+ All Categories
Home > Documents > The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although...

The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although...

Date post: 19-Aug-2019
Category:
Upload: vuongbao
View: 217 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
25
1 The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence of FDI Over Time Joseph D. ALBA*, Peiming WANG and Donghyun PARK, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore Abstract We examine the impact of exchange rates on FDI inflows into the United States in the context of a model that allows for interdependence of FDI over time. Interdependence is modeled as a two-state Markov process where the two states can be interpreted as either a favorable or an unfavorable environment for FDI in an industry. We use unbalanced industry-level panel data from the US wholesale trade sector and our analysis yields two main results. First, we find evidence that FDI is interdependent over time. Second, under a favorable FDI environment, the exchange rate has a positive and significant effect on the average rate of FDI inflows. Keywords: Exchange rate, FDI, Markov, unbalanced panel JEL Codes: F31, F21, F23 _______________ * Corresponding author: Joseph D. Alba, Room No. S3-B2B-56, Economics Division, School of Humanities and Social Sciences, Nanyang Technological University (NTU), Singapore 639798 [E-mail] [email protected] [Telephone] (65)6790-6234 [Fax] (65)6792-4217 Co-Author: Peiming Wang, Room No. S3-B1A-33, Banking and Finance Division, Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University (NTU), Singapore 639798 Co-Author: Donghyun Park, Room No. S3-B1A-10, Economics Division, School of Humanities and Social Sciences, Nanyang Technological University (NTU), Singapore 639798
Transcript
Page 1: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

1

The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence of FDI Over Time

Joseph D. ALBA*, Peiming WANG and Donghyun PARK, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore

Abstract We examine the impact of exchange rates on FDI inflows into the United States in the context of a model that allows for interdependence of FDI over time. Interdependence is modeled as a two-state Markov process where the two states can be interpreted as either a favorable or an unfavorable environment for FDI in an industry. We use unbalanced industry-level panel data from the US wholesale trade sector and our analysis yields two main results. First, we find evidence that FDI is interdependent over time. Second, under a favorable FDI environment, the exchange rate has a positive and significant effect on the average rate of FDI inflows. Keywords: Exchange rate, FDI, Markov, unbalanced panel JEL Codes: F31, F21, F23 _______________ * Corresponding author: Joseph D. Alba, Room No. S3-B2B-56, Economics Division, School of Humanities and Social Sciences, Nanyang Technological University (NTU), Singapore 639798 [E-mail] [email protected] [Telephone] (65)6790-6234 [Fax] (65)6792-4217 Co-Author: Peiming Wang, Room No. S3-B1A-33, Banking and Finance Division, Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University (NTU), Singapore 639798 Co-Author: Donghyun Park, Room No. S3-B1A-10, Economics Division, School of Humanities and Social Sciences, Nanyang Technological University (NTU), Singapore 639798

Page 2: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

2

1 Introduction

Foreign direct investment (FDI) flows into the Unites States have shown substantial

fluctuations in the 1980s and 1990s. A growing theoretical and empirical literature attempts to

explain those fluctuations primarily in terms of the impact of the real exchange rate on FDI.

Contributions to this literature include Froot and Stein (1991), Blonigen (1997), Klein and

Rosengren (1994), Guo and Trivedi (2002) and Kiyota and Urata (2004). Theoretical

considerations based on the relative wealth and relative labor cost effects suggest that a stronger

US dollar may deter FDI into the US.1 At the same time, however, a stronger US dollar may

improve the home-currency revenues and thus profitability of foreign firms entering the US

market. This helps to explain the entry of foreign firms into the US market during the first half of

the 1980s, when the US dollar appreciated sharply.

Interestingly, there was a tendency among foreign firms to remain in the US market when the

US dollar returned to its original level. Such behavior is an example of hysteresis, or an effect

that persists after its underlying cause has been removed. One possible explanation for the failure

of foreign firms to exit the US market in the face of a falling dollar is the presence of sunk costs

that cannot be recovered upon exit.2 The exchange rate would have to fall below the entry-

triggering level in order to trigger exit. Dixit (1989) further develops the concept of hysteresis by

applying the theory of option pricing from financial economics to analyze investment under

uncertainty.3 Dixit shows that greater price volatility leads to a wider range of prices in which

inactive firms do not enter and active firms do not exit. That is, uncertainty expands the gap

between the entry-triggering price and exit-triggering price, thereby deterring both entry and exit.

Campa (1993) develops an empirically testable model of FDI based on Dixit’s model. Campa’s

model describes a risk-neutral foreign firm that has to incur a sunk cost in order to enter the US

market. It has to decide, at each point in time, whether to enter the US market in this period or

wait until next period. The firm produces a good abroad and can sell it in the US market at a

Page 3: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

3

constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home

currency fluctuate if the bilateral exchange rate fluctuates. If the exchange rate is defined as units

of foreign currency per US dollar, a higher exchange rate increases the home currency-profits. At

the same time, the more volatile the exchange rate, the more volatile will be the home-currency

returns, and the wider is the range of exchange rates in which neither entry nor exit occurs.

Campa’s model thus clearly predicts a positive effect of exchange rate and a negative effect of

exchange rate volatility on FDI.4

Campa empirically tests his model using data consisting of a panel based on 61 four-digit

Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) industries in the US wholesale trade sector for the period

from 1981 to 1987. The choice of wholesale industries eliminates the complications of

manufacturing industries pertaining to input origin or final output destination.5 The dependent

variable is the number of foreign firms that entered a US industry in a given year while the

independent variables are measures of exchange rate level R, rate of change in the exchange rate

μ, volatility of the exchange rate σ, sunk costs k, and variable costs of production in the United

States relative to foreign countries w.6 Campa uses a Tobit model to estimate the probability that

an FDI entry occurs in the US wholesale trade sector. The model predicts the probability of entry

is positively related to R and μ, and negatively related to σ, k and w. All variables other than μ

have the predicted sign. Most importantly, the exchange rate level R has a significant positive

effect and the standard deviation of the exchange rate σ has a significant negative effect.7

Tomlin (2000) extends Campa’s sample period to 1993 and uses a zero-inflated Poisson (ZIP)

model to analyze FDI in the US wholesale trade industry. While Campa calculates the probability

that an FDI entry occurs, Tomlin estimates the average rate of FDI entries per industry for the

period 1982 to 1993. Tomlin pools industry data for a period of 12 years, so that her model is in

effect a cross-sectional model that does not consider interdependence over time. In contrast to

Campa, Tomlin finds that neither the level nor the standard deviation of the exchange rate has any

Page 4: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

4

effect on the rate of FDI. This suggests that while exchange rate variables may affect the

probability of entry, they do not affect the average rate of FDI entries.

All previous studies of FDI have failed to consider the interdependence of FDI over time. This

possibility is articulated by Caves (1971) using the concept of corporate rivalry in FDI. Caves

argues that rival firms in an oligopoly with product differentiation tend to follow each other in

making direct investments in foreign countries.8 For example, a foreign firm may find that among

its potential markets, an industry in the United States may have a favorable investment

environment. The foreign firm may then decide to enter the US industry. As the first foreign firm

enters the US market, rival firms may also find the investment environment of the US industry

favorable and follow suit. The opposite may happen if a foreign firm finds a better investment

environment in markets outside the United States. A foreign firm may then find the US industry

to be unfavorable to FDI and instead consider other markets. Rival firms may also find the

investment environment in the United States to be unfavorable. Hence, rival firms may view an

industry as favorable or unfavorable to FDI depending on whether their competitors viewed an

industry as favorable or unfavorable to FDI in the previous period.

In the context of corporate rivalry in FDI, whether a foreign firm finds the investment

environment of a US industry favorable or unfavorable may depend not only on the investment

environment in the United States but also on other factors such as its home investment

environment, its interactions with its rivals in markets outside the United States and political

actions of governments affecting it but not its rivals. Since these factors include interactions

among foreign firms and governments as well as changing conditions in various markets, they

may be difficult to measure and subject to uncertainty. Hence, it is impractical to include these

factors as regressors in a model that explains FDI.9

The central focus of our paper is to re-examine the relationship between the exchange rate and

FDI taking into account the possible interdependence of FDI over time, which is described by the

Page 5: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

5

Markov zero-inflated Poisson (MZIP) model developed by Wang (2001). More specifically, we

model the interdependence of FDI over time as a two-state Markov process in which the two

states can be interpreted as either a favorable or an unfavorable environment for FDI in an

industry in the United States. The Markov process incorporates the factors affecting the two states

which are difficult to measure and subject to uncertainty. Furthermore, since the MZIP model is

first proposed for a time-series specification but we use industry-level panel data for our

empirical analysis, we formally re-define the MZIP model for panel data and conduct a

simulation study on the applicability of the MZIP model for the analysis of panel data.

Significantly, we address the reclassification of four-digit SIC industry codes after 1987 by

constructing an unbalanced panel data set - i.e. the number of industries in our sample is greater

during 1988-1994 than 1982-1987. We use as our basic empirical framework Campa’s (1993)

empirical application of the theoretical model developed by Dixit (1989). Our results clearly

show evidence of the interdependence of FDI over time as described by the two-state Markov

process and, most critically, our findings empirically re-confirm a significant impact of the real

exchange rate on FDI.

2 The Data and the MZIP Model

2.1 The FDI data

We examine the average rate of FDI in the US wholesale industry using a panel-data model that

incorporates the interdependence of the states of an industry over time. We use as our basic

empirical framework Campa’s (1993) empirical implementation of the theoretical model

developed by Dixit (1989). Our data sources and specification of empirical variables are also

based largely on Campa although there are some differences which we explain below. Above all,

we use the MZIP model whereas Campa uses the Tobit model. Following Campa, we eliminate

the influence of input origin, production location and output destination on the relationship

between FDI and exchange rate by considering FDI into the United States wholesale trade sector

Page 6: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

6

rather than the manufacturing sector. FDI data in the wholesale trade sector is from the United

States International Trade Administration (ITA) publication entitled, “Foreign Direct Investment

in the United States: Transactions.” The ITA publication includes information on the type of

investment, the name and nationality of the foreign investor, the name of the US affiliate, the US

affiliate’s four-digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) code and the value of investment in

US dollars.10 However, the ITA publication has many missing observations on the values of

investments due to confidentiality agreements with foreign investors. Because of this, we use the

number rather than the value of FDI in four-digit SIC industries in the wholesale trade sector.11

Following Tomlin, we extend the sample period to cover 1982 to 1994. 12 Due to the

reclassification of some four-digit SIC industry codes after 1987, we have 59 and 69 industries

for 1982-1987 and 1988-1994, respectively. It is important to emphasize that we handle the post-

1987 reclassification by constructing an unbalanced panel data set which contains more SIC four-

digit industries for 1988-1994 than 1982-1987.13 Fourteen additional SIC industries were created

after 1987 while four SIC industries were discontinued after 1987. For each year and each

industry, we enter as our observation the number of FDI. We have 389 non-zero entries or

observations from 1982 to 1994, which show foreign investors from 32 countries making 1,111

investments in the US wholesale trade sector. However, there are years when an industry does not

have FDI recorded in the ITA publication. When there is no FDI in a certain year, we enter zero

as our observation for that year. We have 405 zero observations and they make up 51% of our

total observations. Our sample has a size of 794 observations.

2.2. The MZIP Model for Panel Data

To formally describe the interdependence of FDI over time and to handle the excess zeros in

our data, we adopt a count data model known as the Markov zero-inflated Poisson (MZIP) model

developed by Wang (2001). The MZIP is based on the zero-inflated Poisson (ZIP) regression

models. The ZIP model is used to handle count data with excess zeros but it is not valid when

Page 7: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

7

there is interdependence of observations over time. As the ZIP model is a special case of the

MZIP model, we can compare the two models and test for the interdependence of FDI over time

by conducting the likelihood ratio test.

We extend the MZIP model developed by Wang (2001) to panel data with k subjects or

industries. Let }....,,1);,,{( iijijij njtxy = be a sequence of observed data for industry i (i = 1,

….., k), where yij is an observed FDI count associated with time exposure of tij during the jth

period and a vector of covariates ),( )2()1(ijijij xxx = for 2≥j and )2(

1)1(

1 ii xx = where the dimensions

of vectors )1(ijx and )2(

ijx are d1 and d2 respectively. The MZIP model for panel data assumes that:

(i) for an observed FDI count yij for industry i during period j, there corresponds a partially

observed binary random variable, Sij, representing the state of a two-state discrete time

Markov chain with Sij = 1 when yij > 0 and Sij = 0 when yij = 0. Furthermore, we define

the state represented by Sij = 0 as the zero state in which industry i is not favorable to

FDI, and the state represented by Sij = 1 as the Poisson state in which industry i is

favorable to FDI;

(ii) the partially observed binary random vector ).....,,,( 21 jinii SSS for industry i follows the

two-state discrete time Markov chain with transition probabilities defined by

),(log)exp(1

)exp(

)()00Pr(

)1(10)1('

0

)1('0

00)1(

ijij

ij

jiij

xitx

x

ijpSS

ββ

β≡

+=

=== −

(1)

)(1)()01Pr( 0001)1( ijpijpSS jiij −==== − (2)

)x(itlog

)xexp(1)x(exp(

)ij(p)0S0SPr(

)1(ij

'1)1(

ij'

1

)1(ij

'1

11)1j(iij

ββ

β≡

+=

=== −

(3)

)(1)()10Pr( 1110)1( ijpijpSS jiij −==== − (4)

Page 8: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

8

where ).....,,(10010 dβββ = and ).....,,(

11111 dβββ = are two unknown parameter vectors

related to the transition probabilities )(00 ijp and )(11 ijp respectively; and

(iii) conditional on Sij = 1, observed FDI count yij follows a Poisson distribution

]),([exp]),([!

1)1,,,( )2()2()2(1 ijij

yijij

ijijijiji txtx

yStxyf ij αλαλα −== (5)

where ),'(exp),(.....,,1,0 )2()2(ijijij xxy ααλ == and ).....,,(

21 dααα = is an unknown

parameter vector; conditional on ,0,0 ≡= ijij yS i.e.,

⎪⎩

⎪⎨⎧

>

===

00

01)0(0

ij

ijijij yif

yifSyf (6)

Under the above assumptions, the likelihood function of the model is

)}1,,,(

)}()([)0()]()({[

)]1,,,()0([

)2(1

11010102

00

11)2(

111)1(

11101

)1(0

=

++=+

=+==

=

=

ijiijij

ijij

n

j

iiiii

ii

k

i

i

Sjtxyf

ijpijpSyfijpijp

StxyfpSyfpl

i

α

α

(7)

Note that while )0Pr( 1)1(

0 == ii Sp and )1Pr( 1

)1(1 == i

i Sp are the unknown probabilities of the

initial states of the Markov chain for industry i, we assume that both initial states are equally

likely and set 5.0)1(1

)1(0 == ii pp . Our Monte Carlo study, which we report below, indicates that

the values of probabilities have little effect on parameter estimates for a large sample. Also, as in

Wang (2001), a sequence of repeated observations over time for a subject is modeled by the

MZIP model for a time series, and the serial dependence of repeated observations for a subject is

described by the hidden Markov chain. The series of repeated observations for different subjects

in a panel data set are assumed to be independent of each other.

As in Wang (2001), we obtain the maximum likelihood estimates using a combination of the

EM algorithm and the quasi-Newton algorithm. Although a numerical method like the quasi-

Page 9: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

9

Newton algorithm allows us to directly maximize the likelihood function (equation 7), the EM

method has at least two advantages. First, the EM algorithm is less sensitive to the starting values

of the parameters partially because the functions in the M-step of the EM algorithm are less

complex than the likelihood function. Second, the E-step of the EM algorithm produces the

estimated posterior probabilities which we can use to identify an observation as belonging to

either the zero state or the Poisson state. Finally, we test for the serial dependence of repeated

observations using the likelihood ratio test. We fit the data with an unconstrained model and an

identical model with constraints on the transition probabilities. The second model is nested in the

first, which is why we use a likelihood ratio test for inference.14

2.3 The Monte Carlo Simulation

We use Monte Carlo simulation with 2000 replicates for the MZIP to investigate the variability

of estimates, the effect of the probabilities of initial studies on parameter estimates, and some

finite-sample properties of the maximum likelihood estimates. The number of subjects or

industries k in the sample for each of the four simulations is 10, 20, 40 and 80, respectively, with

each subject or industry having 10 repeated observations. Hence the sample size n = 10k is

accordingly 100, 200, 400 and 800.

Data are generated from the MZIP model which has the Poisson rate function

)5.45.0exp(),( )2(ijij xx +−=αλ for ki .....,,1= and ,10.....,,1=j and the transition probabilities

)5.15.1(log)(00 ijxitijp −= and )22(log)(11 ijxitijp +−= for ki .....,,1= and .10.....,,2=j

Throughout, the covariate xij takes on n uniformly spaced values between 0 and 1, and the first 10

uniformly spaced values are the covariates for subject 1, the next 10 values for subject 2, and so

on. The probabilities of both initial states are 0.5. Note that the time exposure is chosen as

1=ijt for each observation. With these values, the Poisson rate function ),( )2( αλ ijx ranges from

0.38 to 7.39, with a median of 1.67. Both )(00 ijp and )(11 ijp range from 0.27 to 0.73, with a

Page 10: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

10

median of 0.5. The parameter values are chosen so that the corresponding functions can be clearly

separated.

We fit each of the 2,000 replicates to the MZIP model using two different probabilities of the

initial states: (1) ;5.0)1(1

)1(0 == ii pp and (2) )1(

0ip is generated by a (0,1) - uniform distribution.

Table 1 reports the simulation results for both probabilities. Clearly, the two probabilities yield

almost identical parameter estimates for all n, suggesting that the probabilities of the initial states

have little impact on parameter estimates when the sample size is at least 100. For all n, both the

mean and median (over 2,000 replicates) of each parameter estimate is close to the corresponding

true value. For n = 100 and 200, the standard errors (over 2,000 replicates) of the parameter

estimates in the transition probabilities are relatively large, suggesting less accuracy in the

estimation of those parameters. This is not surprising since even the standard logistic regression

maximum likelihood estimates have infinite bias in finite samples. The logistic regressions for the

transition probabilities are, of course, harder to fit than the standard logistic regressions because

the state binary random variables are only partially observable. What is encouraging, however, is

that when n > 200 all the parameters can be estimated accurately. This confirms that our

estimation algorithm is reliable. Moreover, we can accurately estimate the parameters in the

Poisson rate function even if we cannot do so for the parameters in the transition probabilities due

to small sample size.

Table 2 reports 95% confidence intervals based on the bootstrap method and normal theory for

four different sample sizes. The lower and upper limits of the bootstrap intervals are the 2.5th

percentile and 97.5th percentile of 2,000 replicates; and the lower and upper limits of the normal

intervals are calculated by the formula: mean ± 1.959964 ×standard deviation. Observe that for all

n the discrepancies between these two types of intervals for parameters in the Poisson rate

function are rather small, suggesting that the maximum likelihood estimates should be normal;

and they are relatively smaller than those for parameters in the transition probabilities. Observe

Page 11: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

11

also that the discrepancies between these two types of intervals for each parameter in the

transition probabilities are small for n = 800 and n = 400; the discrepancies for some parameters

in the transition probabilities are slightly significant for n = 200 and n = 100. These results

suggest that the maximum likelihood estimates of the parameters in the transition probabilities are

approximately normal when the sample size is at least 400, and slightly skewed when the sample

size is less than 400. They also suggest that the bootstrap intervals may be more appropriate when

the sample size is not large enough.

2.4. Vectors of covariates

As mentioned earlier, we use as our framework Campa’s empirical model and specify the two

vectors of regressors of the FDI rate function and the transition probabilities for industry i at year

t, )1(itx and )2(

itx , to be the same variables as Campa’s. We initially assume )2(it

)1(it xx = . The

vectors of regressors in our analysis are measures of exchange rate level itR , the rate of change in

the exchange rate itμ , volatility of the exchange rate itσ , sunk costs itk , and variable costs of the

US relative to foreign countries itw . We can summarize Campa’s reduced form function of FDI

projects ity to be estimated, which is instructive for our own MZIP regression, along with the

expected signs of the coefficients, as below.

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

−−+−+= ititititit

itwkR

y,,,, 2σμ

φ (7)

The definitions and computations of the three exchange rate variables – itR , itμ and itσ – are

based on Campa. More specifically, we define the exchange rate level itR as the average of the

exchange rate in the year of the FDI, itμ as the trend in exchange rate, and itσ as the standard

deviation of the monthly change in the logarithm of the exchange rate. Since itμ and itσ

incorporate firms’ expectations about the future levels of those variables, their computation

Page 12: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

12

requires assumptions about how firms form such expectations. As in Campa (1993), we make two

alternative assumptions – perfect foresight and static expectations. The former implies that firms

have perfect forecast expectations of the ex-post value of the exchange rate of the next year. The

latter implies that firms estimate the future exchange rate as the exchange rate of the year

previous to the FDI. Following Campa, the exchange rate variables are computed using monthly

index of foreign currency per US dollar and weighted by the number of FDI.15 Campa provides a

detailed discussion of the FDI weights for the exchange rate variables.16 When the number of FDI

is positive for an industry in a particular year, we calculate an effective exchange rate as the

average of the exchange rate indexes weighted by the number of FDI from a given country.

However, there are two main differences between our and Campa’s computations of the three

exchange rate variables. First, our base year for computing those variables is 1995 whereas

Campa’s base year is 1980. Second, and more importantly, we differ from Campa in terms of the

data source we use to calculate the FDI weights for the three variables when there is no FDI. If

the number of FDI is zero for an industry in a particular year, we calculate an effective exchange

rate using weights based on the total number of firms from a foreign country operating in that

industry from 1973 up to that year. We choose 1973 since it is the first year for which data are

available from the US Department of Commerce, International Trade Administration, “Foreign

Direct Investment in the United States: Completed Transactions”. This data source provides FDI

data for four-digit SIC industries. In contrast, Campa uses a data source which provides three-

digit SIC data, from which he estimates the four-digit SIC data needed to compute the FDI

weights. More specifically, Campa uses the 1980 benchmark survey of the US Department of

Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, “Foreign Direct Investment in the United States:

Operations of US Affiliates: 1977-1980”. Our FDI weights are likely to be more accurate since

our data source provides four-digit SIC data whereas Campa’s data source provides three-digit

SIC data.

Page 13: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

13

Let us now look at the variables which are not related to exchange rates, namely sunk costs and

foreign variable costs. While sunk costs are a theoretically important determinant of FDI, they are

difficult to measure empirically. We use the two empirical proxies for industry-specific sunk

costs proposed by Campa. SUNKit is the ratio of fixed assets to net wealth of all US firms in a

four-digit SIC industry and represents all the physical investments that a firm has to incur to

establish itself in the market.17 ADVit is the ratio of media expenditures to company sales by all

US firms in a four-digit SIC industry and represents largely unsalvageable non-physical

investments in advertising, sales force and media promotion.18 We compute both SUNKit and

ADVit exactly as described in Campa. Our measure of the variable production cost or labor cost,

itw , is also the same as Campa’s. However, in computing itw , we use the weighted average of

the unit labor cost indexes of eleven countries with respect to the US rather than ten as in Campa.

Furthermore, we use a more up-to-date version of Campa’s data source, namely the Bureau of

Labor Statistics, News Release 2002, Table 10. The weights are the proportion of FDI from a

given country in each four-digit SIC industry.19

4 Empirical Results

We first examine the interdependence of FDI over time for the case of static expectations,

which means that firms estimate the future exchange rate as the exchange rate of the year

previous to the FDI. To check for evidence of interdependence of FDI over time, we compare the

MZIP and the ZIP regression models using the same covariates for the average FDI rate and for

the transition probabilities and the zero probability in the MZIP and ZIP models respectively. The

parameter estimates of the unrestricted coefficients are reported in Table 3. The results show that

while the parameter estimates of the FDI rate function for both the MZIP and the ZIP models are

quantitatively similar with signs consistent with theoretical predictions, the inference about some

of the parameters differs. For example, at 10% significance level, the coefficient of the unit labor

costs is not significant for the MZIP model, but significant for the ZIP model. This suggests that

Page 14: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

14

different models for FDI may lead to different results of the inference about the parameters. The

coefficients of the exchange rate level and trend are positive while the coefficient of the exchange

rate standard deviation is negative. The coefficients of both measures of sunk costs as well as the

labor costs are negative. Since the ZIP model is nested in the MZIP model, we conduct the

likelihood ratio test which gives a test statistic of 72 and a p-value of 0.0000. This rejects the ZIP

model in favor of the MZIP model and shows the interdependence of FDI over time. This also

implies that without consideration of the interdependence of FDI the use of ZIP model may lead

to incorrect inference about the parameters.

For the MZIP with unrestricted coefficients, the t-statistics indicate significance at the 5% level

for the exchange rate trend and 1% level for the exchange rate level. Both measures of sunk costs

are significant at the 1% level. However, the exchange rate standard deviation and unit labor costs

are insignificant even at the 10% level. The bottom half of Table 3 also shows that most of the

regressors of the transition probabilities are insignificant even at the 10% level. Since our results

suggest that the coefficients of the regressors in transition probabilities may be zero, we fit the

data to a restricted MZIP regression with these coefficients equal to zero. The results of the

restricted MZIP model are also shown in Table 3. For comparison, we also run the ZIP

regression with restricted coefficients for the zero probability. As in the unrestricted models, the

inference about some of the coefficients of the regressors differs, and the ZIP model is rejected in

favor of the MZIP model using the likelihood ratio test. We also use the likelihood ratio test to

compare the unrestricted MZIP model with the restricted MZIP model. Since the log-likelihood

ratio test statistic is 16.2 with the p-value of 0.1822, we cannot reject the restricted MZIP in favor

of the unrestricted MZIP. Hence, the restricted MZIP model is more appropriate than the

unrestricted model. For the restricted model, when an industry is favorable to FDI, the average

rate of FDI is given by:

(8) itititit R σμμ 6328.07767.0008.0031.1exp( −++=

)1591.00174.00051.0 ititit ADVSUNKw −−−

Page 15: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

15

Using the logit function, we compute the transition probabilities of the restricted MZIP

model 00p , 01p , 11p and 10p to be 0.6966, 0.3034, 0.7161 and 0.2839, respectively.20 This means

that the probability that an industry is in the FDI-unfavorable state in one period when it was in

the unfavorable state in the previous period is thus 69.66% and the probability that an industry is

in the FDI-favorable state in one period when it was in the favorable state in the previous period

is thus 71.61%. Such numbers provide evidence of the interdependence of FDI over time. Our

results also imply that in the long run an industry is in the FDI-unfavorable state 51.66% of the

time, and in the FDI-favorable state 48.35% of the time as the stationary probabilities of the states

of the Markov chain are p0 = 0.5166 and p1 = 0.4835 respectively.21

We now report in Table 4 our results for the case of perfect foresight, which means that firms

have perfect forecast expectations of the ex-post value of the exchange rate of the next year. As

in the case of static expectations, we test for the interdependence of FDI over time by fitting the

data to the ZIP and MZIP models for both the unrestricted and restricted coefficients of the

transition and zero-probabilities. We then conduct the likelihood ratio test to compare the ZIP

and the MZIP models. We get a test statistic of 71.6 for the models with unrestricted coefficients

and a test statistic of 65 for the models with restricted coefficients. For the models with

unrestricted coefficients, we reject the ZIP model in favor of the MZIP model, and hence there is

strong evidence of interdependence in FDI over time.

We report the parameter estimates in Table 4 of the MZIP and ZIP models for perfect foresight.

For the model with unrestricted coefficients, our MZIP regression results for the average rate of

FDI in industries with favorable FDI environments, are largely consistent with theoretical

predictions. The coefficients of the exchange rate level and trend are positive while the

coefficients of both measures of sunk costs as well as the labor costs are negative. The exception,

the positive coefficient for the exchange rate standard deviation, is insignificant, as is unit labor

Page 16: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

16

costs. The t-statistics indicate significance at the 1% level for the exchange rate level and 10%

level for the exchange rate trend. Both measures of sunk costs are significant at the 1% level.

Such results are broadly similar to those for static expectations.

Our MZIP regression results for the transition probabilities indicate that none of the regressors

are significant. As noted above, the statistical insignificance of the regressors suggests that we

should restrict their coefficients to be zero, as we did for static expectations. Table 4 shows the

parameter estimates and log-likelihood when we do so.

To compare the two MZIP models reported in Tables 4, we conduct the likelihood ratio test.

Since the test statistic is 6.6 and the p-value is 0.8829, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that

the coefficients of the regressors of the transition probabilities are zero. This confirms that the

restricted MZIP model reported is more appropriate. For industries with favorable investment

environment, all coefficients of the regressors of the rate of FDI other than itσ have the expected

signs and the t-statistic values are also similar although the exchange rate trend is no longer

significant at the 10% level. For the restricted MZIP model with perfect foresight, when an

industry is favorable to FDI, the average rate of FDI is given by:

(9)

Using the logit function, we compute the transition probabilities 00p , 01p , 11p and 10p to be

0.6978, 0.3022, 0.7151 and 0.2839, respectively. The estimated transition probabilities strongly

support the notion that FDI may be interdependent over time. Furthermore, in the long run, each

industry will have a favorable FDI environment with a probability of 51.47% and an unfavorable

FDI environment with a probability of 48.53%.

Our two main empirical findings are the interdependence of FDI over time and a positive

relationship between the exchange rate and rate of FDI inflows for industries which are favorable

to FDI. Our computed Markov transition probabilities suggest that FDI inflows into US

itititit R σμμ 3476.03873.00091.06905.0exp( +++=

)16.00141.00028.0 ititit ADVSUNKw −−−

Page 17: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

17

wholesale trade industries may be interdependent over time because of uncertainty over whether

an industry’s environment is favorable or unfavorable to FDI. This uncertainty could be modeled

as a two-state Markov chain. More precisely, if an industry had been favorable to FDI in the

previous period, it is more likely to be favorable to FDI in this period and likewise for the

probability of an industry being unfavorable to FDI.

Our MZIP regression results show that for industries with favorable FDI environments, most of

the coefficients of the regressors of the rate of FDI have the expected signs and some of the

coefficients are highly significant. In particular, under the static expectations and, to a lesser

extent perfect foresight, the exchange rate level and trend have positive and significant impact on

the rate of FDI. This suggests that a stronger US dollar has a positive impact on the rate of FDI

into US wholesale industries. Our finding thus re-confirms the empirical results of Campa for

exchange rate level. Unlike Campa, we find a positive and significant coefficient for the trend in

the exchange rate for the model with static expectation — although it is less significant for the

model with perfect foresight — and a negative but insignificant coefficient for standard deviation

of the exchange rate. Hence, while the coefficients have the expected signs, we do not find

evidence to support Dixit’s (1989) hypothesis that exchange rate uncertainty deters the average

rate of FDI. Our findings also differ from those of Tomlin even for the ZIP regressions. Our ZIP

regression results suggest a positive significant impact of the exchange rate level on the rate of

FDI. This might seem puzzling at first since Tomlin also uses ZIP regressions. However, we

should keep in mind that we use panel data while Tomlin uses pooled cross-sectional data.

Furthermore, we address the issue of post-1987 SIC reclassifications by building up an

unbalanced panel data set and construct the three exchange rate variables on the basis of more

accurate FDI weights. Because of the existence of the interdependence of FDI over time, the

MZIP model is more appropriate than the ZIP model for the analysis of panel FDI data since the

use of the ZIP model may lead to incorrect inference about the parameters.

Page 18: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

18

5 Concluding Remarks

Common sense tells us that the real exchange rate has an effect on FDI, just as it has an effect

on international trade. A number of theoretical and empirical studies have examined the

relationship between FDI and the real exchange rate more formally. In particular, Campa

develops an empirically testable model of FDI based on Dixit’s model of investment, which in

turn, is derived from the theory of option pricing in financial economics. Campa’s model predicts,

and the empirical evidence from his Tobit estimation strongly supports, a significant effect of the

real exchange rate on the probability of FDI entry in US wholesale trade industries. However,

using the ZIP model, Tomlin fails to find a meaningful relationship between the exchange rate

and the average rate of FDI.

Our study expands the ZIP model by incorporating the possibility of interdependence of FDI

over time in each industry. To do so, we use the MZIP model, which is based on two-state

Markov chains. For empirical purposes, we extend the MZIP model, which is a time-series

specification, for panel data since we use industry-level panel data for our empirical analysis.

While our data are based largely on Campa, there are some differences. It is also important to

point out that we use an unbalanced panel data set. One of our two main empirical findings is that

FDI is indeed interdependent over time. Such interdependence captures immeasurable and

uncertain factors that affect the state of an industry – whether firms view an industry as favorable

or unfavorable to FDI – and, in turn, these views may be affected by the state of the industry in

the previous period. As mentioned earlier, corporate rivalry may explain such interdependence

since it may induce foreign firms in a particular industry to view investments in an industry as

either favorable or unfavorable in response to competition at home and abroad. Our second main

empirical finding is that when industries are favorable to FDI, the exchange rate-related variables

have positive and mostly significant impact on the rate of FDI inflows. This is especially true for

the level and to a lesser extent the trend. Among the variables not related to the exchange rate,

Page 19: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

19

both measures of sunk costs have significant negative effects on FDI.

If FDI is interdependent over time, a model such as the MZIP model that explicitly accounts for

such interdependence is more appropriate for empirical analysis of FDI. Our evidence does

indeed provide strong support for the interdependence of FDI over time, and our study suggests

that the ZIP model may be inappropriate for the analysis of panel FDI data as it may result in

incorrect inference about the parameters. In line with Campa’s findings but in contrast to

Tomlin’s findings, we find that the exchange rate, in particular the level of the exchange rate, has

a significant effect on the rate of FDI inflows into the US. Although there are theoretical grounds

for why the exchange rate level might have either a positive or negative effect on FDI, for the US

wholesale trade sector, our results clearly indicate a positive effects of both the level and the trend

in exchange rate. This implies that a stronger US dollar will promote FDI inflows into the US

wholesale trade sector. At a broader level, our analysis points to a need for future researchers to

incorporate possible interdependence in FDI over time when they examine the determinants of

FDI. Considering such a possibility will strengthen the robustness of their findings.

Page 20: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

20

References Baldwin, R., (1989). Hysteresis in import prices: The beachhead effect. American Economic

Review 78, 773-785. Baldwin, R., Krugman, P., (1989). Persistent trade effects of large exchange rate shocks.

Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, 635-654. Blonigen, B., (1997). Firm-specific assets and the link between exchange rates and foreign direct

investment. American Economic Review 87, 447-465. Campa, J., (1993). Entry by foreign firms in the United States under exchange rate uncertainty.

Review of Economics and Statistics 75, 614-622. Caves, R., (1989). Exchange-rate movements and foreign direct investment in the United States.

In: Audretsch, D., Claudon, M. (Eds.), The Internationalization of US Markets. New York University Press: New York.

Caves, R., (1971). International corporations: The industrial economics of foreign investment. Economica 38, 1-27.

Dempster, A., Laird, N., Rubin, D., (1977). Maximum likelihood from incomplete data via the EM Algorithm. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society B 39, 1-38.

Dixit, A., (1989). Entry and exit decisions under uncertainty. Journal of Political Economy 97, 620-638.

Froot, K., Stein, J., (1991). Exchange rates and foreign direct investment: An imperfect capital markets approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 1191-1217.

Guo, J., Trivedi, P., (2002). Firm-specific assets and the link between exchange rates and Japanese foreign direct investment in the United States: A re-examination. Japanese Economic Review 53, 337-349.

Kiyota, K., Urata, S., (2004). Exchange rate, exchange rate volatility and foreign direct investment. World Economy 27, 1501-1536.

Klein, M., Peek, J., Rosengren, E., (2002). Troubled banks, impaired foreign direct investment: The role of relative access to credit. American Economic Review 92, 664-682.

Klein, M., Rosengren, E., (1994). The real exchange rate and foreign direct investment in the United States: Relative wealth vs. relative wage effects. Journal of International Economics 36, 373-389.

Lambert, D., (1992). Zero-inflated Poisson regression, with an application to defects in manufacturing. Technometrics 34, 1-14.

Nash, J., (1990). Compact Numerical Methods for Computers. Adam Hilger: New York. Pindyck, R., (1991). Irreversibility, uncertainty, and investment. Journal of Economic Literature

29, 1110-1148. Tomlin, K., (2000). The effects of model specification on foreign direct investment models: An

application of count data models. Southern Economic Journal 67, 460-468. Wang, P., (2001). Markov zero-inflated Poisson regression models for a time series of counts

with excess zeros. Journal of Applied Statistics 28, 623-632.

Page 21: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

21

Table 1

The Results of the Monte Carlo Simulation Poisson Rate Transition Probabilities α1 α2 β01 β02 β11 β12

True Initial Probabilities Mean

k=80, n=800 -0.6156 4.5720 1.4251 -1.4163 -1.9809 1.9619 k=40, n=400 -0.6192 4.5756 1.4455 -1.4545 -2.0112 1.9879 k=20, n=200 -0.6428 4.6097 1.4458 -1.4566 -2.0820 2.0387 k=10, n=100 -0.6641 4.6378 1.4882 -1.5286 -2.4460 2.3969

Median k=80, n=800 -0.6137 4.5698 1.4244 -1.4168 -1.9527 1.9533 k=40, n=400 -0.6156 4.5711 1.4388 -1.4544 -1.9741 1.9565 k=20, n=200 -0.6291 4.5993 1.4462 -1.4498 -1.9197 1.8877 k=10, n=100 -0.6478 4.6250 1.4542 -1.5037 -2.0156 2.0752

Standard Deviation k=80, n=800 0.0867 0.1057 0.2807 0.4505 0.4664 0.6473 k=40, n=400 0.1265 0.1535 0.3996 0.6414 0.6851 0.9663 k=20, n=200 0.1777 0.2122 0.5651 0.8942 1.0691 1.4536 k=10, n=100 0.2479 0.2965 0.8525 1.3497 2.6273 3.1365

Random Initial Probabilities Mean

k=80, n=800 -0.6143 4.5704 1.4298 -1.4218 -1.9653 1.9435 k=40, n=400 -0.6163 4.5725 1.4496 -1.4583 -1.9978 1.9726 k=20, n=200 -0.6398 4.6072 1.4502 -1.4605 -2.0663 2.0225 k=10, n=100 -0.6623 4.6357 1.4949 -1.5352 -2.4124 2.3591

Median k=80, n=800 -0.6109 4.5649 1.4282 -1.4204 -1.9421 1.9465 k=40, n=400 -0.6114 4.5660 1.4481 -1.4515 -1.9606 1.9470 k=20, n=200 -0.6291 4.5993 1.4462 -1.4498 -1.9197 1.8877 k=10, n=100 -0.6390 4.6162 1.4584 -1.5198 -1.9876 2.0127

Standard Deviation k=80, n=800 0.1177 0.1220 0.2820 0.4515 0.4629 0.6425 k=40, n=400 0.1515 0.1675 0.4000 0.6401 0.6791 0.9583 k=20, n=200 0.2016 0.2281 0.5683 0.8980 1.0680 1.4477 k=10, n=100 0.2694 0.3119 0.8544 1.3478 2.6326 3.1373

Page 22: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

22

Table 2 95% Two-Sided Confidence Intervals Based on 2,000 Replicates

Poisson Rate Transition Probabilities Α1 α2 β01 β02 β11 β12

Bootstrap Interval k=80, n=800

lower -0.7937 4.3682 0.8865 -2.2987 -2.9855 0.7351 upper -0.4520 4.7892 1.9882 -0.5358 -1.1214 3.2954

k=40, n=400 lower -0.8685 4.2991 0.6752 -2.7130 -3.4923 0.1979 upper -0.3818 4.8724 2.2225 -0.2218 -0.8790 4.0139

k=20, n=200 lower -1.0055 4.1921 0.3565 -3.2588 -4.5045 -0.5070 upper -0.3046 5.0425 2.5610 0.2582 -0.4202 5.2757

k=10, n=100 lower -1.1911 4.0656 -0.1406 -4.2278 -7.4886 -1.7634 upper -0.2253 5.2474 3.2573 1.0266 0.2711 8.1567

Normal Interval k=80, n=800

lower -0.7856 4.3648 0.8749 -2.2994 -2.8951 0.6932 upper -0.4456 4.7792 1.9754 -0.5333 -1.0666 3.2306

k=40, n=400 lower -0.8670 4.2747 0.6622 -2.7116 -3.3541 0.0939 upper -0.3713 4.8764 2.2287 -0.1974 -0.6683 3.8819

k=20, n=200 lower -0.9910 4.1938 0.3383 -3.2093 -4.1774 -0.8102 upper -0.2946 5.0256 2.5533 0.2961 0.0134 4.8877

k=10, n=100 lower -1.1499 4.0568 -0.1828 -4.1741 -7.5954 -3.7506 upper -0.1783 5.2189 3.1591 1.1168 2.7035 8.5445

Page 23: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

23

Table 3 Markov Zero-Inflated Poisson (MZIP) and Zero-Inflated Poisson (ZIP) Regression Results for Static Expectations

Unrestricted Coefficients Restricted Coefficients Variable

MZIP ZIP MZIP ZIP

Constant 1.031** 1.076** 1.031** 1.068** Exchange rate level 0.008*** 0.008*** 0.008*** 0.008***

Trend in exchange rate 0.650** 0.742** 0.777** 0.908** Standard deviation in

exchange rate -0.400 -0.435 -0.633 -0.827

Unit Labor Costs -0.005 -0.005* -0.005 -0.006** Sunk Costs -0.018*** -0.018*** -0.017*** -0.019***

Advertising Expenses -0.163*** -0.169*** -0.159*** -0.163***

Transition Probabilities Zero-Probability Transition Probabilities Zero-Probability

00p 11p p 00p 11p p

Constant -0.066 -0.216 0.232 0.831*** 0.925*** -0.298*** Exchange rate level -0.006 0.007 -0.008*

Trend in exchange rate -2.265 3.148* -2.157** Standard deviation of

exchange rate 11.42* -1.657 5.433*

Unit Labor Costs 0.011 0.002 0.002 Sunk Costs 0.002 0.001 0.005

Advertising Expenses 0.036 0.071 -0.057

Log-likelihood -1,381.6 -1,417.6 -1,389.7 -1,425.5 Notes: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. All the variables are described in greater detail in Section 2. 00p ( 11p ) refers to the probability that an unfavorable (favorable) FDI environment in the previous period will remain unfavorable (favorable) in the current period in the MZIP model. Zero-probability, p, refers to the probability of an unfavorable FDI environment in the ZIP model.

Page 24: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

24

Table 4 Markov Zero-Inflated Poisson (MZIP) and Zero-Inflated Poisson (ZIP) Regression Results for Perfect Foresight

Unrestricted Coefficients Restricted Coefficients Variable

MZIP ZIP MZIP ZIP Constant 0.713** 0.728* 0.690 0.667

Exchange rate level 0.009*** 0.009*** 0.009*** 0.009*** Trend in exchange rate 0.399* 0.373 0.387 0.393* Standard deviation in

exchange rate 0.279 0.615 0.352 0.694

Unit Labor Costs -0.003 -0.003 -0.003 -0.003 Sunk Costs -0.017*** -0.018*** -0.018*** -0.019***

Advertising Expenses -0.164*** -0.171*** -0.160*** -0.165***

Transition Probabilities Zero-Probability Transition Probabilities Zero-Probability

00p 11p p 00p 11p p

Constant 0.998 -1.122 1.324 0.837*** 0.920*** -0.287*** Exchange rate level -0.001 0.009 -0.010**

Trend in exchange rate 0.990 0.119 -0.574 Standard deviation of

exchange rate -5.690 0.543 -0.027

Unit Labor Costs 0.004 0.010 -0.004 Sunk Costs 0.001 -0.001 0.005

Advertising Expenses 0.019 0.069 -0.055

Log-likelihood -1,388.4 -1,424.2 -1,391.7 -1,424.2 Notes: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. All the variables are described in greater detail in Section 2. 00P ( 11P ) refers to the probability that an unfavorable (favorable) FDI environment in the previous period will remain unfavorable (favorable) in the current period in the MZIP model. Zero-probability, p, refers to the probability of an unfavorable FDI environment in the ZIP model.

Page 25: The Impact of Exchange Rate on FDI and The Interdependence ... · 3 constant dollar price. Although the firm faces a certain price in US dollars, its returns in its home currency

25

Endnotes 1 Froot and Stein (1991) point out that in the presence of capital market imperfections which make external finance more costly than internal finance, a real depreciation of the US dollar increases the relative wealth of foreign firms and gives them an advantage in buying US assets. Blonigen (1997) develops a theoretical model and finds empirical support for this viewpoint. Furthermore, Klein and Rosengren (1994) note that a weaker US dollar attracts foreign capital into the US by lowering the relative labor costs of the US. 2 See Baldwin and Krugman (1989) and Baldwin (1989). 3 Pindyck (1991) provides an excellent review of the literature on investment decisions under uncertainty. 4 In addition, Campa’s model predicts a positive effect of the rate of change in the exchange rate on FDI, as well as negative effects of both the variable costs of production and sunk costs. 5 According to the literature on foreign investment, the exchange rate’s effect on the investment decision depends on the country where the good is produced, the national source of the inputs used in its production, and the country where the final good is sold. See, for example, Caves (1989). 6 For a full explanation of the empirical measures of all the variables, please refer to Campa (1993). 7 In the limited empirical literature on the link between exchange rates and FDI, Froot and Stein (1991) and Klein and Rosengren (1994) also find evidence of a significant relationship. 8 Caves points out that the existence of local production facilities can give a foreign firm a competitive edge in marketing its product. For example, local production may enable the firm to better adapt its product to the local market and provide ancillary service of higher quality or lower cost. 9 Other than political actions of governments, Caves (1971) notes that another source of uncertainty is the high costs of information about foreign markets which causes foreign firms to make FDI decisions with incomplete information but incomplete information on foreign markets is difficult to measure. Caves also mentions exchange rate changes as a source of uncertainty. However, as in Campa (1993), exchange rate uncertainty may be represented in regressions by the standard deviation of the change in the log of the exchange rate. 10 The types of investments are acquisition and mergers, equity increase, joint venture, new plant, plant expansion, real estate and other categories. 11 Other than Campa (1993), Blonigen (1997), Tomlin (2000) and Klein et al. (2002) also use the number of FDI instead of the dollar values of FDI from ITA publication. 12 The last year in our expanded sample period is 1994 since ITA stopped publishing firm-level FDI transactions that year. 13 The full list of industries for the two sub-periods is available from the authors upon request. 14 Note that the second model is equivalent to the ZIP model of Lambert (1992). Please refer to Wang (2001) for a more comprehensive discussion. 15 Source: International Monetary Fund, “International Financial Statistics,” CD-ROM -2005. 16 Please refer to page 617 of Campa (1993). 17 Source: For 1981, Robert Morris Associates (1982), “Annual Statement Studies”. For other years, Dun’s & Bradstreet, “Industry Norms and Key Business Ratios,” several issues. 18 Source: US Federal Trade Commission, Bureau of Economics, “Statistical Report: Annual Line of Business Report 1977,” Washington D.C., 1985. 19 When there is no FDI, we compute the weights as we do for the three exchange rate variables. 20 For example, 00p = logit(0.8313) = )1/( 8313.08313.0 ee + = 0.6966, 01p = 1 - 00p = 0.3034. 21 After calculating the transition probabilities, we can calculate the stationary probabilities of the two

states of the Markov chain, 0p and, 1p from ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛×⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

1

0

1

0

1110

0100

pp

pp

pppp .


Recommended