+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Microsimulation Modelling for Policy...

Microsimulation Modelling for Policy...

Date post: 11-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: trannga
View: 212 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
23
Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysis Challenges and Innovations EDITED BY LAVINIA MITTON, HOLLY SUTHERLAND AND MELVYN WEEKS
Transcript
Page 1: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

Microsimulation Modelling forPolicy AnalysisChallenges and Innovations

EDITED BY

LAVINIA MITTON, HOLLY SUTHERLAND AND

MELVYN WEEKS

Page 2: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

The Pitt Building, Trumpington Street, Cambridge, United Kingdom

The Edinburgh Building, Cambridge CB2 2RU, UK http://www.cup.cam.ac.uk40 West 20th Street, New York, NY 10011–4211, USA http://www.cup.org10 Stamford Road, Oakleigh, Melbourne 3166, AustraliaRuiz de Alarcón 13, 28014 Madrid, Spain

© Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge 2000

This book is in copyright. Subject to statutory exceptionand to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,no reproduction of any part may take place withoutthe written permission of Cambridge University Press.

First published 2000

Printed in the United Kingdom at the University Press, Cambridge

Typeface Times MT 10/12pt System QuarkXPress™ [S E]

A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library

ISBN 0 521 79006 9 hardback

Page 3: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

Contents

List of figures page xiiList of tables xivList of contributors xviiForeword xixAcknowledgements xxi

1 Introduction 1Lavinia Mitton, Holly Sutherland and Melvyn Weeks

1.1 New directions for microsimulation 41.2 Dynamic modelling 71.3 Modelling behavioural response 81.4 Investing in microsimulation models 10

Part One NEW DIRECTIONS FOR MICROSIMULATION 13

2 The unit of analysis in microsimulation models for personal income taxes: fiscal unit or household? 15André Decoster and Guy Van Camp

2.1 Introduction 152.2 The two data sets 172.3 The matching procedure 182.4 Empirical results for the personal income tax reform in

Belgium between 1988 and 1993 222.5 Conclusion 33

Appendix 2.1 The measurement of liability progression and redistributive effect 35Appendix 2.2 Sensitivity of the distributional analysis with auniform income concept 38

vii

Page 4: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

3 Assessing the direct and indirect effects of social policy:integrating input–output and tax microsimulation models at Statistics Canada 42Grant Cameron and Ross Ezzeddin

3.1 Introduction 423.2 Model specifics 473.3 Previous work in this area and model limitations 543.4 Assessing the direct and indirect effects of different policy

options 563.5 Conclusions 63

4 A microsimulation analysis of the distribution of the indirect tax burden among Greek households 66Georgia Kaplanoglou

4.1 Introduction 664.2 Methodological choices 674.3 Modelling the Greek indirect tax system 704.4 The distribution of the indirect tax burden among Greek

households 744.5 The effects of indirect taxation on the income distribution:

a comparison with an equal-yield uniform tax 874.6 Conclusions 90

5 Can we do better comparative research using microsimulationmodels? Lessons from the micro-analysis of pensions systemsKatherine Rake 96

5.1 The problem of comparative research 965.2 Simulating incomes in old age using MAPS 985.3 Using microsimulation to analyse features of the pension

system 1035.4 ‘Playing God’: altering the life-course of model individuals 1125.5 Conclusions 119

6 Integrating output in EUROMOD: an assessment of the sensitivity of multi-country microsimulation results 124Cathal O’Donoghue, Holly Sutherland and Francesca Utili

6.1 Introduction 1246.2 Adjusting inputs and integrating outputs 1266.3 Method 1276.4 Non-response bias 1296.5 Accounting period adjustment 1306.6 Income under-reporting adjustment 131

viii Contents

Page 5: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

6.7 Common point-in-time adjustment 1346.8 Exchange rate adjustment 1366.9 Equivalence scales 138

6.10 Non-cash incomes 1416.11 How sensitive are the results? 1426.12 Conclusions 145

7 The impact of demographic and other changes on expenditureon pharmaceutical benefits in 2020 in Australia 149Agnes Walker, Richard Percival and Ann Harding

7.1 Why are health expenditures of concern? 1497.2 Previous studies of the scheme compared with NATSEM’s

approach 1527.3 Scenarios 1537.4 Results 1627.5 Summary and conclusions 168

Appendix 7.1 Classification of medications 169

Part Two DYNAMIC MODELLING 173

8 Public pensions in a dynamic microanalytic framework: the case of France 175Carole Bonnet and Ronan Mahieu

8.1 Introduction 1758.2 Overview of the Destinie model 1778.3 Overview of the French social security system 1808.4 The simulation of contributions and benefits between 1945

and 2078 1828.5 Long-run impact of demographic trends on the rate of

return of pensions 1838.6 Conclusions 198

Appendix 8.1 The rate of return on a pay-as-you-go system 198

9 Validation of longitudinal dynamic microsimulation models:experience with CORSIM and DYNACAN 200Steven Caldwell and Richard J. Morrison

9.1 Introduction 2009.2 Background 2019.3 The role of validation 2029.4 Special challenges 2039.5 Major principles and objectives 2049.6 Comparisons to administrative programme data 205

Contents ix

Page 6: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

9.7 Survey, vital statistics, and census data 2119.8 Collateral validation 2159.9 Other models and projections 218

9.10 Special considerations relating to Monte Carlo modelling 2219.11 Conclusions 223

10 Charging for care in later life: an exercise in dynamic microsimulation 226Ruth Hancock

10.1 Introduction 22610.2 Long-term care and dynamic microsimulation 22710.3 Paying for residential care 22810.4 What is modelled 22910.5 First results 23210.6 Concluding remarks 236

11 Individual alignment and group processing: an application tomigration processes in DYNACAN 238Denis Chénard

11.1 Introduction 23811.2 The migration process 23811.3 The alignment problem 23911.4 The ‘pageant’ method of alignment 24011.5 Special cases 24111.6 Error correction 24211.7 An important (but subtle) detail 24311.8 Results 24311.9 Drawbacks of the method 244

11.10 Conclusions 245Appendix 11.1 Migration modules 246

Part Three MODELLING BEHAVIOURAL RESPONSE 249

12 Unemployment insurance and labour mobility: analysis using a new Swedish microsimulation model 251Neil Swan

12.1 Introduction 25112.2 Two theoretical issues 25212.3 Regression analysis of migration and unemployment

benefits 25912.4 Conclusions 266

x Contents

Page 7: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

13 Joint labour supply of married couples: efficiency and distribution effects of tax and labour market reforms 269Rolf Aaberge, Ugo Colombino, Steinar Strøm and Tom Wennemo

13.1 Introduction 26913.2 The model 26913.3 The empirical specification 27313.4 Data and estimation 27513.5 Policy simulations 27813.6 Conclusions 286

Appendix 13.1 Estimation and simulation uncertainty 287

14 Transitions estimators in discrete choice models 292Alan Duncan and Melvyn Weeks

14.1 Introduction 29214.2 A statistical framework 29414.3 Simulating predicted state transitions 29514.4 Calibration-based transition estimators 29814.5 Bootstrap confidence intervals 30014.6 Computational results 30114.7 Conclusions 306

Bibliography 309Index 325

Contents xi

Page 8: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

Figures

3.1 Flow of control for ISEAM page 544.1 Cumulative indirect taxes by deciles of expenditure 764.2 Tax incidence by deciles: households without cars 804.3 Tax incidence by deciles: households with cars 814.4 Differences in the indirect tax burden within each decile

between households with and without cars 824.5 Lorenz curves for the distribution of total expenditure under

the actual indirect tax system and under a uniform system 894.6 Lorenz curves for the distribution of non-durable

expenditure under the actual indirect tax system and under a uniform system 90

4.7 Lorenz curves for the distribution of total expenditure under the actual indirect tax system and under a uniform system(excluding car taxes) 92

4.8 Lorenz curves for the distribution of non-durable expenditure under the actual tax system and under a uniformsystem (excluding car taxes) 93

5.1 The structure of MAPS 995.2 Change in women’s income by income quintile following

alterations to the life-course 1166.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK,

1984–1994 1356.2 Percentages of country populations in the bottom decile of

the Eur6 distribution: cumulative effects of adjustments 1437.1 Spenders on prescribed drugs and all persons in private

dwellings in 2020 1577.2 Deaths and projected deaths from cardiovascular disease

per 100,000 of the population aged 25–74 years, Australia 1617.3 Patient contributions to PBS drug costs, base case and

scenarios, 1996–97 165

xii

Page 9: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

7.4 Government subsidies to PBS patients, base case and scenarios, 1996–7 166

8.1 Rate of return of public pensions 1858.2 Contribution rates for pensions 1878.3 Rate of return of public pensions for each sex 1888.4 Variations in the rate of return 1918.5 Variations in the contribution rate 1928.6 Variations in the rate of return 1938.7 Variations in the contribution rate 1958.8 Distribution of the impact of scenario 6 on the future

discounted income of people born about 1940 and 1960 1968.9 Distribution of the impact of scenario 6 on the future

discounted income of people born about 1960 1979.1 CORSIM validation using administrative data: percentage

of retired male workers in the US by Social Security benefit level in 1996 207

9.2 RoC persons with earnings over year’s basic exemption, byage and sex, administrative data vs DYNACAN, 1971 210

9.3 CORSIM validation using survey of income and programme participation (SIPP) data 213

9.4 RoC population aged 651: interpolated census vsDYNACAN 215

9.5 CORSIM collateral validation: exits by cause from female-headed status in US, 1962–2014 217

9.6 Proportion of RoC population living in childless couples with at least one senior 219

9.7 Distribution of single-parent families by number of children, DYNACAN and SCF 220

9.8 Total projected CPP benefits, ACTUCAN and DYNACAN 22211.1 Cumulative immigration to the year 2030: actual vs needed 24411.2 Cumulative emigration to the year 2030: actual vs needed 24411.3 Cumulative emigration to the year 1980: actual vs needed 245

11.A1.1 Flowchart of migration models 24613.1 The opportunity set in the traditional approach 27113.2 The opportunity set in our model approach 272

List of figures xiii

Page 10: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

Tables

2.1 IPCAL and the budget survey compared page 192.2 The 14 variables used in the distance function and their

weight 212.3 Rate structure before and after the reform of 1988 232.4 Exemption levels after the tax reform of 1988 252.5 Sensitivity of the distributional analysis of TRA88 to the

choice of unit of analysis 272.6 Sensitivity of the distributional analysis of TRA88 to the

choice of unit of analysis after correction with an equivalence scale 30

2.7 Comparison of the distributional analysis of TRA88 with and without correction with an equivalence scale 32

2.A2.1 Sensitivity of the distributional analysis of TRA88 to the choice of unit of analysis with a uniform income concept 38

2.A2.2 Sensitivity of the distributional analysis of TRA88 to the choice of unit of analysis with a uniform income concept and after correction with an equivalence scale 39

3.1 Summary of direct and indirect effects for each scenario 573.2 Halved social assistance in Ontario 58

(a) Average change in Census family income, $1992(b) Percentage of Census families who lose $75 or more

3.3 Reduction in Ontario’s tax fraction 59(a) Average change in Census family income, $1992(b) Percentage of Census families who gain $75 or more

3.4 Reduction in Newfoundland’s tax fraction 60(a) Average change in Census family income, $1992(b) Percentage of Census families who gain $75 or more

4.1 Sources of indirect tax revenue and their inclusion in this analysis 71

xiv

Page 11: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

4.2 Indirect tax burden by expenditure group, 1988 744.3 The effect of car taxes on the progressivity of the Greek

indirect tax system 784.4 The effects of household characteristics on the indirect tax

burden, 1988: a regression analysis 844.5 Present system of indirect taxes vs a uniform system of

indirect taxes: a comparison of inequality measures 915.1 Principal characteristics of the three national-level

simulations 1025.2 Women’s and men’s simulated lifetime earnings 1055.3 Women’s mean weekly pension as a percentage of men’s 1065.4 Mean weekly pension as a percentage of mean weekly

earnings 1085.5 The coverage of credits 1105.6 The value of credits 1115.7 Women’s mean gross individual income as a percentage of

men’s under three different life-course scenarios 1146.1 Country composition of the Eur6 income distribution using

base assumptions 1286.2 Country composition of the Eur6 income distribution:

differential national weights 1296.3 Percentage of national accounts disposable income in Eur6 1326.4 Country composition of the Eur6 income distribution:

national accounts adjustment 1336.5 National currency market and PPP exchange rates for ecu,

1994 averages 1366.6 Country composition of the Eur6 income distribution:

PPP exchange rate 1376.7 Mean equivalised disposable income (and rank of country)

in Eur6 by equivalence scale elasticity 1396.8 Country composition of the Eur6 income distribution:

per capita incomes 1406.9 Cash and non-cash social expenditure, 1992 1417.1 Policy settings of the Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme for

1996–97: base case 1517.2 PBS prescription numbers and expenditures 1587.3 Estimated change in deaths from cardiovascular disease

per 100,000 of the population aged 25–74 years, Australia 1627.4 Total number of prescriptions: base case and scenarios 1637.5 Total costs to government: base case and scenarios 167

7.A1.1 Classification of medications 1698.1 Average annual growth rates between 1998 and 2040 189

List of tables xv

Page 12: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

8.2 Increase in the global contribution rate for pensions from wages between 1998 and 2040 190

9.1 CORSIM Monte Carlo variation, 1965–2035: estimates calculated from seven independent CORSIM simulations 224

10.1 A comparison of some of the characteristics of people currently aged 80–94 and living alone and those of people predicted to be in the same situation in 15 years’ time 232

10.2 Simulated contributions to residential care costs of people currently aged 80–94 and living alone and those of people predicted to be in the same situation in 15 years’ time 233

10.3 Simulated contributions to residential care costs of people currently aged 80–94 and living alone and those of people predicted to be in the same situation in 15 years’ time, housing wealth disregarded in full 235

12.1 Rates of unemployment benefit 26012.2 Logit predictions of moving labour market area 26513.1 Descriptive statistics: married couples 27613.2 Estimates of the parameters of the utility function 27713.3 Estimates of the market opportunity, hours, and wage

densities 27813.4 Participation rates, annual hours of work, gross income,

taxes and disposable income for couples under alternativedifferent tax regimes and labour market reforms by decilesof household disposable income in 1993 280

13.5 The Gini coefficient for distributions of households’ gross and disposable income, and degree of redistribution undervarious tax regimes 284

13.6 Decile-specific proportions of winners from two alternativetax reforms, by household disposable income in 1993 285

13.A1.1 Total, estimation and simulation uncertainty, 1993 tax rules 28914.1 Monte Carlo simulations: balanced design 30314.2 Monte Carlo simulations: unbalanced design 30414.3 Simulated transitions: labour supply design 305

xvi List of tables

Page 13: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

1 Introduction

Lavinia Mitton, Holly Sutherland and Melvyn Weeks

Microsimulation models use micro-data on persons (or households, orfirms or other micro-units) and simulate the effect of changes in policy (orother changes) on each of these units. Differences before and after thechange can be analysed at the micro-level or aggregated to show the overalleffect of the change. It is the dependence on individual information fromthe micro-data at every stage of the analysis that distinguishes microsimula-tion models from other sorts of economic, statistical or descriptive models.

Modern policy problems require analysts to capture the interactionsbetween policy and the complexities of economic and social life, as well asbetween policies of different types. Microsimulation is increasingly a tech-nique that is employed to analyse these problems. At the same time,developments in computing power and analytical techniques allow agreater sophistication in the view of the world that microsimulationmodels can attempt to portray, and hence in the range of questions thatthey may address. This book brings together examples of microsimulationmodelling that are at the frontiers of developments in the field, eitherbecause they are extending the range of techniques available to modellers,or because they demonstrate new applications for established methods.

The problem of determining the impact of a proposed change in policyhas been succinctly summarised by Heckman and Smith (1995, p. 87) asbeing:

the fundamental evaluation problem that arises from the impossibility of observ-ing what would happen to a given person in both the state where he or she receivesa treatment (or participates in a program) and the state where he or she does not. Ifa person could be observed in both states, the impact of the treatment on thatperson could be calculated by comparing his or her outcomes in the two states, andthe evaluation problem would be solved.

In principle, the effect of a policy change can be isolated by the compari-son of ‘before’ and ‘after’ observations, or comparison of two groups that

1

Page 14: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

are considered identical except that one group has received the treatment.However, despite the use of a range of statistical techniques, the difficultyof creating ceteris paribus conditions may result in selection bias, dis-torting the true impact of the treatment. Often we do not observe all thesignificant characteristics that need to be controlled for. Furthermore, wemay wish to use models to inform the design of new types of policy or topredict their impact in changed social or economic conditions. In thesesituations, microsimulation models can provide a consistent and struc-tured framework in which to explore a range of ‘what if ’ questions aboutthe outcomes of policy reforms.

Traditionally, microsimulation models are divided into two types: staticand dynamic. Microsimulation is essentially a set of methods for thegeneration of missing information, and the distinction between static anddynamic depends on the particular method that is used. Most critical is themethod for ageing the micro-units (Harding, 1996; Merz, 1991). Staticmodels typically use a combination of re-weighting of micro-units andindexation of money amounts to update cross-sectional micro-data to therequired point in time. Some static models may use no ageing at all, andmay operate in terms of the time at which the underlying data were col-lected. Dynamic ageing, on the other hand, changes the characteristics ofthe micro-units in response to accumulated experience or the passage oftime. At the most basic level, units are older by a year in each year of theupdating. As the unit gets older, combinations of stochastic and determin-istic methods are used to predict changes in status. In models of persons,the changes in status typically include labour force participation, co-habi-tation and parenthood. At each stage, incomes are estimated, based oncurrent status and circumstances and past history. Dynamic models gener-ate long-term or lifetime data describing each micro-unit. They mayoperate in a time warp, abstracting from real changes such as economicgrowth, or they may either predict the future or fill in missing informationabout the past (see Harding, 1990). Dynamic ageing is sensitive to assump-tions about macro conditions (such as unemployment) and dynamicmodels may be used to explore the effects of incorporating alternativeassumptions about the future, or alternative representations of the past.

In principle, static or dynamic models may be augmented by intro-ducing behavioural response, which allows the calculation of second-ordereffects due to changes in, for example, labour supply or fertility, followinga policy change. For dynamic models, incorporating behavioural responsemeans altering the nature of the transition probabilities that are used toage the micro-units. In practice, this is rarely done.

The way in which behaviour change is estimated is clearly an importantissue. The principal drawback of behavioural models derived from cross-

2 L. Mitton, H. Sutherland and M. Weeks

Page 15: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

sectional data is one of interpretation. Given that cross-sectional modelslack an explicit time dimension, it is not possible to examine the timeprofile of the impact of a particular policy change. Further, it is not possi-ble to differentiate between the two major problems in predicting individ-ual behaviour – namely heterogeneity and time dependence (see Heckman,1981). The increasing availability of panel data provides us with prospectsfor improvement on two fronts: first, the opportunity to estimate econo-metric models of behavioural response that incorporate ‘dynamics’; andsecond, better-founded estimation of transition probabilities that are usedto age the sample in a dynamic microsimulation model.1

The choice of whether to use a static or dynamic microsimulationmodel, and whether to include behavioural modelling, depends in princi-ple on the policy question to be addressed and also on the quality and suit-ability of available data. (In practice, it also depends on the institutionalcontext and the speed with which an answer to the question is necessary.These issues are considered below.)

Static microsimulation is generally used when only cross-sectionalinformation is needed to answer a policy question. For example, in thisvolume, Kaplanoglou models the distributional effect of a change in taxrates. Dynamic methods are used when a set of repeated cross-sections isneeded, as when modelling the effects of pension reform (see Bonnet andMahieu in this volume), or when long-range future prediction is requiredfor a current sample, such as in Hancock’s paper exploring the financing oflong-term care. In either case, whether behavioural responses to the policychanges are modelled depends on a number of factors. In some circum-stances we may want to know the first-round effects (for example, if we areconcerned about the perception of the fairness of the reform) or we maywant to know both the first-round effects and the full effects because webelieve behaviour will take some time to change. In addition, whether wemodel changes in behaviour depends on the availability of suitable data forthe estimation of behaviour, and whether we believe that our estimation issufficiently reliable to make the exercise worthwhile. However, in caseswhere the proposed policy is designed to alter behaviour – such as the pro-vision of subsidised child-care, considered by Duncan and Weeks in thisvolume – then an estimate of the revenue cost using only a deterministicset of rules will, in general, generate a misleading estimate of the overallimpact.

On the other hand, the introduction of a behavioural component willalso introduce an additional element of uncertainty, generated by theparameter estimates. All microsimulation model results are subject tosome degree of error. The great strength of microsimulation based onmicro-data is that the full range of variation in circumstances is captured.

Introduction 3

Page 16: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

However, many of the processes that are part of building any microsimula-tion model – updating and uprating, imputing missing values and re-weighting, as well as estimation – involve some degree of aggregation andapproximation. The effect of sampling error on the reliability of a range ofstatic model outputs has been calculated by Pudney and Sutherland(1994). The same authors have estimated the additional error due to alabour supply response model (Pudney and Sutherland, 1996).2 It is oftena question of judgement as to whether the bias introduced by failing tocapture important effects (such as behaviour change, or differencesbetween small groups) is outweighed by additional uncertainty due toimperfect estimation procedures or underlying data. The calculation ofconfidence intervals around model results that account for all sources oferror remains a major challenge.

In dynamic microsimulation modelling, the simulation of a realisticageing of the population depends on the existence of reliable transitionprobabilities. Since these probabilities are estimates, they naturally intro-duce an additional element of uncertainty. Given the nature of thesemodels, any error in one component is likely to be compounded withrepeated use during the ageing process. Devising methods to assess theextent of error in dynamic model outputs, particularly those that cannotbe subjected to direct or ‘collateral’ comparison with independentinformation, is currently ‘an art rather than a science’ (see Caldwell andMorrison in this volume).

The categorisations ‘static’, ‘dynamic’ and ‘behavioural’ are useful fromthe model-builder’s perspective because the nature of the work involved,and the physical resources required to carry out these three types of mod-elling are quite different. For these reasons the sections in this book followtraditional divisions: the first section includes papers that use staticmethods innovatively; the second focuses on developments in dynamicmodel building and the third on modelling behaviour change. This intro-duction considers the papers in each section in turn and concludes withsome reflections on the process of model building.

1.1 New directions for microsimulation

Part One of this volume contains chapters on what would traditionally betermed static models. However, it is increasingly the case that microsimula-tion models do not fall conveniently into the established categories ofstatic and dynamic models, either with or without behavioural change.Indeed, some of the contributors to this volume would challenge the tax-onomy that we have set out above. Thus, many of the chapters in Part Oneincorporate an innovative dimension that makes the choice of ageing

4 L. Mitton, H. Sutherland and M. Weeks

Page 17: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

method less relevant as a classification criterion. For example, the pensionsmodel described by Rake could be defined as static in that it employs asingle cross-section for its data source and uses static ageing. But it alsocontains elements in common with dynamic models in relation to themethods used to simulate lifetime earnings and pension contributions ofthe sample individuals that were not recorded in the original survey data.

The aim of Rake’s chapter is to illustrate how microsimulation can beused when conducting cross-country comparative social policy research.In the field of social policy, cross-national comparisons are frequentlylimited to the descriptive: the researcher can become overwhelmed by thevariation between national policies. Microsimulation can strip away someof the underlying national variations in order to improve our under-standing of the link between policy and outcome. Thus, Rake is able toshow the effect of the British, French and German pensions systems in‘exaggerating, replicating or mitigating the earnings differential betweenwomen and men’.

Another innovation in microsimulation is the linking of micro-modelsto macro-models of various kinds. The paper by Cameron and Ezzeddindescribes a preliminary exercise to link two established models together inorder to incorporate some macroeconomic second order effects. Themodels are a static microsimulation model and a regional input–outputmodel for Canada. The linked models simulate both the direct and indirecteffects on micro-level economic well-being of various tax/transfer andsocial policy alternatives in the Canadian Provinces. They can also be usedto assess the distributional effects on households of changes to the eco-nomic climate and the industrial base. Although its preliminary naturemeans that some of the links are crude (the adjustments to micro-levelearnings are proportional, for example), this paper demonstrates thepotential for integrating personal and industrial sector models.

The models described in Part One are not used simply to measure theeffects of actual or prospective policy reforms – the original motivationfor the development of static microsimulation models. Policy simulationsare also used as analytical devices to understand the operation of existingsystems (as in Rake’s paper) and the sensitivity of results to conventionalassumptions. For example, Kaplanoglou uses microsimulation methodsto discover that the apparent mild progressivity of the Greek indirect taxsystem is due solely to taxes on private transport: if car taxes are treatedas road use charges rather than pure taxes, the regressive parts of thesystem are left to dominate the overall pattern. Some of the apparentprogressivity arises from the lower rates of car ownership among lesswell off groups. Based on her results from simulating a uniform VAT asan alternative to the immensely complex Greek indirect tax structure,

Introduction 5

Page 18: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

Kaplanoglou is able to make a strong argument for simplifying Greekindirect taxes.

Decoster and Van Camp also use microsimulation to explore thesensitivity of results to conventional assumptions, at the same time as pro-viding a distributional analysis of the 1988 Belgian tax reform. They con-sider the issue of the unit of analysis and the effect of the choice betweenfiscal unit and household on conclusions about the distributionalcharacteristics of the tax system. Using a statistical matching procedure, alink is made between an administrative fiscal data set and the householdbudget survey for Belgium. This allows personal tax liabilities to beimputed for each fiscal unit within each household in the survey, andhence for the implications of either unit of analysis to be explored. Onefinding is that the redistributive power of the tax system was reduced bythe reform, and that this conclusion is not sensitive to the choice of unit.However, for both the pre-reform and post-reform tax systems, the choiceof the unit of analysis does affect conclusions about the redistributive effectof the systems themselves. In both cases, use of the fiscal unit leads tohigher parameters of the tax system than if the household is used.

Taking the issue of sensitivity of results in another direction, the paperby O’Donoghue et al., focuses on the comparability of model resultsacross countries. Using a prototype of the EUROMOD model, a statictax–benefit model for the whole European Union, it addresses the ques-tion of the sensitivity of European model results to the way in whichincomes are measured across household types and across countries. Itshows that the country composition of quantiles of the European incomedistribution can be sensitive to the choice of equivalence scale, adjust-ments for apparent differences in the quality of micro-data, and exchangerates. It implies that the evaluation of policy at the European level requirescareful interpretation in the light of the assumptions that have beenchosen.

Finally, the paper by Walker et al., extends the use of static microsimula-tion into a new policy area: the growth in expenditure on the AustralianPharmaceutical Benefits Scheme (PBS) which subsidises the cost of medi-cines. The model uses static ageing techniques and detailed information on arange of types of prescribed medicines. The paper illustrates the potential ofthe model by analysing the likely outcomes for the present scheme in 2020under three scenarios: an ageing population; a continued upward trend inmedicine costs; and a general improvement in Australians’ health leading tolower usage of prescribed medicines. The analysis finds that increases indrug prices are likely to have the greatest impact on the cost of the PBS, andpopulation ageing the least impact, but suggest that improvements inAustralians’ health have the potential to limit cost increases significantly.

6 L. Mitton, H. Sutherland and M. Weeks

Page 19: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

1.2 Dynamic modelling

The development of microsimulation models can challenge the resultsachieved through other methods. Two of the papers in Part Two – byCaldwell and Morrison, and by Bonnet and Mahieu – confront othertypes of model that are traditionally used to analyse policy issues relatedto pensions. Bonnet and Mahieu contrast the use of dynamic microsimula-tion with that of Computable General Equilibrium ‘overlapping genera-tions’ models. Their dynamic model is able to study the transfers withingenerations as well as between them. Caldwell and Morrison confront thedynamic model, DYNACAN, with results from the Canadian actuarialmodel of pensions in a more direct way: it is expected to produce resultsthat are consistent with the more traditional actuarial approach.

Population ageing and slower rates of economic growth raise manyquestions about the future of intergenerational public transfers in coun-tries such as France with generous pay-as-you-go public pension systems.Bonnet and Mahieu describe their dynamic microsimulation model,Destinie, and use it to explore the implications of six alternative economic,demographic and policy scenarios. Since they are concerned to comparethe microsimulation approach with overlapping generations models, theirfocus is mainly on the differential effects on successive generations.However, they also examine effects by gender and income level withincohorts.

As Caldwell and Morrison point out in their paper, validation is a vitalpart of integrating the use of microsimulation models into the policydevelopment process. They present a range of types of validation and rec-onciliation for two dynamic models sharing a common basic structure(DYNACAN for Canada and CORSIM for the US). They note the lack ofliterature or theory on which to base a validation exercise, but are nonethe-less optimistic, maintaining that validation is ‘not a problem to be avoided,but an asset to be exploited’. It can be seen as an opportunity for improv-ing understanding of the modelling process itself.

Hancock uses dynamic microsimulation to simulate the contributionsthat older people will make towards the cost of care in a residential home,should they need it. She simulates what older people in a relatively high-risk group might pay towards care costs, both now and in 15 years’ time.She explores a range of charging options including the use of housingwealth. Of particular interest to prospective builders of dynamic micro-simulation models is Hancock’s ‘progress through small steps’ approach.Most dynamic model construction projects involve teams of people, a long-term and large-scale resource commitment (by social science standards)and the associated costs of management and co-ordination. In contrast,

Introduction 7

Page 20: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

Hancock single-handedly focuses on the new and particular issues raisedby her research questions, leaving aside for later development aspects of themodel that are not central to them.

At a practical level, building microsimulation models is all about detail,on the one hand, and finding ways of representing complex processes ina tractable form, on the other. Chénard’s paper describes the solutionfound to one particular problem faced by the Canadian dynamic model,DYNACAN. It does so in a way that graphically illustrates to the non-practitioner the process of constructing a dynamic microsimulation model,at the same time as documenting, for the fellow-modeller, a neat solution toa difficult problem. The problem is migration. While migration itself affectsa whole family, keeping the model consistent with external totals (‘align-ment’) must be done on an individual basis. The technique developed inthe paper is based on the pageant principle (‘many are called but few getchosen’). It allows alignment on an individual basis at the same time astransition on a family basis, and is in principle applicable to problems otherthan migration.

1.3 Modelling behavioural response

Three papers include some behavioural response modelling. The chapterby Swan examines the distortionary effects on migratory behaviour ofunemployment benefit in Sweden. The model Sverige is in the early stagesof development as a dynamic microsimulation model. The design is fairlystandard, but with two important innovations. The first is that the under-lying data include information on the location in Sweden of every personin the sample to within 100 square metres. Thus there is enormous poten-tial to explore the spatial aspects of policy. In this chapter, a logistic regres-sion approach is used to estimate separately the effects on migration ofchanges in unemployment and changes in unemployment benefits. Theresults show that there is a significant – but small – effect of benefit levelson migration. However, the effect is purely monetary in the sense thatunemployment itself does not appear to have a significant effect.

The second innovative feature that is planned is the ability to choosebetween alternative labour market functions in the model. The standardtreatment is to use ‘natural rate of unemployment’ theory to achieve align-ment during simulation. Using other theories would give rise to differentresults for changes in regional and national unemployment rates followingmigration. In the case considered by Swan, the small predicted migrationeffect would give rise to – at most – small changes in unemployment underany theoretical assumption. However, the general prospects for users of

8 L. Mitton, H. Sutherland and M. Weeks

Page 21: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

being able to choose their preferred theoretical framework, is a significantstep. Indeed, the laying bare of underlying theoretical assumptions is aninnovation in this context.

The two remaining chapters both focus on the problems of modellinglabour supply responses. Unlike the majority of models of labour supply,the study by Aaberge et al., considers the joint labour supply of householdmembers. A second innovation is the incorporation of demand con-straints. Otherwise unconstrained choices are adjusted by the likelihood ofobtaining jobs with given hours and wages combinations. Previous studies(see van Soest, 1994) have noted the empirical tendency of labour supplymodels to overestimate predicted part-time employment. This is due, inpart, to the focus on the supply-side characteristics of individuals, therebyignoring the influence of the fixed costs of employment on the availabilityof part-time employment.

Using Italian survey data, the authors simulate the impact of a numberof tax reforms including the introduction of a flatter profile of tax ratesand a negative income tax regime. The reforms involve incentives for somepeople to work less and others to work more, such that the more pro-ductive decide to work longer hours. However, if the quantity constraintson hours choice are removed, an increase in the participation rates forindividuals in the poorest income deciles is predicted. This result providesfurther evidence that models of labour supply that ignore demand-sidefactors will on average over-predict participation rates for lower incomegroups whose opportunity set consists mainly of home production anddifficult-to-find part-time jobs.

The problem of the tendency to over-predict part-time working in dis-crete choice models of labour supply is also addressed in the chapter byDuncan and Weeks. They recognise that a discrepancy between observedand predicted choice is not a problem if the analyst is simply interested inpredicting aggregate frequencies. However, if the estimation model islinked to a microsimulation model in order to predict the costs of, forexample, the introduction of subsidised child-care, then the within-sampleforecasts of the underlying choice model need to be accurate.

The chapter assesses the performance of a number of transition estima-tors, including the maximum probability rule estimator and estimatorsbased upon calibration. Using both a Monte Carlo study and labourmarket data from a household survey, substantial differences in per-formance between the alternative estimators are found. Significantly betterproperties are exhibited by those based on calibration, where the baselinemodel is adjusted to remove discrepancies between observed and predictedoutcomes.

Introduction 9

Page 22: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

1.4 Investing in microsimulation models

Several of the chapters in this volume refer to their models as being proto-types, ‘preliminary’ or work in progress. In practice, most microsimulationmodels are – as far as their builders are concerned – major enterprisesrequiring many person-years of expertise, attention to detail and stamina.As investment in research capacity, they can all be considered to be workin progress in some sense or another. They may develop one step at a time,as resources permit (in this volume, see Hancock). Or they may be set upas large-scale enterprises with multiple goals and a relatively long timehorizon (in this volume, see Caldwell and Morrison, and Chénard(DYNACAN); Swan (Sverige); O’Donoghue et al., (EUROMOD)).3 It isalso the case that some models may never be distinct objects withidentifiable histories. They may be a collection of procedures and tech-niques that are assembled, re-assembled or discarded in the search formethodological improvement (in this volume see Aaberge et al.; Duncanand Weeks). Some model builders consider themselves to be answerable toa set of ‘users’ or ‘clients’ (see Caldwell and Morrison in this volume, andalso Immervoll et al., 1999). This can constrain the model developmentprocess. It can also provide a valuable focus and discipline. For others,there are no distinctions or separations between model builder, model useror user of the model’s output.

These differences are related to the range of types of institutions inwhich microsimulation model construction and analysis takes place (seeSutherland, 1998). This volume combines chapters reporting on modellingefforts in government departments with modelling developments that arecarried out in academic environments. The institutional differences can beimportant in understanding the motivation for the project and the con-straints under which it operates. For example, modelling by governmentdepartments is often initiated by policy-makers’ needs to find answers tospecific questions. These may be regular or multiple needs, encouraginginvestment within government in the development of durable and flexiblemodels. The incentives in the academic world for this investment are lessobvious, although the EUROMOD project shows that it is possible. It isalso quite clear that innovation in technique is not the preserve of acade-mic modellers: in some countries, many of the most exciting projects arecarried out by government analysts. At the same time, academics do havethe freedom to look beyond the analytical needs of current policy agendas,both in the direction of technical virtuosity and in order to model inde-pendent, alternative or dissident policy ideas.

Thus there is not only a role for microsimulation modelling in each typeof institution, but also a set of good reasons to encourage and maintain a

10 L. Mitton, H. Sutherland and M. Weeks

Page 23: Microsimulation Modelling for Policy Analysisassets.cambridge.org/97805217/90062/sample/9780521790062...6.1 Growth in total household income: Italy and the UK, 1984–1994 135 6.2

lively – and international – dialogue between them. This volume, and theworkshop on which it is based, represent part of that dialogue. It is one ofa series of such international volumes, including Orcutt, Merz and Quinke(eds) (1986), Harding (ed.) (1996), and Gupta and Kaipur (forthcoming).4

Given the analytical challenges posed by modern policy development, andthe innovative directions in which microsimulation is moving, hopefully itwill not be the last!

Notes

1 It is important to be clear that the terms ‘static’ and ‘dynamic’ have differentmeanings in the vernacular of econometrics from those used here in relation tomicrosimulation models.

2 See also the Appendix to Aaberge et al., in this volume.3 It is notable that two of the newer models – DYNACAN and Sverige have taken

the short cut of inheriting the model structure of a more mature model(CORSIM).

4 There are many other collections of papers that are not focused solely on micro-simulation or which have a less international scope. Brunner and Petersen (eds)(1990) consider simulation models in general. For models for North America,see Lewis and Michel (eds) (1990) and Citro and Hanushek (eds) (1991), and forthe UK, see Hancock and Sutherland (eds) (1992).

Introduction 11


Recommended