nominal exchange rate that is defined as Mexican pesos per US dollar. Notethat although we would like to include gross domestic product as a measure of output,the data are not available at the monthly frequency. The interest rate is the Mexicangovernment’s three-month bond rate (CETES interest rate). Finally, we use totalfamily remittances as a measure of Mexico’s inward remittances. All the data areobtained from Mexico’s Central Bank.

    A first glance at the data Figure 1 plots the smoothed cross-section distribution of thesample averages (i.e. averaged over the sample period) of the 272 price change seriesalong with a theoretical normal distribution with the same mean and variance as thecross-section distribution of price changes. The price changes are the first log differ-ences of seasonally adjusted price series.The sample average price change for each itemis positive with an unweighted mean of 0.009225 for the cross-section distribution of272 price changes. Note that although a mean of 0.009225 looks small, if one convertsit into percentage annual rate, it equals 11.07% (= 0.009225 ¥ 12 ¥ 100). A comparisonwith the normal distribution reveals that the actual distribution is positively skewedand leptokurtic.

    REMITTANCES AND RELATIVE PRICES 49

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • To shed light on the nature of the relation between remittances and prices, wecalculate correlation coefficients between remittance growth and price changes foreach of 272 items over the sample period. Figure 2 plots the cross-section distributionof the correlation coefficients, along with a theoretical normal distribution with thesame mean and variance as the empirical distribution. The distribution has a positivemean and is slightly negatively skewed indicating that a relatively larger number ofprice changes have positive correlation with remittance growth.

    In Figure 3 we plot various moments of the cross-section distribution of pricechanges along with remittance growth for the entire sample period. The first,the second, and the third order moments have positive relation with remittancegrowth while kurtosis has negative correlation. The skewness and remittancegrowth appear to have the strongest correlation. Although these figures capture theevolution of the cross-section distribution of price changes over the sample period, the

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    -.004 .000 .004 .008 .012 .016 .020

    ActualNormal

    Den

    sity

    Figure 1. Cross-section Distribution of Sample Averages of Individual Price Changes

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    -.3 -.2 -.1 .0 .1 .2 .3

    ActualNormal

    Den

    sity

    Figure 2. Cross-section Distribution of Average Correlations Between Price Changesand Remittance Growth

    50 Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • -.4-.2.0.2.4

    -.02

    .00

    .02

    .04

    .06

    .08

    9798

    9900

    0102

    0304

    0506

    07

    rem

    itta

    nce

    grow

    thav

    erag

    e pr

    ice

    chan

    geremittance growth

    average price change

    Mon

    ths:

    199

    5:02

    - 20

    07:0

    6C

    orr

    = 0

    .039

    -.4-.2.0.2.4

    .01

    .02

    .03

    .04

    .05

    .06

    .07

    95

    96

    95

    9695

    96

    95

    9697

    9899

    0001

    0203

    0405

    0607

    rem

    itta

    nce

    grow

    thst

    d de

    v. o

    f pri

    ce c

    hang

    es

    remittance growth

    std dev. of price changes

    Mon

    ths:

    199

    5:02

    - 20

    07:0

    6C

    orr

    = 0

    .002

    -.4-.2.0.2.4

    -15

    -10

    -50510

    9798

    9900

    0102

    0304

    0506

    07

    rem

    itta

    nce

    grow

    thsk

    ewne

    ss o

    f pri

    ce c

    hang

    es

    remittance growth

    skewness of price changes

    Mon

    ths:

    199

    5:02

    - 20

    07:0

    6C

    orr

    = 0

    .091

    -.4-.2.0.2.4

    04080120

    160

    9798

    9900

    0102

    0304

    0506

    07

    rem

    itta

    nce

    grow

    thku

    rtos

    is o

    f pri

    ce c

    hang

    es

    remittance growth

    kurtosis of price changes

    Mon

    ths:

    199

    5:02

    - 20

    07:0

    6C

    orr

    = -0

    .039

    Fig

    ure

    3.T

    ime

    Seri

    esof

    Sele

    cted

    Mom

    ents

    ofth

    eC

    ross

    -sec

    tion

    Dis

    trib

    utio

    nof

    Pri

    ceC

    hang

    esan

    dR

    emitt

    ance

    Gro

    wth

    REMITTANCES AND RELATIVE PRICES 51

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • contemporaneous correlations between remittance growth and the respectivemoments reported at the bottom of each graph do not reveal much about the dynamicrelation between remittances and cross-section distribution of price changes.Therefore,we examine the dynamic relation between remittances and relative prices, controllingfor a standard set of macroeconomic variables.

    4. Results

    Remittances and the Distribution of Relative Price Responses

    In this subsection and the next, we present the results based on impulse responses ofrelative prices to a one standard deviation shock to remittances, generated from theestimation of the VAR model discussed above. Remember that these responses are tobe interpreted as effects of remittances on individual prices over and above their effectson the general price level. This interpretation has two important implications. First, anegative response does not necessarily imply that the price decreases in response to aremittance shock. It may simply be that the increase in that particular price is lowerthan the overall price rise. Second, the response may be small in magnitude but to takefull stock of the absolute price response we need to combine the responses of thegeneral price level and the individual price. The following results are important to theextent that they change relative prices which, as we have discussed above, are crucialfor consumption and production decisions of the millions of economic agents in theeconomy.

    Figure 4 plots the fractions of negative and positive relative price responses to aremittance shock at various horizons. Until the ninth month, the proportion of negativerelative price responses is not only higher than that of positive relative price responsesbut also the difference rises. After the horizon of 9 months, however, these two pro-portions converge. Past the 21st month, the proportion of positive relative priceresponses exceeds the proportion of negative relative price responses. It seems that inthe short run, innovations to remittances have a negative impact on a larger number of

    .2

    .3

    .4

    .5

    .6

    .7

    .8

    2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24

    negativepositive

    months

    frac

    tion

    s

    Figure 4. Fractions of Negative and Positive Price Responses at Various Horizons

    52 Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • relative prices. A remittance shock has positive effects on a larger number of relativeprices only in the longer horizon.

    Figure 5 provides yet another look at the evolution of the distribution of relativeprice responses to a remittance shock. Figure 5 plots the mean, and the 5 and 95percentile of the cross-section distribution of price responses over the horizons from 1to 24 months. As we can see, the mean response becomes positive after eighteenmonths. Note that the lower 5 percentile decreases steadily until the eighth month,increases sharply between months 9 and 13 and increases very slowly after the 14thmonth. The 95 percentile increases until the 14th month and then becomes somewhatvolatile.

    In Figure 6, we present the cross-section distribution of relative price responses athorizons of 1, 6, 12, and 24 months, along with normal distributions with the same meansand variances as the empirical distributions. Although the mean of contemporaneousprice responses (i.e. at a horizon of one month) to a remittance shock is positive it isinfinitesimally small. Then the mean responses are negative until the time horizon ofnineteen months when it turned positive. For example, the annualized percentage mean(unweighted) price response at a horizon of one month is 0.03. At an horizon of 6months, it is -1.06%, at 12 months it is -0.59%, and at a horizon of 24 months it is0.29%.

    The dispersion of price responses seems to increase from horizon one to horizon six.The distribution seems to be positively skewed at a horizon of 1 month while it seemsto have a longer tail to the left at a horizon of 6 months. At horizons of 12 and 24months, the distribution is almost symmetric with some fluctuations in between.Although the distribution is leptokurtic at all horizons, the kurtosis decreases overtime.These changes in the distribution of price responses indicate that relative prices ofvarious goods and services change at different horizons as a result of changes inremittances.

    In Figure 7, we plot higher order moments along with the mean of impulseresponses for horizons of 1–24 months. As discussed above, there is a substantialliterature that indicates that positive relations between mean and higher order

    -.008

    -.006

    -.004

    -.002

    .000

    .002

    .004

    .006

    .008

    .010

    2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24

    mean responses5 percentile95 percentile

    months

    resp

    onse

    s

    Figure 5. Mean, 5 Percentile and 95 Percentile of Price Responses to a Remittance Shockat Various Horizons

    REMITTANCES AND RELATIVE PRICES 53

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • moments are robust empirical results. Although remittances do not seem to generatean empirically plausible relation between mean and standard deviation of relativeprice changes, they may have significant explanatory power for the relation betweenmean and skewness. In this case (mean and skewness), the estimated correlationcoefficient is 0.60.

    Remittances and Individual Relative Price Responses

    While the previous discussion provides useful details about the impact of remittanceson the cross-section distribution of relative prices, it is also important to look at theresponse of individual relative prices to the remittance shock over time. For spaceconsiderations we do not include the responses of all 272 consumer prices to theremittance shock. However, a few words regarding the responses of representativegoods and services prices are in order.

    Two food items, beef steak and fresh pasteurized milk, with relatively higherweights among food items in the consumption basket (1.14 and 1.86 respectively)differ in their responses to the remittance shock.5 For beef steak, a delicacy, as aresult of the remittance shock, demand seems to increase steadily raising relativeprice over time. The price of fresh pasteurized milk, a necessity, meanders aroundzero indicating that the price change is similar to the change in the general pricelevel. As we will see below, a large percentage of variation in relative prices of

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    600

    700

    -.03 -.02 -.01 .00 .01 .02 .03

    Den

    sity

    horizon = 1

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    -.04 -.02 .00 .02 .04

    Den

    sity

    horizon = 6

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    -.03 -.02 -.01 .00 .01 .02 .03

    Den

    sity

    horizon = 12

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    -.03 -.02 -.01 .00 .01 .02 .03

    actualnormal

    Den

    sity

    horizon =24

    Figure 6. Cross-section Cumulative Distribution of Price Responses to a RemittanceShock

    54 Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • -.001

    6

    -.001

    2

    -.000

    8

    -.000

    4

    .000

    0

    .000

    4

    .002

    5

    .003

    0

    .003

    5

    .004

    0

    .004

    5

    24

    68

    1012

    1416

    1820

    2224

    mea

    nst

    d. d

    ev

    corr

    =-0

    .21

    mean

    standard deviation

    -.001

    6

    -.001

    2

    -.000

    8

    -.000

    4

    .000

    0

    .000

    4

    -8-4048

    24

    68

    1012

    1416

    1820

    2224

    mea

    nsk

    ewne

    ss

    corr

    =0.

    60

    mean

    skewness

    -.001

    6

    -.001

    2

    -.000

    8

    -.000

    4

    .000

    0

    .000

    402040608010

    0

    24

    68

    1012

    1416

    1820

    2224

    mea

    nku

    rtos

    is

    corr

    =-0

    .30

    meankurtosis

    Fig

    ure

    7.M

    ean,

    Stan

    dard

    Dev

    iatio

    n,Sk

    ewne

    ss,a

    ndK

    urto

    sis

    ofP

    rice

    Res

    pons

    esto

    aR

    emitt

    ance

    Shoc

    k

    REMITTANCES AND RELATIVE PRICES 55

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • durable items like living room furniture, modular equipment, and glazed pottery isexplained by remittances. The relative prices decrease in response to the remittanceshock for all these three items. For consumption items that provide nontradable ser-vices such as housing, house for rent, electricity, cars, and restaurants and have largerweights in the consumption basket, relative prices rise steadily over time in responseto the remittance shock.

    The impulse responses of relative prices for two additional service items, educationand health that have been shown to be affected by remittances in the previous micro-economic studies (Adams, 2005; Taylor and Mora, 2006) provide interesting results.Therelative price of education (all levels) responds very little and meanders around zero.The relative price of doctor visits increases steadily in the first 5 months and thendecreases until it starts rising again after 18 months.

    In order to get an idea how remittances affect the volatility of prices of individualconsumption items in Mexico, we order the items by the variability of impulseresponses over horizons of 1–24 months (measured by standard deviation over thisperiod). We report the standard deviation of the top 20 items in Panel A of Table 1 andthe standard deviation of the bottom 20 items in Panel B of the same table. We alsoreport the mean responses and the number of times the responses to a remittanceshock are positive. Note that the items which are most volatile in their price responsesalmost exclusively include food items such as vegetables and fruits.

    In contrast, the items that are least volatile in their price responses include a com-bination of nontradable services and tradable goods. For example, education at variouslevels shows very little variability in price responses. The average changes in prices arealso relatively small for this group. Among others, visits to cafeterias, nightclubs, res-taurants, and bars exhibit low volatility in their responses to a remittance shock. Theseresults are not surprising. The prices of food items are generally more flexible thanthose of nonfood and service items and they respond very quickly to changes in themarket conditions. The prices of education, restaurant food, etc., are slow to adjust tothose changes and therefore exhibit less volatility.

    Variance Decompositions

    We further resort to variance decomposition to calculate the percentage of variationin individual prices that is explained by remittances. We order the consumption itemsaccording to the percentage of price variation explained by remittances from largestto the smallest at horizons of 6, 12, and 24 months and report the top 20 items inTable 2. Remittances seem to explain relatively larger proportion of price variationsfor a number of durable items at various horizons. For example, at a horizon of 6months, significant variations in prices of stove, glazed pottery, antecomedores (spe-cialty furniture), radio and recorders, and other domestic electronic gadgets seem tobe explained by remittances. Further, at horizons of 12 and 24 months, modularequipment, cassettes, CDs and living room furniture are some additional durableitems which are included among the top 20 items for which significant price vari-ations are explained by remittances. Substantial variation in prices of nontradableservices such as car insurance, phone line, other entertainment, and houses for rent isalso explained by remittances at various time horizons. Note that there are few fooditems in Table 2.

    To summarize, a positive shock to remittances lowers relative prices for a largernumber of consumption items in the short run. At longer horizons, however, a largernumber of relative prices rise in response to the remittance shock. The relative prices

    56 Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • Tabl

    e1.

    Item

    sO

    rder

    edby

    Var

    iabi

    lity

    inIm

    puls

    eR

    espo

    nses

    over

    1–24

    Mon

    thH

    oriz

    onsa

    Pan

    elA

    :Top

    20ite

    ms

    Pan

    elB

    :Bot

    tom

    20ite

    ms

    Item

    sSt

    anda

    rdde

    viat

    ion

    Mea

    n(%

    )P

    ositi

    vere

    spon

    ses

    Item

    sSt

    anda

    rdde

    viat

    ion

    Mea

    n(%

    )P

    ositi

    vere

    spon

    ses

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    1Se

    rran

    och

    ili0.

    0183

    –4.1

    011

    253

    Shoe

    sm

    ales

    0.00

    03–0

    .54

    42

    Cha

    yote

    0.01

    358.

    7717

    254

    Caf

    eter

    ias

    0.00

    030.

    3019

    3G

    reen

    tom

    atoe

    s0.

    0132

    –6.9

    29

    255

    Und

    erw

    ear

    girl

    s0.

    0003

    –0.3

    16

    4O

    nion

    s0.

    0124

    –23.

    620

    256

    Can

    dy0.

    0003

    0.69

    245

    Lem

    ons

    0.01

    23–5

    .22

    925

    7O

    ther

    shoe

    s0.

    0003

    –0.3

    85

    6To

    mat

    oes

    0.01

    18–1

    .34

    825

    8E

    duca

    tion

    ,sho

    rtca

    reer

    0.00

    030.

    1519

    7P

    inea

    pple

    s0.

    0103

    –0.7

    39

    259

    BB

    Q,c

    ooke

    d0.

    0003

    0.65

    248

    Avo

    cado

    es0.

    0103

    3.33

    1126

    0E

    duca

    tion

    ,col

    lege

    0.00

    03–0

    .33

    39

    Pum

    pkin

    s0.

    0089

    –0.3

    112

    261

    Jack

    ets

    and

    coat

    s0.

    0003

    –0.9

    40

    10C

    hick

    peas

    0.00

    8610

    .80

    2026

    2N

    ight

    club

    0.00

    03–0

    .63

    111

    Ora

    nges

    0.00

    76–1

    0.31

    426

    3C

    otto

    npa

    nts

    mal

    es0.

    0003

    –0.1

    98

    12Po

    tato

    es0.

    0073

    3.61

    1626

    4R

    esta

    uran

    ts0.

    0003

    –0.0

    112

    13O

    ther

    chili

    s0.

    0073

    –5.1

    69

    265

    Und

    erw

    ear

    mal

    es0.

    0002

    –0.6

    21

    14C

    arro

    ts0.

    0071

    2.35

    1326

    6Te

    xtbo

    oks

    0.00

    020.

    1917

    15P

    apay

    as0.

    0071

    1.06

    1226

    7E

    duca

    tion

    ,pri

    mar

    y0.

    0002

    –0.4

    61

    16B

    anan

    as0.

    0065

    2.30

    1326

    8T

    ires

    0.00

    020.

    0813

    17C

    hile

    pobl

    ano

    0.00

    64–2

    .39

    926

    9B

    ars

    0.00

    020.

    0816

    18W

    ater

    mel

    ons

    0.00

    591.

    7913

    270

    Edu

    cati

    on,i

    nter

    med

    iate

    0.00

    020.

    2721

    19C

    ucum

    ber

    0.00

    581.

    5414

    271

    Edu

    cati

    on,k

    inde

    rgar

    ten

    0.00

    02–0

    .13

    920

    Subw

    ay0.

    0055

    3.93

    1327

    2B

    eaut

    ysa

    lon

    visi

    t0.

    0002

    –0.0

    86

    Not

    e:a C

    olum

    n(2

    )re

    port

    sth

    est

    anda

    rdde

    viat

    ion

    ofth

    eim

    puls

    ere

    spon

    ses,

    colu

    mn

    (3)

    repo

    rts

    the

    mea

    nof

    the

    impu

    lse

    resp

    onse

    s(a

    nnua

    lized

    perc

    entr

    ate)

    ,and

    colu

    mn

    (4)

    repo

    rts

    the

    num

    ber

    ofpo

    siti

    vere

    spon

    ses.

    REMITTANCES AND RELATIVE PRICES 57

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • Tabl

    e2.

    Item

    sO

    rder

    edby

    Per

    cent

    age

    ofV

    aria

    tion

    Exp

    lain

    edby

    Rem

    ittan

    cesa

    Hor

    izon

    =6

    Hor

    izon

    =12

    Hor

    izon

    =24

    Item

    sV

    aria

    tion

    (%)

    Item

    sV

    aria

    tion

    (%)

    Item

    sV

    aria

    tion

    (%)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    1H

    ouse

    deod

    oran

    t49

    .09

    Oth

    erliq

    uors

    62.2

    6Te

    quila

    66.9

    42

    Oth

    erliq

    uors

    41.4

    1Po

    wde

    rm

    ilk55

    .98

    Mod

    ular

    equi

    pmen

    t56

    .26

    3Te

    quila

    39.7

    2H

    ouse

    deod

    oran

    t55

    .27

    Can

    ned

    soda

    s54

    .36

    4To

    wel

    s39

    .50

    Toile

    tpa

    per

    52.9

    1O

    ther

    elec

    t.do

    mes

    tics

    50.5

    35

    Car

    insu

    ranc

    e38

    .08

    Tequ

    ila52

    .31

    Saus

    age

    47.1

    96

    Pow

    der

    milk

    36.2

    7M

    odul

    areq

    uipm

    ent

    51.2

    4W

    ine

    45.8

    47

    Win

    e34

    .09

    Win

    e44

    .13

    Shir

    tsfo

    rm

    ales

    45.5

    18

    Stov

    e33

    .66

    Pho

    nelin

    e43

    .28

    Liv

    ing

    room

    furn

    itur

    e45

    .24

    9P

    hone

    line

    32.5

    9A

    ntec

    omed

    ores

    40.2

    9C

    asse

    ttes

    and

    CD

    s44

    .95

    10Fo

    reig

    nbu

    ses

    32.1

    4D

    ress

    esfo

    rfe

    mal

    es40

    .26

    Toile

    tpa

    per

    43.7

    911

    Hat

    s31

    .82

    Gla

    zed

    pott

    ery

    39.4

    5O

    ther

    liquo

    rs43

    .78

    12G

    laze

    dpo

    tter

    y31

    .62

    Shir

    tsfo

    rm

    ales

    38.2

    9O

    ther

    spic

    es43

    .59

    13T-

    shir

    tsfo

    rba

    bies

    31.0

    0To

    wel

    s37

    .55

    New

    spap

    ers

    42.5

    014

    Ant

    ecom

    edor

    es29

    .35

    Stov

    e36

    .16

    Oth

    eren

    tert

    ainm

    ent

    42.4

    815

    Toile

    tpa

    per

    29.0

    4C

    anne

    dso

    das

    35.7

    7N

    apki

    ns41

    .29

    16R

    adio

    and

    reco

    rder

    s27

    .65

    Cas

    sett

    es&

    CD

    s35

    .59

    Gal

    zed

    pott

    ery

    39.9

    917

    Oth

    erpe

    rson

    alhy

    gien

    e27

    .23

    Nap

    kins

    34.7

    3D

    ress

    esfo

    rfe

    mal

    es39

    .46

    18O

    ther

    serv

    ices

    27.1

    2N

    ewsp

    aper

    s32

    .30

    Subw

    ay38

    .69

    19B

    eer

    26.5

    1T-

    shir

    tsfo

    rba

    bies

    31.7

    3Po

    wde

    rm

    ilk37

    .63

    20O

    ther

    elec

    t.do

    mes

    tic

    26.1

    7Sh

    irts

    and

    T.fo

    rbo

    ys31

    .58

    Hou

    ses

    for

    rent

    37.1

    8

    Not

    e:a C

    olum

    ns(2

    ),(4

    )an

    d(6

    )re

    port

    the

    perc

    enta

    geof

    the

    vari

    atio

    nin

    pric

    eof

    the

    prod

    uct

    expl

    aine

    dby

    rem

    itta

    nces

    .

    58 Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • that remittances seem to affect positively include mostly those items that providenontradable services such as house for rent, housing, electricity, cars, and restaurants.These positive effects are more prominent at longer horizons. The relative prices ofdurable items, in contrast, tend to respond negatively to the remittance shock. Theimpulse responses of most food prices are highly variable over time. Furthermore,remittances explain substantial variation in the prices of consumer durables such asantecomedores, living room furniture, glazed pottery, domestic electronic gadgets,modular equipment, radio and recorders; and services such as car insurance, phone line,entertainment, subway, and houses for rent at various horizons after a shock.

    6. Concluding Remarks

    Previous microeconomic studies have suggested that workers’ remittances may haveimportant effects on the spending patterns of the receiving households. Hence, at theaggregate level remittance flows may affect prices of different goods and services in away that has implications for relative prices. In order to examine this possibility, weconsider a fairly general VAR model of the Mexican economy, in which we include, inaddition to standard macro variables and remittances, consumer price indices of 272items.

    Our results indicate that in the short run a positive shock to remittances lowersrelative prices for a larger number of consumption items. At longer horizons,however, a larger number of consumer prices rise in response to the remittanceshock. More importantly, our results suggest important differences in the responses ofrelative prices according to various categories of consumer items. While there is aconsistent rise in relative prices for a number consumption items providing nontrad-able services such as housing, electricity, cars, and restaurants, the relative prices ofseveral durable items such as furniture, glazed pottery, and modular equipment tendto respond negatively to the remittance shock. Furthermore, remittances explain sub-stantial variation in prices for a large number of consumer durables and services atvarious time horizons. The relative price responses are more volatile over time formost food items and less volatile for nonfood and service items reflecting differentdegrees of price flexibility. These results are consistent with the previous microeco-nomic studies that suggest that remittance transfers are spent on a wide range ofgoods and not on food alone.

    Overall, our results clearly indicate that remittances affect prices of various con-sumption items, having important implications for relative prices. It will be far-fetchedto draw any definitive conclusions on their implications for the overall price level andinflation. However, that relative prices change as a result of remittances is in itself animportant result because changes in relative prices affect the decisions of consumersand producers, and therefore have implications for the allocation of resources and theoverall well-being. To avoid distortions owing to these changes in relative prices, thepolicymakers may take into account the differential effects of remittances on prices ofvarious categories of consumer items and accommodate fiscal and monetary policiesaccordingly.

    REMITTANCES AND RELATIVE PRICES 59

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • Appendix

    Table A1. List of Consumer Prices Series

    Corn tortillas Candy Doctor visit Oil (cooking) Local callingCorn meal Gelatin Surgery Apples Long dist. nat. callCorn Other food. Dental care Bananas Long dist. int. callSweet bread Carnitas. Haircut Oranges Phone lineWhite bread Roasted chicken. Beauty salon visit Avocadoes Domestic serviceSandwich bread BBQ, cooked. Hair products Mangos Kitchen furnitureCakes, pies Beer Perfumes and lotions Papayas AntecomedoresNoodles Tequila Hand soap Lemons StovePopular cookies Other liquors Toothpaste Grapes Water heatherOther cookies Rum Deodorant Melons Living room furnit.Wheat flour Brandy Skin lotion Watermelons Dinning tableCereal Wine Shaving machine Pears SofaRice Cigarettes Other hygiene Peaches Bed furniturePoultry Shirts males Toilet paper Grapefruits FridgeChicken (pieces) Underwear males Diapers Pineapples Washing machineWhole chicken Socks males Pads (females) Guavas Other electro.Pork pulp Pants males Napkins Tomatoes FansPork chops and fat Suits males Facial tissue Potatoes IronPork loin Other pants males Colectivo Onions BlenderPork legs Clothe males Urban bus Other legumes Modular equipmentBeefsteak Shirts females Taxi Green tomatoes Radios/recordersGround beef Underwear fem. Subway Pumpkins Light bulbsCow remnants Pantyhose Foreign bus Serrano chili MatchesSpecial beef cuts Cotton pants fem. Air transportation Carrots BatteriesLiver Other pants fem. Cars Other chilis CandlesOther cow Suits females Bicycles Chile poblano BroomsHam Dresses females Lubricant oil Lettuce and cabbage Glazed potterySausage Skirts females Tires Chickpeas CookwareChorizo Cotton pants boys Other car accessories Prickly pears Utensils (plastic)Other stuffed food Other pants boys Car batteries Chayote Other utensilsDry meat Shirts boys Car insurance Cucumber BedspreadBacon Dresses girls Other car spending Green beans Other home textilesOther fish Underwear boys Car maintenance Beans Bed sheetShrimp Underwear girls Tolls Dry chili BlanketsMojarra Socks boys Parking Other dry legumes TowelsOther seafood Dresses babies Private edu., college Canned juices CurtainsBass and grouper Shirts babies Private edu., primary Processed chili Laundry detergentHuachinango Jackets and coats Private edu., high Canned vegetables Soap for dishesTuna Hats Private edu., int. Tomato paste/soup House deodorantCanned seafood Sweaters child Private edu., short Other canned fruits PesticidesFresh milk School unif. Boys Private edu., kinder Fruits for babies AntibioticsPowder milk School unif. Girls Textbooks Sugar AnalgesicsEvaporated milk Tennis shoes Other books Instant coffee Cardiovascular md.Fresh cheese Shoes females Notebooks Toasted coffee Nutritional supp.Yogurt Shoes males Pens, pencils Canned sodas Birth control pillsOaxaca cheese Shoes boys Hotels Mayonnaise/mustard Gastrointestinal Md.Sour cream Other shoes Cinema Chicken/salt spices ExpectorantChihuahua cheese Baggage Nightclub Other seasoning Other medicinesOther cheeses Watches, jewelry Other entertainment French fries Flu medicineIce cream Houses for Rent Sport clubs Concentrated drinks First aidYellow cheese Housing Sport events Chocolate Glasses (eye)Butter Electricity Newspapers Toys Cameras and relatedEggs Domestic gas Magazines Cassettes and CDs Musical instrumentsSport accessories Restaurants Cafeterias Memorial services Other servicesLunch places Bars

    60 Hiranya K. Nath and Carlos Vargas-Silva

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy

  • References

    Adams, Richard H., Jr and Alfredo Cuecuecha, “Remittances, Household Expenditure andInvestment in Guatemala,” World Development 38 (2010):1626–41.

    Amuedo-Dorantes, Catalina and Susan Pozo, “Workers’ Remittances and the Real ExchangeRate: A Paradox of Gifts,” World Development 32 (2004):1407–17.

    Amuedo-Dorantes, Catalina, Susan Pozo, and Tania Sainz, “Remittances and Healthcare Ex-penditure Patterns of Populations in Origin Communities: Evidence from Mexico,” Integration& Trade Journal 27 (2007):159–184.

    Balke, Nathan and Mark Wynne. “The Relative Price Effects of Monetary Shocks,” Journal ofMacroeconomics 29 (2007):19–36.

    Barth, Marvin and Valerie Ramey, “The Cost Channel of Monetary Transmission,” NationalBureau of Economic Research working paper 7675 (2000).

    Betts, Caroline and Timothy Kehoe, “Real Exchange Rate Movements and the Relative Priceof Non-traded Goods,” National Bureau of Economic Research working paper 14437 (2008).

    Davis, Steven and John Haltiwanger, “Sectoral Job Creation and Destruction Responses to OilPrices Changes,” Journal of Monetary Economics 48 (2001):465–512.

    Golob, John and David Bishop, “Inflation and Relative Price Variability: Durables vs.Nondurables and Services,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City working paper 12 (1997).

    Lastrapes, William, “Inflation and the Distribution of Relative Prices: The Role of Productivityand Money supply Shocks,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38 (2006):2159–98.

    Nath, Hiranya, “Relative Importance of Sectoral and Aggregate Sources of Price Changes,”Applied Economics 36 (2004):1781–96.

    Orozco, Manuel, “Remittances, the Rural Sector, and Policy Options in Latin America,” USAIDand BASIS Collaborative Research Support Program (CRSP) (2003).

    Ruiz, Isabel and Carlos Vargas-Silva, “To Send, or Not to Send: That is the Question. A Reviewof the Literature on Workers’ Remittances,” Journal of Business Strategies 26 (2009):65–90.

    Sims, Christopher, “Macroeconomics and Reality,” Econometrica 48 (1980):1–49Sims, Christopher, James Stock, and Mark W. Watson,“Inference in Linear Time Series Models

    with some Unit Roots,” Econometrica 58 (1990):113–44.Taylor, J. Edward and Jorge Mora, “Does Migration Reshape Expenditures in Rural House-

    holds? Evidence from Mexico,” World Bank Policy Research working paper 3842 (2006).Vargas-Silva, Carlos, “The Tale of Three Amigos: Remittances, Exchange Rates and Money

    Demand in Mexico,” Review of Development Economics 13 (2009):1–14.Zarate-Hoyos, German, “Consumption and Remittances in Migrant Households: Toward a

    Productive use of Remittances,” Contemporary Economic Policy 22 (2004):555–65.

    Notes

    1. For a survey, see Ruiz and Vargas-Silva (2009).2. Following Balke and Wynne (2007), we include these variables in levels. Sims(1980) andSims, Stock and Watson (1990) are among the first to suggest that even if the variables areunit root processes, they should be included in levels. They argue that the goal of a VARanalysis is to determine the interrelationships among variables, not to determine the parameterestimates.3. This paper focuses on the demand side effect of remittances on relative prices. However, if aportion of the remittances is used for investment they may also affect the supply side. Byincluding industrial production in our VAR model, we indirectly consider the supply side of themarket. But introducing a direct channel through which remittances may affect supply is outsidethe scope of the current study.4. Balke and Wynne (2007), Barth and Ramey (2000) and Davis and Haltiwanger (2001) makea similar assumption about feedback in their papers.5. The weights are percentage consumption shares in the market basket of a typical urbanhousehold in Mexico.

    REMITTANCES AND RELATIVE PRICES 61

    © 2012 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

    Author's copy


Recommended